Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes"

Transcription

1 Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani, Swiss Institute of Banking and Finance, University of St. Rosenbergstr. 5, CH-9 St. Gallen, Gallen,

2 Contents 1 Introduction to Probability Theory The Binomial Model The Risky Asset The Riskless Asset A Basic No Arbitrage Condition Some Basic Remarks Pricing Derivatives: a first Example Finite Probability Spaces Measurable Spaces Probability measures Random Variables Expected Value of Random Variables Defined on Finite Measurable Spaces Examples of Probability Spaces and Random Variables with Finite Sample Space General Probability Spaces Some First Examples of Probability Spaces with non finite Sample Spaces Continuity Properties of Probability Measures Random Variables Expected Value and Lebesgue Integral Some Further Examples of Probability Spaces with uncountable Sample Spaces Stochastic Independence Conditional Expectations and Martingales 33.1 The Binomial Model Once More Sub Sigma Algebras and Partial Information

3 .3 Conditional Expectations Motivation Definition and Properties Martingale Processes Pricing Principles in the Absence of Arbitrage Stock Prices, Risk Neutral Probability Measures and Martingales Self Financing Strategies, Risk Neutral Probability Measures and Martingales Existence of Risk Neutral Probability Measures and Derivatives Pricing Uniqueness of Risk Neutral Probability Measures and Derivatives Hedging Existence of Risk Neutral Probability Measures and Absence of Arbitrage Introduction to Stochastic Processes Basic Definitions Discrete Time Brownian Motion Girsanov Theorem: Application to a Semicontinuous Pricing Model A Semicontinuous Pricing Model Risk Neutral Valuation in the Semicontinuous Model A Discrete Time Formulation of Girsanov Theorem A Discrete Time Derivation of Black and Scholes Formula Continuous Time Brownian Motion Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Starting Point, Motivation The Stochastic Integral Some Basic Preliminaries Simple Integrands

4 5..3 Squared Integrable Integrands Properties of Stochastic Integrals Itô s Lemma Starting Point, Motivation and Some First Examples A Simplified Derivation of Itô s Formula An Application of Stochastic Calculus: the Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Market Self Financing Portfolios and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model Probabilistic Interpretation of Black-Scholes Prices: Girsanov Theorem once more

5 1 Introduction to Probability Theory 1.1 The Binomial Model We start with the binomial model to introduce some basic ideas of probability theory related to the pricing of contingent claims, basically for the following reasons: It is a simple setting where the arbitrage concept and its relation to risk neutral pricing can be explained It is a model used in practice where binomial trees are calibrated to real data, for instance to price American derivatives It is a simple setting to introduce the concept of conditional expectations and martingales, which are at the hearth of the theory of derivatives pricing The Risky Asset S t is the price of a risky stock at time t I, where we start for simplicity with a discrete time index I = {, 1, }. The dynamics of S t is defined by us t 1 with probability p S t = ds t 1 with probability 1-p, where p, 1. We impose for brevity the further condition u = 1 d > 1 giving a recombining tree The Riskless Asset B t is the price at time t of a riskless money account. r > is the riskless interest rate on the money account, implying B t = 1 + r B t 1 4

6 for any t = 1,. For simplicity we impose the normalization B = A Basic No Arbitrage Condition A necessary condition for the absence of arbitrage opportunities in our model is d < 1 + r < u. 1 Example 1 In the sequel we will often use a numerical example with parameters S = 4, u = 1/d =, r = Some Basic Remarks Notice that to any trajectory T T, T H, HT, HH, in the tree we can associate the corresponding values of S 1 and S. Thus, from the perspective of time, both S 1 and S are random entities whose value depends on which event/trajectory will be realized in the model. To fully describe the random behaviour of S 1 and S we can make use of the space Ω = {T T, T H, HT, HH} of all random sequences that can be realized on the tree. Basically, Ω contains all the information about the single outcomes that can be realized in our model. Definition i The set Ω of all possible outcomes in a random experiment is called the sample space. ii Each single event ω Ω is called an outcome of the random experiment. Example 3 In the above two period model we had Ω = {T T, T H, HT, HH} and ω = T T or ω = T H or ω = HT or ω = HH. Exercise 4 Give the sample space and all single outcomes in a binomial tree with three periods Pricing Derivatives: a first Example Definition 5 An European call option with strike price K and maturity T I is the right to buy at time T the underlying stock for the price K. We denote by c t the price of the European call option at time t. 5

7 From the definition we immediately have for the pay-off at maturity of the call option: S T K S T > K c T =, S T K or, more compactly: c T = S T K +, where x + := max x, is the positive part of x. Remark 6 Notice that c T depends on ω Ω only through S T ω. The goal in any pricing model is to determined the time price as for instance the price c of a derivative payoff falling at a later time T, say as for instance the pay-off c T = S T K +. Assumption 7 To illustrate the main ideas we start with T = 1. Definition 8 A perfect hedging portfolio for c T with value V at time is a position in stock and V S money accounts recall the normalization B = 1, such that c 1 H = S 1 H + V S 1 + r c 1 T = S 1 T + V S 1 + r Remark 9 A perfect hedging portfolio replicates exactly the future pay-off of the derivative to be hedged. Therefore, it is a vehicle to fully eliminate the risk intrinsic in the randomness of the future value of a derivative. Proposition 1 i For T = 1, the quantity is given by = c 1 H c 1 T S 1 H S 1 T. 3 is called the delta of the hedging portfolio. ii The risk neutral valuation formula follows: c = V = r [ pc 1 H + 1 p c 1 T ], where p = 1 + r d u d. 6

8 Proof. i Compute the difference between the first and the second equation in and solve for. ii Insert given by 3 in one of the two equations in and solve for V. Absence of arbitrage then implies V = c. Remark 11 i The price V = c does not depend on the binomial probability p. ii Under the given conditions cf. 1 one has p, 1. Therefore the identity c = r [ pc 1 H + 1 p c 1 T ] says that the price c is a discounted expectation of the call future random pay-offs, computed using the risk adjusted probabilities p and 1 p. More compactly, we could thus write c = Ẽ c r, where Ẽ denotes expectations under p, 1 p. This is a so called risk adjusted or risk neutral valuation formula. Exercise 1 i For the case T = 1 and for the model parameters in Example 1 compute the numerical value of c. ii For the case T = compute recursively the hedging portfolio of the derivative, starting from 1 H, 1 T, V 1 H, V 1 T, and finishing with and V. 1. Finite Probability Spaces In the sequel we let Ω be a given sample space Measurable Spaces Let F be the family of all subsets of Ω; F is an example of a so called sigma algebra, a concept that we define in the sequel. Definition 13 i A sigma algebra G F is a family of subsets of Ω such that: 1. G 7

9 . If A G then it follows A c G 3. If A i i N G is a countable sequence in G, then it follows A i G i N ii The couple Ω, G is called a measurable space. Example 14 i F is a sigma algebra, the finest one on Ω. Indeed, F. Moreover, for any set A F the complement A c is a subset of Ω, i.e. is in F. The same holds for any not only for a countable union of sets in F. ii The subfamily G := {, Ω} is the coarsest sigma algebra on Ω. iii In the setting of the binomial model of Example 1, it is easy to verify please do it! that the subfamily G := {, Ω, {HT, HH}, {T T, T H}}, is a sigma algebra, the sigma algebra generated by the first period price movements in the model. Remark 15 We make use of sigma algebras to model different information sets at the disposal of the investor in doing her portfolio choices. For instance, in the setting of the binomial model of Example 1, the information available at time before observing prices can be modelled by the trivial information set G := {, Ω}. That is, at time investors only know that the possible realized outcome ω has to be an element of the sample space Ω. At time 1 investors can observe S 1. Thus, depending on the value of S 1 they will know at time 1 that either ω {HT, HH} if and only if S 1 ω = S u, or ω {T T, T H} if and only if S 1 ω = S d. 8

10 Thus at time 1 investors do not have full information about ω, since they still do not know the direction of the price movement in period. However, they can determine to which specific event of their information set ω belongs. The larger smaller this set, the preciser the rougher the information on the realized outcome ω. For instance, while at time investors only know that the outcome will be an element of the sample space, at time 1 they know that the outcome implies either an upward or a downward price movement in the first period. Based on these considerations a natural sigma algebra G 1 to model investors price information at time 1 is G 1 := {, Ω, {HT, HH}, {T T, T H}}, verify that G 1 is indeed a sigma algebra. Similarly, by observing only the price S investors will know at time that either ω = HH if and only if S ω = S u, or ω = T T if and only if S ω = S d, or ω {T H, HT } if and only if S ω = S du. On the other hand, by observing the prices S 1 and S investors will know at time ω = HH if and only if S ω = S u, or ω = T T if and only if S ω = S d, or ω = T H if and only if S 1 ω = S d and S ω = S du, or ω = HT if and only if S 1 ω = S u and S ω = S du. 9

11 Based on these considerations a natural sigma algebra G to model investors price information up to time is the smallest one containing the system of subsets of Ω given by E := {, Ω, {HT }, {HH}, {T T }, {T H}}. We denote this sigma algebra by G = σ E. Finally, the sigma algebra representing the information obtained by observing only the price S is G 3 = {, Ω, {HH}, {T H, HT, T T }, {T T }, {T H, HT, HH}, {T H, HT }, {T T, HH}} Notice that while the relation G G 1 G implies an information set growing over time, we do not have G 1 G 3 why?. Therefore, the sequence of sigma algebras G, G 1, G 3 is not consistent with the idea of an investor s information set growing over time. Exercise 16 Borel sigma algebra on R Let Ω := R and denote by T the set of all open intervals in R T = {a, b a b, a, b R}. 1. Show with a simple counterexample that T is not a sigma algebra on R.. We know that there does exist a sigma algebra over R containing T which one?. Thus, there also exists a minimal sigma algebra containing T, the so-called Borel sigma algebra over R denoted by B R which has to be of the form B R = G is σ algebra over R T G G To show that B R is indeed a sigma algebra over R it is thus sufficient to show that intersections of sigma algebras are sigma algebras. Do this, by verifying the corresponding definition. 3. Show, using simple set operations, that the events, a, a,, [a, b], a, b], {a}, where a b, are elements of B R. 1

12 4. Show that any countables subset {a i } i N of R is an element of B R. As mentioned, a natural way to model a growing amount of information over time is through increasing sequences of sigma algebras. This is the next definition. Definition 17 Let Ω, G be a measurable space. A sequence G i i=,1,...,n of sigma algebras over Ω such that G G 1... G n G, is called a filtration. Example 18 In Remark 15 the sequence G i i=,1, is a filtration, while the sequence G i i=,1,3 is not. 1.. Probability measures For the whole section let Ω, G be a measurable space. Definition 19 We say that an event A G is realized in a random experiment with sample space Ω if ω A. Example In the two period binomial model we have {T H, T T } = {The stock price drops in the first period}. Thus, if a time 1 we observe T, {T H, T T } is realized. On the other hand, if we observe H, then {T H, T T } is not realized i.e. A c = {HT, HH} is realized. The next step is to assign in a consistent way probabilities to events that can be realized in a random experiment. 11

13 Definition 1 i A probability measure on Ω, G is a function P : G [, 1] such that: 1. P Ω = 1. For any disjoint sequence A i i N G such that A i A j = for i j it follows P A i = P A i. i N i N This property is called sigma additivity. ii We call a triplet Ω, G, P a probability space. Example In the two period binomial model we set Ω = {T T, T H, HT, HH}, G = F, and define probabilities with the binomial rule P HH = p, P T T = 1 p, P T H = P HT = p 1 p. The sigma additivity then implies, for instance P HT, HH = P HH + P HT = p + p 1 p. More generally, we have, in this finite sample space setting: P A = ω A P ω Proposition 3 Let Ω, G, P be a probability space. We have: 1. P A\B = P A P A B. P A B = P A + P B P A B 3. P A c = 1 P A 4. If A B then P A P B 1

14 Proof. 1. A\B = A B c and A = A B A B c. By sigma additivity if follows: P A = P A B + P A B c = P A B + P A\B.. A B = A\B B. Therefore, using 1 and by sigma additivity: P A B = P A\B + P B = P A + P B P A B. 3. This is a particular case of 1. with A = Ω and B = A. 4. By 1. we have, under the given assumption: P B = P B A + P B\A = P A + P B\A P A. Remark 4 In Definition 1, the condition 1. for a probability measure implies the condition, 1. P =. In fact, a function µ : G [, ] satisfying condition 1. and. in Definition 1 is called a measure on the measurable space Ω, G. Notice, that in this case we can have µ Ω =. Exercise 5 The Lebesgue measure on the measurable space R, B R denoted by µ is a measure µ : B R [, ] such that µ a, b = b a for any open interval a, b, a b. It can be shown that Lebesgue measure exists and is unique we will not prove this, we will just assume it in the sequel. Show the following properties of Lebesgue measure, using the general definition of a measure. 1. µ =, µ R + =. µ {a} = for any a R 3. For any countable subset {a i } i N of R one has µ {ai } i N =. 13

15 1..3 Random Variables For the whole section let Ω, G be a measurable space such that the cardinality of Ω is finite Ω <. We will extend the concept of a random variable to non finite sample spaces in a later section. Definition 6 Let X : Ω R be a function from Ω to the real line. i The sigma algebra σ X := { X 1 B : B is a subset of R }, where X 1 B is a short notation for the preimage {ω : X ω B} of B under X, is called the sigma algebra generated by X. ii X is called a random variable on Ω, G if it is measurable with respect to G, that is if σ X G. Remark 7 i It is useful to know some properties of preimages. We have for any subset B of R, and for any non necessarily countable sequence B α α A of subsets of R: X 1 B c = X 1 B c X 1 B α = X 1 B α α A X 1 α A B α = X 1 B α α A α A ii σ X is a sigma algebra. Indeed, = X 1 σ X. Moreover, if A = X 1 B for some subset of R, then A c = X 1 B c = X 1 B c σ X, because B c is a subset of R. Similarly, given a sequence A i i N such that A i = X 1 B i for a sequence of subsets B i i N of R we have: A i = X 1 B i = X 1 B i σ X, i N i N i N because i N B i is a subset of R. iii σ X represents the partial information set that is available about an outcome ω Ω by observing the values of X. 14

16 Example 8 In the two period binomial model S, S 1 and S are all trivially measurable with respect to the finest sigma algebra F over Ω. However, since S is constant we have σ S = {, Ω} = G, and S is G measurable. Further, σ S 1 = {, Ω, {HT, HH}, {T T, T H}} = G 1, and S 1 is G 1 but not G measurable. Finally, σ S = {, Ω, {HH}, {T H, HT, T T }, {T T }, {T H, HT, HH}, {T H, HT }, {T T, HH}} = G 3. Therefore, S is G 3 but not G 1 measurable. On the other hand, S 1 is G 1 but not G 3 measurable why? Expected Value of Random Variables Defined on Finite Measurable Spaces For the whole section let Ω, G, P be a probability space such that the cardinality of Ω is finite Ω <. We will extend the concept of expected value of a random variable to the non finite sample space setting in a later section. Further, let X : Ω, G R be a random variable. Definition 9 i The expected value E X of a random variable X defined on a finite sample space is given by E X := ω Ω X ω P ω. ii The variance V ar X of X is given by [ V ar X := E X E X ] = E X E X. 15

17 Example 3 In the two period binomial model of Example 1 we have: S HH = 16 ; P HH = p S HT = S T H = 4 ; P T H = P HT = p 1 p S T T = 1 ; P HH = 1 p Therefore, E S = 16 p + 4 p 1 p p 1..5 Examples of Probability Spaces and Random Variables with Finite Sample Space Example 31 The Bernoulli distribution with parameter p is a probability measure P on the measurable space Ω, G given by Ω := {, 1}, G := F, such that: P 1 = p, 1. Example 3 The Binomial distribution with parameters n and p is a probability measure P on a measurable space Ω, G given below. The sample space is given by Ω := {n dimensional sequences with components or 1}. For instance, a possible element of Ω is ω = }{{} n components. Further, we set G := F. Finally, P is given by P ω = p # of 1 in ω 1 p # of in ω. For instance, using the properties of a probability measure we have: P at least a 1 over the n components = 1 P no 1 over the n components = 1 1 p n, 16

18 and so forth. Example 33 A discrete uniform distribution modelling the toss of a fair die is obtained by setting Ω := {1,, 3, 4, 5, 6}, G := F, and P ω = 1 6, ω Ω. For instance, using the properties of a probability measure we then have: P obtaining an even number = P + P 4 + P 6 = 1, and so forth. Example 34 A discrete uniform distribution modelling the toss of two independent fair dies is obtained by setting Ω := {11, 1, 13, 14, 15, 16, 1,,..., 66} G := F, and P ω = 1 36, ω Ω. For instance, using the properties of a probability measure we then have: P the sum of the two numbers is larger than 1 = P 66 + P 56 + P 65 = 1 1, and so forth. Let X : Ω {, 3, 4,.., 1} be the function giving the sum of the numbers on the two dies. We have: σ X =, Ω, {11} }{{} X 1 that is X is a random variable on Ω, F., {1, 1}, {13, 31, },... }{{}}{{} F, X 1 3 X General Probability Spaces Definition 1 of a probability space does not require the assumption Ω <. 17

19 1.3.1 Some First Examples of Probability Spaces with non finite Sample Spaces A first simple example of a probability space defined on a non finite sample space is the following. Example 35 Let Ω = R, G = B R and define P A = µ A [, 1]. P is a probability measure, the uniform distribution on the interval [, 1]. Indeed, we have: 1. P Ω = µ Ω [, 1] = µ [, 1] = 1.. For any disjoint sequence A i i N B R it follows P i N A i = µ i N A i [, 1] = µ i N A i [, 1] = i N µ A i [, 1] = i N P A i More generally, setting P A = µ A [a, b] µ [a, b], defines a uniform distribution on the interval [a, b]. A famous example of a probability space with non finite sample space is the one underlying a Poisson distribution on N. Example 36 Let Ω := N and G := F. Thus in this case Ω is an infinite, countable, sample space. We define for any ω Ω Setting for A F P ω := λω ω! e λ, λ >. P A := ω A P ω, one obtains the Poisson distribution on N, F with parameter λ. P is a probability measure on Ω, F. Indeed, we have P Ω = ω Ω P ω = k= λ k k! e λ = 1, 18

20 and, for any disjoint sequence A i i N F, P A i = P ω = P ω = P A i. i N ω S i N Ai i N ω A i i N The last example of a probability space with non finite sample space that we present is the one underlying a Binomial experiment where n. Example 37 Let Ω := {T, H} be the space of infinite sequences with components T or H. Thus any outcome ω Ω is of the form ω = ω i i N, ω i {T, H}. This is an infinite, uncountable, sample space. Therefore, some caution is needed in constructing a suitable sigma algebra on Ω, on which we are enabled in a second step to extend the binomial distribution in a consistent way. We define G n := {The sigma algebra generated by the first n tosses}, for any n N. For instance, we obtain for G 1 : G 1 = {, Ω, {ω Ω : ω 1 = T }, {ω Ω : ω 1 = H}}, and so on for n > 1. We know that there is a sigma algebra F over Ω such that G n F for all n N. However, this sigma algebra is too large to assign binomial probabilities on it in a consistent way. Therefore, we work in the sequel with the smallest sigma algebra containing all G n s. We define G := H, H n N G n H is sigma algebra over Ω the sigma algebra generated by n N G n. Notice that G contains events that can be quite rich and that do not belong to any G n, n N. An example of such an event is A := {H on every toss} = {ω Ω : ω i = H for all i N} = {ω Ω : ω i = H for i n} G, }{{} n N G n 19

21 where {ω Ω : ω i = H for i n} = {H on the first n tosses}. We now define a probability measure P on G whose restriction on any G n is a binomial distribution with parameters n and p. Precisely, define for any A G n and some given n N P A = p # of H in the first n tosses 1 p # of T in the first n tosses. For instance, for the event {H on the first tosses} = {ω Ω : ω i = H for i }, we obtain P H on the first tosses = p, and so forth. Using the properties of a probability measure we can then uniquely extend P to all of G. For instance, we have P H on all tosses P H on the first n tosses = p n, for all n N. Therefore, for p, 1 it follows P H on all tosses = Continuity Properties of Probability Measures Two further continuity properties of a probability measure - in excess of the properties in Proposition 3 - are useful when working with countable set operations over monotone sequences of events. They are given below. Proposition 38 Let A n n N G be a countable sequence of events. It then follows: 1. If A 1 A..., then: continuity from below. P A n P n A n n N,

22 . If A 1 A..., then: continuity from above. P A n P n A n n N Proof. 1. Let A := n N A n. We have, A = n N A n \A n 1, where A :=. Thus, under the given assumption the event A is written as a countable, disjoint, union of subsets of G. It then follows using the properties of a probability measure P A = n N P A n \A n 1 = n N P A n P A n 1 = lim n P A n P A = lim n P A n.. We have P A n P n n N A n P A c n P n c A n = P n N n N A c n, by de Morgan s law. The proof now follows from Random Variables For the whole section let Ω, G, P be a probability space and R, B R be a Borel measurable space over R. When working with uncountable sample spaces, the measurability requirement behind Definition 6 of a random variable for finite sample spaces has to be modified. Basically, we are going to require measurability only for preimages of any Borel subset of R, rather than measurability for preimages of any subset of R. This is a necessary step, in order to be able to assign consistently probabilities to Borel events determined by the images of some random variable on Ω, G, P. Definition 39 Let X : Ω R be a real valued function. i The sigma algebra σ X := { X 1 B : B B R }, 1

23 is the sigma algebra generated by X. ii X is a random variable on Ω, G if σ X G. Example 4 For a set A Ω let a function 1 A : Ω {, 1} be defined by 1 ω A 1 A ω =. otherwise 1 A is called the indicator function of the set A. We have please verify σ 1 A = {, Ω, A, A c }. Hence, 1 A is a random variable over Ω, G if and only if A G. The measurability property in Definition 44 allows us to assign in a natural way probabilities also to Borel events that are induced by images of random variables, as is illustrated in the next example. Example 41 Let X be a random variable on a probability space Ω, F, P. For any event B B R we define L X B := P X 1 B. 4 L X is a probability measure on B R, the probability distribution of X or the probability induced by X on B R. Remark, that 4 is well defined, precisely because of the measurability of the random variable X. Showing that L X is indeed a probability measure is very simple. In fact, we have: L X R = P X 1 R = P X R = P Ω = 1. Moreover, for any sequence B i i N of disjoint events we obtain: L X B i = P X 1 B i = P X 1 B i = P X 1 B i = L X B i, i N i N i N i=1 i=1 using in the third equality the fact that B i i N and thus also X 1 B i is a sequence of i N disjoint events.

24 Checking measurability of a candidate random variable can be by definition a quite hard and lengthy task, since we have to check preimages of any Borel subset of R. Fortunately, the next result offers a much easier criterion by which measurability is easy to verify in many applications. Proposition 4 For a function X : Ω R let E := { X 1, t : t R } = {{X < t} : t R}, be the set of preimages of open intervals of the form, t under X. Then it follows: E G σ X G. Proof. Define: H := { B B R : X 1 B G } B R. It is sufficient to show that under the given conditions B R H, i.e. B R = H. We start by showing that H is a sigma algebra. We have first X 1 = G, hence H. Second, for a set B H it follows X 1 B c = X 1 B }{{} G Finally, for a sequence B n n N H we have c G. X 1 B n = X 1 B n G, }{{} n N n N G showing that H is a sigma algebra as claimed. Since B R is by definition the smallest sigma algebra containing all open intervals on the real line it is sufficient to show that under the given conditions H contains all open intervals on the real line. To this end, recall that all sets of the form, t are by assumption elements of H. For a general open interval a, b, a b it then 3

25 follows: X 1 a, b = X 1, b = X 1, b n N n N = X 1, b }{{} n N G This concludes the proof of the proposition., a + 1 c n, a + 1 c n X 1 c, a + 1 n G. } {{ } G Example 43 Let X n n N be an arbitrary sequence of random variables on Ω, G. It then follows: 1. ax 1 + bx is a random variable for any a, b R. sup n N X n and inf n N X n are random variables 3. lim sup X n := lim n sup k n X k and lim inf X n := lim n inf k n X k are random variables. Proof. We apply several times Proposition For a, b we have {ax 1 + bx < t} = r Q For statement. we obtain: { } sup X n < t n N {ax 1 < r} {bx < t r} = r Q = {X n < t} G, }{{} n N G { X 1 < r } }{{ a } G { X < t r } G. b }{{} G { } inf X n < t = {X n < t} G. n N }{{} n N G 3. For any n N it follows that Y n := sup k n X k and Z n := inf k n X k are random variables, by. Moreover, the sequences Y n n N and Z n n N are monotonically decreasing and increasing, respectively. Thefore: This concludes the proof. {lim sup X n < t} = {lim inf X n < t} = { } lim Y n < t n { } lim Z n < t n = {Y n < t} G. }{{} n N G = {Z n < t} G. }{{} n N G 4

26 1.3.4 Expected Value and Lebesgue Integral For the whole section let Ω, G, P be a probability space and R, B R be the Borel measurable space over R. The expected value of a general random variable is defined as its Lebesgue integral with respect to some probability measure P on Ω, G. More generally, Lebesgue integrals of measurable functions can be defined with respect to some measure as for instance Lebesgue measure µ defined on a corresponding measurable space as for instance the measurable space R, B R. The construction of the Lebesgue integral for a general random variable X starts by defining the value of the Lebesgue integral for linear combinations of indicator functions, goes over to extend the integral to functions that are pointwise monotonic limits of sequences of simple functions, and finally defines the integral for the more general case of an integrable random variable see below the precise definition. Definition 44 i A random variable X is simple if X = where n N, c 1,.., c n R, and A 1,.., A n G n c i 1 Ai, i=1 are mutually disjoint events. The vector space of simple random variables on Ω, G is denoted by S G.The expected value E X of a simple function X is defined by E X := Ω XdP := n c i P A i. ii Let X be a non negative random variable. The expected value E X of X is defined by E X := iii A random variable X is integrable, if Ω i=1 { } XdP := sup Y dp : Y X and Y S G Ω. E X + <, E X <, where X + := max X, and X := max X, are the positive and negative part of X, respectively. We denote the vector space of integrable random variable by L 1 P. For any X L 1 P 5

27 the expected value E X of X is defined by E X = E X + E X. iv Finally, for a random variable X L 1 P and a set A G we define A XdP := Ω 1 A XdP Remark 45 i The key point in the definition of E X is iii. In fact, iii is a quite reasonable definition because for any random variable X there always exists a sequence X n n N of simple random variables converging monotonically pointwise to X from below. Such a sequence is obtained for instance by setting for any ω Ω X n ω = n n k=1 k 1 n 1 { k 1 n <X k n } ω + n1 {X>n} ω. Moreover, it can be shown that the limit of the sequence of integrals E X n does not depend on the choice of the specific approximating sequence. Therefore, iii in Definition 44 could be also equivalently written as E X := lim E X n := lim X n dp, n n Ω for a given approximating sequence X n n N. ii As mentioned, expected values are by definition just integrals of measurable functions with respect to some probability measure. In fact, the definition of the Lebesgue integral of a measurable function with respect to some measure µ, say, follows exactly the same steps as above, readily by replacing everywhere the probability measure P with the measure µ in i, ii, iii and iv. Let us discuss some first very simple examples of expected values computed using the above definitions. Example 46 Let Ω := R, G := B R and set for any A G P A = µ A [, 1]. 6

28 The expected value of X := 1 Q is E X = 1 µ Q [, 1] =, because Q is a countable set. Notice, that this function is not Riemann integrable in the usual sense. The expected value of ω = Y ω := otherwise, can be computed as the limit of the expected values in an approximating sequence X n n N of simple functions given by Hence: n ω = X n ω := otherwise. E Y = lim n E X n = lim n n µ {} [, 1] = lim n n µ {} =. Notice, that also Y is not Riemann integrable in the usual sense. The basic properties of the above integral definition are collected in the next proposition. Proposition 47 Let X,Y L 1 P and a,b R; it then follows: 1. E ax + by = ae X + be Y. If X Y pointwise, then E X E Y 3. For two sets A, B G such that A B = it follows A B XdP = Ω 1 A B XdP = Ω 1 A + 1 B XdP = 1. A XdP + XdP. B 7

29 Proof. 1. For brevity we show this property only for indicator functions X = 1 A, Y = 1 B, where A, B G are disjoint events. We have E ax + by = E a1 A + b1 B = Def ii ap A+bP B = ae 1 A +be 1 B = ae X+bE Y.. If Y X, then there exists a sequence of simple approximating functions X n converging monotonically to Y X. This implies: E Y E X = 1. E Y X = lim E X n = lim n n say, because for any n N we have c 1n,.., c kn n. k n i=1 c in P A in, Some Further Examples of Probability Spaces with uncountable Sample Spaces For the whole section let Ω, G, P be a probability space and R, B R be the Borel measurable space over R. Using Lebesgue integrals we are also able to construct probability measures by integrating a suitable density function over events A G. A well-known example in this respect arises by integrating the density function of a standard normal distribution. Example 48 Ω, G := R, B R; φ : R R + is defined by φ x = 1 exp x π, x R. φ is the density function of a standard normally distributed random variable and is such that R φ x dµ x = φ x dx = 1, i.e. φ L 1 µ. A standard normal probability distribution P on R, B R is obtained by setting for any A G: P A := φ x dµ x. A It is straightforward to verify, using the basic properties of Lebesgue integrals together with some monotone convergence property, that P is indeed a probability measure. 8

30 More generally, densities can be also defined on abstract probability spaces, as is demonstrated in the next final example. Example 49 Let X be a random variable on Ω, G such that X L 1 P, and define Q A := E 1 AX E X X = E 1 A E X. It is easy to verify, using the basic properties of Lebesgue integrals together with some monotone convergence property, that Q is a further probability measure on Ω, G. Moreover, the absolute continuity property P A = Q A =, follows from the definition. If, moreover, P A = Q A = the probabilities Q and P are called equivalent. This property holds when X >. The random variable Z := X EX By construction dq dp is called the Radon Nykodin derivative of Q with respect to P, denoted by dq dp. dq is a density function on Ω, G because dp and E dq X = E = 1. dp E X 1.4 Stochastic Independence For the whole section let Ω, G, P be a probability space Definition 5 Two events A, B G are stochastically independent if P A B = P A P B. 5 We use the notation A B to denote two independent events. 9

31 Remark 51 Condition 5 states that two events are independent if and only if their conditional and unconditional probabilities are the same, i.e.: P A B := P A B P B P A P B = = P A, A B P B provided of course P B >. This property is symmetric in A, B. Example 5 Stochastic independence is a feature determined by the structure of the underlying probability P. As an illustration of this fact consider again the two period binomial model of Example 1. We have there: P HH, HT P HT, T H = p + p 1 p p 1 p = p 1 p, 6 and P {HH, HT } {HT, T H} = P HT = p 1 p. 7 Therefore, 6 and 7 are equal if and only if p = 1, that is the only binomial probability under which the above events are independent is the one implied by p = 1. The concept of stochastic independence between events can be naturally extended to stochastic independence between information sets, i.e. sigma algebras. Definition 53 Two sigma algebras G 1, G G are stochastically independent if for all A G 1 and B G one has A B. We use the notation G 1 G to denote independent sigma algebras. Example 54 In the two period binomial model of Example 1 we define the two following sigma algebras: G 1 := {, Ω, {HT, HH}, {T T, T H}}, the sigma algebra generated by the first price increment, and G := {, Ω, {HH, T H}, {T T, HT }}, 3

32 the sigma algebra generated by the second price movement. We then have, for any p [, 1]: G 1 G. For instance, for the sets {HT, HH} and {HH, T H} one obtains P HT, HH P HH, T H = p + p 1 p p + p 1 p = p, and P {HT, HH} {HH, T H} = P HH = p. These features derive directly from the way how probabilities are assigned by a binomial distribution where P ω = p # of H in ω 1 p # of T in ω. Finally, we can also define independence between random variables as independence of the information sets they generate. Definition 55 Two random variables X,Y on Ω, G, P are independent if σ X σ Y. We use the notation X Y to denote independence between random variables. Example 56 We already discussed that the two sigma algebras G 1, G of Example 54 are independent in the binomial model. Notice that we have please verify! G 1 = {, Ω, {HT, HH}, {T T, T H}} = σ S 1 /S, and G := {, Ω, {HH, T H}, {T T, HT }} = σ S /S 1. Therefore, the stock price returns S 1 /S and S /S 1 in a binomial model are stochastically independent. 31

33 Example 57 Let A, B G be two independent events and let the functions 1 ω A 1 ω B 1 A ω =, 1 B ω = otherwise otherwise, be the indicator functions of the sets A and B, respectively. We then have please verify: σ 1 A = {, Ω, A, A c }, σ 1 B = {, Ω, B, B c }. Therefore, 1 A 1 B if and only if A B please verify. Some properties related to independence are important. The first one says that independence is maintained under measurable transformations. Proposition 58 Let X,Y be independent random variables on Ω, G, P and h, g : R R be two measurable functions. It then follows: h X g Y. Proof. We give a graphical proof of this statement, which makes use of the fact that preimages of composite mappings are contained in the preimage of the first function in the composition: σ X By assumption σ Y. σ h X σ g Y The second important property of stochastic independence is related to the expectation of a product of random variables. Proposition 59 Let X,Y be independent random variables on Ω, G, P. It then follows E XY = E X E Y. Proof. For the sake of brevity we give the proof for the simplest case where X = 1 A, Y = 1 B, for events A, B G such that A B. As usual, the extension of this result for more general 3

34 setting requires considering linear combinations of indicator functions, i.e. simple functions, and pointwise limits of simple functions. For the given simplified setting we have: E XY = E 1 A 1 B = E 1 A B = 1 P A B + P A B c = P A B = A B P A P B = E 1 A E 1 B = E X E Y. This concludes the proof. Conditional Expectations and Martingales For the whole section let Ω, G, P be a probability space.1 The Binomial Model Once More For later reference, we summarize the structure of a general n period binomial model, since it will be used to illustrate some of the concepts introduced below. I := {, 1,,.., n} is a discrete time index representing the available transaction dates in the model The sample space is given by Ω := {Sequences of n coordinates H or T } with single outcomes ω of the form for instance. ω = T T T H..HT }{{} n coordinates, G := F, the sigma algebra of all subsets of Ω Dynamics of the stock price and money account: us t 1 with probability p S t = with probability 1 p ds t 1, B t = 1 + r B t 1 33

35 for given B = 1, S and where u = 1/d, u > 1 + r > d. The sequence S t t=,..,n is a sequence of random variables defined on a single probability space Ω, G, P. This is an example of a so called stochastic process on Ω, G, P. Associated with stochastic processes are flows of information sets i.e. sigma algebras generated by the process history up to a given time. For instance, for any t I we can define t G t := σ σ S, σ S 1,.., σ S t := σ σ S k k=, the smallest sigma algebra containing all sigma algebras generated by S, S 1,...,S t. G t represents the information about a single outcome ω Ω which can be obtained exclusively by observing the price process up to time t. Clearly, G t G s t s. Therefore, the sequence G t t=,..,n constitutes a filtration, the filtration generated by the process S t t=,..,n.. Sub Sigma Algebras and Partial Information We model partial information about single outcomes ω Ω or about single events A G using sub sigma algebras of G. Example 6 Let X be a random variable on Ω, G. Then σ X is by definition a sub sigma algebra of G. σ X represent the partial information about an outcome ω Ω which can be obtained by observing X ω. For instance, set n = 3 in the above binomial model and consider the outcome ω = T T T. By observing S 1, i.e. using σ S 1 as the available information set we can only conclude ω {T T T, T HH, T HT, T T H} S 1 ω = S d. 34

36 However, when observing all price movements from t = to t = 3 we can make use of the sigma algebra 3 G 3 := σ σ S t, t= to fully identify ω Ω. Both σ S 1 and G 3 are sub sigma algebras of G, which however represent different pieces of information about ω Ω Based on the above simple considerations we can now formally define what it means for an event to be realized. Definition 61 i An event A G is realized by means of a sub sigma algebra G G if A G. ii Let G t be a sigma algebra generated by some price process 1 up to time t. We say that A is realized by means of the price information up to time t if A G t. Remark 6 By definition, realization of an event A G by means of G is precisely measurability of that event with respect to the sub sigma algebra G. Precisely, given an event A G we can determine it uniquely using G, i.e. we can say that A has been realized, if and only if A G. For instance, in the above 3 period binomial model we can consider the event A = {T T T }. Clearly, A / σ S 1 since we do not know using σ S 1 the value of the second and the third coin tosses. Therefore, A is not realized by means of σ S 1, i.e. it is not realized by means of the price information up to time 1. However, 3 A G 3 := σ σ S t t=, i.e. A is realized by means of the whole price information available up to time 3. Example 63 The event {The first two price returns are both positive} is realized by means of the price information up to time, while the event {The total number of positive price returns is } is not. 1 See for instance the above examples. 35

37 .3 Conditional Expectations For the whole section let X be a random variable on Ω, G..3.1 Motivation Given an event A = X 1 a G, for some a R, we are always able to identify for any ω A the corresponding value X ω of the random variable X using the information set G. Indeed, we then have by definition ω X 1 a G, i.e. X ω = a, σx G for all ω A. However, using a coarser information set G σ X it may happen that we are not able to fully determine the value X ω that a random variable X associates to a given single outcome ω A. Specifically, it may happen that based on the information available in G we can only state for some non singleton set B B R ω X 1 B, i.e. X ω B. 8 In this case, the information set G is not sufficiently fine to fully determine the precise value of X ω associated with a specific ω A. Thus, the goal in such a situation is to define a suitable candidate prediction E X G ω for the unknown value X ω based on the information G. We will call E X G the conditional expectation of X conditionally on G. Notice, that a first necessary requirement on E X G is that it can be fully determined using the information G, that is it has to be G measurable. Further, a natural idea to compute the prediction E X G as an unbiased forecast such that the expectation of E X G and X agree on all sets A G : E X G dp = XdP see below the precise definition. A A 36

38 .3. Definition and Properties Definition 64 Let G G be a sub sigma algebra. The conditional expectation E X G of X conditioned on the sigma algebra G is a random variable satisfying: 1. E X G is G measurable. For any A G : E X G dp = XdP, A A partial averaging property. In the sequel, we write for any further random variable Y on Ω, G: E X Y := E X σ Y Remark 65 i E X G exists, provided X L 1 P ; this is a consequence of the so called Radon Nykodin Theorem. ii The random variable E X G is unique, up to events of zero probability. Precisely, if Y and Z are two candidate G measurable random variables satisfying. of the above definition, then: P Y = Z = 1 Example 66 i If G = {, Ω} then E X G = E X 1 Ω, that is conditional expectations conditioned on trivial information sets are unconditional expectations. Indeed, E X 1 Ω is G measurable and E X 1 Ω dp = E X P Ω = E X = XdP Ω Ω ii If X is G measurable then E X G = X, that is if the conditioning information set is sufficiently fine to determine X completely then conditional expectations of a random variable are the random variable itself. Indeed, in this case we trivially have: E X G dp = XdP, for any set A G. A A 37

39 Proposition 67 Let G G be a sub sigma algebra and X, Y L 1 P. It then follows: 1. E E X G = E X Law of Iterated Expectations.. For any a, b R: E ax + by G = ae X G + be Y G, Linearity. 3. If X then E X G with probability 1 Monotonicity. 4. For any sub sigma algebra H G : E E X G H = E X H, Tower Property. 5. If σ X G then E X G = E X 1 Ω, Independence. 6. If V is a G measurable random variable such that V X L 1 P then E V X G = V E X G Proof. 1. Set A = Ω G ; by definition in then follows E X = Ω XdP = Ω E X G dp = E E X G.. By construction ae X G + be Y G is G measurable. Moreover, for any A G : A ae X G + be Y G dp = a = a = 38 A A A E X G dp + b XdP + b Y dp A ax + by dp, A E Y G dp

40 using in the first and the third equality the linearity of Lebesgue integrals and in the second equality the definition of conditional expectations. 3. Let A := {E X G < } G. Then, E X G dp = XdP, A A since X and by the monotonicity of Lebesgue integrals. Further, the monotonicity of Lebesgue integrals also implies A E X G dp, since 1 A E X G <. Therefore, A E X G dp =, implying P A =. 4. E X H is by definition H measurable. Further, for any A H: A E X H dp = A XdP = A E X G dp =: Y dp, A since A G because H G. By definition, this implies that E X H is the conditional expectation of the random variable Y := E X G conditioned on the sigma algebra H. 5. E X 1 Ω is trivially G measurable. We show the statement for the case X = 1 B, where B G. The extension to the general case follows by standard arguments. We have for any A G : A E X 1 Ω dp = E X P A = E 1 B P A = P B P A = P A B = E 1 A 1 B = XdP, using in the fourth equality the independence assumption, in the fifth the properties of indicator functions and in the sixth the definition of X. 6. V E X G is G measurable. Again, we show A 39

41 the statement for the simpler case V = 1 B, where B G. We have for any A G, V E X G dp = A = 1 B E X G dp = E X G dp A A B XdP = 1 B XdP = V XdP, A B A A using in the third equality the definition of conditional expectations, and otherwise the properties of indicator functions. Example 68 In the n period Binomial model we have E S 1 σ S 1 = S 1, by the σ S 1 measurability of S 1. S is not σ S 1 measurable. However, we know that σ S /S 1 σ S 1. Therefore, S E S σ S 1 = E S 1 S 1 σ S 1 = S 1 E More generally, we have S S 1 σ S 1 = S 1 E σ S t /S t 1 G t 1, S S 1 = S 1 pu + 1 p d. where G t 1 := σ t 1 t = 1,..., n. Therefore, by the same arguments: k= σ S k, E S t G t 1 = S t 1 pu + 1 p d. 4

42 Finally, the tower property gives after some iterations: E S t+k G t 1 = E E S t+k G t+k 1 G t 1 = E S t+k 1 pu + 1 p d G t 1 = pu + 1 p d E S t+k 1 G t 1 =... = pu + 1 p d k E S t G t 1 = pu + 1 p d k+1 S t 1..4 Martingale Processes We now introduce a class of stochastic processes that are particularly important in finance: the class of martingale processes. Indeed, it will turn out in a later chapter that the price processes of many financial instruments are martingale processes after a suitable change of probability. In this section we give the necessary definitions and present some first examples of martingale processes. Definition 69 i Let G := G t t=,..,n be a filtration over Ω, G, P. The quadruplet Ω, G, G,P is called a filtered probability space. ii A stochastic process X := X t t=,..,n on a filtered probability space Ω, G, G,P is adapted is G adapted if for any t =,.., n the random variable X t is G t measurable. iii A G adapted process is a martingale if for any t =,.., n 1 one has X t = E X t+1 G t, 9 martingale condition. The process is a submartingale a supermartingale if in 9 the sign the sign holds. Remark 7 Notice, that in Definition 69 both the filtration G and the relevant probability P are crucial in determining the validity of the martingale condition 9 for an adapted process. Indeed, 41

43 different probabilities and filtrations can imply 9 to be satisfied or not. For instance, in the n period binomial model we obtained, using the filtration generated by the stock price process, E S t G t 1 = S t 1 pu + 1 p d. Therefore, the only binomial probability measure under which the stock price process is a martingale is the one satisfying pu + 1 p d = 1, i.e. p = 1 d u d. 1 The binomial probabilities such that p > 1 d / u d p < 1 d / u d imply a stock price process that is a submartingale a supermartingale. Being a martingale is a quite strong condition on a stochastic process, which strongly relates future process coordinates with current ones. This is made more explicit below. Proposition 71 Let X t t=,..,n be a martingale on the filtered probability space Ω, G, G,P. 1. It then follows for any t, s {, 1,..., n} such that s t: X t = E X s G t.. If Y t t=,..,n is a further martingale on the filtered probability space Ω, G, G,P and such that Y n = X n then Y t = X t almost surely for all t {, 1,..., n}. Proof. 1. The tower property combined with the martingale property implies X t = E X t+1 G t = E E X t+ G t+1 G t = E X t+ G t =... = E X t+k G t, for any k = s t.. From 1. we have X t = E X n G t = E Y n G t = Y t. This concludes the proof. 4

44 Example 7 AR1 process: Let ε t t=1,...,n be an identically distributed, zero mean, adapted process on a filtered probability space Ω, G, G,P and such that for any t the random variable ε t is independent from the process history up to time t 1, i.e.: σ ε t σ t 1 i=1 σ ε i, t = 1,..., n. 11 An Autoregressive Process of Order 1 AR1 is defined by t = X t = ρx t 1 + ε t t >, where ρ R. It is easily seen that X t t=,..,n is G adapted. Furthermore, for any t = 1,..., n, E X t G t 1 = E ρx t 1 + ε t G t 1 = ρe X t 1 G t 1 +E ε t G t 1 = ρx t 1 +E ε t = ρx t 1, using in the second equality the linearity of conditional expectations, in the third the G t 1 measurability of X t 1 and the independence assumption 11, and in the fourth the zero mean property of ε t E ε t =. Therefore, an AR1 process is a martingale if and only if ρ = 1. The process resulting for ρ = 1 is called a Random Walk process. Example 73 MA1 process: Let ε t t=,..,n be the same process as in Example 7. A Moving Average Process of Order 1 MA1 is defined by t = X t = ε 1 t = 1, ε t + ρε t 1 t > 1 where ρ R. It is easily seen that X t t=,..,n is G adapted. Furthermore, for any t =,.., n we have, similarly to above, E X t G t 1 = E ε t + ρε t 1 G t 1 = ρe ε t 1 G t 1 + E ε t G t 1 = ρε t 1 + E ε t = ρε t 1. Therefore, X t 1 = E X t G t 1 ε t 1 + ρε t = ρε t 1, 43

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting. Binomial Models Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October 14, 2016 Christopher Ting QF 101 Week 9 October

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13 Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree An over-simplified model with surprisingly general extensions a single time step from 0 to T two types of traded securities: stock S and a bond

More information

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model Class Notes on No-Arbitrage Pricing Model April 18, 2016 Dr. Riyadh Al-Mosawi Department of Mathematics, College of Education for Pure Sciences, Thiqar University References: 1. Stochastic Calculus for

More information

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Adapted processes We have seen that the sampling space Ω = {H, T } N underlies the N-period binomial model for the stock-price process Elementary event ω = ω ω

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/33 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/33 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part one) Dr Nic Freeman

Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part one) Dr Nic Freeman Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part one) Dr Nic Freeman December 15, 2017 Contents 0 Introduction 3 0.1 Syllabus......................................... 4 0.2 Problem sheets.....................................

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/27 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/27 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance Stochastic Finance C. Azizieh VUB C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 1/91 Agenda of the course Stochastic calculus : introduction Black-Scholes model Interest rates models C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

More information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Eni Musta Università degli studi di Pisa San Miniato - 16 September 2016 Overview 1 Self-financing portfolio 2 Complete

More information

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Binomial model: numerical algorithm Binomial model: numerical algorithm S / 0 C \ 0 S0 u / C \ 1,1 S0 d / S u 0 /, S u 3 0 / 3,3 C \ S0 u d /,1 S u 5 0 4 0 / C 5 5,5 max X S0 u,0 S u C \ 4 4,4 C \ 3 S u d / 0 3, C \ S u d 0 S u d 0 / C 4

More information

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Bernard Bercu Bordeaux University, France IFCAM Summer School Bangalore, India, July 2015 Bernard Bercu Asymptotic results for discrete

More information

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch chris bemis November 27, 2006 0-0 Goal: Derive the Black-Scholes PDE To do this, we will need to: Come up with some dynamics for the stock returns Discuss Brownian motion

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Romuald Elie LAMA, CNRS UMR 85 Université Paris-Est Marne-La-Vallée elie @ ensae.fr Idris Kharroubi CEREMADE, CNRS UMR 7534, Université Paris Dauphine kharroubi

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Steven E. Shreve Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 USA shreve@andrew.cmu.edu A Talk in the Series Probability in Science and Industry

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Martingale Measure TA

Martingale Measure TA Martingale Measure TA Martingale Measure a) What is a martingale? b) Groundwork c) Definition of a martingale d) Super- and Submartingale e) Example of a martingale Table of Content Connection between

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar BROWNIAN MOTION II D.Majumdar DEFINITION Let (Ω, F, P) be a probability space. For each ω Ω, suppose there is a continuous function W(t) of t 0 that satisfies W(0) = 0 and that depends on ω. Then W(t),

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Lecture 3 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Several important concepts were illustrated in the example in Lecture 2: arbitrage; risk neutral probability

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut Financial Mathematics Spring 22 Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut These notes are c 22 by Richard Bass. They may be used for personal use or class use, but not for commercial

More information

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus and Financial Derivatives. Simone Calogero

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus and Financial Derivatives. Simone Calogero Introduction to Stochastic Calculus and Financial Derivatives Simone Calogero December 7, 215 Preface Financial derivatives, such as stock options for instance, are indispensable instruments in modern

More information

2.1 Multi-period model as a composition of constituent single period models

2.1 Multi-period model as a composition of constituent single period models Chapter 2 Multi-period Model Copyright c 2008 2012 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 2.1 Multi-period model as a composition of constituent single period models In Chapter 1, we have looked at the single-period

More information

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES D. S. SILVESTROV, H. JÖNSSON, AND F. STENBERG Abstract. A general price process represented by a two-component

More information

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Matteo Burzoni Marco Frittelli Marco Maggis June 30, 2015 Abstract In a model independent discrete time financial

More information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Mathematical Finance in discrete time Lecture Notes for Mathematical Finance in discrete time University of Vienna, Faculty of Mathematics, Fall 2015/16 Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna christa.cuchiero@univie.ac.at Draft Version June

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

The Infinite Actuary s. Detailed Study Manual for the. QFI Core Exam. Zak Fischer, FSA CERA

The Infinite Actuary s. Detailed Study Manual for the. QFI Core Exam. Zak Fischer, FSA CERA The Infinite Actuary s Detailed Study Manual for the QFI Core Exam Zak Fischer, FSA CERA Spring 2018 & Fall 2018 QFI Core Sample Detailed Study Manual You have downloaded a sample of our QFI Core detailed

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Michael Perlmutter Department of Mathematics Purdue University 1 M. Perlmutter(Purdue) Brownian Motion and Martingales Outline Review of Basic Probability

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

Lecture 23: April 10

Lecture 23: April 10 CS271 Randomness & Computation Spring 2018 Instructor: Alistair Sinclair Lecture 23: April 10 Disclaimer: These notes have not been subjected to the usual scrutiny accorded to formal publications. They

More information

Random Variables Handout. Xavier Vilà

Random Variables Handout. Xavier Vilà Random Variables Handout Xavier Vilà Course 2004-2005 1 Discrete Random Variables. 1.1 Introduction 1.1.1 Definition of Random Variable A random variable X is a function that maps each possible outcome

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial

More information

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach Giulia Di Nunno Third AMaMeF Conference: Advances in Mathematical Finance Pitesti, May 5-1 28 based on a work in progress with

More information

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3 Chapter 3 The Binomial Model In Chapter 1 the linear derivatives were considered. They were priced with static replication and payo tables. For the non-linear derivatives in Chapter 2 this will not work

More information

Binomial Option Pricing

Binomial Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing The wonderful Cox Ross Rubinstein model Nico van der Wijst 1 D. van der Wijst Finance for science and technology students 1 Introduction 2 3 4 2 D. van der Wijst Finance for science

More information

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Leonardo P. Santiago & Pirooz Vakili November 2004 Abstract In this paper we consider the question of whether an increase in uncertainty increases

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval A. N. Shiryaev M. V. Zhitlukhin arxiv:1212.379v1 [math.st] 15 Dec 212 December 18, 212 Abstract We consider optimal

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

Derivative Securities

Derivative Securities Derivative Securities he Black-Scholes formula and its applications. his Section deduces the Black- Scholes formula for a European call or put, as a consequence of risk-neutral valuation in the continuous

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58-6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15-19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9-31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36-37)

More information

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations Nico van der Wijst 1 Finance: A Quantitative Introduction c Cambridge University Press 1 The setting 2 3 4 2 Finance:

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets (Hull chapter: 12, 13, 14) Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 17 The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model Black and Scholes

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

Keeping Your Options Open: An Introduction to Pricing Options

Keeping Your Options Open: An Introduction to Pricing Options The College of Wooster Libraries Open Works Senior Independent Study Theses 2014 Keeping Your Options Open: An Introduction to Pricing Options Ryan F. Snyder The College of Wooster, rsnyder14@wooster.edu

More information

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Model-independent bounds for Asian options Model-independent bounds for Asian options A dynamic programming approach Alexander M. G. Cox 1 Sigrid Källblad 2 1 University of Bath 2 CMAP, École Polytechnique University of Michigan, 2nd December,

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1 Computational Finance Computational Finance p. 1 Outline Binomial model: option pricing and optimal investment Monte Carlo techniques for pricing of options pricing of non-standard options improving accuracy

More information

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE. Risk Neutral Pricing Thursday, May 12, 2011 2:03 PM We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE. This is used to construct a

More information

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Numerical schemes for SDEs Lecture 5 Numerical schemes for SDEs Lecture Notes by Jan Palczewski Computational Finance p. 1 A Stochastic Differential Equation (SDE) is an object of the following type dx t = a(t,x t )dt + b(t,x t

More information

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments T. Fischer Darmstadt University of Technology November 11, 2003 Abstract This brief paper explains how to obtain upper boundaries of shortfall

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia Marco Frittelli Università degli Studi di Firenze Winter School on Mathematical Finance January 24, 2005 Lunteren. On Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets. based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini

More information

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

Option Pricing with Delayed Information Option Pricing with Delayed Information Mostafa Mousavi University of California Santa Barbara Joint work with: Tomoyuki Ichiba CFMAR 10th Anniversary Conference May 19, 2017 Mostafa Mousavi (UCSB) Option

More information

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time Chapter 7 Option Pricing 7.1 Discrete Time In the next section we will discuss the Black Scholes formula. To prepare for that, we will consider the much simpler problem of pricing options when there are

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation. Stochastic Differential Equation Consider. Moreover partition the interval into and define, where. Now by Rieman Integral we know that, where. Moreover. Using the fundamentals mentioned above we can easily

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Merton-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 18 The Black-Merton-Scholes-Merton (BMS) model Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton

More information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Magnus Wiktorsson September 27, 2018 Magnus Wiktorsson L8 September 27, 2018 1 / 14 The risk neutral valuation formula Let X be contingent claim with maturity T.

More information

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics CHAPTER Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics In the last chapter, we observe how the application of the no arbitrage argument enforces the forward price of a forward contract. The forward

More information

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Hariharan Narayanan December 7, 2014 Martingales 1 Introduction Martingales were originally introduced into probability theory as a model for fair betting games. Essentially

More information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model (joint work with J. Dong and L. Korobenko) A. Deniz Sezer University of Calgary April 28, 2016 Merton s model of corporate debt A corporate bond is a contingent

More information

Homework 1 posted, due Friday, September 30, 2 PM. Independence of random variables: We say that a collection of random variables

Homework 1 posted, due Friday, September 30, 2 PM. Independence of random variables: We say that a collection of random variables Generating Functions Tuesday, September 20, 2011 2:00 PM Homework 1 posted, due Friday, September 30, 2 PM. Independence of random variables: We say that a collection of random variables Is independent

More information

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science Multi-Asset Options A Numerical Study Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL Department of Mathematical Sciences Chalmers University of Technology

More information

Outline of Lecture 1. Martin-Löf tests and martingales

Outline of Lecture 1. Martin-Löf tests and martingales Outline of Lecture 1 Martin-Löf tests and martingales The Cantor space. Lebesgue measure on Cantor space. Martin-Löf tests. Basic properties of random sequences. Betting games and martingales. Equivalence

More information

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis Jim Zhu Western Michigan University Kalamazoo, Michigan, USA March 3, 2011 A tale of two financial economists Edward O. Thorp and Myron Scholes Influential works: Beat the Dealer(1962) and Beat the Market(1967)

More information

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10.

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10. IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models Fall 2013, Professor Whitt Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10. The Central Limit Theorem and Stock Prices 1. The Central Limit Theorem (CLT See

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics Chapter 12 American Put Option Recall that the American option has strike K and maturity T and gives the holder the right to exercise at any time in [0, T ]. The American option is not straightforward

More information