Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus"

Transcription

1 Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Romuald Elie LAMA, CNRS UMR 85 Université Paris-Est Marne-La-Vallée ensae.fr Idris Kharroubi CEREMADE, CNRS UMR 7534, Université Paris Dauphine ceremade.dauphine.fr October 11, 213

2 Contents 1 Probability reminder Generalities on probability spaces Measure theory and probability space Moments Gaussian random variables Scalar Gaussian variables Multivariate Gaussian variables Conditional expectation Sub-σ-algebra and conditioning Computations of conditional expectations Arbitrage theory Assumptions on the market The notion of arbitrage Portfolio comparison under (NFL) Call-Put parity relation Valuation of a forward contract Exercises Put and Call options Currency forward contract Binomial model with a single period Probabilistic model for the market Simple portfolio strategy Risk neutral probability Valuation and hedging of contingent claims Exercices Pricing of a call and a put option at the money Binomial tree with a single period Binomial model with multiple periods Some facts on discrete time processes and martingales

3 4.2 Market model Portfolio strategy Arbitrage and risk neutral probability Duplication of contingent claims Valuation et hedging of contingent claims Exercices Martingale transforms Trinomial model Stochastic Calculus with Brownian Motion General facts on random processes Random processes L p spaces Filtration Martingale Gaussian processes Brownian motion Total and quadratic variation Stochastic integration Ito s formula Ito s processes Stochastic differential equation Exercices Brownian bridge SDE with affine coefficients Ornstein-Ulhenbeck process Black & Scholes Model Assumptions on the market Probabilistic model for the market Risk neutral probability Self-financing portfolios Duplication of a financial derivative Black & Scholes formula Greeks Exercices Option valuation in the Black & Scholes model Put option with mean strike Asian Option

4 Chapter 1 Probability reminder 1.1 Generalities on probability spaces Measure theory and probability space Definition (σ-algebra). Let Ω be a set with P(Ω) the class of all subsets of Ω. A σ-algebra A on Ω is a sub-class of P(Ω) satisfying Ω, A, if A A then A c := {ω Ω : ω / A} A, if (A n ) n 1 is a sequence of elements of P(A) such that A n A and A n A n+1 for all n 1 then n 1 A. The couple (Ω, A) with A such a σ-algebra on Ω is called a measurable space. Proposition Let C be a class of elements of P(Ω). Then there exists a smallest σ-algebra σ(c) containing C. It is given by σ(c) = T. σ(c) is called the σ-algebra generated by C. {T σ algebra : C T } Example If we take Ω = R and C = {[x, ), x R} then σ(x) is called the Borel σ-algebra and is denoted by B(R). Il is also the σ-algebra generated by the open (resp. closed) subsets of R. 3

5 Definition (Probability measure). Let (Ω, A) be a measurable space. A probability measure P on (Ω, A) is a function P : A [, 1 such that for any sequence (A n ) n 1 of elements of A satisfying A i A j =, for any i j, we have ( P n 1 A n ) = lim N N n=1 P(A n ) The triplet (Ω, A, P) is called a probability space. Definition (independence). Let (Ω, A, P) be a probability space (i) Let A and B two elements of A. We say that A and B are independent if P(A, B) := P(A B) = P(A) P(B). (ii) Let B and C be two sub-σ-algebra of A. We say that B and C are independent if any B B and C C are independent. Definition (Measurability and random variables). Let (Ω, A, P) be a probability space. A function X : Ω R is A-measurable if for any x R we have X 1( [x, + ) ) := { ω Ω : X(ω) x } A. A random variable X on the probability space (Ω, A, P) is an A-measurable function. Proposition Let (Ω, A, P) be a probability space and X be a random variable on (Ω, A, P). Denote by σ(x) the σ-algebra σ ( {X 1 ([x, + ) : x R} ) (see Proposition 1.1.1). Then σ(x) is the smallest sub-σ-algebra of A such that X is σ(x)-measurable. Definition Let X and Y be two random variables defined on a probability space (Ω, A, P). We say that X and Y are independent if σ(x) and σ(y ) are independent. Proposition Let X and Y be two random variables on a probability space (Ω, A, P). Y is σ(x)-measurable if and only if it can be written f(x) with f : R R a B(R)-measurable function. Proof. Suppose that Y = f(x). Then, for any borel subset B of R we have f(x) 1 (B) = X 1 ( f 1 (B) ) σ(x). 4

6 Conversly, if Y is the indicator function of a σ(x)-measurable set A, A can then be written A = X 1 (B) for B B(R d ) and, we have Y = 1 A = 1 X 1 (B) = 1 B (X), and the identification Y = f(x) holds with f = 1 B. if Y is a finite sum of indicator functions 1 Ai with A i = σ(x), A i can then be written A i = X 1 (B i ) for B i B(R) andthe equality holds with f = i 1 B i convient. If Y is positive, it can be written as an increasing limit of random variables Y n which are finite sum of indicator functions. We then have Y n = f n (X) and we get Y = f(x) with f = limf n. If Y is not positive, we apply the previous result to its positive and negative parts Moments Definition Let X be a positive random variable on a probability space (Ω, A, P). The expectation E[X of X is defined by E[X = X(ω)dP(ω). Ω Let X be a random variable such that E[ X < + (we say that X is integrable). The expectation E[X of X is defined by E[X = E[X + E[X, where X + and X are the random variables defined by X + = max(x, ) and X = max( X, ) Definition For p 1, we define the space L p (Ω, A, P) (or L p (Ω) for short) by { L p (Ω) = X random variable on (Ω, A, P) such that E [ X p } <. Proposition For p 1, the space L p (Ω) endowed with the norm p defined by is a Banach (i.e. complete vector) space. X p = ( E[ X p ) p, X L p (Ω) Proposition (Jensen Inequality). Let X be a random variable and ϕ : R R be a convex function. Suppose that E[ ϕ(x) <, then we have ϕ ( E[X ) E [ ϕ(x). Definition Let (X n ) n be a sequence of random variables and X random variable on (Ω, A, P). We say that X n converges P-a.s. to X and we write X n X P-a.s. if P( {ω Ω : X n (ω) X(ω) as n }) = 1 5

7 Theorem (Dominated Convergence Theorem). Let Let (X n ) n be a sequence of random variables and X random variable on (Ω, A, P) such that X L p (Ω) and X n L p (Ω) for all n. Suppose that there exists a random variable Y L p (Ω) such that X Y and X n Y. If then X n X as n + P a.s. X n X as n + in L p (Ω). 1.2 Gaussian random variables We fix in the rest of this chapter a probability space (Ω, A, P) Scalar Gaussian variables Definition A real random variable X is a standard Gaussian random variable if it admits the density f X given by 1 ( ) f X (x) = exp x2, x R. 2π 2 We recall that a random variable X admits a density f if for any Borel bounded function ϕ we have [ E ϕ(x) = ϕ(x)f(x)dx. We also notice that for a standard Gaussian random variable X we have E[X = and E[X 2 = 1. Definition Let m and σ > be two constants. A random variable Y is a Gaussian random variable with mean m and variance σ 2 if the random variable Y m is a standard Gaussian random σ variable. We then write Y N (m, σ 2 ). If Y N (m, σ 2 ) then Y admits the density f Y given by Definition f Y (y) = Multivariate Gaussian variables R 1 ( exp y ) m 2, x R. 2πσ 2 2σ 2 Definition A random vector (X 1,..., X n ) is a Gaussien vector if any linear combination of the components X i is a Gaussian random variable i.e. the random variable a, X defined by n a, X := a i X i k=1 is a Gaussian random variable for all a = (a 1,..., a n ) R n. 6

8 We now give two useful properties related to Gaussian vectors. Proposition Let (X 1,..., X n ) be a Gaussian vector. The components X i and X j are independent if and only if cov(x i, X j ) = for any i, j {1,..., n}. Proposition Let X = (X 1,..., X n ) be a random vector such that the components X 1,..., X n are independent and follows Gaussian laws. Then X is a Gaussian vector Remark One should take care about the fact that it is possible to have Gaussian random variables X 1 and X 2 which are not independent and satisfy cov(x 1, X 2 ) =. 1.3 Conditional expectation Sub-σ-algebra and conditioning Theorem Let B be a sub-σ algebra of A. For any integrable random variable X, there exists an integrable B-measurable random variable Y such that E [ 1 B X = E [ 1 B Y for any B B. If Ỹ is another random variable with these properties we have Ỹ = Y, P-a.s. The almost surely uniquely defined random variable Y given by the previous theorem is called the conditional expectation of X given B and is denoted by E[X B. This conditional expectation satisfies the following properties. Proposition Let B be a sub-σ algebra of A. (i) If X is an integrable B-measurable random variable we have E[X B = X. (ii) If X is a random variable and Za bounded B-measurable random variable we have In particular, we have ZE [ X B = E [ ZX B. E [ ZE[X B = E [ ZX. (iii) Linearity: if X 1 and X 1 are two random variables and a 1 and a 2 two constants we have E [ X 1 a 1 + X 2 a 2 B = a 1 E [ X 1 B + a 2 E [ X 2 B. (iv) If C is a sub-σ-algebra of B and X a random variable we have E [ E[X B C = E [ X C. 7

9 (v) Conditional Jensen Inequality: if ϕ : R R is a convex function X a random variable such that ϕ(x) is integrable we have E [ ϕ(x) B ( ϕ E [ X B ). (vi) Conditional dominated convergence theorem: Let (X n ) n be a sequence of random variables and X and Y two random variables such that and then if Y L p (Ω) we have X n Y, for all n, X n X as n + P a.s. E [ X n B E [ X B as n + in L p (Ω) Computations of conditional expectations Proposition Let B be a sub-σ algebra of A. Let X be a random variable independent of B. Then we have E [ X B = E [ X. Proposition Let B be a sub-σ algebra of A. Let X and Y be two random variables such that X is independent of B and Y is B-measurable. Then if Φ is a measurable function such that Φ(X, Y ) is integrable we have where the function ϕ : R R is defined by by for all y R. E [ Φ(X, Y ) B = ϕ(y ) ϕ(y) = E[Φ(X, y) 8

10 Chapter 2 Arbitrage theory 2.1 Assumptions on the market In the sequel, we shall make the following assumptions. The assets are infinitely divisible: One can sell or buy an proportion of asset. Liquidity of the market: one can sell or buy any quantity of any asset at any time. One can short sell any asset. There is no transaction costs. One can borrow and lend money at the same interest rate r. 2.2 The notion of arbitrage To model the uncertainty of financial market, we use the probability theory. We consider a probability set Ω endowed with a probability measure P. We now give the definition of a portfolio. Definition A self-financing portfolio consists in a initial capital x and an investment strategy without bringing or consuming any wealth. For a portfolio X, we denote by X t its value at time t. We now consider the situation where one can earn money with no risk of loss. Definition An arbitrage between times and T is a self financing portfolio X with initial value X = and such that P(X T ) = 1 and P(X T > ) >. 9

11 We now introduce an assumption which ensures that such an opportunity does not happened. (NFL) (No Free Lunch) There is no arbitrage opportunity between times and T : for any portfolio X, we have [ X = and X T P(X T > ) =. This assumption simply means that there is no way to earn money without taking any risk. This assumption also correspond to the reality of the markets. Indeed, even if an arbitrage opportunity appears in a market, it is quickly taken by a trader. 2.3 Portfolio comparison under (NFL) Proposition Let X and Y be two self-financing portfolios. Under (NFL), we have X T = Y T P a.s. = X = Y. Proof. Suppose that X < Y and consider the following strategy. At time t =, we buy X, we sell Y and we put Y X > in the bank account at interest rate r. At the terminal time t = T the portfolio value is always positive. value at value at T Buy X X X T Sell Y Y Y T Put the difference in the bank account Y X > (Y X )/B(, T ) > Portfolio value > Therefore, (NFL) implies X Y. Replacing X by Y, we get X Y and X = Y. Remark To construct an arbitrage opportunity we buy the cheapest portfolio and sell the most expensive one. Since the portfolios have the same terminal value, this strategy provides a positive gain. Proposition Let X and Y be two self-financing portfolios. Under (NFL), we have X T = Y T P a.s. = X t = Y t P a.s. for all t T. This result is a direct consequence of the following proposition. Proposition Let X and Y be two self-financing portfolios. Under (NFL), we have X T Y T = X t Y t for all t T. 1

12 Proof. Fix t T and consider the following strategy: at time : we do nothing. at time t: on the set {ω Ω, X t (ω) > Y t (ω)}, we buy Y at price Y t, we sell X at price X t and we put the difference X t Y t > in the bank account, on the set {ω Ω, X t (ω) Y t (ω)}, we do nothing. Finaly, at time T, on {X t > Y t }, the portfolio contains Y T X T and the positive amount in the bank account, thus it has a positive value, on {X t Y t }, the portfolio value is equal to zero. at time t t en T On {X t > Y t } Buy Y at time t Y t Y T Sell X at time t X t X T Put the difference in the bank account X t Y t > (X t Y t )/B(t, T ) > Portfolio value > On {X t Y t } Portfolio value Therefore (NFL) implies P(X t > Y t ) =. 2.4 Call-Put parity relation A call option with strike K and maturity T on the underlying S is a contract that provides the payoff (S T K) + =: max{s T K, } at time T. We denote by C t the price of such a contract at time t. A put option with strike K and maturity T on the underlying S is a contract that provides the payoff (K S T ) + =: max{k S T, }. We denote by P t its price at time t. A zero-coupon bond with maturity T is a financial product with value 1 at time T. We denote by B(t, T ) its price at time t. We then have the following relation between C, P and B. Proposition Under (NFL), the call and put prices satisfy the parity relation for all t T. C t P t = S t KB(t, T ) 11

13 Proof. Consider the two following self-financing strategies: at at t at T Port. 1 Buy a put option at t P t (K S T ) + Buy the underlying asset at t S t S T Value P t + S t (K S T ) + + S T Port. 2 Buy a call option at t C t (S T K) + Buy K units of zero-coupon bond at t KB(t, T ) K Value C t + KB(t, T ) (S T K) + + K We then notice that (K S T ) + + S T = K 1 {ST K} + S T 1 {K ST } = (S T K) + + K. Therefore, these two portfolios have the same terminal value. Under (NFL), we get from Proposition that they have the same value at every time t T, which gives the call-put parity relation. Remark This parity relation is specific to the (NFL) assumption. In particular it does not depend no the model that we put on the market. 2.5 Valuation of a forward contract A forward contract is a contract signed at time t = between two parties to buy or sell an asset at a specified future time at a price F (, T ) agreed upon today. There is no change of money between the two parties at time t =. To determine the forward price F (, T ) we consider the two self-financing strategies: at time at time T Port. 1 Buy a unit of the underlying S at time S S T Sell F (, T ) units of zero-coupons bounds at time F (, T )B(, T ) F (, T ) Value S F (, T )B(, T ) S T F (, T ) Port. 2 Buy the forward contrat at time S T F (, T ) Under (NFL), we get from Proposition Remark More generally, we have F (, T ) = S B(, T ). for all t T. F (t, T ) = 12 S t B(t, T )

14 2.6 Exercises Put and Call options We suppose that there is not any arbitratage opportunity on the market i.e. (NFL) holds. We denote by B the price at time t = of the riskless asset with gain 1 at maturity t = T. We also denote by C and P the respective prices at time t = of a Call and a Put option on the underlying S with maturity T and strike K. 1. Prove by an arbitrage argument that 2. Deduce from the previous question that (S KB ) + C S. (KB S ) + P KB. 3. Prove that the Call option price is a nonincreasing function of the strike K and a nondecreasing function of the maturity. 4. What can you say about the Put option price? Currency forward contract We consider on the time interval [, T the market of the currency pair euro/us dollar. This market can be described as follows. 1. In the european economy, there is a riskless asset with continuous time interest rate r d. This european riskless asset pays 1 at maturity T, thus its price at time t is given by B d t = e r d(t t) e for all t [, T. 2. In the american economy, there also exists a riskless asset with continuous time interest rate r f. This american riskless asset pays 1 at maturity T, thus its price at time t is given by B f t = e r f (T t) $ for all t [, T. 3. To get 1 dollar at time t [, T, one has to pay S t. 4. Finaly, on this market there exist forward contracts for any date t [, T. A forward contract signed at time t [, T is defined by the following rules: no change of money at the entering date t, at time T, we get 1 $ and we pay F t e, where the amount F t is fixed at the initial time t. 1. Fix t [, T. Using S T, give the pay-off a time T in euro, of the following portfolios constructed at time t. 13

15 (a) Buy B f t $ at time t. this amount is invested in the american riskless asset. Borrow F t Bt d time t. e at (b) Sign a forward contract at time t. 2. Give the pay-off in euro at time T of the portfolio composed by buying a forward contract with forward price F and the short selling at time t a forward contract with forward price F t. By a no free lunch argument, deduce the value f t in euro at time t of the forward contract signed at time as a function of F t and F and then as a function of S t and S. 14

16 Chapter 3 Binomial model with a single period The binomial model is very useful for the computation of prices and most of its properties can be generalised to the continuous time case. 3.1 Probabilistic model for the market We consider a market with two assets and two dates: t = et t = 1. A riskless asset S with value 1 at t = and value R = (1 + r) at t = 1. The dynamics of the riskless asset S is therefore given by S = 1 S 1 = R = 1 + r. A risky asset S with initial value S at t =. At time t = 1, S can take two different values: an upper value S u 1 = u.s and a lower value S d 1 = d.s where u and d are two constants such that d < u. S 1 = us S S 1 = ds The probabilistic model consists in three objects: Ω, F and P. Ω is the set of all the states of the world. There are two possible states, depending on the value that can take the risky asset at time t = 1. We therefore take Ω = {ω u, ω d } P is the historical probability on Ω. It is defined by P(ω u ) = p and P(ω d ) = 1 p. The price S 1 of the risky asset at time 1 has a probability p to go up and a probability 1 p to go down. We take p, 1[ to allow both events ω u and ω d to occur. F = {F, F 1 } is a couple of σ-algebras representing to global information available a times t = et t = 1. 15

17 At time t =, there is no information, so F is the trivial σ-algebra: F = {, Ω}. At time t = 1, one knows if the the asset S went up or down: F 1 = P(Ω) = {, Ω, {ω u }, {ω d }}. This σ-algebra represents all the subsets of Ω that can be said to have occurred or not at time t = 1. Remark We have F F 1. Indeed, we get more and more information with time. Remark F 1 is the σ-algebra generated by S 1 : F 1 = σ(s 1 ). Indeed, by definition, the σ-algebra generated by S 1 is the class of inverse images by S 1 of Borel subsets of R, i.e. {S1 1 (B), B B(R)}. It is also the smallest σ-algebra that makes S 1 measurable. For any Borel subset B of R, if us and ds belong to B, we have S 1 1 (B) = Ω, if us belongs to B, we have S 1 1 (B) = {ω u }, if ds belongs to B, we have S 1 1 (B) = {ω d }, and if any of these two values is in B, we have S 1 1 (B) =. Therefore F 1 is the σ-algebra generated by S 1. Definition A contingent claim (or financial derivative) is an F 1 -measurable random variable. The value of a contingent claim depends on the state of the world at time t = 1. From Proposition and Remark 3.1.6, any contigent claim C can be written C = φ(s 1 ) where φ : R R is a deterministic measurable function. For instance, if C is a Call option with strike K, we have C = φ(s 1 ) with φ : x R (x K) + We consider the problem of the valuation of a contingent claim at time t =. To this end we construct a hedging portfolio for our contigent claim. Under Assumption (NFL) we obtain that all the replicating portfolios have the same initial capital which is the economic definition of the price of the contingent claim. 16

18 3.2 Simple portfolio strategy Definition A simple portfolio strategy (x, ) consists in an initial amount x and a quantity (number of units) of risky asset S. We denote by X x, t the value of the associated self-financing portfolio at time t =, 1. For a simple portfolio strategy (x, ), we have at time t = X x, = S + (x S ) 1 = x. Since X x, is a self-financing portfolio, its value at time t = 1 is given by X x, 1 = S 1 + (x S )R = (S 1 S R) + x R. Such a strategy (x, ) is said to be simple since it consists in investing only in the assets S and S 1. Definition A contingent claim C is said to be replicated if there exists a simple strategy (x, ) such that X x, 1 = C P-a.s. Theorem The binomial model with a single period is complete: any contingent claim C can be replicated by a simple portfolio strategy (x, ). Proof. Consider a contingent claim C. We look for a couple couple (x, ) satisfying { C(ωu ) = S1 u + (x S )R = xr + (u R) S, C(ω d ) = S1 d + (x S )R = xr + (d R) S. Since u > d, this system of two equations with two unknowns is invertible. It therefore admits a unique solution (x, ) which is given by = C(ω u) C(ω d ) and x = 1 ( R d (u d)s R u d C(ω u) + u R ) u d C(ω d). Under (NFL) assumption, all the replication portfolios of the a contingent claim C have the same initial value given by C = 1 ( R d R u d C 1(ω u ) + u R ) u d C 1(ω d ). The economic definition of the price of a contingent claim at time t = is therefore C. 17

19 3.3 Risk neutral probability Definition A simple arbitrage opportunity is a simple portfolio strategy (x, ) with initial amount equal to zero, x =, and a nonnegative terminal wealth which is positive with positive probability: [ X, 1 et P X, 1 > > We then introduce the no free lunch assumption in this context. (NFL ) For any simple strategy (, ), we have [ X, 1 P a.s. = [ X, 1 = P a.s. Proposition Under (NFL ) we have d < R < u. Proof. Suppose that d R. An arbitrage strategy is then given by (, ) with = 1 (i.e. buying a unit of a risky asset). Indeed, at time t = 1, we have { X, 1 (ω u ) = S (u R) >, X, 1 (ω d ) = S (d R). Suppose that u R. An arbitrage strategy is then given by (, ) with = 1 (i.e. selling a unit of a risky asset). Indeed, at time t = 1, we have { X, 1 (ω u ) = S (R u), X, 1 (ω d ) = S (R d) >. For a simple portfolio strategy (x, ), let us introduce the discounted value X x, of the portfolio X x, defined by X x, t := Xx, t R t x, x, for t =, 1. We then have X = x and X 1 = S 1 + (x S ). The self-financing condition can be rewritten with the discounted values under the following form: X x, 1 X x, = ( S 1 S ). Definition A risk neutral probability is a probability measure Q defined on Ω and equivalent to P, under which any discounted value X x, of self-financing portfolio is a martingale, i.e. X x, = E Q x, [ X 1 or equivalently x = 1 R EQ [X x, 1. 18

20 Remark Two probability measures P and Q are said to be equivalent if they have the same negligible sets, i.e. P(A) > Q(A) >, for any event A. In the binomial, this simply means Q(ω d ) > and Q(ω u ) >. A first result is that we cannot have multiple risk neutral probabilities. Proposition Since the market is complete, there is at most a unique risk neutral probability. Proof. Indeed, suppose that we have two risk neutral probability measures Q 1 and Q 2. Fix B F 1 = P(Ω), and consider the contingent claim C = 1 B. Since the market is complete there exists a simple portfolio strategy (x, ) that replicates C. We then get Q 1 (B) = E Q 1 [1 B = E Q 1 [X x 1 = Rx Q 2 (B) = E Q 2 [1 B = E Q 2 [X x 1 = Rx. Therefore, Q 1 (B) = Q 2 (B), and since B is arbitrarily chosen in F 1 we have Q 1 = Q 2. Proposition Suppose that d < R < u, then there exists a unique risk neutral probability Q. Proof. Let us take a simple portfolio strategy (x, ). We have the following equations: { X x, 1 (ω u ) = S 1 (ω u ) + (x S )R = xr + (u R) S X x, 1 (ω d ) = S 1 (ω d ) + (x S )R = xr + (d R) S which give x = 1 R ( u R u d Xx, 1 (ω d ) + R d ) u d Xx, 1 (ω u ). (3.3.1) Introduce the probability measure Q defined on Ω by Q(ω u ) := R d u d := q and Q(ω d) := u R u d = 1 q. Since d < R < u, we get q, 1[ and Q is equivalent to P. From the definition of Q, equation rewrites x = 1 ( ) Q(ω d ) X x, 1 (ω d ) + Q(ω u ) X x, 1 (ω u ) = 1 R R EQ [X x, 1. The uniqueness of Q follows from Proposition Proposition Suppose that there exists a (unique) risk neutral probability Q, then assumption (NFL ) holds true. 19

21 Proof. Fix R such that X, 1. Since Q is a risk neutral probability, we have E Q [X, 1 = R. =. So, X, 1 is a nonnegative random variable with expectation under Q equal to zero. Therefore Q(X, 1 > ) =. Since P and Q are equivalent we get P(X, 1 > ) =. We have finaly proved (NFL ) = d < R < u = There exists a unique risk neutral probabilty = (NFL ), therefore, all this implications become equivalences (NFL ) d < R < u There exists a unique risk neutral probabilty 3.4 Valuation and hedging of contingent claims We can now give the definition of the price of a contingent claim. Theorem Let C be a contingent claim. Under (NFL ), all the strategies (x, ) that replicate C have the same initial capital P (C) given by P (C) = r EQ [C, where Q is the unique probability measure. P (C) is called the price of the contingent claim C. Proof. Let (x, ) and (x, ) be two simple strategies replicating C. Then we have X x, 1 = X x, 1 = C. Under (NFL ), there exists a unique risk neutral probability measure Q. Since X x, and X x, are martingales under Q we get Therefore, we get x = x. x = x = r EQ [X x, 1 = r EQ x, [X1 = r EQ [C, r EQ [C. The price P (C) can be expressed with the parameter q as follows: P (C) = 1 ( q C(ωu ) + (1 q) C(ω d ) ) = 1 R 1 + r EQ [C 2

22 Remark The risk neutral probability does not depend on the historical probability P. Therefore, The price of a contingent claim does not depend on the historical probability P. Remark To compute the price of a cotigent claim C, we only need to know the parameters r, u et d. The coefficients u et d correspond to what we call the volatility of the asset in the next chapters. Remark In the hedging portfolio of a contigent claim C, the number of shares of S held is given by: = C(ω ( ) u) C(ω d ) = φ(su 1 ) φ(s1) d, (u d)s S1 u S1 d which is the relative variation of the contingent claim w.r.t. the risky asset S. 3.5 Exercices Pricing of a call and a put option at the money Let us take S = 1, r =.5, d =.9 et u = What is the price and the hedging strategy of a Call option at the money i.e. K = S = 1? We compute the risk neutral probability: q = 1 + r d u d We deduce the price and the hedging strategy: P (C) = =.75. = and = Cu 1 C1 d = 1 (u d)s 2 =, 5 Hedging strategy: Buy 1/2 unit of risky asset S and put (7.14 5) in the riskless asset S. 2. What about the Put option at the money? Since we know the risk neutral probability, we can compute the price and the hedging strategy of the put option: P (P ) = = and = P 1 u P1 d = 1 (u d)s 2 =, 5 Hedging strategy: sell 1/2 unit of risky asset S and put ( ) in the riskless asset S. 3. Is the Call-Put parity relation satisfied? P (C) P (P ) = = = = 1 1 R = S KB(, T ).

23 3.5.2 Binomial tree with a single period We consider a financial market with two dates and composed by a riskless asset S and a risky asset S. The dynamics of these assets are given by Riskless asset: S = 1 S 1 = 15 Risky asset: S = 1 S 1 = 12 with probability.75 S 1 = 9 with probability Describe the probability space (Ω, F, P). 2. Give the definition of the risk neutral probability. Calculate it. 3. Calculate the prices of a Call and a Put Option with strike Recall the Call-Put parity and show that it is satisfied. 22

24 Chapter 4 Binomial model with multiple periods With this model, also called Cox Ross Rubinstein model, we get similar results to those obtained in the previous chapter for the one period binomial model. 4.1 Some facts on discrete time processes and martingales We fix in this section a probability space (Ω, A, P). Definition A (discrete time) process is a finite sequence of random variables (Y k ) k n defined on (Ω, A, P). Definition A (discrete time) filtration is a nondecreasing sequence (F k ) k n of σ-algebras included in A, i.e. for all k {,..., n 1}. F k F k+1 A, Definition A process (Y k ) k n, is adapted to the filtration F (or F-adapted) if Y k is F k -measurable for all k n. Proposition Let (Y k ) k n be an F-adapted process. Then, the random variable Y i is F k -measurable for all i k. Proof. In terms of information, if the result of the random variable Y i is included in the information given by F i, it is included in the information given by F k F i. In the formalism of measure theory, one notice that the reciprocal image Y 1 i (B) of any Borel set B by Y i is in F i. Since F i F k for k i, we get Y 1 i (B) F k. Definition The filtration generated by a process (Y k ) k n is the smallest filtration F Y such that (Y k ) k n is F Y -adapt. It is given by for all k {,..., n}. F Y k := σ(y,..., Y k ), 23

25 Remark A a consequence of measurability properties, a random variable is F Y k -measurable if and only if it can be written as a (Borel) function of (Y,..., Y k ). Definition A discrete time process (M k ) k n is an F-martingale under P if it satisfies: (i) M is F-adapted, (ii) E[ M k < for all k {,..., n}, (iii) E[M k+1 F k = M k for all k {,..., n 1}. Remark The process M is said to be a supermartingale (resp. submartingale) if it satisfies conditions (i) and (ii) of the previous definition and E[M k+1 F i (resp. ) M k for all k {,..., n 1}. The martingale (resp. supermartingale, submartingale) property means that the best estimate (in the least-square sense) of M k+1 given all the past is (resp. is lower than, is greater than) M k. Remark If M is an F-martingale under P we have E[M k F i = M i, for all i k. In particular E[M k = M for all k. 4.2 Market model We keep the same model as in the previous chapter but with n periods (n 2). We consider a time interval [, T divided in n periods = t < t 1 <... < t n = T. We suppose that the market is composed by two assets. The first one is a riskless asset S. We denote by S t k it value at time t k. We suppose that the dynamics of the process (S t k ) k n is given by: S = 1 S t 1 = (1 + r) S t 2 = (1 + r) 2... S T = (1 + r) n. The second one is a risky asset S. We denote by S tk it value at time t k. We fix two constants u > d >, and we suppose that the dynamics of the process (S tk ) k n is given by the following tree: 24

26 u n 1 S... u n S ds u 2 S du n 1 S... us... S uds d 2 S d n 1 us... d n 1 S d n S Since the tree is recombining, the risky asset can take i + 1 values at each time t i. To complete the description of the dynamics of S, we have to define the set Ω and the law of the evolution of the asset on each branch of the tree. Set of the possible states of the world: Ω is actually the set of possible trajectories for the process S. ω is therefore the set of n-tuples (ω 1,..., ω n ) such that each ω i can take only two possible values ω d i or ω u i. Ω := {(ω 1,..., ω n ) : ω i = ω d i ou ω i = ω u i, for all i = 1,..., n} We then are given an historical probability measure P for the occurrence of of each event. We assume that and we make the fundamental assumption: P(ω i = ω u i ) = p et P(ω i = ω d i ) = 1 p The risky the asset returns Y i := S t i S ti 1, i = 1,..., n, are independent random variables. From the previous option we deduce that: P(ω 1,..., ω n ) = p #{j,ω j=ω u j } (1 p) #{j,ω j=ω d j }. 25

27 We can the rewrite the dynamics of the risky asset S as follow: i S ti = S. Y k, i = 1,..., n, k=1 where Y 1,..., Y n are independent random variable defined on Ω such that: P(Y i = u) = P(ω i = ωi u ) = p and P(Y i = d) = P(ω i = ωi d ) = 1 p. The information available at each time t i, i =,..., n, is given by the filtration (F ti ) i n defined by and F t = {, Ω}, F ti := σ(y 1, Y 2,..., Y i ) = σ(s t, S t1, S t2,..., S ti ), i = 1,..., n. Thus, an F ti -measurable random variable is given by the information accumulated until time t i. It therefore can be written as a function of (S t1,..., S ti ) or equivalently as a function of (Y 1,..., Y i ). Definition A contingent claim (or financial derivative) C T variable. Such a contigent claim can therefore be written an F T -measurable random C T = φ(s t1,..., S tn ), with φ a Borel function. We now look for the price of such a financial derivative. As previously, we use the (NFL) property to show that all the hedging portfolios of this contingent claim have the same initial value which is the economic definition of the claim s price. 4.3 Portfolio strategy Definition A (simple) portfolio strategy (x, ) consists in an initial capital x and an F- adapted process (,..., n 1 ) where i represents the number of shares of risky asset S held by the investor at time t i, for i =,..., n 1. In the previous definition, we ask the process to be F-adapted since at each time t i, the investor does not have more information than F ti. Therefore, the investments done at time t i should be measurable w.r.t. the information F ti available at time t i. Denote by X x, t i the value of the portfolio with strategy (x, ) at time t i for i =,..., n. At time t i, the portfolio X x, contains i shares of S. Therefore, it contains (X x, i i S ti )/St i units of the riskless asset S. From the definition of S, this can be written as t i = i S ti + (Xx, t i i S ti ) (1 + r) i. (1 + r) i X x, 26

28 We suppose that the portfolio is self-financing i.e. no bringing or consuming any wealth. We therefore get at time t i+1. t i+1 = i S ti+1 + (Xx, t i i S ti ) (1 + r) i+1 (1 + r) i X x, Let us introduce the discounted processes: X x, t i := Xx, t i The previous equation can be rewritten as follow and (1 + r) S i ti := S t i. (1 + r) i X x, t i = i S ti + ( X x, t i i Sti ) 1, and Xx, t i+1 = i Sti+1 + ( X x, t i i Sti ). We then get the self-financing relation: X x, t i+1 X x, t i = i ( S ti+1 S ti ). Since this equation holds for any i =,..., n 1, we get by induction for all i =,..., n 1. X x, t i+1 = x + i k ( S tk+1 S tk ), k= Remark From the previous equation we deduce that the portfolio value process X x, is F-adapted. 4.4 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability Definition An arbitrage opportunity is a portfolio strategy (x, ) with initial amount equal to zero, x =, and a nonnegative terminal wealth which is positive with positive probability: [ X, t n et P X, t n > >. Recall that t n = T. In the binomial model with multiple periods, the no arbitrage opportunity assumption takes the following form. (NFL ) We have the following implication X, T = X, T = P a.s. for any F-adapted process = (,..., n 1 ). 27

29 Proposition Under Assumption (NFL), we have d < 1 + r < u. Proof. Suppose for instance that 1 + r d and consider the portfolio strategy (, ), where = 1 and i = for i = 1,..., n (we buy the risky asset at time t, we sell it at time t 1 and we put our gain in the riskless asset). The process is F-adapted since it is deterministic and the portfolio value at time T = t n is given by: X, T = + i k ( S tk+1 S tk ) = S t1 S t k= From the definition of S t1, X, T (1 + r) n S ( u 1 + r 1 can take only two possible values: ) ( d >, and (1 + r) n S 1 + r 1 ) with respective probabilities p > and 1 p >. This strategy is therefore an arbitrage opportunity. In the case u 1 + r we construct an arbitrage opportunity by considering the strategy = 1 and i = for i = 1,..., n 1. Remark As in the one period binomial model, if 1 + r u or 1 + r d one of the two assets S and S always provides a better gain than the other. Therefore, this generates an arbitrage opportunity. Remark Under Assumption (NFL), there is no arbitrage opportunity on every subtree. Indeed, if there is an arbitrage opportunity on a subtree, the strategy consisting in doing nothing out of the subtree, following the arbitrage strategy on the subtree, is a a global arbitrage opportunity, since the probability of reaching any sub tree is positive. Following the results obtained in the previous chapter, we introduce the probability measure Q on Ω equal to the risk neutral probability for the binomial model with single period on each one period subtree and keeping the random variables Y i independent. This probability measure is therefore given by Q(ω 1,..., ω n ) = q #{j,ω j=ω u j }.(1 q) #{j,ω j=ω d j } with q := Remark From the definition of the measure Q we have: (1 + r) d u d. Q(S ti = us ti 1 ) = Q(Y i = u) = q et Q(S ti = ds ti 1 ) = Q(Y i = d) = 1 q Definition A risk neutral probability is a probability measure equivalent to the historical probability P under which any simple portfolio discounted value process is a martingale. 28

30 We next aim at proving that the measure Q is a risk neutral probability. Proposition S is an F-martingale under Q. Proof. S is integrable and F-adapted. We then have E Q[ Ftk 1 Stk+1 = (q u 1 + r S tk + (1 q) d S ) tk ( 1 (1 + r) d u (1 + r) = u r u d u d for any k =,..., n 1. = S tk ) d S tk Proposition The discounted value X x, of a portfolio with strategy (x, ) is an F- martingale under Q. Proof. Xx, est intgrable F-adapted and E Q[ x, Xx, k+1 X [ k Ftk = E Q k ( S tk+1 S tk ) Ftk = k E Q[ ( S tk+1 S tk ) Ftk =. Remark The revious proposition tells us that any portfolio discounted value process is a martingale as soon as the discounted assets are martingales. This is mainly due to the fact that the number of shares of S held by the investor between t k and t k+1 is constant (from the self-financing condition) and F tk -measurable. This property can actually be extended to some transformation of martingales w.r.t. predictable processes called stochastic integration and which remains a martingale as we will see in the next chapter. Theorem Suppose that d < 1 + r < u. Then there exists a risk neutral probability (Q). Proof. We juste have seen that X x, is an F-martingale under Q for any strategy (x, ). Moreover Q is equivalent to P. Indeed since d < R < u, q and (1 q) are positive. Therefore Q(ω 1,..., ω n ) is positive for any (ω 1,..., ω n ) Ω. We now focus on the link between the existence of a risk neutral probability Q and Assumption (NFL). Proposition Suppose that there exists a risk neutral probability. Then Assumption (NFL ) is satisfiyed. Proof. Let Q be a risk neutral probability measure and (, ) a strategy such that, Since Q is a risk neutral probability, we have E Q[ X, T X, T = (1 + r) n X, = 29

31 Hence, we obtain Thus X, T Q(X, T = ) = 1. = Q-a.s. and also P-a.s. since Q and P are equivalent We therefore get the same result as in the binomial model with a single period: (NFL ) d < R < u there exists a unique risk neutral probability. At each time t i the value of a portfolio with strategy (x, )and with terminal value X x, T given by is X x, t i = 1 (1 + r) EQ[ X x, n i T Fi. Once we have a hedging portfolio for a contingent claim, we get from (NFL ) that its value at any time t i time is given by the conditional expectation given F ti of the discounted contingent claim under the risk neutral probability. We now concentrate on the existence of such a hedging portfolio. 4.5 Duplication of contingent claims Theorem any contingent claim C is duplicable by a portfolio strategy (x, ) i.e. there exists a strategy (x, ) such that X x, T = C. The market is said to be complete. Analysis of the problem. We look for a portfolio strategy (x, ) that replicates the contigent claim C at time T. Since C is F tn -measurable, it can be rewritten φ(s t1,..., S tn ) for some borel fuction φ. We therefore look for (x, ) such that X x, t n = φ(s t1,..., S tn ). Since any discounted portfolio value process is a martingale under the risk neutral probability Q the hedging portfolio process X x, satisfies X x, t k = 1 (1 + r) n k EQ[ φ(s t1,..., S tn ) Ftk, k =,..., n. In particular, its initial value x is necessarily given by x := 1 (1 + r) n EQ[ φ(s t1,..., S tn ). 3

32 We then notice that 1 (1+r) n k E Q [φ(s t1,..., S tn ) F tk, as an F tk -measurable random variable, can be rewritten as V k (S t1,..., S tk ) with V k a deterministic (i.e. nonrandom) function. We then have V k (S t1,..., S tk ) := 1 (1 + r) n k EQ[ φ(s t1,..., S tn ) Ftk, k =,..., n. In the previous chapter, we have seen that in the hedging portfolio, the number of shares of the risky asset held by the investor is equal to the relative variation of the contingent claim value w.r.t. the risky asset. We then propose the hedging process defined by k := V k+1(s t1,..., S tk, u.s tk ) V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d.s tk ) u.s tk d.s tk, for all k {1,..., n 1}. We notice that this process is F-adapted. Therefore (x, ) defines une a simple portfolio strategy. Solution of the problem. We now prove that the strategy (x, ) defined previously is a hedging strategy for the contingent claim C. To this end, we prove by induction that for all k {,..., n}. X x, t k = V k (S t1,..., S tk ) By construction of the strategy (x, ), we have x := Thus the result holds true for k =. 1 (1 + r) n EQ[ φ(s t1,..., S tn ) = V. Suppose that the result holds true for k and let us prove it for k + 1. We first notice that X x, t k = V k (S t1,..., S tk ) 1 = [ (1 + r) n k EQ φ(s t1,..., S tn ) Ftk [ 1 = [E (1 + r) EQ Q 1 = (1 + r) EQ[ V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk+1 ) F tk = = = 1 (1 + r) n (k+1) φ(s t 1,..., S tn ) Ftk+1 F tk 1 (1 + r) EQ[ V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, u S tk ) 1 {Xk+1 =u} +V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d S tk ) 1 {Xk+1 =d} F tk 1 { Q(Xk+1 = u).v k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, u S tk ) (1 + r) +Q(X k+1 = d).v k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d S tk ) } 1 { q.vk+1 (S t1,..., S tk, u S tk ) + (1 q).v k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d S tk ) }. (1 + r) 31

33 The self-financing condition writes X x, t k+1 = X x, t k + k ( S tk+1 S tk ). Writing the undiscounted value we get X x, t k+1 = q.v k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, u S tk ) + (1 q).v k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d S tk ) + V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, u S tk ) V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d S tk ) ( ) Stk+1 (1 + r)s tk. u S tk d S tk Replacing S tk+1 by Y k+1 S tk and q by 1+r d, we deduce u d X x, t k+1 = V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, u S tk ) Y k+1 d u d Since Y k+1 takes only the values d and u, we get alors + V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, d S tk ) u Y k+1 u d. X x, t k+1 = V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, Y k+1 S tk ) = V k+1 (S t1,..., S tk, S tk+1 ), which concludes the induction. A consequence of the completeness of the market is the unicity of the risk neutral probability measure. Proposition Since the market is complete there is at most one risk neutral probability measure. Proof. Let Q 1 and Q 2 be two risk neutral probability measures. For any B F T = P(Ω), 1 B is a contingent claim since it is F T -measurable. It can therefore be duplicated by a simple strategy (x, ) and we have Therefore Q 1 = Q 2. Q 1 (B) = E Q 1 [1 B = (1 + r) n x = E Q 2 [1 B = Q 2 (B). 4.6 Valuation et hedging of contingent claims Theorem Let C be a contingent claim. Under (NFL ), all the strategies (x, ) that replicate C have the same initial capital P (C) given by P (C) = 1 (1 + r) n EQ [C, where Q is the unique probability measure. P (C) is called the price of the contingent claim C. 32

34 Proof. Let (x, ) and (x, ) be two simple strategies replicating C. Then we have X x, t n = X x, t n = C. Under (NFL ), there exists a unique risk neutral probability measure Q. Since X x, and X x, are martingales under Q we get x = x = 1 (1 + r) n EQ [X x, t n = 1 (1 + r) n EQ x, [Xt n = 1 (1 + r) n EQ [C, 1 (1 + r) n EQ [C. Therefore, we get x = x. Finally, since the market is complete such a replicating strategy exists. Remark As in the binomial model with a single period the price of the contingent claim depends only on its payoff,u, r et d. In particular the price does not depend on the historical probability P!!! To remember: - Le price of a contingent claim can be written as the expectation of the discounted gain under the risk neutral probability Q. - Under the risk neutral probability, the discounted values of simple self-financing portfolios are martingales. In the case where n goes to infinity, and for a good choice of the parameters u d and r, we can prove that this model converges to a continuous time model called the Black & Scholes model. To study such a model, we need to define similar objects in continuous time. This will be done in the next chapter through the stochastic calculus theory. 4.7 Exercices Martingale transforms Let (X k ) k n be an F-martingale and (H k ) k n 1 be a bounded F-adapted process. We define the process (M k ) k n by M = x and M k := x + k H i 1 (X i X i 1 ), 1 k n. i=1 1. Prove that the process M is an F-martingale. 2. In the binomial model with n periods if the discounted risky asset is a martingale under the risk neutral probability, what can you say about the self financing strategies? 33

35 4.7.2 Trinomial model We consider an extended version of the Cox Ross Rubinstein model allowing the asset price to take three different values at each time step. We suppose that there are n periods and that the market is composed by two assets. The first one is a riskless asset S. We denote by S t k it value at time t k. We suppose that the dynamics of the process (S t k ) k n is given by: S = 1 S t 1 = (1 + r) S t 2 = (1 + r) 2... S T = (1 + r) n. The second one is a risky asset S. We denote by S tk it value at time t k. We fix three constants u > m > d > 1, and we suppose that the dynamics of the process (S tk ) k n is given by S tk = Y k S tk 1, 1 k n, where (Y k ) 1 k n is an IID sequence of random variable with law P(Y 1 = u) = p u, P(Y 1 = d) = p d and P(Y 1 = m) = p m := 1 p u p d, with p u, p m, p d (, 1). 1. (a) Suppose that 1 + r d. Construct an arbitrage opportunity. (b) Suppose that 1 + r u. Construct an arbitrage opportunity. (c) Give a necessary condition to ensure the viability of the market. 2. We look for a risk neutral probability measure. We firstly suppose that n = 1. (a) Denote by Q such a probability measure with Q(Y 1 = u) = q u, Q(Y 1 = d) = q d and Q(Y 1 = m) = q m := 1 q u q d, Use the martingale relation to get an equation satisfied by (q u, q m, q d ). E Q[ S1 = S (b) Give the expressions of q m and q d as functions of q u, r, u, d and m. (c) By distinguishing the cases m 1 + r and m < 1 + r prove that there exists an infinity of risk neutral probability under the condition u > 1 + r > d. Extend this result to a multiple period model. 3. (a) Prove that the existence of a risk neutral probability measure ensures the viability of the market. (b) Deduce a necessary and sufficient condition for the viability of the market. 34

36 Chapter 5 Stochastic Calculus with Brownian Motion We fix a complete probability space (Ω, A, P). 5.1 General facts on random processes Random processes Definition A (random) process X on the probability space (Ω, A, P) is a family of random variables. (X t ) t [,T. Such a process X can also be seen as a function of two variables X : { [, T Ω R (t, ω) X t (ω). The functions t X t (ω), for ω varying in Ω, are called the trajectories of the process X Remark Since we aim at representing the dynamic evolution of a sysem by a random process X, the variable t [, T correspond to the time. However, if one want to represent more general systems, t can be chosen as an element of R, R 2... The space where X is valued can also be more complex than R. Definition A random process X is a continuous process its trajectories t X t (ω) are continuous for almost every ω Ω, i.e. P( {ω Ω : t Xt (ω) is a continuous function }) = L p spaces Notation: For p R +, we denote by: } L p (Ω) := {X random variable on (Ω, A, P) such that X p := E[ X p 1 p < 35

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance Stochastic Finance C. Azizieh VUB C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 1/91 Agenda of the course Stochastic calculus : introduction Black-Scholes model Interest rates models C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

S t d with probability (1 p), where

S t d with probability (1 p), where Stochastic Calculus Week 3 Topics: Towards Black-Scholes Stochastic Processes Brownian Motion Conditional Expectations Continuous-time Martingales Towards Black Scholes Suppose again that S t+δt equals

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Binomial model: numerical algorithm Binomial model: numerical algorithm S / 0 C \ 0 S0 u / C \ 1,1 S0 d / S u 0 /, S u 3 0 / 3,3 C \ S0 u d /,1 S u 5 0 4 0 / C 5 5,5 max X S0 u,0 S u C \ 4 4,4 C \ 3 S u d / 0 3, C \ S u d 0 S u d 0 / C 4

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting. Binomial Models Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October 14, 2016 Christopher Ting QF 101 Week 9 October

More information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Eni Musta Università degli studi di Pisa San Miniato - 16 September 2016 Overview 1 Self-financing portfolio 2 Complete

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Michael Perlmutter Department of Mathematics Purdue University 1 M. Perlmutter(Purdue) Brownian Motion and Martingales Outline Review of Basic Probability

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II)

Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II) Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II) Olivier Lévêque, IC LTHI, EPFL (with special thanks to Simon Guilloud for the figures) July 31, 018 Contents 1 Conditional expectation Week 9 1.1 Conditioning

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics CHAPTER Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics In the last chapter, we observe how the application of the no arbitrage argument enforces the forward price of a forward contract. The forward

More information

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 21th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 3 1 / 51 Outline 1 Some model independent definitions and principals

More information

Risk-Neutral Valuation

Risk-Neutral Valuation N.H. Bingham and Rüdiger Kiesel Risk-Neutral Valuation Pricing and Hedging of Financial Derivatives W) Springer Contents 1. Derivative Background 1 1.1 Financial Markets and Instruments 2 1.1.1 Derivative

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model

Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model Class Notes on No-Arbitrage Pricing Model April 18, 2016 Dr. Riyadh Al-Mosawi Department of Mathematics, College of Education for Pure Sciences, Thiqar University References: 1. Stochastic Calculus for

More information

Lesson 3: Basic theory of stochastic processes

Lesson 3: Basic theory of stochastic processes Lesson 3: Basic theory of stochastic processes Dipartimento di Ingegneria e Scienze dell Informazione e Matematica Università dell Aquila, umberto.triacca@univaq.it Probability space We start with some

More information

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut Financial Mathematics Spring 22 Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut These notes are c 22 by Richard Bass. They may be used for personal use or class use, but not for commercial

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh Option Pricing Mrinal K. Ghosh 1 Introduction We first introduce the basic terminology in option pricing. Option: An option is the right, but not the obligation to buy (or sell) an asset under specified

More information

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 13 Haijun Li Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Week 13 1 / 28 Outline 1 Simulation

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Mathematical Finance in discrete time Lecture Notes for Mathematical Finance in discrete time University of Vienna, Faculty of Mathematics, Fall 2015/16 Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna christa.cuchiero@univie.ac.at Draft Version June

More information

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Matematiikan päivät, Tampere, 4-5. January 2006 Tommi Sottinen University of Helsinki 4.1.2006 Outline 1. The classical pricing model:

More information

Lévy models in finance

Lévy models in finance Lévy models in finance Ernesto Mordecki Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay PASI - Guanajuato - June 2010 Summary General aim: describe jummp modelling in finace through some relevant issues.

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations Anne EYRAUD-LOISEL Workshop : Enlargement of Filtrations and Applications to Finance and Insurance May 31st - June 4th, 2010, Jena

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives M. Vidyasagar Cecil & Ida Green Chair The University of Texas at Dallas Email: M.Vidyasagar@utdallas.edu October

More information

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t Economathematics Problem Sheet 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 1. Calculate Ee X where X is a gaussian random variable with mean µ and volatility σ >.. Verify that where W is a Wiener process. Ws dw s = 1 3 W t 3

More information

European Contingent Claims

European Contingent Claims European Contingent Claims Seminar: Financial Modelling in Life Insurance organized by Dr. Nikolic and Dr. Meyhöfer Zhiwen Ning 13.05.2016 Zhiwen Ning European Contingent Claims 13.05.2016 1 / 23 outline

More information

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5. MATH136/STAT219 Lecture 21, November 12, 2008 p. 1/11 Last Time Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.3 MATH136/STAT219

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 5 Haijun Li An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Week 5 1 / 20 Outline 1 Martingales

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

Option Pricing with Delayed Information Option Pricing with Delayed Information Mostafa Mousavi University of California Santa Barbara Joint work with: Tomoyuki Ichiba CFMAR 10th Anniversary Conference May 19, 2017 Mostafa Mousavi (UCSB) Option

More information

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS 1 2 FAIR PRICING There is a market for an object called S. The prevailing price today is S 0 = 100. At this price the object S can be bought or sold by anyone for any

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar BROWNIAN MOTION II D.Majumdar DEFINITION Let (Ω, F, P) be a probability space. For each ω Ω, suppose there is a continuous function W(t) of t 0 that satisfies W(0) = 0 and that depends on ω. Then W(t),

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market Xiaowei Chen Uncertainty Theory Laboratory, Department of Mathematical Sciences Tsinghua University, Beijing 184, China chenxw7@mailstsinghuaeducn

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 14 Lecture 14 November 15, 2017 Derivation of the

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58-6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15-19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9-31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36-37)

More information

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing presented by Yue Kuen KWOK Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology 1 Parable of the bookmaker Taking

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M The Financial Market The Financial Market We assume there are

More information

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs. Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs Andrea Cosso LPMA, Université Paris Diderot joint work with Francesco Russo ENSTA,

More information

2 The binomial pricing model

2 The binomial pricing model 2 The binomial pricing model 2. Options and other derivatives A derivative security is a financial contract whose value depends on some underlying asset like stock, commodity (gold, oil) or currency. The

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Magnus Wiktorsson September 27, 2018 Magnus Wiktorsson L8 September 27, 2018 1 / 14 The risk neutral valuation formula Let X be contingent claim with maturity T.

More information

Martingale Measure TA

Martingale Measure TA Martingale Measure TA Martingale Measure a) What is a martingale? b) Groundwork c) Definition of a martingale d) Super- and Submartingale e) Example of a martingale Table of Content Connection between

More information

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH HAMPUS ENGSNER, MATHIAS LINDHOLM, AND FILIP LINDSKOG Abstract. We present an approach to market-consistent multi-period valuation

More information

Lecture 7: Computation of Greeks

Lecture 7: Computation of Greeks Lecture 7: Computation of Greeks Ahmed Kebaier kebaier@math.univ-paris13.fr HEC, Paris Outline 1 The log-likelihood approach Motivation The pathwise method requires some restrictive regularity assumptions

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery Peter Carr and Jiming Yu Courant Institute, New York University September 13, 2012 Carr/Yu (NYU Courant) Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery September 13, 2012 1 / 30 P, Q,

More information

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? A Summary of Arbitrage Restrictions and Smile Asymptotics Vimal Raval Imperial College London & UBS Investment Bank www2.imperial.ac.uk/ vr402 Joint Work with Mark

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Kyiv, June 19-23, 2006 Tommi Sottinen, University of Helsinki Based on a joint work No-arbitrage pricing beyond semimartingales with C. Bender, Weierstrass

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

MATH3733 Stochastic Financial Modelling

MATH3733 Stochastic Financial Modelling MATH3733 Stochastic Financial Modelling beta version 30.11.2008 Semester 1; Year 2008/2009 Lecturer: Prof. Alexander Veretennikov, e-mail: A.Veretennikov@leeds.ac.uk, office 10.18d; home-page: http://www.maths.leeds.ac.uk/

More information

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Adapted processes We have seen that the sampling space Ω = {H, T } N underlies the N-period binomial model for the stock-price process Elementary event ω = ω ω

More information

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach Giulia Di Nunno Third AMaMeF Conference: Advances in Mathematical Finance Pitesti, May 5-1 28 based on a work in progress with

More information

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus and Financial Derivatives. Simone Calogero

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus and Financial Derivatives. Simone Calogero Introduction to Stochastic Calculus and Financial Derivatives Simone Calogero December 7, 215 Preface Financial derivatives, such as stock options for instance, are indispensable instruments in modern

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Bernard Bercu Bordeaux University, France IFCAM Summer School Bangalore, India, July 2015 Bernard Bercu Asymptotic results for discrete

More information

Stochastic Finance - A Numeraire Approach

Stochastic Finance - A Numeraire Approach Stochastic Finance - A Numeraire Approach Stochastické modelování v ekonomii a financích 28th November and 5th December 2011 1 Motivation for Numeraire Approach 1 Motivation for Numeraire Approach 2 1

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences UNIVERSITY OF OSLO Faculty of Mathematics and Natural Sciences Examination in MAT2700 Introduction to mathematical finance and investment theory. Day of examination: Monday, December 14, 2015. Examination

More information

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Spring 2016 c 2016 by Martin Haugh A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging In these notes we briefly describe the martingale approach to the pricing of

More information

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics and Statistics Washington State University Lisbon, May 218 Haijun Li An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Lisbon,

More information

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE DOI: 1.1214/ECP.v7-149 Elect. Comm. in Probab. 7 (22) 79 83 ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE FIMA KLEBANER Department of Mathematics & Statistics,

More information

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends. 224 10 Arbitrage and SDEs last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends. 10.1 (Calculation of Delta First and Finest

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3 Chapter 3 The Binomial Model In Chapter 1 the linear derivatives were considered. They were priced with static replication and payo tables. For the non-linear derivatives in Chapter 2 this will not work

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model. Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model Henrik Brunlid September 16, 2005 Abstract When we introduce transaction costs

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

Fixed-Income Options

Fixed-Income Options Fixed-Income Options Consider a two-year 99 European call on the three-year, 5% Treasury. Assume the Treasury pays annual interest. From p. 852 the three-year Treasury s price minus the $5 interest could

More information

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions Arfima Financial Solutions Contents Definition 1 Definition 2 3 4 Contenido Definition 1 Definition 2 3 4 Definition Definition: A barrier option is an option on the underlying asset that is activated

More information

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson Economics is extremely useful as a form of employment

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information