Advanced Financial Models. Michael R. Tehranchi

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Advanced Financial Models. Michael R. Tehranchi"

Transcription

1 Advanced Financial Models Michael R. Tehranchi

2

3 Contents 1. Standing assumptions: complications we ignore 5 2. Prerequisite knowledge 8 Chapter 1. One-period models 9 1. One-period models 9 2. Arbitrage, martingale deflators and 1FTP 1 3. Equivalent martingale measures Contingent claim pricing Markets with an infinite number of assets Call prices from moment generating functions Forward contracts and forward prices 29 Chapter 2. Discrete-time models Investment and consumption A motivating utility maximisation problem and arbitrage Arbitrage and the first fundamental theorem Elements of the proof of the harder direction of 1FTAP Numéraires and equivalent martingale measures Contingent claims Super-replication of American claims 55 Chapter 3. Brownian motion and stochastic calculus Brownian motion 6 2. Itô stochastic integration 6 3. Itô s processes and quadratic variation Itô s formula Girsanov s theorem A martingale representation theorem 69 Chapter 4. Continuous-time models The set-up Admissible strategies Arbitrage and local martingale deflators The structure of local martingale deflators Replication and super-replication The Black Scholes model and formula Markovian markets and the Black Scholes PDE PDEs and local martingales Risk-neutral pricing and PDEs 86 3

4 1. Examples Local volatility models Black Scholes volatility 94 Chapter 5. Crashcourse on probability theory Measures Random variables Expectations and variances Special distributions 1 5. Conditional probability and expectation, independence Probability inequalities Characteristic functions Fundamental probability results 12 4

5 Financial mathematics as a subject is young (as compared to, say, number theory), but it is mature enough now that there has emerged some consensus on the notation, vocabulary and important results. These notes are an attempt to present many of the main ingredients of this theory, mainly concerning the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. But before launching into the story, we will begin by acknowledging some of the real-world complications that will not be discussed at length hereafter. 1. Standing assumptions: complications we ignore Unfortunately, actual financial markets are very complicated. Of course, in order to develop a systematic financial theory, it is prudent to concentrate on the essential features of these markets and ignore the less essential complications. Therefore, the theory that will be presented in these notes is concerned with the analysis of market models that have plenty of simplifying assumptions. That is not to say that these complications are not important. Indeed, there is active ongoing research attempting to remove these simplifying assumptions from the canonical theory. Below is a list of these assumptions Dividends. The total stock of a publicly traded firm is divided into a fixed number N of shares. The owner of each share is then entitled to the fraction 1/N of the total profit of the firm. 1 A portion of the firm s profit is usually reinvested by management, for instance by building new factories, but the rest of the profit is paid out to the shareholders. In particular, the owner of each share of stock will receive periodically a dividend payment. However, in this course, we will assume that there are no dividend payments. Actually, this assumption is not as terrible as it sounds. Example sheet 1 will show how to adapt the theory developed for assets that pay no dividends to incorporate assets that have non-zero dividend payments Tick size. Financial markets usually have a smallest increment of price, the tick. (The tick refers back to the days when prices were quoted on ticker tape.) Indeed, the tick size can vary from market to market, and even for assets traded in the same market. However, in this course, we will assume that the tick size is zero. This is a convenient assumption for those who prefer continuous mathematics to discrete. It is usually a harmless assumption, unless the prices of interest are very close to zero. 1 Actually, things are even more complicated. For instance, stocks can be classified as either common or preferred, with implications on dividends, voting rights and claims on the firm s assets in case of bankruptcy. Also, the number N of shares outstanding is not necessarily fixed. 5

6 1.3. Transactions costs. Financial transactions are processed by a string of middle men, each of whom charge a fee for their services. Usually the fee is nearly proportional to the size of the transaction. However, in this course, we will assume that there are no transactions costs. This assumption is justified by by the fact that transactions costs are often very small relative to the size of typical transactions. But one must always remember that in some applications, it might not be wise to neglect these costs Short-selling constraints. In the real world, it is actually possible for someone to sell an asset that he does not own. The essential mechanism is to borrow a share of that asset from a broker, and then immediately to sell it to the market. This procedure is called short selling. Brokers, however, place contraints on this behaviour. Indeed, they usually require collateral and charge a fee for their service. Furthemore, if the market price of the asset increases, or if the price of the collateral decreases, the broker may ask the short seller to put up even more collateral. However, in this course, we will assume that there are no short-selling constraints. Indeed, the theory of discrete-time trading is cleaner without additional assumptions on the sizes of trades. But we will see that to overcome some technical problems in the theory of continuous-time trading, it will be natural to restrict trading to what are called admissible strategies Divisibility of assets. There is another real-world trading constraint of a rather technical nature. The smallest unit of stock is the share. A share cannot be further divided it is generally impossible to buy half a share of a particular stock. However, in this course, we will assume that assets are infinitely divisible Bid-ask spread. Real-world trading is asymmetrical since the price to buy a share is usually higher than the price to sell it. The reason is that are two different ways to buy or sell an asset listed on an exchange: the limit order and the market order. A limit buy order is an offer to buy a certain number of shares of the asset at a certain price. A limit sell order is defined similarly. The collection of unfilled limit orders is called the limit order book. At any time, there is the highest price for which there is an order to buy the asset. This is called the bid price. The lowest price for which there is an order to sell is called the ask price. The bid/ask spread is the difference. Figure 1 illustrates the evolution of a hypothetical limit order book as various orders arrive and are filled. A market order are instructions to execute a transaction at the best available price. In particular, if the market order is to buy, then the lowest limit sell order is filled first. Therefore, for small market buy orders, the per share price paid is the ask price. Similarly, 6

7 if a market sell order arrives, then the highest limit buy order is filled first, and hence the per share price received is the bid price. However, in this course, we will assume that there are no bid-ask spreads. This assumption is justified by the observation that in many markets, the spread is very small. However, in times of crisis, this assumption is not usually applicable, and hence the theory breaks down dramatically. Figure 1. Top left. The bid price is 8 and the ask is 11. Top right. A limit sell order for three shares at 11 arrives. Bottom left. A limit buy order for two shares at 8 is cancelled. Bottom right. A market order to buy five shares arrives. Note that four shares are sold at 11 and one at 12. After the transaction, the ask price is Market depth. As described above, there are only a finite number of limit orders on the book at one time. If a large market buy order arrives, for instance, then the lowest limit sell order is filled first. But if the market order is bigger than the total shares available to buy at the ask price, then the limit orders at the next-to-lowest price are filled, and progresses up the book until the market order is finally filled. In this way, the ask price increases. 7

8 The market depth is the number of shares available to buy or sell at the ask or bid price respectively. Equivalently, the depth of a market is a measure of the size of a market order necessary to move quoted prices. However, in this course, we will assume that there is infinite market depth. Equivalently, we will assume that investors are small relative to the limit order book, so they are price takers, not price makers. However, the most recent financial crisis shows that this assumption does not always approximate reality just ask the traders at Lehman Brothers! 2. Prerequisite knowledge The emphasis of this course is on some of the mathematical aspects of financial market models. Very little is assumed of the reader s knowledge of the workings of financial markets. However, some mathematical background is needed. Our starting point is the famous observation (sometimes attributed to Niels Bohr) that it is difficult to make predictions, especially about the future. Indeed, anyone with even a passing acquaintance with finance knows that most of us cannot predict with absolute certainty how the the price of an asset will fluctuate otherwise we would be much richer! Therefore, the proper language to formulate the models that we will study is the language of probability theory. An attempt is made to keep this course self-contained, but you should be familiar with the basics of the theory, including knowing the definition and key properties of the following concepts: random variable, expected value, variance, conditional probability/expectation, independence, Gaussian (normal) distribution, etc. Familarity with measure theoretical probability is helpful, though a crashcourse on probability theory is given in an appendix. Please send all comments and corrections (including small typos and major blunders) to me at m.tehranchi@statslab.cam.ac.uk. 8

9 CHAPTER 1 One-period models 1. One-period models We consider a market with n assets. The identity of the assets is not important as long as the standing assumptions (zero dividends, zero tick size, zero transaction costs, no short-selling constraints, infinite divisibility, zero bid-ask spread, infinite market depth) are fulfilled. We usually think of the assets as being stocks and bonds, but they also can be more exotic things like pork belly futures. The models we will encounter in this course will be of form (Pt 1,..., Pt n ) t T where Pt i will model the price of asset labelled i at time t T. In this course, the index set T will be one of the three sets {, 1} for single period models, Z + = {, 1, 2,...} when time is discrete, and R + = [, ) when time is continuous. As simple as it seems, much of the financial aspects of this course already appear in oneperiod models where T = {, 1}. It is, therefore, appropriate to devote a significant portion of the course to this important special case. We now describe our first model. As we shall see later, this set-up captures most of the essential features of the general discrete-time model. We think of time as the present, where we have full information. Time 1 is the future, so outcomes are uncertain. We model this as follows P R n is not random and P 1 is a R n -valued random vector How can we tell if a model is good? Note that the non-random vector P is already observed, so the only thing left to model is the distribution of the random vector P 1. A statistical criterion would be to say a model is good if it fits data well. However, we are in a situation where we have only one realisation of P 1, which will happen in the future. In particular, at time we have no observations of P 1 and hence conventional statistics is impossible! Therefore, we think about the question economically. We consider an investor in the market. Suppose his initial wealth is the non-random amount x R. He chooses a nonrandom portfolio H R n, where the real number H i denotes the number of shares held in asset i. (If H i > then the position is said to be long, and if H i < then the position is said to be short.) The investor consumes the remaining wealth x H P, where we are using the notation n a b = a i b i 9 i=1

10 for the usual Euclidean inner (or dot) product in R n. At time 1, the agent then liquidates the position, receiving the random amount H P 1 which is consumed. We are lead to the following problem: Problem. Given x R and the function U : R 2 R { } which is strictly increasing in both arguments. Find H R n to (*) maximise E[U(c, c 1 )] subject to c = x H P, c 1 = H P Arbitrage, martingale deflators and 1FTP When does the above optimal investment problem (*) have a solution? To answer the question, we introduce a crucial definition: Definition. An arbitrage is a portfolio H R n such that H P H P 1 almost surely, and P(H P = = H P 1 ) < 1. Example. Consider a market with two assets with prices given by (P 1, P 2 ) (4, 7) 1/2 (3, 4) 1/2 (2, 3) (The above diagram should be read P 1 = 3, P(P1 2 = 7) = 1/2, etc.) Consider the portfolio H = ( 4, 3). It costs H P = to buy at time, but the time-1 wealth H P 1 is strictly positive in all states of the world: 5 1/2 1/2 At this point, you should check that the portfolio H = ( 3, 2) is also an arbitrage in the example above. Proposition. If the market has an arbitrage, then the optimal investment problem (*) has no maximiser. Conversely (and more importantly for us) if the problem (*) has a maximiser then the market has no arbitrage. [Technical point. One should be careful about integrability. Recall for that expected value E(Z) is always defined whenever Z almost surely. But for non-negative random variables, the expected value may take the value +. On the other hand, the expected value E(Z) for a general real-random variable Z is defined only if either E(Z + ) < or E(Z ) < (or if both expectations are finite) in which case E(Z) = E(Z + ) E(Z ). This convention avoids 1 1

11 having to define. By the way, here we are using the standard notation z + = max{z, } and z = max{ z, } for real z. To ensure that the objective function of (*) is well-defined, we implicitly assume that the given initial wealth x, utility function U, the initial price vector P, and the terminal price random vector P 1 have the following property: either E[U(c, c 1 ) + ] < or E[U(c, c 1 ) ] < for all portfolios H, where c = x H P and c 1 = H P 1. Easy-to-check sufficient conditions which would imply this assumption are either to assume that either the random vector P 1 is bounded or to assume that U is bounded from either above or below. These points were omitted in lecture to avoid getting too bogged down on technicalities...] Proof. Fix an initial wealth x and for a portfolio H R n, let c (H) = x H P be the initial consumption and c 1 (H) = H P 1 the terminal consumption, and let F (H) = E[U(c (H), c 1 (H))] be the expected utility of consumption as a function of the portfolio. Suppose H is the optimal portfolio. That is, assume that F (H ) is finite (that is, neither or + ) and F (H) F (H ) for all H R n. Assume, for the sake of finding a contraction, that K is an arbitrage. Hence c (H +K) = c (H ) K P and c 1 (H + K) = c 1 (H ) + K P 1, and the event that at least one of the inequalities is strict has positive probability. Since U is strictly increasing in both arguments, we have F (H + K) > F (H ), contradicting the optimality of H. Markets with an arbitrage opportunity would be nice we all would be a lot richer. But for the sake of building realistic models, we usually assume that markets are free of arbitrages. Indeed, the existence of arbitrage is not very economical. In particular, note that if H is an arbitrage, so are the portfolios 2H, 3H,.... That is, if we spot an arbitrage in the market, we could scale it to larger and larger proportions and consume more and more. Eventually, the assumption that we are price takers (meaning we are so small relative to the market that we can trade with no price impact) becomes unrealistic. We now stop briefly to discuss other notions of arbitrage that make sense in this oneperiod framework: Definition. An arbitrage relative to a portfolio K R n is a portfolio H R n such that H P K P and K P 1 H P 1 almost surely, and P(H P = K P and K P 1 = H P 1 ) < 1. An arbitrage relative to the portfolio is sometimes called an absolute arbitrage, but this is just our ordinary definition of arbitrage introduced above. Aside. Note that if H is an absolute arbitrage, and K is any portfolio, then H + K is an arbitrage relative to K. Similarly, if H is an arbitrage relative to K then the portfolio H K is an absolute arbitrage. These comments indicate that in this one-period framework there is little motivation to introduce the notion of relative arbitrage. 11

12 But to see why one might want to distinguish between relative and absolute arbitrage, suppose we want to build a theory where we restrict portfolios to a set A R n. In the theory described in this chapter, we are letting A = R n. Since R n is a vector space, we have that H, K A implies that both H + K A and H K A. But one may want to develop a theory where, for instance, short-selling is prohibited, in which case we would take A = {H R n : H i for all i}. Note that if H, K A the vector H + K is in A but the vector H K need not be an element of A. Hence, for this version of the theory, an absolute arbitrage still gives rise to relative arbitrage, but one cannot necessarily construct an absolute arbitrage from a relative arbitrage. We will return to the notion of relative arbitrage again when we discuss continuous time models. But until then, the term arbitrage will mean absolute arbitrage. In many discussions of arbitrage theory, there is the assumption that at least one asset is a numéraire: Definition. An asset is a numéraire iff its price is strictly positive for all time, almost surely. More generally, a portfolio η R n is a numéraire portfolio is η P > and η P 1 > almost surely. Having a numéraire in the market simplifies the story in some ways. For instance, when we discuss arbitrage theory, we no longer have to allow for intermediate consumption. Definition. A terminal consumption arbitrage a portfolio K such that K P = K P 1 almost surely. P(K P 1 > ) >. Proposition. If H is an arbitrage and η is a numéraire portfolio then K = H H P η P η is a terminal consumption arbitrage. Proof. Note that K P = by construction. Also we have K P 1 = H P 1 η P 1 η P H P. Note that K P 1 almost surely. Also, since η P 1 η P > almost surely, we have P(K P 1 = ) = P(H P = = H P 1 ) < 1. Aside. There is a further reason why we traditionally look at markets with no arbitrage. To explain, we take a moment to ask where do prices come from? The terminal price P 1 is unknown at time but is revealed at time 1, so we model it as random. What determines the randomness? One could argue that all that matters is the beliefs of the market participants, not the underlying mechanism that causes the apparent randomness. So, we assume that there are J investors, and each investor j has a probability measure P j, where j = 1,..., J modelling the distribution of P 1. We also assume that each agent j comes to the market with initial capital x j. The market already has the n assets, with total supply of asset i 12

13 given by S i and S = (S 1,..., S n ). The agents trade with each other until each arrive at an optimal allocation Hj and collectively determine an initial price P. To formalise this, we have the following definition: Definition. Given initial wealths x j, utility functions U j and probability measures P j, for j = 1,... J which determine the distribution of the random vector P 1, let H j (p) = arg max{e j [U(c, c 1 )] : c = x j H p, c 1 = H P 1 } be the optimal portfolio for agent i assuming the initial price is P = p. An equilibrium price P is a solution to the equation J H j (P ) = S, where the notation E j denotes expectation with respect to P j. j=1 Note that the above condition says that for the equilibrium initial price P, the agents portfolios Hj solve their version of the optimal investment problem (*). A consequence of the previous proposition is the following motivating result: Proposition. If the market is in equilibrium then no agent can believe there is an arbitrage. We now return to our market model P, P 1. Our goal is to develop a structure theorem that characterises markets without arbitrages. In order to achieve this goal, we now explore heuristically the implication of having a maximiser to an optimal investment problem. Given the utility maximisation problem (*), it is very natural consider the dual problem. The following calculations are purely formal, with no claim to rigorous justification. Also, we assume for the moment some knowledge of Lagrangian duality, at the level of IB Optimisation, but nothing here is needed for the rest of the course. We define the Lagrangian L(c, c 1, H; Y, Y 1 ) = E[U(c, c 1 )] + Y (x c H P ) + E[Y 1 (H P 1 c 1 )] = E[U(c, c 1 ) Y c Y 1 c 1 ] + Y x + H [E(Y 1 P 1 ) Y P ] where the Lagrange multipliers are a real number Y and a real-valued random variable Y 1. To identify the dual feasibility constraint, we ask for which Y and Y 1 does the Lagrangian have an unconstrained maximiser over the triple c, c 1, H. Since H can take any value in R n, in order for the maximum of the Lagrangian over H to exist, we need E(Y 1 P 1 ) = Y P. Similarly, since the function U is strictly increasing in both variables, the existence of a maximiser implies that Y > and Y 1 > almost surely. Indeed, the maximisers are related by [ ] U E = Y and U = Y 1. c c 1 Given the above motivation, we now make a definition: 13

14 Definition. A martingale deflator for a market model P, P 1 consists of a non-random Y >, a random variable Y 1 > almost surely such that for all i = 1,..., n. E(Y 1 P i 1 ) <, and E(Y 1 P i 1) = Y P i Now we come to first theorem of the course, and one of the most important theorems in financial mathematics. It is no surprise that it is often called the first fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Theorem (First fundamental theorem of asset pricing). A market model has no arbitrage if and only if there exists a martingale deflator. The origin of the terminology martingale deflator is that the process (Y t P t ) t {,1} is a martingale, in the most trivial sense of the word. However, we will use this observation to define martingale deflators in both discrete and continuous time. Note that if Y = (Y t ) t {,1} is a martingale deflator, so is cy for any constant c >. In particular, in the one period setting, it is convenient to work with the normalised random variable ρ = Y 1 /Y. Definition. A pricing kernel (or stochastic discount factor or state price density) is a ρ be a positive random variable such P = E(ρP 1 ) Aside. This is a comment on the origin of the term state price density. Suppose the sample space Ω = {1,..., m} is finite. Then the random vector P 1 has the representation m P 1 = 1 {j} P 1 (j). j=1 That is to say, that each price P1 i is a linear combination of the indicator functions 1 {j}. Each indicator function can be interpreted as the value of a security which pays one unit of money if the outcome (or state) is ω = j and zero otherwise. These are called Arrow Debreu securities. The formula m P = E(ρP 1 ) = P{j}ρ(j)P 1 (j). j=1 shows that we can think of P{j}ρ(j) as the time- price of the Arrow Debreu security of state j. Hence, the quantity ρ(j) is the state-price density (with respect to the probability measure). Proof of the easy direction. First we prove that if there exists a martingale deflator, then there is no arbitrage. Letting X t = H P t for t =, 1, we have by the definition of martingale deflator and the linearity of expectations E(Y 1 X 1 ) = H E(Y 1 P 1 ) = H (Y P ) = Y X. 14

15 Now suppose X and X 1 almost surely. Since Y and Y 1 almost surely, we have Y X = E(Y 1 X 1 ) so that Y X = = E(Y 1 X 1 ). Since Y, we see that X =. Also, see that Y 1 X 1 = almost surely by the pigeonhole principle (Recall the pigeonhole principle: if Z a.s and E(Z) = then Z = a.s.) Again, since Y 1 almost surely, we conclude that X 1 = almost surely. In particular, the portfolio H is not an arbitrage. Proof of the hard direction. We now suppose that the market has no arbitrage, so that for any vector H R n that has the property that H P H P 1 almost surely, it must be the case that H P = = H P 1 almost surely. We will show that, given any positive random variable Z, there exists a martingale deflator Y, Y 1 such that the product Y 1 Z is bounded by a constant. This extra boundedness assumption is much stronger than what we need, but it comes for free from the proof and we will find it useful later in the course. Let ζ = e P 1 2 /2 1 + Z. Define a function F : R n R by F (H) = e H P + E[e H P 1 ζ]. The positive random variable ζ is introduced to ensure integrability. Indeed note that the integrand e H P 1 ζ e H 2 /2 is bounded for each choice of H. In particular, the function F is finite everywhere and (by the dominated convergence theorem) smooth. We will show that no investment-consumption arbitrage implies that the function F has a minimiser H. By the first order condition for a minimum, we have and hence we may take = F (H ) = e H P P E[e H P 1 ζp t ] Y = e H P and Y 1 = e H P 1 ζ. Note that Y 1 Z < C for some constant C > (which depends on H in general). So let (H k ) k be a sequence such that F (H k ) inf H F (H). If (H k ) k is bounded, we can pass to a convergent subsequence, by the Bolzano Weierstrass theorem, such that H k H. By the smoothness of F we have inf H F (H) = lim k F (H k) = F (lim k H k ) = F (H ) so H is our desired minimiser. It remains to show that no arbitrage implies that there exists a bounded minimising sequence (H k ) k. So for the sake of finding a contradiction, suppose every minimising sequence (H k ) k is unbounded. Now we arrive at a little technicality. Let and let U = {u R n : u P = = u P 1 a.s.} R n V = U. 15

16 Notice that if u U and v V then F (u + v) = F (v). Hence, by projecting a given minimising sequence onto the subspace V, we consider an unbounded minimising sequence (H k ) k taking values in V. We can pass to a subsequence such that H k. Now let Ĥ k = H k H k. Note that Ĥk = 1 and that Ĥk V. Since (Ĥk) k is bounded, we can again pass to a convergent subsequence such that Ĥk Ĥ. Notice once more that Ĥ = 1 and that Ĥ V. We know that the sequence F (H k ) is bounded (since it is convergent) but we also have F (H k ) = (eĥk P ) H k + E[(e Ĥk P 1 ) H k ζ] so we must conclude that Ĥ P Ĥ P 1 a.s. (since otherwise the right-hand side would blow up). By the assumption of no arbitrage we conclude that Ĥ P = = Ĥ P 1 a.s., which means Ĥ U. But we also know that Ĥ V. Since the subspaces are orthogonal, we have U V = {}, and in particular, we have H =. But this contradicts the fact that Ĥ = Equivalent martingale measures In this section, we introduce the notion of an equivalent martingale measure. We will see that an equivalent martingale measure is, essentially, the same as a pricing kernel. However, unlike a pricing kernel, the definition of equivalent martingale measure depends crucially on the existence of a numéraire. The primary purpose of this section is to reconcile concepts and terminology used by other authors to the theory developed so far. We will also find that equivalent martingale measures can be used to simplify some calculations later in the course. Our goal is to define an equivalent martingale measure. We begin with another definition: Definition. Let (Ω, F) be a measurable space and let P and Q be two probability measures on (Ω, F). The measures P and Q are equivalent, written P Q, iff iff P(A) = 1 Q(A) = 1 P(A) = Q(A) =. The above definition says that equivalent probability measures have the same almost sure events. Complementarily, equivalent probability measures have the same null sets. It turns out that equivalent measures can be characterised by the following theorem. When there are more than one probability measure floating around, we use the notation E P to denote expected value with respect to P, etc. Theorem (Radon Nikodym theorem). The probability measure Q is equivalent to the probability measure P if and only if there exists a P-a.s. positive random variable Z such that Q(A) = E P (Z1 A ) 16

17 for each A F. The random variable Z is called the density, or the Radon Nikodym derivative, of Q with respect to P, and is often denoted Z = dq dp. As a mnemonic device, note that the Radon Nikodym derivative satisfies the identity dq Q(A) = dp dp. Also, note that P has a density with respect to Q given by dp dq = 1 Z. We only need the easy direction of the theorem, that the existence of a positive density implies equivalence, for this course. Here is a proof. The proof of the harder direction is omitted since we do not need it. Proof. Suppose P(Z > ) = 1 and that E P (Z) = 1. Define a set function Q by A Q(A) = E P (Z1 A ). Note that Q is countably additive by the monotone convergence theorem. Also, Q(Ω) = E P (Z) = 1, so Q is a probability measure. If P(A) =, then the event {1 A = } is P-almost sure and hence Q(A) = E P (Z1 A ) =. Conversely, if Q(A) = we can conclude that {Z1 A = } is P-a.s. by the pigeon-hole principle since {Z1 A } is P-a.s. But since {Z > } is P-a.s., we must conclude that {1 A = } is P-a.s., i.e. P(A) =. Thus Q and P are equivalent. Example. Consider the sample space Ω = {1, 2, 3} with the set F of events all subsets of Ω. Consider probability measures P and Q defined by P{1} = 1, P{2} = 1, and P{3} = 2 2 Q{1} = 1 999, Q{2} =, and Q{3} =. 1 1 Then P and Q are equivalent. We may take their density Z = dq to be dp Z(1) = 1 999, Z(2) =, Z(3) =. 5 5 (Since both measures don t see the event {3}, we can let Z(3) be any value.) Definition. Let (P t ) t {,1} be a market model defined on a probability space (Ω, F, P). The measure P is called the objective (or historical or statistical) measure for the model. Suppose the market has a numéraire portfolio η. Let N t = η P t for t =, 1. An equivalent martingale measure relative to the numéraire is any probability measure Q equivalent to P such that E Q ( P1 /N i 1 ) < and ( ) P E Q i 1 = P i N 1 N for all i {1,..., n}. 17

18 Remark. The idea is that a numéraire can be used to count money. Hence, we can speak in terms of prices relative to (or discounted by) the numéraire. As a preview of what s to come, the term equivalent martingale measure is appropriate since the discounted price processes (Pt i /N t ) t {,1} are a martingale for Q with respect to the filtration (F t ) t {,1} where F = {, Ω} and F 1 = F. We will elaborate on this in the multi-period case. When the market has a numéraire, then the notion of a pricing kernel and that of an equivalent martingale measure are essentially the same. Proposition. Consider a market with numéraire portfolio η, and let N t = η P t for t =, 1. Let Q be an equivalent measure. Then Q is an equivalent martingale measure relative to the numéraire if and only if for a pricing kernel ρ. dq dp = ρn 1 N Proof. This is a matter of chasing the definitions. Putting these ingredients together yields the more common version of the first fundamental theorem: Theorem (First fundamental theorem of asset pricing). Suppose that the market has a numéraire. Then there is arbitrage if and only if there exists an equivalent martingale measure relative to the numéraire. Aside. Recall that if the market model admits a numéraire portfolio, then there is no arbitrage if and only if there is no terminal consumption arbitrage. Since most books assume from the beginning that a numéraire exists, it is rare to see this distinction addressed. Finally, we introduce some more definitions which are frequently used in financial modelling. They will crop repeatedly through these lectures. To avoid repeating the same definition multiple times, we give the following definitions in the context of a possibly multi-period market model. Definition. A (riskless) bond is an asset whose price at a fixed time T > is a positive constant. Unless otherwise indicated, we will adopt the convention that the time-t price of a bond is exactly one unit of money. Definition. An equivalent martingale measure relative to a bond is called a forward measure. Of course, in one period, the fixed time is T = 1. The next definition is also stated in terms of a possibly multi-period model: Definition. A riskless asset (or more generally a portfolio) in a discrete-time model is one whose time t price is known at time t 1, for all t 1. Definition. An equivalent martingale measure relative to a riskless numéraire is called a risk-neutral measure. 18

19 In one period, a riskless numéraire is a bond, and assuming no arbitrage, a bond is a riskless numéraire. Hence the notions of forward measure and risk-neutral measures coincide in this context. But be careful - in general multiperiod models, bonds need not be riskless assets and riskless numéraires need not be bonds. 4. Contingent claim pricing The setting of this section is as follows. We find ourselves in a market with prices (P t ) t {,1}. A new asset (a contingent claim) is introduced to the market with time 1 price ξ 1, a given random variable. The question is this: what is a good value for the initial price ξ of this new asset? Example (Call option). A European call option gives the owner of the option the right, but not the obligation, to buy a given stock at time 1 at some fixed price K, called the strike of the option. Let S 1 denote the price of the stock at the maturity date 1. There are two cases: If K S 1, then the option is worthless to the owner since there is no point paying a price above the market price for the underlying stock. On the other hand, if K < S 1, then the owner of the option can buy the stock for the price K from the counterparty and immediately sell the stock for the price S 1 to the market, realising a profit of S 1 K. Hence, the payout of the call option is ξ 1 = (S 1 K) +, where a + = max{a, } as usual. The hockey-stick graph of the function g(x) = (x K) + is below. We will assume that the original market (P t ) t {,1} has no arbitrage, since otherwise it is difficult to formulate a reasonable answer to the question. Now recall that given a utility function U, a consumption stream c = (c t ) t {,1} is preferred to consumption stream c iff E[U(c)] > E[U(c )], and say that the agent is indifferent between consumption streams c and c iff E[U(c)] = E[U(c )]. Thus, an agent seeks to maximise the expected utility of the consumption stream subject to the constraint that the initial wealth x is fixed. The budget constraint amounts to c = x H P and c 1 = H P 1, where H is the portfolio. Since the consumption stream is parametrised by H, it makes sense to talk of preferences over portfolios. Now add the claim to the market. For which initial price ξ would you be willing to hold one share of the claim? Using the reasoning above, the answer is iff there exists a portfolio H R n such that the augmented portfolio (H, 1) R n+1 (the portfolio of holding (H ) i 19

20 shares of asset i for i = 1,..., n and holding one share of the claim) is preferred to the augmented portfolio (H, ) for all H R n. That is to say, you would be willing to pay ξ for one share of the claim iff (1) max{e[u(c)] : c = x ξ H P, c 1 = ξ 1 + H P 1 )} This leads us to a definition: max{e[u(c)] : c = x H P, c 1 = H P 1 )}. Definition. Given the market (P t ) t {,1}, the payout of the claim ξ 1, the initial wealth x and the utility function U, the utility indifference price ξ is defined to any solution to (2) max{e[u(c)] : c = x ξ H P, c 1 = ξ 1 + H P 1 )} = max{e[u(c)] : c = x H P, c 1 = H P 1 )}. The idea is that if U is increasing in both arguments, so you prefer to consume more rather than less, then the indifference price ξ is an upper bound for the price you would be willing to pay for one share of the claim. Although the notion of the indifference price does provide an answer to our question, it is a bit unsatisfactory since it depends both the model of the future prices and our preferences. While there is plenty of price data available and hence there are many popular statistical models for prices, we do not directly observe our utility function. So in practice, it is hard to compute the utility indifference price. The following concept tackles the pricing problem in a preference-independent way. Definition. A portfolio H R n super-replicates the claim with payout ξ 1 iff H P 1 ξ 1 almost surely. The connection between super-replication and indifference pricing is this: Proposition. Suppose H P 1 ξ 1 almost surely. If U is strictly increasing in both arguments, then H P ξ. This says that if a portfolio super-replicates the claim, then the initial cost of this portfolio is an upper bound for your utility indifference price for the claim, and we have already argued that your utility indifference price is an upper bound for the price you would be willing to pay for the claim. Proof. For any portfolio K we have and using the assumption U(c, ) is increasing we have E[U(x H P K P, ξ 1 + K P 1 )] E[U(x (H + K) P, (H + K) P 1 )] max E[U(x J P, J P 1 )] J = max E[U(x ξ J P, ξ 1 + J P 1 )] J where the last line is just the definition of indifference price. Now by maximising over K and using the assumption that U(, c 1 ) is strictly increasing, we have H P ξ which is what we wanted to show. We finally come to a theorem which answers the question of when super-replication is possible. 2

21 Theorem (Characterisation of super-replication). Consider a market (P t ) t {,1} that is free of arbitrage and let ξ 1 be the time-1 payout of a contingent claim. There is a constant x such that E(ρξ 1 ) x for all pricing kernels ρ such that ρξ 1 is integrable if and only if there exists a portfolio H R n such that H P x and H P 1 ξ 1 a.s. Proof of the easy direction. Suppose that for some portfolio H we have H P x and H P 1 ξ 1 a.s. Then for any suitably integrable ρ we have E(ρξ 1 ) E(ρH P 1 ) = H P x. Proof of the harder direction. Suppose E(ρξ 1 ) x for every pricing kernel ρ such that ρξ 1 is integrable. We need to show that there exists a H R n such that H P x and H P 1 ξ 1 a.s. To that end, let F (H, γ) = e γ(x H P ) + E[e γ(h P 1 ξ 1 ) ζ] where the factor ζ = e P ξ 1 is introduced to ensure integrability. (This function is motivated by the utility maximisation problem introduced in the last chapter. The parameter γ > is the investor s risk aversion. We plan to send γ +, which corresponds the limit where the investor can tolerate no losses.) For each γ >, by the proof of the first fundamental theorem of asset pricing, there exists a unique H γ V such that where We now show that F (H γ, γ) = inf H F (H, γ), V = {u R n : u P = = u P 1 a.s.}. sup F (H γ, γ) <. γ 1 Firt note that by the first order condition for a minimum H F H=Hγ =, we see that by setting Y γ = e γ(hγ P x) and Y γ 1 = e γ(ξ 1 H γ P 1 ) ζ we have found a martingale deflator, and ρ = Y 1 /Y is a pricing kernel. Note that γ F H=H γ = Y γ (H γ P x) + E[Y γ 1 (ξ 1 H γ P 1 )] = H γ (Y γ P E[Y γ 1 P 1 ]) + E[Y γ 1 ξ 1 ] Y γ ξ by since ρ is a pricing kernel and the assumption that E(ρξ 1 ) x. 21

22 Next note that γ H γ is differentiable. (Indeed, recall that H γ is defined as the root of the function F (, γ) : V V, and D 2 (, γ) is a strictly positive definite operator on V, so the differentiability of H γ follows from the implicit function theorem.) Furthermore, since H γ is the minimiser of F γ and hence F (H γ, γ) F (H γ±ε, γ) g F (H g, γ) g=γ =. Putting this together implies γ F (H γ, γ) is nonincreasing, which proves the claim. Now we consider the sequence (H k ) k where the risk-aversion parameter takes the values γ = k N. If (H k ) k is bounded, then we can find a convergent subsequence such that H k H. Note that since the sequence F (H k, k) = (e H k P x ) k + E[(e ξ 1 H k P 1 ) k ζ] is bounded, we must have that x H P and ξ 1 H P 1 a.s. So it remains to rule out the case that the sequence (H k ) k is unbounded. Suppose that it was unbounded, for the sake of finding a contradiction. Then we can pass to a subsequence that H k. Like in our proof of the 1FTAP, let Ĥ k = H k H k and pass to a subsequence such that Ĥk Ĥ. Note that we have that Ĥ V and that Ĥ = 1. But by the formula x F (k, H k ) = H (eĥk P k ) k Hk + E[(e ξ 1 H k Ĥk P 1 ) k Hk ζ] we see that boundedness forces Ĥ P Ĥ P 1. By no arbitrage, we have Ĥ P = = Ĥ P 1 a.s. Since Ĥ V we conclude that Ĥ =, contradicting Ĥ = 1. The take-away message about super-replication is the following proposition: Proposition. Suppose that the market with prices (P t ) t {,1} has no arbitrage. Introduce a contingent claim with prices (ξ t ) t {,1}. If H super-replicates the time-1 payout ξ 1 of the claim and if augmented market (P, ξ) has no arbitrage, then ξ H P. Now we focus on claims that can be both super-replicated and sub-replicated by the same portfolio. Definition. A contingent claim with payout ξ 1 is replicable or attainable iff there exists a portfolio H such that H 1 P 1 = ξ 1 almost surely. Theorem (Characterisation of replicable claims). Suppose that the market model has no arbitrage, and let ξ 1 be the payout of a contingent claim. The claim is attainable if and only if there exists an x R such that E(ρξ 1 ) = x for all pricing kernels ρ such that ρξ 1 is integrable, if and only if there is a unique initial price ξ = x such that the augmented market (P, ξ) has no arbitrage. 22

23 Proof. Suppose E(ρξ 1 ) = x for all suitably integrable ρ. By the characterisation of super-replication (applied to ξ 1 ) there exists H such that H P x and H P 1 ξ 1 a.s. Similarly, the characterisation of super-replication (applied to ξ 1 ) yields the existence of K such that K P x and K P 1 ξ 1 a.s. Adding gives us (H + K) P (H + K) P 1 a.s. Since there is no arbitrage by assumption, we have (H + K) P = = (H + K) P 1 a.s. Therefore, ξ 1 H P 1 = K P 1 ξ 1 so both H and K replicate the claim. By the same argument, both have initial price H P = K P = x. Remark. For any contingent claim with payout ξ 1 there is an interval [ξ, ξ ] where ξ = inf{h P : H P 1 ξ 1 } is the cost of the cheapest super-replicating portfolio and ξ = inf{h P : H P 1 ξ 1 } is the cost of the most expensive sub-replicating portfolio. However, if the claim is replicable, then the interval collapses into a single price, which can be calculated by computing the expected value of ξ 1 ρ for any pricing kernel ρ. Since attainable claims have unique no-arbitrage prices, we single out the markets for which every claim is attainable: Definition. A market is complete if and only if every contingent claim is replicable. A market is incomplete otherwise. We can characterise complete markets: Theorem (Second Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing). An arbitrage-free market model is complete if and only if there exists a pricing kernel. Proof. Suppose that there is a unique pricing kernel. Let ξ 1 be any random variable. By the proof of the first fundamental theorem, we know that the random variable ξ 1 ρ is integrable. In particular, there is a number x such that x = E(ρξ 1 ) for all (the unique) pricing kernels. By the characterisation of attainable claims, there exists a portfolio such that H P 1 = ξ 1. Hence the market is complete. Conversely, suppose that the market is complete. Let ρ and ρ be pricing kernels. Fix for the moment claim with payout ξ 1 1 (The bound is just to ensure integrability). Since ρ+ρ ξ 1 is attainable, there exists x such that E(ρξ 1 ) = x = E(ρ ξ 1 ) E[ξ 1 (ρ ρ )] =. 23

24 Now letting ξ 1 = ρ ρ (ρ + ρ ) 2 Since we have E[(ρ ρ ) 2 Z] = where Z = (ρ+ρ ) 2 >, the pigeon-hole principle yields ρ = ρ almost surely as desired. This box summarises the fundamental theorems: 1FTAP: No arbitrage Existence of martingale deflator 2FTAP: Completeness + No arb Uniqueness of martingale deflator In complete markets have even more (arguably too much) structure: Theorem. If the market model P with n assets is complete, there there exists at most n events of positive probability. In particular, the n-dimensional random vector P 1 takes values in a set of at most n elements. Proof. Suppose A 1,..., A k are a collection of disjoint events with P(A i ) > for all i. Claim: the set {1 A1,..., 1 Ak } is linearly independent, and in particular, the dimension of the span of {1 A1,..., 1 Ak } is exactly k. To prove this claim, we must show that if a 1 1 A a k 1 Ak = a.s. for some constants a 1,..., a k, then a 1 = = a k =. To this end, note that if i j the sets A i and A j are disjoint and hence 1 Ai 1 Aj =. By multiplying both sides of the equation by 1 Ai we get a i 1 Ai =. But since P(A i ) > it must be the case that a i =. Now if the market is complete, each of the 1 Ai is replicable. Hence span{1 A1,..., 1 Ak } {H P 1 : H R n } = span{p 1 1,..., P n 1 } Looking at the dimensions of the spaces above, we must conclude k n. Example. (Put-call parity formula) Suppose we start with a market with three assets with prices (B, S, C). The first asset a bond, so its time-1 price B 1 = 1 is not-random. The next asset is a stock. The last asset is a call option on that stock with strike K and maturity T, so that C T = (S T K) +. Suppose that this market is free of arbitrage. Now we introduce another claim, called a put option. A put option gives the owner of the option the right, but not the obligation, to sell the stock for a fixed strike price at a fixed maturity date. If the strike is K and maturity date is T, then a similar argument as we used for the call option, the payout of a put option is P T = (K S T ) +. It turns out that the put option is replicable in the market (B, S, C). Indeed, we have the identity P 1 = (K S 1 ) + = K S 1 + (S 1 K) + = (K, 1, +1) (B 1, S 1, C 1 ). Hence H = (K, 1, +1) is a replicating portfolio. 24

25 Now, suppose we want to assign a price P to the put for t =. The cost of replication is the unique indifference price (for all increasing utility functions) and also the unique price such that the augmented market (B, S, C, P ) has no arbitrage. Hence we usually set P to satisfy This is the famous put-call parity formula. P C = B K S. Figure 1. A plot of P C versus K, where t = corresponds to 23 October 217 and and t = 1 is 17 November 217, and the underlying asset is the S&P 5 index with S = 2, The price of the calls and puts is taken to be the last traded price on the day (as opposed to the bid or ask price). All data is taken from 5. Markets with an infinite number of assets We now consider the seemingly unrealistic situation where the market is allowed to have an infinite number of assets. Rather than being an exercise for mathematicians to generalise needlessly, we will see shortly that this modelling framework does have practical applications. We now let I be an arbitrary index set, and we assume that for each i I there is an asset i with price Pt i at time t. For instance, if we let I = {1,..., n} we recover the case where there are n assets. For a finite subset J I we will let Pt J denote the J -dimensional vector (P j t ) j J of asset prices indexed by J. Consider a portfolio of holding H j shares of asset j for each j J. We let H J denotes the J -dimensional vector (H j ) j J and so the time t price of this portfolio is given by H J P J 1 = j J H j P j 1. 25

26 Definition. A sequence of finite-dimensional portfolios (H J ) J I asymptotically superreplicates a contingent claim with payout ξ 1 iff lim inf J H J P J 1 The sequence asymptotically replicates the claim iff lim J HJ P J 1 ξ 1 almost surely. = ξ 1 almost surely. Rather than give some abstract theory around these definitions, we move to a concrete example. We consider a market consisting of a risk-free bond with time-1 price B 1 = 1, a stock with time-1 price S 1, and a family of call prices indexed by the strike K with time-1 price C 1 (K) = (S 1 K) +. Theorem. Let ξ 1 = g(s 1 ). If g C 2 [, ) and S 1, then there exists a family of portfolios that asymptotically replicates the claim with payout ξ 1. If g C 2 (, ) and S 1 >, then the same conclusion holds. Proof. Before we begin, note that put options are replicable by put-call parity, so we can and will assume that the market also has put options of all strikes. Now the following formula holds identically g(s 1 ) = g(a) + g (a)(s 1 a) + a g (K)(K S 1 ) + dk + a g (K)(S 1 K) + dk for any a >. Note that the integrand of the first integral is zero unless min{s 1, a} K a. Similarly, the integrand of the second integral is zero unless a K max{s 1, a}. In particular, the ranges of both integrals are bounded intervals on which g is assumed continuous, so both integrals are ordinary Riemann integrals. (One way to prove the identity is to fix S 1 and let h(a) equal the right-hand side. By the standard rules of calculus, we have h (a) = and hence h(a) is a constant. To evaluate that constant, let a = S 1 and note that both integrals vanish since the ranges of integration have zero length.) To exhibit a family of portfolios approximating g(s 1 ), we fix an a > and consider a family of finite subsets of (, ) defined by K n = {K n 1,..., K n n} such that n i = K n i+1 K n i for 1 i < n, that max 1 i<n n i and K n n as n. By a Riemann integration theory the sum g(a) ag (a) + g (a)s 1 + i:k n i <a n i g (K n i )P 1 (K n i ) + i:k i a n i g (K n i )C 1 (K n i ) converges to g(s 1 ) as n. Hence the desired asymptotically replication is achieved by the family of portfolios consisting of holding g(a) ag (a) shares of the bond, holding g (a) shares of stock, and holding n i g (Ki n ) puts of strike Ki n < a and n i g (Ki n ) calls of strike Ki n a for i = 1,..., n. 26

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Department of Mathematics MA408 Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Thursday 15th January, 2009 2pm 4pm Duration: 2 hours Attempt THREE questions MA408 Page 1 of 5 1. (a) Suppose 0 < E 1 < E 3 and E 2

More information

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance Lecture 1 s from finance Financial market instruments can be divided into two types. There are the underlying stocks shares, bonds, commodities, foreign currencies; and their derivatives, claims that promise

More information

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing THE UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON Paul Klein Office: Murray Building, 3005 Email: p.klein@soton.ac.uk URL: http://paulklein.se Economics 3010 Topics in Macroeconomics 3 Autumn 2010 Lecture 8: Introduction

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Lecture 3 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Several important concepts were illustrated in the example in Lecture 2: arbitrage; risk neutral probability

More information

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +... No-Arbitrage Pricing Theory Single-Period odel There are N securities denoted ( S,S,...,S N ), they can be stocks, bonds, or any securities, we assume they are all traded, and have prices available. Ω

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Fall 2017 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2 Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO September 25, 2015 A Brief Look at General Equilibrium Asset Pricing Last week, we saw a general equilibrium model in which banks were irrelevant.

More information

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS David Heath 1 and Hyejin Ku 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA, email:heath@andrew.cmu.edu 2 Department of Mathematics

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Risk-Neutral Valuation

Risk-Neutral Valuation N.H. Bingham and Rüdiger Kiesel Risk-Neutral Valuation Pricing and Hedging of Financial Derivatives W) Springer Contents 1. Derivative Background 1 1.1 Financial Markets and Instruments 2 1.1.1 Derivative

More information

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Friday, 27 May, 2016 1:30 pm to 4:30 pm PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry equal

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives M. Vidyasagar Cecil & Ida Green Chair The University of Texas at Dallas Email: M.Vidyasagar@utdallas.edu October

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Matematiikan päivät, Tampere, 4-5. January 2006 Tommi Sottinen University of Helsinki 4.1.2006 Outline 1. The classical pricing model:

More information

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund Alexander M. G. Cox Sam M. Kinsley University of Bath Recent Advances in Financial Mathematics, Paris, 10th January, 2017 A. M. G. Cox, S.

More information

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications Huyen Pham Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications 4y Springer Some elements of stochastic analysis 1 1.1 Stochastic processes 1 1.1.1 Filtration and processes 1

More information

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints 1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints In this section we study conditions under which savings react to changes in income uncertainty. Recall that in the PIH, when you abstract from

More information

Comparison of Payoff Distributions in Terms of Return and Risk

Comparison of Payoff Distributions in Terms of Return and Risk Comparison of Payoff Distributions in Terms of Return and Risk Preliminaries We treat, for convenience, money as a continuous variable when dealing with monetary outcomes. Strictly speaking, the derivation

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 implied Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 : May 7, 2015 1 / 28 implied 1 implied 2 / 28 Motivation and setup implied the goal of this chapter is to treat the implied which requires an algorithm

More information

The value of foresight

The value of foresight Philip Ernst Department of Statistics, Rice University Support from NSF-DMS-1811936 (co-pi F. Viens) and ONR-N00014-18-1-2192 gratefully acknowledged. IMA Financial and Economic Applications June 11, 2018

More information

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes A Simple Martingale Method Approach Frank Thomas Seifried University of Kaiserslautern March 20, 2009 F. Seifried (Kaiserslautern) Deferred Capital

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Matteo Burzoni Marco Frittelli Marco Maggis June 30, 2015 Abstract In a model independent discrete time financial

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

by Kian Guan Lim Professor of Finance Head, Quantitative Finance Unit Singapore Management University

by Kian Guan Lim Professor of Finance Head, Quantitative Finance Unit Singapore Management University by Kian Guan Lim Professor of Finance Head, Quantitative Finance Unit Singapore Management University Presentation at Hitotsubashi University, August 8, 2009 There are 14 compulsory semester courses out

More information

Outline of Lecture 1. Martin-Löf tests and martingales

Outline of Lecture 1. Martin-Löf tests and martingales Outline of Lecture 1 Martin-Löf tests and martingales The Cantor space. Lebesgue measure on Cantor space. Martin-Löf tests. Basic properties of random sequences. Betting games and martingales. Equivalence

More information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia Marco Frittelli Università degli Studi di Firenze Winter School on Mathematical Finance January 24, 2005 Lunteren. On Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets. based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini

More information

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options IEOR E476: Financial Engineering: Discrete-Time Asset Pricing c 21 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options We consider some further applications of

More information

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

A Robust Option Pricing Problem IMA 2003 Workshop, March 12-19, 2003 A Robust Option Pricing Problem Laurent El Ghaoui Department of EECS, UC Berkeley 3 Robust optimization standard form: min x sup u U f 0 (x, u) : u U, f i (x, u) 0,

More information

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics CHAPTER Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics In the last chapter, we observe how the application of the no arbitrage argument enforces the forward price of a forward contract. The forward

More information

Introduction to Real Options

Introduction to Real Options IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Introduction to Real Options We introduce real options and discuss some of the issues and solution methods that arise when tackling

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Chapter 2. An Introduction to Forwards and Options. Question 2.1

Chapter 2. An Introduction to Forwards and Options. Question 2.1 Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options Question 2.1 The payoff diagram of the stock is just a graph of the stock price as a function of the stock price: In order to obtain the profit diagram

More information

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 7 - part 2 Option Pricing Foundations Nico van der Wijst 1 Finance: A Quantitative Introduction c Cambridge University Press 1 The setting 2 3 4 2 Finance:

More information

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation. Stochastic Differential Equation Consider. Moreover partition the interval into and define, where. Now by Rieman Integral we know that, where. Moreover. Using the fundamentals mentioned above we can easily

More information

The Uncertain Volatility Model

The Uncertain Volatility Model The Uncertain Volatility Model Claude Martini, Antoine Jacquier July 14, 008 1 Black-Scholes and realised volatility What happens when a trader uses the Black-Scholes (BS in the sequel) formula to sell

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 24, November 28 Outline 1 Sequential Trade and Arrow Securities 2 Radner Equilibrium 3 Equivalence

More information

INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS. Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero

INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS. Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS Table of Contents PREFACE...1

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options June 1, 2005 Abstract Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options In this paper we re-examine

More information

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid alejandro.balbas@uc3m.es Content Introduction. Describing volatility derivatives. Pricing and

More information

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Hariharan Narayanan December 7, 2014 Martingales 1 Introduction Martingales were originally introduced into probability theory as a model for fair betting games. Essentially

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

Path-dependent inefficient strategies and how to make them efficient.

Path-dependent inefficient strategies and how to make them efficient. Path-dependent inefficient strategies and how to make them efficient. Illustrated with the study of a popular retail investment product Carole Bernard (University of Waterloo) & Phelim Boyle (Wilfrid Laurier

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Yao s Minimax Principle

Yao s Minimax Principle Complexity of algorithms The complexity of an algorithm is usually measured with respect to the size of the input, where size may for example refer to the length of a binary word describing the input,

More information

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Ineffectiveness of VaR and ES constraints John Armstrong (KCL), Damiano Brigo (Imperial) Quant Summit March 2018 Are ES constraints effective against rogue

More information

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Uncertainty in Equilibrium Uncertainty in Equilibrium Larry Blume May 1, 2007 1 Introduction The state-preference approach to uncertainty of Kenneth J. Arrow (1953) and Gérard Debreu (1959) lends itself rather easily to Walrasian

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

MSc Financial Mathematics

MSc Financial Mathematics MSc Financial Mathematics Programme Structure Week Zero Induction Week MA9010 Fundamental Tools TERM 1 Weeks 1-1 0 ST9080 MA9070 IB9110 ST9570 Probability & Numerical Asset Pricing Financial Stoch. Processes

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging Johannes Muhle-Karbe TU München Joint work with Jan Kallsen and Richard Vierthauer Workshop "Finance and Insurance", Jena Overview Introduction Utility-based

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting. Binomial Models Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October 14, 2016 Christopher Ting QF 101 Week 9 October

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Econ 204A - Henning Bohn * Most of modern macroeconomics involves models of agents that optimize over time. he basic ideas and tools are the same as in microeconomics,

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions COMS 6998-3: Algorithmic Game Theory October 6, 2008 Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions Lecturer: Sébastien Lahaie Scribe: Sébastien Lahaie In this lecture we examine a procedure that generalizes

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES Along with providing the way uncertainty is formalized in the considered economy, we establish in this chapter the

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information Frank hierbach Department of Statistics University of Bonn Adenauerallee 24 42 53113 Bonn, Germany email: thierbach@finasto.uni-bonn.de Abstract

More information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Mathematical Finance in discrete time Lecture Notes for Mathematical Finance in discrete time University of Vienna, Faculty of Mathematics, Fall 2015/16 Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna christa.cuchiero@univie.ac.at Draft Version June

More information

Risk management. Introduction to the modeling of assets. Christian Groll

Risk management. Introduction to the modeling of assets. Christian Groll Risk management Introduction to the modeling of assets Christian Groll Introduction to the modeling of assets Risk management Christian Groll 1 / 109 Interest rates and returns Interest rates and returns

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process

Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process Communications in Mathematical Finance, vol. 2, no. 2, 2013, 1-21 ISSN: 2241-1968 (print), 2241 195X (online) Scienpress Ltd, 2013 Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process

More information

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging Johannes Muhle-Karbe ETH Zürich Joint work with Jan Kallsen and Richard Vierthauer LUH Kolloquium, 21.11.2013, Hannover Outline Introduction Asymptotic

More information