4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS"

Transcription

1 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87

2 General Single-Period Market Models The main differences between the elementary and general single period market models are: The investor is allowed to invest in several risky securities instead of only one. The sample set is bigger, that is, there are more possible states of the world at time t = 1. The sample space is Ω = {ω 1, ω 2,..., ω k } with F = 2 Ω. An investor s personal beliefs about the future behaviour of stock prices are represented by the probability measure P(ω i ) = p i > 0 for i = 1, 2,..., k. The savings account B equals B 0 = 1 and B 1 = 1 + r for some constant r > 1. The price of the jth stock at t = 1 is a random variable on Ω. It is denoted by S j t for t = 0, 1 and j = 1,..., n. A contingent claim X = (X(ω 1 ),..., X(ω k )) is a random variable on the probability space (Ω, F, P). M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 2 / 87

3 Questions 1 Under which conditions a general single-period market model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) is arbitrage-free? 2 How to define a risk-neutral probability measure for a model? 3 How to use a risk-neutral probability measure to analyse general single-period market models? 4 Under which conditions a general single-period market model is complete? 5 Is completeness of a market model related to the uniqueness of a risk-neutral probability measure? 6 How to define and compute the arbitrage price of an attainable claim? 7 Can we still apply the risk-neutral valuation formula to compute the arbitrage price of an attainable claim? 8 How to deal with contingent claims that are not attainable? 9 How to use the class of risk-neutral probability measures to value non-attainable claims? M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 3 / 87

4 Outline We will examine the following issues: 1 Trading Strategies and Arbitrage-Free Models 2 Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing 3 Examples of Market Models 4 Risk-Neutral Valuation of Contingent Claims 5 Completeness of Market Models M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 4 / 87

5 PART 1 TRADING STRATEGIES AND ARBITRAGE-FREE MODELS M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 5 / 87

6 Trading Strategy Definition (Trading Strategy) A trading strategy (or a portfolio) in a general single-period market model is defined as the vector (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) R n+1 where x is the initial wealth of an investor and φ j stands for the number of shares of the jth stock purchased at time t = 0. If an investor adopts the trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) at time t = 0 then the cash value of his portfolio at time t = 1 equals V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := ( x n ) φ j S j 0 (1 + r) + j=1 n φ j S j 1. j=1 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 6 / 87

7 Wealth Process of a Trading Strategy Definition (Wealth Process) The wealth process (or the value process) of a trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) is the pair (V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ), V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n )). The real number V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) is the initial endowment V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := x and the real-valued random variable V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) represents the cash value of the portfolio at time t = 1 V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := ( x n ) φ j S j 0 (1 + r) + j=1 n φ j S j 1. j=1 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 7 / 87

8 Gains (Profits and Losses) Process The profits or losses an investor obtains from the investment can be calculated by subtracting V 0 ( ) from V 1 ( ). This is called the (undiscounted) gains process. The gain can be negative; hence it may also represent a loss. Definition (Gains Process) The gains process is defined as G 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = 0 and G 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) ( n ) n = x φ j S j 0 r + φ j S j 1 j=1 j=1 where the random variable S j 1 = Sj 1 Sj 0 in the price of the jth stock. represents the nominal change M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 8 / 87

9 Discounted Stock Price and Value Process To understand whether the jth stock appreciates in real terms, we consider the discounted stock prices of the jth stock Ŝ j 0 := Sj 0 = Sj 0 B 0, Ŝ j 1 := Sj r = Sj 1 B 1. Similarly, we define the discounted wealth process as V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := x, V1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := V 1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ) B 1. It is easy to see that V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = ( x ) n j=1 φj S j 0 + n j=1 φj Ŝ j 1 = x + n j=1 φj (Ŝj 1 Ŝj 0 ). M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 9 / 87

10 Discounted Gains Process Definition (Discounted Gains Process) The discounted gains process for the investor is defined as Ĝ 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = 0 and Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) := V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) n = φ j Ŝj 1 j=1 where Ŝj 1 = Ŝj 1 Ŝj 0 stock. is the change in the discounted price of the jth M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 10 / 87

11 Arbitrage: Definition The concept of an arbitrage in a general single-period market model is essentially the same as in the elementary market model. It is worth noting that the real-world probability P can be replaced here by any equivalent probability measure Q. Definition (Arbitrage) A trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) in a general single-period market model is called an arbitrage opportunity if A.1. V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = 0, A.2. V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n )(ω i ) 0 for i = 1, 2,..., k, A.3. E P { V1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) } > 0, that is, k V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n )(ω i ) P(ω i ) > 0. i=1 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 11 / 87

12 Arbitrage: Equivalent Conditions The following condition is equivalent to A.3. A.3. There exists ω Ω such that V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n )(ω) > 0. The definition of arbitrage can be formulated using the discounted value and gains processes. This is sometimes very helpful. Proposition (4.1) A trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) in a general single-period market model is an arbitrage opportunity if and only if one of the following conditions holds: 1 Assumptions A.1-A.3 in the definition of arbitrage hold with V (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) instead of V (x, φ 1,..., φ n ). 2 x = 0 and A.2-A.3 in the definition of arbitrage are satisfied with Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) instead of V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ). M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 12 / 87

13 Proof of Proposition 4.1 Proof of Proposition 4.1: First step. We will show that the following two statements are true: The definition of arbitrage and condition 1 in Proposition 4.1 are equivalent. In Proposition 4.1, condition 1 is equivalent to condition 2. To prove the first statement, we use the relationships between V (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) and V (x, φ 1,..., φ n ), that is, V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = x, V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = r V 1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ), { E P V1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) } = r E { P V1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) }. This shows that the first statement holds. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 13 / 87

14 Proof of Proposition 4.1 Proof of Proposition 4.1: Second step. To prove the second statement, we recall the relation between V (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) and Ĝ1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ) Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) x. It is now clear that for x = 0 we have Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ). Hence the second statement is true as well. In fact, one can also observe that Ĝ1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ) does not depend on x at all, since Ĝ1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = n j=1 φj Ŝj 1. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 14 / 87

15 Verification of the Arbitrage-Free Property It can be sometimes hard to check directly whether arbitrage opportunities exist in a given market model, especially when dealing with several risky assets or in the multi-period setup. We have introduced the risk-neutral probability measure in the elementary market model and we noticed that it can be used to compute the arbitrage price of any contingent claim. We will show that the concept of a risk-neutral probability measure is also a convenient tool for checking whether a general single-period market model is arbitrage-free or not. In addition, we will argue that a risk-neutral probability measure can also be used for the purpose of valuation of a contingent claim (either attainable or not). M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 15 / 87

16 Risk-Neutral Probability Measure Definition (Risk-Neutral Probability Measure) A probability measure Q on Ω is called a risk-neutral probability measure for a general single-period market model M if: R.1. Q (ω i ) > 0 for all ω i Ω, R.2. E Q ( Ŝ j 1) = 0 for j = 1, 2,..., n. We denote by M the class of all risk-neutral probability measures for the market model M. Condition R.1 means that Q and P are equivalent probability measures. A risk-neutral probability measure is also known as an equivalent martingale measure. (Ŝj Note that condition R.2 is equivalent to E Q 1) = Ŝ j 0 or, more explicitly, ( E Q S j) 1 = (1 + r)s j 0. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 16 / 87

17 Example: Stock Prices Example (4.1) We consider the following model featuring two stocks S 1 and S 2 on the sample space Ω = {ω 1, ω 2, ω 3 }. The interest rate r = 1 10 so that B 0 = 1 and B 1 = We deal here with the market model M = (B, S 1, S 2 ). The stock prices at t = 0 are given by S 1 0 = 2 and S2 0 = 3. The stock prices at t = 1 are represented in the table: ω 1 ω 2 ω 3 S S M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 17 / 87

18 Example: Value Process Example (4.1 Continued) For any trading strategy (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) R 3, we have V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) = ( x 2φ 1 3φ 2) ( ) + φ 1 S1 1 + φ 2 S We set φ 0 := x 2φ 1 3φ 2. Then V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) equals ( V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 1 ) = φ ) + φ 1 + 3φ 2, 10 ( V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 2 ) = φ ) + 5φ 1 + φ 2, 10 ( V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 3 ) = φ ) + 3φ 1 + 6φ M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 18 / 87

19 Example: Gains Process Example (4.1 Continued) The increments S j 1 are represented by the following table ω 1 ω 2 ω 3 S S The gains G 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) are thus given by G 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 1 ) = 1 10 φ0 φ 1 + 0φ 2, G 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 2 ) = 1 10 φ0 + 3φ 1 2φ 2, G 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 3 ) = 1 10 φ0 + φ 1 + 3φ 2. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 19 / 87

20 Example: Discounted Stock Prices Example (4.1 Continued) Out next goal is to compute the discounted wealth process V (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) and the discounted gains process Ĝ1(x, φ 1, φ 2 ). To this end, we first compute the discounted stock prices. Of course, Ŝj 0 = Sj 0 for j = 1, 2. The following table represents the discounted stock prices Ŝj 1 for j = 1, 2 at time t = 1 Ŝ1 1 Ŝ1 2 ω 1 ω 2 ω M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 20 / 87

21 Example: Discounted Value Process Example (4.1 Continued) The discounted value process V (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) is thus given by V 0 (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) = V 0 (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) = x and V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 1 ) = φ φ φ2, V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 2 ) = φ φ φ2, V 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 3 ) = φ φ φ2, where φ 0 = x 2φ 1 3φ 2 is the amount of cash invested in B at time 0 (as opposed to the initial wealth given by x). M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 21 / 87

22 Example: Discounted Gains Process Example (4.1 Continued) The increments of the discounted stock prices equal Ŝ ω 1 ω 2 ω Ŝ Hence the discounted gains Ĝ1(x, φ 1, φ 2 ) are given by Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 1 ) = φ φ2, Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 2 ) = φ φ2, Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 )(ω 3 ) = 8 11 φ φ2. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 22 / 87

23 Example: Arbitrage-Free Property Example (4.1 Continued) The condition Ĝ1(x, φ 1, φ 2 ) 0 is equivalent to 12φ 1 3φ φ 1 23φ 2 0 8φ φ 2 0 Can we find (φ 1, φ 2 ) R 2 such that all inequalities are valid and at least one of them is strict? It appears that the answer is negative, since the unique vector satisfying all inequalities above is (φ 1, φ 2 ) = (0, 0). Therefore, the single-period market model M = (B, S 1, S 2 ) is arbitrage-free. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 23 / 87

24 Example: Risk-Neutral Probability Measure Example (4.1 Continued) We will now show that this market model admits a unique risk-neutral probability measure on Ω = {ω 1, ω 2, ω 3 }. Let us denote q i = Q(ω i ) for i = 1, 2, 3. From the definition of a risk-neutral probability measure, we obtain the following linear system q q q 3 = q q q 3 = 0 q 1 + q 2 + q 3 = 1 The unique solution equals Q = (q 1, q 2, q 3 ) = ( 47 80, 15 80, 18 80). M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 24 / 87

25 PART 2 FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 25 / 87

26 Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing (FTAP) In Example 4.1, we have checked directly that the market model M = (B, S 1, S 2 ) is arbitrage-free. In addition, we have shown that the unique risk-neutral probability measure exists in this model. Is there any relation between no arbitrage property of a market model and the existence of a risk-neutral probability measure? The following important result, known as the FTAP, gives a complete answer to this question within the present setup. The FTAP was first established by Harrison and Pliska (1981) and it was later extended to continuous-time market models. Theorem (FTAP) A general single-period model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) is arbitrage-free if and only if there exists a risk-neutral probability measure for M, that is, M. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 26 / 87

27 Proof of ( ) in FTAP Proof of ( ) in FTAP. ( ) We first prove the if part. We assume that M, so that a risk-neutral probability measure Q exists. Let (0, φ) = (0, φ 1,..., φ n ) be any trading strategy with null initial endowment. Then for any Q M ( E Q V1 (0, φ) ) ( n ) = E Q φ j Ŝj 1 = j=1 n j=1 φ j ( E Q Ŝ j ) 1 = 0. }{{} =0 If we assume that V 1 (0, φ) 0 then the last equation implies that the equality V 1 (0, φ)(ω) = 0 must hold for all ω Ω. Hence no trading strategy satisfying all conditions of an arbitrage opportunity may exist. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 27 / 87

28 Geometric Interpretation of X and Q The proof of the implication ( ) in the FTAP needs some preparation, since it is based on geometric arguments. Any random variable on Ω can be identified with a vector in R k, specifically, X = (X(ω 1 ),..., X(ω k )) T = (x 1,..., x k ) T R k. An arbitrary probability measure Q on Ω can also be interpreted as a vector in R k Q = (Q(ω1),..., Q(ωk)) = (q1,..., qk) R k. We note that k k E Q (X) = X(ω i )Q(ω i ) = x i q i = X, Q i=1 i=1 where, denotes the inner product of two vectors in R k. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 28 / 87

29 Auxiliary Subsets of R k We define the following classes: W = {X } R k X = V1 (0, φ 1,..., φ n ) for some φ 1,..., φ n { } W = Z R k X, Z = 0 for all X W The set W is the image of the map V 1 (0,,..., ) : R n R k. We note that W represents all discounted values at t = 1 of trading strategies with null initial endowment. The set W is the set of all vectors in R k orthogonal to W. We introduce the following sets of k-dimensional vectors: { A = X R k } X 0, x i 0 for i = 1,..., k P + = { Q R k k i=1 } q i = 1, q i > 0 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 29 / 87

30 W and W as Vector Spaces Corollary The sets W and W are vector (linear) subspaces of R k. Proof. It suffices to observe that the map V 1 (0,,..., ) : R n R k is linear. In other words, for any trading strategies (0, η 1,..., η n ) and (0, κ 1,..., κ n ) and arbitrary real numbers α, β (0, φ 1,..., φ n ) = α(0, η 1,..., η n ) + β(0, κ 1,..., κ n ) is also a trading strategy. Hence W is a vector subspace of R k. In particular, the zero vector (0, 0,..., 0) belongs to W. It us easy to check that W, that is, the orthogonal complement of W is a vector subspace as well. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 30 / 87

31 Risk-Neutral Probability Measures Lemma (4.1) A single-period market model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) is arbitrage free if and only if W A =. Proof. The proof hinges on an application of Proposition 4.1. Lemma (4.2) A probability measure Q is a risk-neutral probability measure for a single-period market model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) if and only if Q W P +. Hence the set M of all risk-neutral probability measures for the model M satisfies M = W P + and thus M W P +. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 31 / 87

32 Proof of Lemma 4.2 Proof of ( ) in Lemma 4.2. ( ) We assume that Q is a risk-neutral probability measure. By the property R.1, it is obvious that Q belongs to P +. Using the property R.2, we obtain for any vector X = V 1 (0, φ) W ( X, Q = E Q V1 (0, φ) ) ( n ) = E Q φ j Ŝj 1 = n j=1 φ j ( E Q Ŝ j ) 1 = 0. }{{} =0 We conclude that Q belongs to W as well. j=1 Consequently, Q W P + as was required to show. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 32 / 87

33 Proof of Lemma 4.2 Proof of ( ) in Lemma 4.2. ( ) We now assume that Q is an arbitrary vector in W P +. Since Q P +, we see that Q defines a probability measure satisfying condition R.1. It remains to show that Q satisfies condition R.2 as well. To this end, for a fixed (but arbitrary) j = 1, 2,..., n, we consider the trading strategy (0, φ 1,..., φ n ) with (φ 1,..., φ n ) = (0,..., 0, 1, 0,..., 0) = e j. This trading strategy only invests in the savings account and the jth asset. The discounted wealth of this strategy is V 1 (0, e j ) = Ŝj 1. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 33 / 87

34 Proof of Lemma 4.2 Proof of ( ) in Lemma 4.2 (Continued). Since V 1 (0, e j ) W and Q W we obtain 0 = V 1 (0, e j ), Q = Ŝj 1, Q = E Q( Ŝ1) j. Since j was arbitrary, we see that Q satisfies condition R.2. Hence Q is a risk-neutral probability measure. From Lemmas 4.1 and 4.2, we get the following purely geometric reformulation of the FTAP: W A = W P +. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 34 / 87

35 Separating Hyperplane Theorem: Statement Theorem (Separating Hyperplane Theorem) Let B, C R k be nonempty, closed, convex sets such that B C =. Assume, in addition, that at least one of these sets is compact (that is, bounded and closed). Then there exist vectors a, y R k such that b a, y < 0 for all b B and c a, y > 0 for all c C. Proof of the Separating Hyperplane Theorem. The proof can be found in any textbook of convex analysis or functional analysis. It is sketched in the course notes. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 35 / 87

36 Separating Hyperplane Theorem: Interpretation Let the vectors a, y R k be as in the statement of the Separating Hyperplane Theorem It is clear that y R k is never a zero vector. We define the (k 1)-dimensional hyperplane H R k by setting { } H = a + x R k x, y = 0 = a + {y}. Then we say that the hyperplane H strictly separates the convex sets B and C. Intuitively, the sets B and C lie on different sides of the hyperplane H and thus they can be seen as geometrically separated by H. Note that the compactness of at least one of the sets is a necessary condition for the strict separation of B and C. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 36 / 87

37 Separating Hyperplane Theorem: Corollary The following corollary is a consequence of the separating hyperplane theorem. It is more suitable for our purposes: it will be later applied to B = W and C = A + := {X A X, P = 1} A. Corollary (4.1) Assume that B R k is a vector subspace and set C is a compact convex set such that B C =. Then there exists a vector y R k such that that is, y B, and b, y = 0 for all b B c, y > 0 for all c C. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 37 / 87

38 Proof of Corollary 4.1 Proof of Corollary 4.1: First step. We note that any vector subspace of R k is a closed and convex set. From the separating hyperplane theorem, there exist a, y R k such that the inequality b, y < a, y is satisfied for all vectors b B. Since B is a vector subspace, the vector λb belongs to B for any λ R. Hence for any b B and λ R we have λb, y = λ b, y < a, y. This in turn implies that b, y = 0 for any vector b B, meaning that y B. Also, we have that a, y > 0. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 38 / 87

39 Proof of Corollary 4.1 Proof of Corollary 4.1: Second step. To establish the second inequality, we observe that from the separating hyperplane theorem, we obtain Consequently, for any c C c, y > a, y for all c C. c, y > a, y > 0. We conclude that c, y > 0 for all c C. We now are ready to establish the implication ( ) in the FTAP: W A = W P +. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 39 / 87

40 Proof of ( ) in FTAP: 1 Proof of ( ) in FTAP: First step. We assume that the model is arbitrage-free. From Lemma 4.1, this is equivalent to the condition W A =. Our goal is to show that the class M is non-empty. In view of Lemma 4.2, it thus suffices to show that W A = W P +. We define an auxiliary set A + = {X A X, P = 1}. Observe that A + is a closed, bounded (hence compact) and convex subset of R k. Since A + A, it is clear that W A = W A + =. Hence in the next step we may assume that W A + =. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 40 / 87

41 Proof of ( ) in FTAP: 2 Proof of ( ) in FTAP: Second step. By applying Corollary 4.1 to B = W and C = A +, we see that there exists a vector Y W such that X, Y > 0 for all X A +. (1) Our goal is to show that Y can be used to define a risk-neutral probability Q. We need first to show that y i > 0 for every i. For this purpose, for any fixed i = 1, 2,..., k, we define X i = (P(ω i )) 1 (0,..., 0, 1, 0..., 0) = (P(ω i )) 1 e i so that X i A + since E P (X i ) = X i, P = 1. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 41 / 87

42 Proof of ( ) in FTAP: 3 Proof of ( ) in FTAP: Third step. Let y i be the ith component of Y. It follows from (1) that 0 < X i, Y = (P(ω i )) 1 y i and thus y i > 0 for all i = 1, 2,..., k. We set Q(ω i ) = q i where q i := y i y y k = cy i > 0 It is clear that Q is a probability measure and Q P +. Since Y W, Q = cy for some scalar c and W is a vector space, we have that Q W. We conclude that Q W P + so that W P +. From Lemma 4.2, Q is a risk-neutral probability and thus M. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 42 / 87

43 PART 3 EXAMPLES OF MARKET MODELS M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 43 / 87

44 Example: Arbitrage-Free Market Model Example (4.1 Continued) We consider the market model M = (B, S 1, S 2 ) introduced in Example 4.1. The interest rate r = 1 10 so that B 0 = 1 and B 1 = The stock prices at t = 0 are given by S0 1 = 2 and S2 0 = 3. We have shown that the increments of the discounted stock prices Ŝ1 and Ŝ2 equal Ŝ ω 1 ω 2 ω Ŝ M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 44 / 87

45 Example: Arbitrage-Free Market Model Example (4.1 Continued) The vector spaces W and W are given by W = α + β and W = γ γ R. α, β R We first show the model is arbitrage-free using Lemma 4.1. It thus suffices to check that W A = M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 45 / 87

46 Example: Arbitrage-Free Market Model Example (4.1 Continued) If there exists a vector X W A then the following three inequalities are satisfied by a vector X = (x 1, x 2, x 3 ) R 3 x 1 = x 1 (α, β) = 12α 3β 0 x 2 = x 2 (α, β) = 28α 23β 0 x 3 = x 3 (α, β) = 8α + 27β 0 with at least one strict inequality, where α, β R are arbitrary. It can be shown that such a vector X R 3 does not exist and thus W A =. This is left as an easy exercise. In view of Lemma 4.1, we conclude that the market model is arbitrage-free. In the next step, our goal is to show that M is non-empty. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 46 / 87

47 Example: Arbitrage-Free Market Model Example (4.1 Continued) Lemma 4.2 tells us that M = W P +. If Q W then 47 Q = γ 15 for some γ R. 18 If Q P + then 47γ + 15γ + 18γ = 1 so that γ = 1 80 > 0. We conclude that the unique risk-neutral probability measure Q is given by Q = The FTAP confirms that the market model is arbitrage-free. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 47 / 87

48 Example: Market Model with Arbitrage Example (4.2) We consider the following model featuring two stocks S 1 and S 2 on the sample space Ω = {ω 1, ω 2, ω 3 }. The interest rate r = 1 10 so that B 0 = 1 and B 1 = The stock prices at t = 0 are given by S0 1 = 1 and S2 0 = 2 and the stock prices at t = 1 are represented in the table: ω 1 ω 2 ω 3 S S Does this market model admit an arbitrage opportunity? M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 48 / 87

49 Example: Market Model with Arbitrage Example (4.2 Continued) Once again, we will analyse this problem using Lemma 4.1, Lemma 4.2 and the FTAP. To tell whether a model is arbitrage-free it suffices to know the increments of discounted stock prices. The increments of discounted stock prices are represented in the following table ω 1 ω 2 ω 3 Ŝ1 1 1 Ŝ M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 49 / 87

50 Example: Market Model with Arbitrage Example (4.2 Continued) Recall that Ĝ 1 (x, φ 1, φ 2 ) = φ 1 Ŝ1 1 + φ 2 Ŝ2 1 Hence, by the definition of W, we have W = α + β α, β R. Let us take α = 3 and β = 1. Then we obtain the vector (0, 0, 39) T, which manifestly belongs to A. We conclude that W A and thus, by Lemma 4.1, the market model is not arbitrage-free. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 50 / 87

51 Example: Market Model with Arbitrage Example (4.2 Continued) We note that W = γ γ R. If there exists a risk-neutral probability measure Q then Q W P +. Since Q W, we obtain Q(ω 1 ) = 6Q(ω 2 ). However, Q P + implies that Q(ω) > 0 for all ω Ω. We conclude that W P + = and thus, by Lemma 4.2, no risk-neutral probability measure exists, that is, M =. Hence the FTAP confirms that the model is not arbitrage-free. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 51 / 87

52 PART 4 RISK-NEUTRAL VALUATION OF CONTINGENT CLAIMS M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 52 / 87

53 Contingent Claims We now know how to check whether a given model is arbitrage-free. Hence the following question arises: What should be the fair price of a European call or put option in a general single-period market model? In a general single-period market model, the idea of pricing European options can be extended to any contingent claim. Definition (Contingent Claim) A contingent claim is a random variable X defined on Ω and representing the payoff at the maturity date. Derivatives nowadays are usually quite complicated and thus it makes sense to analyse valuation and hedging of a general contingent claim, and not only European call and put options. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 53 / 87

54 No-Arbitrage Principle Definition (Replication and Arbitrage Price) A trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) is called a replicating strategy (a hedging strategy) for a claim X when V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = X. Then the initial wealth is denoted as π 0 (X) and it is called the arbitrage price of X. Proposition (No-Arbitrage Principle) Assume that a contingent claim X can be replicated by means of a trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ). Then the unique price of X at 0 consistent with no-arbitrage principle equals V 0 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = x. Proof. If the price of X is higher (lower) than x, one can short sell (buy) X and buy (short sell) the replicating portfolio. This will yield an arbitrage opportunity in the extended market in which X is traded at time t = 0. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 54 / 87

55 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model In the elementary market model, a replicating strategy for any contingent claim always exists. However, in a general single-period market model, a replicating strategy may fail to exist for some claims. For instance, when there are more sources of randomness than there are stocks available for investment then replicating strategies do not exist for some claims. Example (4.3) Consider a market model consisting of bond B, stock S, and a random variable v called the volatility. The volatility determines whether the stock price can make either a big or a small jump. This is a simple example of a stochastic volatility model. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 55 / 87

56 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) The sample space is given by Ω = {ω 1, ω 2, ω 3, ω 4 } and the volatility is defined as { h for i = 1, 4, v(ω i ) = l for i = 2, 3. We furthermore assume that 0 < l < h < 1. The stock price S 1 is given by { (1 + v(ωi ))S S 1 (ω i ) = 0 for i = 1, 2, (1 v(ω i ))S 0 for i = 3, 4. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 56 / 87

57 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) Unlike in examples we considered earlier, the amount by which the stock price in this market model jumps is random. It is easy to check that the model is arbitrage-free whenever 1 h < 1 + r < 1 + h. We claim that for some contingent claims a replicating strategy does not exist. In that case, we say that a claim is not attainable. To justify this claim, we consider the digital call option X with the payoff { 1 if S1 > K, X = 0 otherwise, where K > 0 is the strike price. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 57 / 87

58 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) We assume that (1 + l)s 0 < K < (1 + h)s 0, so that and thus (1 h)s 0 < (1 l)s 0 < (1 + l)s 0 < K < (1 + h)s 0 X(ω i ) = { 1 for i = 1, 0 otherwise. Suppose that (x, φ) is a replicating strategy for X. Equality V 1 (x, φ) = X becomes (x φs 0 ) 1 + r 1 + r 1 + r 1 + r + φ (1 + h)s 0 (1 + l)s 0 (1 l)s 0 (1 h)s 0 = M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 58 / 87

59 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) Upon setting β = φs 0 and α = (1 + r)x φs 0 r, we see that the existence of a solution (x, φ) to this system is equivalent to the existence of a solution (α, β) to the system α β h l l h = It is easy to see that the above system of equations has no solution and thus a digital call is not an attainable contingent claim within the framework of the stochastic volatility model. Intuitively, the randomness generated by the volatility cannot be hedged, since the volatility is not a traded asset M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 59 / 87

60 Valuation of Attainable Contingent Claims We first recall the definition of attainability of a contingent claim. Definition (Attainable Contingent Claim) A contingent claim X is called to be attainable if there exists a replicating strategy for X. Let us summarise the known properties of attainable claims: It is clear how to price attainable contingent claims by the replicating principle. There might be more than one replicating strategy, but no arbitrage principle leads the initial wealth x to be unique. In the two-state single-period market model, one can use the risk-neutral probability measure to price contingent claims. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 60 / 87

61 Risk-Neutral Valuation Formula Our next objective is to extend the risk-neutral valuation formula to any attainable contingent claim within the framework of a general single-period market model. Proposition (4.2) Let X be an attainable contingent claim and let Q M be any risk-neutral probability measure. Then the arbitrage price of X at t = 0 equals ( ) X π 0 (X) = E Q. 1 + r Proof of Proposition 4.2. Recall that a trading strategy (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) is a replicating strategy for X whenever V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = X M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 61 / 87

62 Proof of the Risk-Neutral Valuation Formula Proof of Proposition 4.2. We divide both sides by 1 + r, to obtain Hence X 1 + r = V 1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ) = 1 + r V 1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ). 1 } 1 + r E Q (X) = E Q { V1 (x, φ 1,..., φ n ) } = E Q {x + Ĝ1(x, φ 1,..., φ n ) { n } = x + E Q φ j Ŝj 1 = x + j=1 n φ j ( E Q Ŝ1) j = x. (from R.2.) j=1 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 62 / 87

63 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) Proposition 4.2 shows that risk-neutral probability measures can be used to price attainable contingent claims. Consider the market model introduced in Example 4.3 with the interest rate r = 0. Recall that in this case the model is arbitrage-free since 1 h < 1 + r = 1 < 1 + h. The increments of the discounted stock price Ŝ are represented in the following table ω 1 ω 2 ω 3 ω 4 Ŝ1 hs 0 ls 0 ls 0 hs 0 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 63 / 87

64 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) By the definition of the linear subspace W R 4, we have h W = γ l l γ R. h The orthogonal complement of W is thus the three-dimensional subspace of R 4 given by z 1 z 1 h W = z 2 z 3 R4 z 2 z 3, l l = 0. z 4 z 4 h M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 64 / 87

65 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) Recall that a vector (q 1, q 2, q 3, q 4 ) belongs to P + if and only if the equality 4 i=1 q i = 1 holds and q i > 0 for i = 1, 2, 3, 4. Since the set of risk-neutral probability measures is given by M = W P +, we find that q 1 q 2 q 3 q 4 M {(q 1, q 2, q 3, q 4 ) qi > 0, 4 q i = 1 i=1 } and h(q 1 q 4 ) + l(q 2 q 3 ) = 0. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 65 / 87

66 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) The class M of all risk-neutral probability measures in our stochastic volatility model is therefore given by q 1 M = q 2 q 1 > 0, q 2 > 0, q 3 > 0, q 3 q 1 + q 2 + q 3 < 1,. l(q 1 q 1 q 2 q 2 q 3 ) = h(1 2q 1 q 2 q 3 ) 3 This set appears to be non-empty and thus we conclude that our stochastic volatility model is arbitrage-free. Recall that we have already shown that the digital call option is not attainable if (1 + l)s 0 < K < (1 + h)s 0. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 66 / 87

67 Example: Stochastic Volatility Model Example (4.3 Continued) It is not difficult to check that for every 0 < q 1 < 1 2 probability measure Q M such that Q(ω 1 ) = q 1. Indeed, it suffices to take q 1 (0, 1 2 ) and to set there exists a q 4 = q 1, q 2 = q 3 = 1 2 q 1. We apply the risk-neutral valuation formula to the digital call X = (1, 0, 0, 0). For Q = (q 1, q 2, q 3, q 4 ) M, we obtain E Q (X) = q q q q 4 0 = q 1. Since q 1 is any number from (0, 1 2 ), we see that every value from the open interval (0, 1 2 ) can be achieved. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 67 / 87

68 Extended Market Model and No-Arbitrage Principle We no longer assume that a contingent claim X is attainable. Definition A price π 0 (X) of a contingent claim X is said to be consistent with the no-arbitrage principle if the extended model, which consists of B, the original stocks S 1,..., S n, as well as an additional asset S n+1 satisfying S0 n+1 = π 0 (X) and S1 n+1 = X, is arbitrage-free. The interpretation of Definition 4.1 is as follows: We assume that the model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) is arbitrage-free. We regard the additional asset as a tradable risky asset in the extended market model M = (B, S 1,..., S n+1 ). We postulate its price at time 0 should be selected in such a way that the extended market model M is still arbitrage-free. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 68 / 87

69 Valuation of Non-Attainable Claims We already know that the risk-neutral valuation formula returns the arbitrage price for any attainable claim. The next result shows that it also yields a price consistent with the no-arbitrage principle when it is applied to any non-attainable claim. The price obtained in this way is not unique, however. Proposition (4.3) Let X be a possibly non-attainable contingent claim and Q is an arbitrary risk-neutral probability measure. Then π 0 (X) given by ( ) X π 0 (X) := E Q (2) 1 + r defines a price at t = 0 for the claim X that is consistent with the no-arbitrage principle. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 69 / 87

70 Proof of Proposition 4.3 Proof of Proposition 4.3. Let Q M be an arbitrary risk-neutral probability for M. We will show that Q is also a risk-neutral probability measure for the extended model M = (B, S 1,..., S n+1 ) in which S0 n+1 = π 0 (X) and S1 n+1 = X. For this purpose, we check that ( ) ( ) X E Q Ŝn+1 1 = E Q 1 + r π 0(X) = 0 and thus Q M is indeed a risk-neutral probability in the extended market model. By the FTAP, the extended model M is arbitrage-free. Hence the price π 0 (X) given by (2) complies with the no-arbitrage principle. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 70 / 87

71 PART 5 COMPLETENESS OF MARKET MODELS M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 71 / 87

72 Complete and Incomplete Models The non-uniqueness of arbitrage prices is a serious theoretical problem, which is still not completely resolved. We categorise market models into two classes: complete and incomplete models. Definition (Completeness) A financial market model is called complete if for any contingent claim X there exists a replicating strategy (x, φ) R n+1. A model is incomplete when there exists a claim X for which a replicating strategy does not exist. Given an arbitrage-free and complete model, the issue of pricing all contingent claims is completely solved. How can we tell whether a given model is complete? M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 72 / 87

73 Algebraic Criterion for Market Completeness Proposition (4.4) Assume that a single-period market model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) defined on the sample space Ω = {ω 1,..., ω k } is arbitrage-free. Then M is complete if and only if the k (n + 1) matrix A A = 1 + r S1(ω 1 1 ) S1 n (ω 1 ) 1 + r S1(ω 1 2 ) S1 n (ω 2 ) 1 + r S1(ω 1 k ) S1 n (ω k ) = (A 0, A 1,..., A n ) has a full row rank, that is, rank (A) = k. Equivalently, M is complete whenever the linear subspace spanned by the vectors A 0, A 1,..., A n coincides with the full space R k. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 73 / 87

74 Proof of Proposition 4.4 Proof of Proposition 4.4. By the linear algebra, A has a full row rank if and only if for every X R k the equation AZ = X has a solution Z R n+1. If we set φ 0 = x n j=1 φj S j 0 then we have 1 + r S1(ω 1 1 ) S1 n (ω 1 ) 1 + r S1(ω 1 2 ) S1 n (ω 2 ) 1 + r S1(ω 1 k ) S1 n (ω k ) where V 1 (ω i ) = V 1 (x, φ)(ω i ). φ 0 φ 1 φ n = V 1 (ω 1 ) V 1 (ω 2 ) V 1 (ω k ) This shows that computing a replicating strategy for X is equivalent to solving the equation AZ = X. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 74 / 87

75 Example: Incomplete Model Example (4.3 Continued) Consider the stochastic volatility model from Example 4.3. We already know that this model is incomplete, since the digital call is not an attainable claim. The matrix A is given by A = 1 + r S 1 1 (ω 1) 1 + r S 1 1 (ω 2) 1 + r S 1 1 (ω 3) 1 + r S 1 1 (ω 4) The rank of A is 2, and thus it is not equal to k = 4. In view of Proposition 4.4, this confirms that this market model is incomplete. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 75 / 87

76 Probabilistic Criterion for Attainability Proposition 4.4 yields a method for determining whether a market model is complete. Given an incomplete model, how to recognize an attainable claim? Recall that if a model M is arbitrage-free then the class M is non-empty. Proposition (4.5) Assume that a single-period model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) is arbitrage-free. Then a contingent claim X is attainable if and only if the expected value ( ) X E Q 1 + r has the same value for all risk-neutral probability measures Q M. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 76 / 87

77 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 1 Proof of Proposition 4.5. ( ) It is easy to deduce from Proposition 4.2 that if a contingent claim X is attainable then the expected value E Q ( (1 + r) 1 X ) has the same value for all Q M. To this end, it is possible to argue by contradiction. We leave the details as an exercise. ( ) (MATH3975) We prove this implication by contrapositive. Let us thus assume that the contingent claim X is not attainable. Our goal is to find two risk-neutral probabilities, say Q and Q, for which E Q ( (1 + r) 1 X ) E Q ( (1 + r) 1 X ). (3) M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 77 / 87

78 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 2 Proof of Proposition 4.5. Consider the matrix A introduced in Proposition 4.4. Since the claim X is not attainable, there is no solution Z R n+1 to the linear system AZ = X. We define the following subsets of R k and C = {X}. B = image (A) = { AZ Z R n+1} R k Then B is a proper subspace of R k and, obviously, the set C is convex and compact. Moreover, B C =. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 78 / 87

79 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 3 Proof of Proposition 4.5. In view of Corollary 4.1, there exists a non-zero vector Y = (y 1,..., y k ) R k such that b, Y = 0 for all b B, c, Y > 0 for all c C. In view of the definition of B and C, this means that for every j = 0, 1,..., n A j, Y = 0 and X, Y > 0 (4) where A j is the jth column of the matrix A. It is worth noting that the vector Y depends on X. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 79 / 87

80 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 4 Proof of Proposition 4.5. We assumed that the market model is arbitrage-free and thus, by the FTAP, the class M is non-empty. Let Q M be an arbitrary risk-neutral probability measure. We may choose a real number λ > 0 to be small enough in order to ensure that for every i = 1, 2,..., k Q(ω i ) := Q(ω i ) + λ(1 + r)y i > 0. (5) In the next step, our next goal is to show that Q is also a risk-neutral probability measure and it is different from Q. In the last step, we will show that inequality (3) is valid. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 80 / 87

81 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 5 Proof of Proposition 4.5. From the definition of A in Proposition 4.4 and the first equality in (4) with j = 0, we obtain k λ(1 + r)y i = λ A 0, Y = 0. i=1 It then follows from (5) that k Q(ω i ) = i=1 k k Q(ω i ) + λ(1 + r)y i = 1 i=1 i=1 and thus Q is a probability measure on the space Ω. In view of (5), it is clear that Q satisfies condition R.1. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 81 / 87

82 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 6 Proof of Proposition 4.5. It remains to check that Q satisfies also condition R.2. We examine the behaviour under Q of the discounted stock price Ŝj 1. For every j = 1, 2,..., n, we have E Q (Ŝj ) k = Q(ω i )Ŝj 1 (ω i) 1 = i=1 k Q(ω i )Ŝj 1 (ω i) + λ i=1 = E Q (Ŝj 1) + λ Aj, Y }{{} =0 k Ŝ j 1 (ω i)(1 + r)y i i=1 (in view of (4)) = Ŝj 0 (since Q M) M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 82 / 87

83 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 7 Proof of Proposition 4.5. We conclude that E Q( Ŝ j 1) = 0 and thus Q M, that is, Q is a risk-neutral probability measure for the market model M. From (5), it is clear that Q Q. We have thus proven that if M is arbitrage-free and incomplete, then there exists more than one risk-neutral probability measure. To complete the proof, it remains to show that inequality (3) is satisfied for the claim X. Recall that X was a fixed non-attainable contingent claim and we constructed a risk-neutral probability measure Q corresponding to X. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 83 / 87

84 Proof of ( ) in Proposition 4.5: 8 Proof of Proposition 4.5. We observe that E Q ( X ) 1 + r = = > k i=1 Q(ω i ) X(ω i) 1 + r k Q(ω i ) X(ω i) k 1 + r + λ y i X(ω i ) i=1 }{{} i=1 k i=1 >0 Q(ω i ) X(ω ( ) i) X 1 + r = E Q 1 + r since the inequalities X, Y > 0 and λ > 0 imply that the braced expression is strictly positive. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 84 / 87

85 Probabilistic Criterion for Market Completeness Theorem (4.1) Assume that a single-period model M = (B, S 1,..., S n ) is arbitrage-free. Then M is complete if and only if the class M consists of a single element, that is, there exists a unique risk-neutral probability measure. Proof of ( ) in Theorem 4.1. Since M is assumed to be arbitrage-free, from the FTAP it follows that there exists at least one risk-neutral probability measure, that is, the class M is non-empty. ( ) Assume first that a risk-neutral probability measure for M is unique. Then the condition of Proposition 4.5 is trivially satisfied for any claim X. Hence any claim X is attainable and thus the model M is complete. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 85 / 87

86 Proof of ( ) in Theorem 4.1 Proof of ( ) Theorem 4.1. ( ) Assume M is complete and consider any two risk-neutral probability measures Q and Q from M. For a fixed, but arbitrary, i = 1, 2,..., k, let the contingent claim X i be given by { X i 1 + r if ω = ωi, (ω) = 0 otherwise. Since M is now assumed to be complete, the contingent claim X i is attainable. From Proposition 4.2, it thus follows that ( ) ( ) X i X Q(ω i ) = E Q = π 0 (X i i ) = = 1 + r E Q 1 + r Q(ω i ). Since i was arbitrary, we see that the equality Q = Q holds. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 86 / 87

87 Summary Let us summarise the properties of single-period market models: 1 A single-period market model is arbitrage-free if and only if it admits at least one risk-neutral probability measure. 2 An arbitrage-free single-period market model is complete if and only if the risk-neutral probability measure is unique. 3 Under the assumption that the model is arbitrage-free: An arbitrary attainable contingent claim X (that is, any claim that can be replicated by means of some trading strategy) has the unique arbitrage price π 0 (X). The arbitrage price π 0 (X) of any attainable contingent claim X can be computed from the risk-neutral valuation formula using any risk-neutral probability Q. If X is not attainable then we may define a price of X consistent with the no-arbitrage principle. It can be computed using the risk-neutral valuation formula, but it will depend on the choice of a risk-neutral probability Q. M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 87 / 87

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Lecture 3 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Several important concepts were illustrated in the example in Lecture 2: arbitrage; risk neutral probability

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing presented by Yue Kuen KWOK Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology 1 Parable of the bookmaker Taking

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics CHAPTER Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics In the last chapter, we observe how the application of the no arbitrage argument enforces the forward price of a forward contract. The forward

More information

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing THE UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON Paul Klein Office: Murray Building, 3005 Email: p.klein@soton.ac.uk URL: http://paulklein.se Economics 3010 Topics in Macroeconomics 3 Autumn 2010 Lecture 8: Introduction

More information

Yao s Minimax Principle

Yao s Minimax Principle Complexity of algorithms The complexity of an algorithm is usually measured with respect to the size of the input, where size may for example refer to the length of a binary word describing the input,

More information

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Lecture 8: Asset pricing BURNABY SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY BRITISH COLUMBIA Paul Klein Office: WMC 3635 Phone: (778) 782-9391 Email: paul klein 2@sfu.ca URL: http://paulklein.ca/newsite/teaching/483.php Economics 483 Advanced Topics

More information

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +... No-Arbitrage Pricing Theory Single-Period odel There are N securities denoted ( S,S,...,S N ), they can be stocks, bonds, or any securities, we assume they are all traded, and have prices available. Ω

More information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Mathematical Finance in discrete time Lecture Notes for Mathematical Finance in discrete time University of Vienna, Faculty of Mathematics, Fall 2015/16 Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna christa.cuchiero@univie.ac.at Draft Version June

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Matteo Burzoni Marco Frittelli Marco Maggis June 30, 2015 Abstract In a model independent discrete time financial

More information

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure Yuri Kabanov 1,2 1 Laboratoire de Mathématiques, Université de Franche-Comté, 16 Route de Gray, 253 Besançon,

More information

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis Help Session 2 David Sovich Washington University in St. Louis TODAY S AGENDA 1. Refresh the concept of no arbitrage and how to bound option prices using just the principle of no arbitrage 2. Work on applying

More information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia Marco Frittelli Università degli Studi di Firenze Winter School on Mathematical Finance January 24, 2005 Lunteren. On Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets. based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences UNIVERSITY OF OSLO Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences Examination in MAT2700 Introduction to mathematical finance and investment theory. Day of examination: Monday, December 14, 2015. Examination

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences H. Mete Soner ETH Zürich and Swiss Finance Institute Joint with Matteo Burzoni, ETH Zürich Frank Riedel, University of Bielefeld Thera Stochastics in Honor of Ioannis

More information

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Uncertainty in Equilibrium Uncertainty in Equilibrium Larry Blume May 1, 2007 1 Introduction The state-preference approach to uncertainty of Kenneth J. Arrow (1953) and Gérard Debreu (1959) lends itself rather easily to Walrasian

More information

3. The Discount Factor

3. The Discount Factor 3. he Discount Factor Objectives Eplanation of - Eistence of Discount Factors: Necessary and Sufficient Conditions - Positive Discount Factors: Necessary and Sufficient Conditions Contents 3. he Discount

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Compulsory Assignment

Compulsory Assignment An Introduction to Mathematical Finance UiO-STK-MAT300 Autumn 2018 Professor: S. Ortiz-Latorre Compulsory Assignment Instructions: You may write your answers either by hand or on a computer for instance

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

European Contingent Claims

European Contingent Claims European Contingent Claims Seminar: Financial Modelling in Life Insurance organized by Dr. Nikolic and Dr. Meyhöfer Zhiwen Ning 13.05.2016 Zhiwen Ning European Contingent Claims 13.05.2016 1 / 23 outline

More information

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET Vol 18 No 2 Journal of Systems Science and Complexity Apr 2005 CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET SUN Wangui (School of Economics & Management Northwest University Xi an 710069 China Email: wans6312@pubxaonlinecom)

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty General Equilibrium under Uncertainty The Arrow-Debreu Model General Idea: this model is formally identical to the GE model commodities are interpreted as contingent commodities (commodities are contingent

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? A Summary of Arbitrage Restrictions and Smile Asymptotics Vimal Raval Imperial College London & UBS Investment Bank www2.imperial.ac.uk/ vr402 Joint Work with Mark

More information

Interpolation of κ-compactness and PCF

Interpolation of κ-compactness and PCF Comment.Math.Univ.Carolin. 50,2(2009) 315 320 315 Interpolation of κ-compactness and PCF István Juhász, Zoltán Szentmiklóssy Abstract. We call a topological space κ-compact if every subset of size κ has

More information

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of New South Wales Joint work with T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and K. Yousiph Seminar 26 September, 2007

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send  to: COPYRIGHT NOTICE: Costis Skiadas: Asset Pricing Theory is published by Princeton University Press and copyrighted, 2009, by Princeton University Press. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

A utility maximization proof of Strassen s theorem

A utility maximization proof of Strassen s theorem Introduction CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique Paris Advances in Financial Mathematics, Paris January, 2014 Outline Introduction Notations Strassen s theorem 1 Introduction Notations Strassen s theorem 2 General

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Arbitrage Pricing. What is an Equivalent Martingale Measure, and why should a bookie care? Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin

Arbitrage Pricing. What is an Equivalent Martingale Measure, and why should a bookie care? Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin Arbitrage Pricing What is an Equivalent Martingale Measure, and why should a bookie care? Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin March 27, 2010 Introduction What is Mathematical Finance?

More information

Introduction to game theory LECTURE 2

Introduction to game theory LECTURE 2 Introduction to game theory LECTURE 2 Jörgen Weibull February 4, 2010 Two topics today: 1. Existence of Nash equilibria (Lecture notes Chapter 10 and Appendix A) 2. Relations between equilibrium and rationality

More information

Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering. A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim. Julienne LaChance

Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering. A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim. Julienne LaChance Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim Julienne LaChance Lecture 1. The Basics risk- involves an unknown outcome, but a known probability

More information

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives Lecture 9 Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives 9.1 Forward risk adjusted probability measures This section is a preparation for valuation of fixed-income derivatives.

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005)

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005) Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters 10-12 of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005) Prof. Alex Stomper MIT Sloan, IHS & VGSF March 2010 Alex Stomper (MIT, IHS & VGSF) Finance March 2010 1 / 15 Fundamental

More information

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET MICHAEL PINSKER Abstract. We calculate the number of unary clones (submonoids of the full transformation monoid) containing the

More information

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Romuald Elie LAMA, CNRS UMR 85 Université Paris-Est Marne-La-Vallée elie @ ensae.fr Idris Kharroubi CEREMADE, CNRS UMR 7534, Université Paris Dauphine kharroubi

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core Camelia Bejan and Juan Camilo Gómez September 2011 Abstract The paper shows that the aspiration core of any TU-game coincides with

More information

Economia Financiera Avanzada

Economia Financiera Avanzada Economia Financiera Avanzada José Fajardo EBAPE- Fundação Getulio Vargas Universidad del Pacífico, Julio 5 21, 2011 José Fajardo Economia Financiera Avanzada Prf. José Fajardo Two-Period Model: State-Preference

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

1 No-arbitrage pricing

1 No-arbitrage pricing BURNABY SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY BRITISH COLUMBIA Paul Klein Office: WMC 3635 Phone: TBA Email: paul klein 2@sfu.ca URL: http://paulklein.ca/newsite/teaching/809.php Economics 809 Advanced macroeconomic

More information

10.1 Elimination of strictly dominated strategies

10.1 Elimination of strictly dominated strategies Chapter 10 Elimination by Mixed Strategies The notions of dominance apply in particular to mixed extensions of finite strategic games. But we can also consider dominance of a pure strategy by a mixed strategy.

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1334ec e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2011 INFORMS Electronic Companion Trust in Forecast Information Sharing by Özalp Özer, Yanchong Zheng,

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Jan Werner University of Minnesota SPRING 2019 1 I.1 Equilibrium Prices in Security Markets Assume throughout this section that utility functions

More information

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis Jim Zhu Western Michigan University Kalamazoo, Michigan, USA March 3, 2011 A tale of two financial economists Edward O. Thorp and Myron Scholes Influential works: Beat the Dealer(1962) and Beat the Market(1967)

More information

Lie Algebras and Representation Theory Homework 7

Lie Algebras and Representation Theory Homework 7 Lie Algebras and Representation Theory Homework 7 Debbie Matthews 2015-05-19 Problem 10.5 If σ W can be written as a product of t simple reflections, prove that t has the same parity as l(σ). Let = {α

More information

Strong bubbles and strict local martingales

Strong bubbles and strict local martingales Strong bubbles and strict local martingales Martin Herdegen, Martin Schweizer ETH Zürich, Mathematik, HG J44 and HG G51.2, Rämistrasse 101, CH 8092 Zürich, Switzerland and Swiss Finance Institute, Walchestrasse

More information

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Hariharan Narayanan December 7, 2014 Martingales 1 Introduction Martingales were originally introduced into probability theory as a model for fair betting games. Essentially

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL

sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL In this chapter we will study, in some detail, the simplest possible nontrivial model of a financial market the binomial model. This is a

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting. Binomial Models Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October 14, 2016 Christopher Ting QF 101 Week 9 October

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Robert Almgren University of Chicago Program on Financial Mathematics MAA Short Course San Antonio, Texas January 11-12, 1999 1 Robert Almgren 1/99 Mathematics in Finance 2 1. Pricing

More information

Arbitrage and Pricing Theory

Arbitrage and Pricing Theory Arbitrage and Pricing Theory Dario Trevisan Università degli Studi di Pisa San Miniato - 13 September 2016 Overview 1 Derivatives Examples Leverage Arbitrage 2 The Arrow-Debreu model Definitions Arbitrage

More information

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives M. Vidyasagar Cecil & Ida Green Chair The University of Texas at Dallas Email: M.Vidyasagar@utdallas.edu October

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS QRMC07 9/7/0 4:45 PM Page 5 CHAPTER SEVEN ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS 7. AN INTRODUCTION TO MATRICES Investors frequently encounter situations involving numerous potential outcomes, many discrete periods

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

Game Theory: Normal Form Games Game Theory: Normal Form Games Michael Levet June 23, 2016 1 Introduction Game Theory is a mathematical field that studies how rational agents make decisions in both competitive and cooperative situations.

More information

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS David Heath 1 and Hyejin Ku 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA, email:heath@andrew.cmu.edu 2 Department of Mathematics

More information

To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months.

To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months. A one period model To have a concrete example in mind, suppose that we want to price a European call option on a stock that matures in six months.. The model setup We will start simple with a one period

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations Nico van der Wijst 1 Finance: A Quantitative Introduction c Cambridge University Press 1 The setting 2 3 4 2 Finance:

More information

Markets with convex transaction costs

Markets with convex transaction costs 1 Markets with convex transaction costs Irina Penner Humboldt University of Berlin Email: penner@math.hu-berlin.de Joint work with Teemu Pennanen Helsinki University of Technology Special Semester on Stochastics

More information

One-Period Valuation Theory

One-Period Valuation Theory One-Period Valuation Theory Part 1: Basic Framework Chris Telmer March, 2013 Develop a simple framework for understanding what the pricing kernel is and how it s related to the economics of risk, return

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Notes on the symmetric group

Notes on the symmetric group Notes on the symmetric group 1 Computations in the symmetric group Recall that, given a set X, the set S X of all bijections from X to itself (or, more briefly, permutations of X) is group under function

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Adapted processes We have seen that the sampling space Ω = {H, T } N underlies the N-period binomial model for the stock-price process Elementary event ω = ω ω

More information

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS ADRIAN D. BANNER INTECH One Palmer Square Princeton, NJ 8542, USA adrian@enhanced.com DANIEL FERNHOLZ Department of Computer Sciences University

More information

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model Appendix 1 A1: American Options in the Binomial Model So far we were dealing with options which can be excercised only at a fixed time, at their maturity date T. These are european options. In a complete

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

Portfolio Choice. := δi j, the basis is orthonormal. Expressed in terms of the natural basis, x = j. x j x j,

Portfolio Choice. := δi j, the basis is orthonormal. Expressed in terms of the natural basis, x = j. x j x j, Portfolio Choice Let us model portfolio choice formally in Euclidean space. There are n assets, and the portfolio space X = R n. A vector x X is a portfolio. Even though we like to see a vector as coordinate-free,

More information

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Dec 2010

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Dec 2010 ASYMPTOTIC PROPERTIES OF OPTIMAL TRAJECTORIES IN DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING SYLVAIN SORIN, XAVIER VENEL, GUILLAUME VIGERAL Abstract. We show in a dynamic programming framework that uniform convergence of the

More information