Derivative Pricing and Logarithmic Portfolio Optimization in Incomplete Markets

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Derivative Pricing and Logarithmic Portfolio Optimization in Incomplete Markets"

Transcription

1 Derivative Pricing and Logarithmic Portfolio Optimization in Incomplete Markets Dissertation zur Erlangung des Doktorgrades der Mathematischen Fakultät der Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg i. Br. vorgelegt von Thomas Goll November 200

2 Dekan: Referenten: Prof. Dr. Ernst Kuwert Prof. Dr. Ludger Rüschendorf Prof. Dr. Dmitry Kramkov Datum der Promotion: 2. Februar 2002 Institut für Mathematische Stochastik Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg Eckerstraße D-7904 Freiburg i. Br.

3 Preface This thesis studies the problem of derivative pricing in incomplete markets and the problem of portfolio optimization for logarithmic utility. In a complete financial market any contingent claim is attainable and the unique price of a derivative compatible with the no arbitrage condition can be obtained by the unique equivalent martingale measure. In an incomplete market, when perfect hedging of contingent claims is not always possible, the no arbitrage criterion does not suffice to value contingent claims any more. Each equivalent martingale measure yields a possible price and it can happen that these prices fill the whole price interval of trivial bounds cf. Eberlein and Jacod 997. Therefore additional criteria have to be imposed for derivative pricing. One approach is to consider the martingale measure which minimizes a certain distance: like L 2 -distance e.g. Schweizer 996, Hellinger distance e.g. Keller 997, or entropy distance e.g. Frittelli 2000a. One aim of this thesis is to characterize such minimal distance martingale measures in general semimartingale models. We do not consider special distances but the whole class of f-divergence distances defined by strictly convex, differentiable functions, which includes all the distances above. Additionally, we allow to restrict the class of martingale measures by moment constraints. An application is derivative pricing when market prices of some derivatives are known and one is looking for a pricing measure consistent with observed market prices. For derivative pricing we propose the minimal distance martingale measure consistent with observed market prices. Some necessary and some sufficient conditions for these measures are derived. Moreover, we show that minimal distance martingale measures are equivalent to so-called minimax martingale measures, which are defined with respect to concave utility functions and were studied in various forms in the past e.g. Bellini and Frittelli Based on the characterization of minimal distance martingale measures we directly obtain a duality result for optimal portfolios, i.e. for portfolios maximizing the expected utility of terminal wealth with respect to utility functions of the kind u : R + R. This duality result does not completely characterize optimal portfolios, since minimal distance martingale measures need not exist for a complete duality result in the case without constraints see Kramkov and Schachermayer 999, but it allows us to show the relationship between derivative pricing by minimal distance martingale measures and utility-based derivative pricing cf. Davis 997. The idea of utility-based derivative pricing is that derivative prices should be such, that trading I

4 II the derivatives does not increase the maximal expected utility of an investor in comparison to just trading the underlyings. Therefore minimal distance martingale measures can be motivated economically. Moreover, our duality result enables us to determine minimal distance martingale measures explicitly in the case without constraints and exponential Lévy processes with respect to several classical distances. Another problem studied in this thesis is the determination of optimal portfolios for logarithmic utility in general semimartingale models. This is a classical problem in mathematical finance, which has been studied for several market models in the past e.g. Merton 97, Cvitanić and Karatzas 992. Recently Kramkov and Schachermayer 999 proved the existence of log-optimal portfolios for terminal wealth in a general semimartingale framework. This thesis provides a complete explicit characterization of log-optimal portfolios in terms of the semimartingale characteristics of the price process, containing earlier results as special cases. We use the so-called duality or martingale approach to obtain these results cf. Chapter 3 and the references therein. This approach represents the connecting link between the two parts of this thesis. What precisely are our results concerning log-optimal portfolios? We give a sufficient condition which turns out to be necessary as well. Moreover, the sufficient part is extended in two respects: Firstly, we allow for random convex constraints similar to Cvitanić and Karatzas 992. This includes, for instance, the case of short sale constraints. Secondly, the consumption clock may be stochastic as well. As an example we consider a life-insurance problem for which the time of consumption is bounded by the random lifetime. Furthermore, we discuss some special properties of log-optimal portfolios by extending earlier results to the general semimartingale framework. We also determine the minimal distance martingale measure with respect to the reverse relative entropy, which is the f-divergence corresponding to logarithmic utility, and discuss its special features. The main tools which are used in this thesis are the theory of f-divergences and the corresponding results on f-projections cf. Liese and Vajda 987 and especially semimartingale characteristics in the sense of Jacod and Shiryaev 987. Characteristics describe the local behaviour of a semimartingale and turn out to be an appropriate tool to characterize martingale measures and optimal portfolios. The thesis is structured as follows. In Chapter we introduce the concept of σ- localization, which is indispensable for the complete characterization of log-optimal portfolios. In particular, σ-martingales, which play an important role in incomplete financial markets, are considered and their differences to local martingales and martingales are pointed out. We show how martingale measures and the related classes of local martingale and σ-martingale measures can be characterized in terms of semimartingale characteristics. Chapter 2 contains an introduction to f-divergences. Some necessary and some sufficient conditions for minimal distance martingale measures consistent with observed market prices are derived. We introduce the notion of a minimax measure and show that minimal distance martingale measures are equivalent to minimax martingale measures. Chapter 3 shows how the results of Chapter 2

5 are related to the problem of portfolio optimization. The relationship between minimal distance martingale measures and utility-based derivative pricing is pointed out. Moreover, minimal distance martingale measures are determined explicitly for exponential Lévy processes with respect to several classical distances. In Chapter 4 we derive a complete explicit solution to the problem of portfolio optimization for logarithmic utility in terms of the semimartingale characteristics of the price process. We determine the martingale measure minimizing the reverse relative entropy and discuss its special features. The final chapter contains some interesting examples of log-optimal portfolios. As an example of a random consumption clock we consider a life-insurance problem. I thank my advisor Ludger Rüschendorf for encouraging me to start this project and for many valuable suggestions and comments. In particular, Chapters 2 and 3 are based on Goll and Rüschendorf 2000, 200. I am also very grateful to Jan Kallsen for many fruitful discussions. A result of them is our joint work in Chapters and 4, and Section 5.. In slightly different form Chapters and 4 have been submitted in Goll and Kallsen 200a. Section 5. is mostly based on Goll and Kallsen 2000, 200b. Special thanks go to Walter Schachermayer for his hospitality and fruitful discussions during my research stay at the Technische Universität Wien. Moreover, I thank Fehmi Özkan for his encouraging spirit and for fruitful discussions and Ulla Lang for correcting my English. I very much enjoyed the time at the Institut für Mathematische Stochastik and I thank all its members for contributing to this. III

6 IV

7 Contents On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures. Introduction σ-localization and σ-martingales Equivalent σ-martingale Measures Minimal Distance Martingale Measures 3 2. Introduction f-divergences and Minimal Distance Measures Minimal Distance Martingale Measures Minimal Distance and Minimax Measures The Relationship to Portfolio Optimization Introduction The Case Without Constraints Examples of Minimal Distance Martingale Measures The Esscher Transform Distance Minimization for Power Functions The Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure The Case With Constraints Optimal Portfolios for Logarithmic Utility Introduction Preliminaries Explicit Solution in Terms of Characteristics Necessity and Existence in the Absence of Constraints Some Properties and Special Cases The Minimal Distance Martingale Measure Examples of Log-Optimal Portfolios Deterministic Consumption Clock Random Consumption Clock A Results from Stochastic Calculus 83 V

8 VI CONTENTS Bibliography 87

9 Chapter On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures. Introduction The aim of this chapter is twofold. On the one hand, it provides the concept of σ- localization, which is needed in the following chapters, especially in Chapter 4. On the other hand, we characterize equivalent martingale measures in terms of semimartingale characteristics. As a particular case of a σ-localized class of semimartingales we consider the class of σ-localized martingales, i.e. σ-martingales. The class of σ-martingales is a useful extension of the class of martingales. In general the stochastic integral with respect to a martingale is not a martingale again. If the stochastic integral is bounded from below, one knows that it is a local martingale cf. Ansel and Stricker 994, Corollary 3.5. This holds true if the integrator is a σ-martingale. Therefore, if one is interested in the gains processes of portfolio strategies, the requirement that the price process is a σ-martingale is as good as the requirement that the price process is a martingale cf. Delbaen and Schachermayer 998, Remark 2.4. Hence σ-martingales are a useful tool in mathematical finance. This becomes evident if one considers the general versions of the Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing in Delbaen and Schachermayer 998 and Cherny and Shiryaev σ-localization and σ-martingales σ-martingales have been introduced by Chou 979 and were investigated further by Emery 980 under the name semimartingales de la classe Σ m. The term σ- martingale was introduced by Delbaen and Schachermayer 998, who used the concept of σ-martingales in mathematical finance for the first time. Note that some researchers prefer the older name martingale transforms, which was originally applied in discrete-time settings cf. Cherny and Shiryaev 200.

10 2 Chapter. On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures A σ-martingale can be interpreted quite naturally as a semimartingale with vanishing drift. Similar to local martingales, the set of σ-martingales can be obtained from the class of martingales by a localization procedure, but here localization has to be understood in a broader sense than usually cf. Jacod and Shiryaev 987, I.d; henceforth Jacod and Shiryaev 987 is abbreviated to JS. In the following we consider a filtered probability space Ω, F, F t t R+, P in the sense of JS, Definition I..2, i.e. the filtration is assumed to be right-continuous but is not necessarily complete. For any semimartingale X and any predictable set D Ω R +, we write X D := X 0 D 0 + D X, where D 0ω := D ω, 0 for ω Ω. In particular, we have X [[0,T ]] = X T for any stopping time T cf. JS, I Definition. For any class C of semimartingales we define the σ-localized class C σ as follows: A process X belongs to C σ if and only if there exists an increasing sequence D n n N of predictable sets such that D n Ω R + up to an evanescent set and X Dn C for any n N. The σ-localization is most useful for classes of semimartingales, which are stable under stopping cf. JS, Definition I..34. Lemma.2 If C is stable under stopping, then C loc σ = C σ. Proof. We mimic the proof of a similar statement in JS, I..35. Let X C loc σ and D n n N a localizing sequence of predictable sets such that X Dn C loc for any n N. Since with C also C loc is stable under stopping cf. JS I..35a, we may assume that D n = D n [0, n]. For any n N there exists a localizing sequence of stopping times T n, p p N and p n N such that X Dn T n,p C for any p N and P T n, p n < n 2 n. We define a new sequence of predictable sets by D n := D n [0, T m, p m ]. m n Observe that D n n N is an increasing sequence. Let k N and ω, t Ω [0, k] with ω, t n N D n\ n N D n = lim sup n D n \ D n. Obviously, this holds up to evanescence also for ω, k instead of ω, t. Since P {ω Ω : ω, k D n \ D n } m n P T m, p m < n m n P T m, p m < m m n 2 m = 2 n, the Borel-Cantelli lemma yields P {ω Ω : ω, k lim supd n \ D n } = 0, n

11 .2. σ-localization and σ-martingales 3 and hence Ω [0, k] n N D n up to an evanescent set. Since C is stable under stopping and X D n = X Dn T n,pn m n+ T m,pm, we deduce that X D n C for any n N. Hence X belongs to C σ. Of course, we have C C loc C σ for any class C of semimartingales. As a particular case, we obtain the set M σ of σ-martingales. Observe the special feature in our notion of a σ-martingale. To be precise, X M σ holds if and only if X X 0 is a semimartingale de la classe Σ m. Equivalent definitions of σ-martingales can be found in Emery 980, Proposition 2. We denote by D the set of semimartingales such that the stopped process X t is of class D for any t R + cf. JS I..46. Below we consider the corresponding localized classes D loc, D σ. The σ-martingale property can be easily read from the characteristics of a semimartingale cf. Kabanov 997, Lemma 3. In the following let X be a real-valued semimartingale with X 0 = 0. Let B, C, ν be a version of the characteristics of X relative to some truncation function h : R R which is of the form B = b A, C = c A, ν = A F,. where A A + loc and b are predictable processes, c is a predictable R +-valued process, and F is a transition kernel from Ω R +, P into R, B. Note that by JS, II.2.9, such a version of the characteristics of X always exists. We start with an auxiliary result. Lemma.3. X D σ if and only if x F dx < P A-almost { x >} everywhere on Ω R X D loc if and only if x F dx LA if and only if X is a special { x >} semimartingale. Proof. 2. The second equivalence follows from JS, II.2.29 and II.2.3. Therefore it suffices to show that X D loc if and only if X is a special semimartingale. This equivalence is stated as an exercise in Jacod 979, Exercise 2., and is proved in the following. : Let X = M + A be a semimartingale decomposition of X, i.e. M is a local martingale and A belongs to V. Let S n be a sequence of stopping times such that X Sn D. Define the stopping time T n := inf{t > 0 : VarA t n} S n cf. JS, I..28b. Since VarA Tn n + A Tn n + A Tn + A Tn 2n + A Tn,

12 4 Chapter. On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures we see that A A loc. By JS, I.4.23, X is a special semimartingale. : By JS, I.4.23, any semimartingale decomposition X = M + A satisfies A A loc. Let S n be a localizing sequence of stopping times such that M Sn is a uniformly integrable martingale and let T n be a localizing sequence such that E Var A Tn <. If we set R n := S n T n, it follows that X Rn D and hence X D loc.. Obviously D is stable under stopping. Therefore, D σ = D loc σ holds by Lemma.2, and the result follows from Statement 2. Remark. The class D σ was introduced by Chou 979 under the name semimartingales de la classe Σ. It was investigated further by Emery 980. To be precise, X D σ holds if and only if X X 0 is a semimartingale de la classe Σ see Emery 980, Proposition 2. The following Lemma compares σ-martingales with local martingales and martingales. Lemma.4. X is a σ-martingale if and only if x F dx < and { x >} b + x hxf dx = 0.2 hold P A-almost everywhere on Ω R X is a local martingale if and only if x F dx LA and Equation { x >}.2 holds P A-almost everywhere on Ω R X is a martingale if and only if X D and Equation.2 holds P A-almost everywhere on Ω R +. Proof. 2. This follows immediately from JS, II.2.29, and Lemma.3.. This follows from Statement 2 because M σ = M loc σ cf. also Lemma A : Since martingales are local martingales which belong to D cf. JS, Proposition I..47 this is a consequence of Statement 2. : It follows from Lemma.3 that X is a special semimartingale. By JS, II.2.29, and Statement 2 we get that X is a local martingale. Due to JS, I..47, we are done. Consequently, martingales, local martingales, and σ-martingales can all be interpreted as processes with vanishing drift see Equation.2 that differ only in the extent of uniform integrability. If we drop Equation.2 and keep the integrability conditions in Lemma.4, then we end up with the sets D σ, D loc, and D. Since in discrete time one can choose A t := s t Ns, Lemma.4 shows that in this case the class of σ-martingales coincides with the class of local martingales see also Shiryaev 999, Ch. II, c. In continuous time this does not hold true. There are σ-martingales which are not local martingales. The following example was given by Emery 980.

13 .2. σ-localization and σ-martingales 5 Example.5 Let τ be an exponential distributed random variable with parameter λ =, i.e. P τ > t = e t. Let η be independent of τ with P η = = P η = =. 2 Define the process M by { 0 if t < τ, M t := η if t τ and set H t =. Obviously M is a martingale with respect to the filtration F t t t R+ generated by M. Moreover we have H L S M, i.e. the process H is M-integrable in the sense of Stieltjes. For X := H M we have { 0 if t < τ, X t := η τ if t τ. Sine we have E X T = for any F t -stopping time T with P T > 0 > 0, the semimartingale X fails to be a local martingale. But, due to Emery 980, Proposition 2, it is a σ-martingale. Let us consider the characteristics of the semimartingale X. Let B, C, ν be the characteristics of M relative to the truncation function hx := x { x }. It turns out that they are of the form B = b A, C = c A, ν = A F,.3 where A t := t, b = 0, c = 0, and F t G = [[0,τ]] 2 ε G + 2 ε G for any G B. Let B, C, ν be the characteristics of H M relative to h. By Lemma A.5, they are of the form.3 as well, but with b = hh t x H t hxf t dx, c = 0, F t G = G H t xf dx for any G B. Now it is easy to check that X fulfills the condition of Lemma.4, i.e. x F dx < and { x >} b + x hx F dx = 0 P A-a.e. on Ω R +. However, it turns out that { x >} and hence X is not a local martingale. x F dx = [[0,τ]] { t >} t / LA

14 6 Chapter. On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures For a further illuminating example of a σ-martingale which is not a local martingale we refer to Delbaen and Schachermayer 998. In the following we summarize some relationships between σ-martingales, local martingales, and martingales. Corollary.6. X is a local martingale if and only if it is both a σ-martingale and a special semimartingale. 2. X is a martingale if and only if it is both a σ-martingale and in D. 3. X is a uniformly integrable martingale if and only if it is both a σ-martingale and of class D. Proof. This follows immediately from Lemma.4, Lemma.3, and JS, I..47. Corollary.7. Any locally bounded σ-martingale is a local martingale. 2. Any bounded σ-martingale is a uniformly integrable martingale. Proof.. By JS, I.4.24 and I.4.25, a locally bounded semimartingale is a special semimartingale. Hence the claim follows from Corollary This follows immediately from Statement and JS, I.47c. The following proposition is an extension of Jacod 979, Lemma 5.7, from local supermartingales to σ-supermartingales. We will need it for the proof of Theorem 4.6. Proposition.8 Let X be a non-negative σ-supermartingale with EX 0 <. Then X is a supermartingale. Proof. Let the characteristics of X be of the form.. Let D n n N be a sequence of predictable sets with D n Ω R + such that Dn X is a supermartingale for any n. Fix n N. By Lemma A.5, the characteristics of Dn X are of the form. as well, but with b := Dn b, c := Dn c, F := Dn F instead of b, c, F. Since Dn X is a supermartingale, it is a special semimartingale and its unique predictable part of bounded variation is given by cf. JS, II.2.29 b + x hxf dx A = b + x hxf dx Dn A. This process must be decreasing cf. Dellacherie and Meyer 982, Theorem VII.2, which implies that b + x hxf dx 0 P A-almost everywhere on D n and hence on Ω R + because n was arbitrarily chosen. The non-negativity of X implies that x 0F dx X F dx. { x >} { x >}

15 .2. σ-localization and σ-martingales 7 By JS, II.2.3, this implies { x >} x 0F dx LA. Since b + x hxf dx 0 and b and hxf dx belong to LA, it follows that x F dx LA. By Lemma.3 this means that X is a special { x >} semimartingale whose predictable part of bounded variation b + x hxf dx A is decreasing. Hence, X is in fact a nonnegative local supermartingale. Due to Jacod 979, 5.7, the claim follows. So far, we have concentrated on real-valued processes. As for local martingales, it makes sense to define R d -valued σ-martingales as semimartingales whose components are σ-martingales. Following Delbaen and Schachermayer 998 one may also call a R d -valued process X σ-martingale if there exists a R d -valued martingale M and a predictable, non-negative process ϕ such that ϕ LM i and X i = X0 i + ϕ M i for i =,..., d. By Cherny and Shiryaev 200, Theorem 5.6, and Emery 980, Proposition 2, the two definitions are consistent. The class of σ-martingales has a particular feature. In contrast to martingales or local martingales this class of semimartingales is stable relative to stochastic integration. We observe that Example.5 of Emery shows that unless the integrand is locally bounded the stochastic integral H M with respect to a local martingale M is in general not a local martingale again. Lemma.9 below shows that the σ-localized classes of local martingales and special semimartingales are stable relative to stochastic integration. Let us briefly touch the concept of stochastic integration with respect to a multidimensional semimartingale as general references we refer to Jacod 980 and Cherny and Shiryaev 200. For predictable processes ϕ = ϕ,..., ϕ d with ϕ i LS i the vector stochastic integral ϕ S is defined and coincides with the sum of the onedimensional stochastic integrals, i.e. ϕ S = d i= ϕi S i. However, the set of componentwise stochastic integrals is too small to have sufficient closedness properties see Cherny and Shiryaev 200 and the references therein. It turns out that a vector stochastic integral ϕ S can be defined for a broader class of predictable processes. For a R d -valued local martingale N and a R d -valued process A with components A i V Jacod 980 defined the classes of predictable processes L loc N and L S A. Now analogous to the one-dimensional case a predictable process ϕ belongs to the class LS if there exists a decomposition S = S 0 + N + A in a R d -valued local martingale N and a R d -valued process A with components A i V such that ϕ L loc N L SA, and the vector stochastic integral is defined as ϕ S = ϕ N+ϕ A. It is important to remark that if ϕ LS and S = S 0 + N + A is a decomposition

16 8 Chapter. On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures of the semimartingale S, one has in general not that ϕ L loc N L SA. Hence for a local martingale N there is the following inclusion L loc N LN. For example the integrand in Example.5 is in LM but not in t L loc M. Note that we have the following equivalence for a local martingale N and a process ϕ LN: ϕ N is a local martingale if and only if ϕ L loc N cf. Jacod 980, Proposition 2, Lemma.9, and Corollary.6. Lemma.9 Let X be a R d -valued semimartingale and H LX. Then the following statements hold:. If X i M σ for i =,..., d, then H X M σ. 2. If X i D σ for i =,..., d, then H X D σ. Proof.. The first statement follows immediately from Lemma.4 and Lemma A According Lemma.3 and Lemma A.5 it is sufficient to show that H x F dx <. { H x >} Define an increasing sequence of predictable sets by By Lemma.3 we have for any n Dn D n := {ω, t : H i tω n for i d}. { H x >} H x F dx n < d i= { x i > dn } x i F dx P A-almost everywhere on Ω R +, and the claim follows. Using Lemma.9 and Proposition.8 one can easily verify the following wellknown result cf. Ansel and Stricker 994, Corollary 3.5. Corollary.0 Let X be a R d -valued σ-martingale and H LX. If H X is bounded from below, then H X is a supermartingale..3 Equivalent σ-martingale Measures In the following we show how equivalent σ-martingale measures can be characterized in terms of semimartingale characteristics. To this end, let S = S,..., S d be a R d - valued semimartingale which stands for the discounted prices of securities,..., d.

17 .3. Equivalent σ-martingale Measures 9 Definition. Let Q loc P. We call Q an absolutely continuous martingale measure resp. absolutely continuous local martingale measure, absolutely continuous σ- martingale measure if S i is a martingale resp. local martingale, σ-martingale relative to Q for i =,..., d. We denote by M a M a loc, Ma σ the set of absolutely continuous martingale resp. local martingale, σ-martingale measures and by M e M e loc, Me σ the subclass of locally equivalent probability measures in M a resp. M a loc, Ma σ. Remark. In Delbaen and Schachermayer 994 the term equivalent local martingale measure is used in the above sense. Kramkov and Schachermayer 999 and Becherer 200, however, apply the same name to denote measures Q P such that + ϕ S is a Q-local martingale for any ϕ LS with + ϕ S 0. In order to avoid confusion, we prefer to call measures of such kind equivalent weak local martingale measures. One easily shows that any σ-martingale measure is a weak local martingale measure while the converse is not true. Nevertheless, the existence of an equivalent weak local martingale measure suffices to ensure the Condition NFLVR cf. Becherer 200, Proposition 2.3. Fix a probability measure Q loc P with density process Z. By N := L Z := Z Z we denote the stochastic logarithm of Z, i.e. the unique semimartingale N such that E N = Z cf. Kallsen and Shiryaev 200 for details on the stochastic logarithm; note that Z and Z are strictly positive by Q loc P and JS, Lemma III.3.6. Suppose that the characteristics B, C, ν of the R d+ -valued semimartingale S, N relative to h : R d+ R d+ are given in the form B = b A, C = c A, ν = A F,.4 where A A + loc is a predictable process, b is a predictable Rd+ -valued process, c is a predictable R d+ d+ -valued process whose values are non-negative, symmetric matrices, and F is a transition kernel from Ω R +, P into R d+, B d+. The Girsanov-Jacod-Mémin theorem as stated in JS, III.3.24, indicates how the characteristics change if P is replaced with Q. Here, we formulate this result in terms of the joint characteristics of S, N, which is convenient for applications. Lemma.2 The Q-characteristics of S, N are of the form.4, but with b = b + c,d+ + hxx d+ F dx, instead of b, c, F. c = c, d F x = + xd+ df

18 0 Chapter. On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures Proof. According to JS, III.3.3, there exists a predictable R d+ -valued process β such that β cβ LA and for i =,..., d. It follows that Secondly, we have c i,d+ A = S i,c, N c = c i β A Z c, S i,c = Z N c, S i,c = Z c i β A. Z t = Z t + N t = Z t + x d+ for µ S,N -almost all t, x R + R d+, which implies that EZU µ S,N = E + x d+ Z U µ S,N for any nonnegative P B d+ -measurable function U. Put differently, we have Y Z = M P µ S,N Z P in the sense of JS, III.3c for Y ω, t, x := + x d+. By JS, III.3.24, we are done. Remark. If Q loc P such that the density process is of the form Z = E N, Lemma.2 still holds true. In general the stochastic logarithm of the density process Z may not exist. But if one makes use of the stopping times R n := inf{t > 0 : Z t < } a n similar result as in Lemma.2 can be achieved on n [0, R n ] see JS, Ch. III., 5a. For the proof of Lemma.4 we need the following proposition, which extends JS, III.3.8, to the σ-martingale case. Proposition.3 A real-valued semimartingale X is a Q-martingale resp. Q-local martingale, Q-σ-martingale if and only if XZ is a P -martingale resp. P -local martingale, P -σ-martingale. Proof. By JS, III.3.8 it suffices to prove the assertion for σ-martingales. : Let D n n N be an σ-localizing sequence for the Q-σ-martingale X. Since Dn X is a Q-martingale this implies that Dn XZ is a P -martingale. By partial integration we have Dn XZ = Dn X Z + Dn Z X + Dn [X, Z] = Dn X Z + Dn XZ Dn X Z.

19 .3. Equivalent σ-martingale Measures Therefore Dn XZ is a P -local martingale. It follows from Lemma.2 that XZ is a P -σ-martingale. : This follows similarly. Just exchange the roles of P and Q and note that Z is the density process of P with respect to Q. We are now ready to characterize equivalent martingale measures and the related classes of equivalent local martingale measures and equivalent σ-martingale measures in terms of semimartingale characteristics: Lemma.4. S is a Q-σ-martingale if and only if { x i >} x i + x d+ F dx < for i =,..., d and b i + c i,d+ + x i + x d+ h i xf dx = 0 for i =,..., d.5 holds P A-almost everywhere on Ω R S is a Q-local martingale if and only if { x i >} xi +x d+ F dx LA for i =,..., d and Condition.5 holds P A-almost everywhere on Ω R S is a Q-martingale if and only if SZ D relative to P and Condition.5 hold P A-almost everywhere on Ω R +. Proof. Statements and 2 follow from Lemmas.2 and : Condition.5 follows from Statement 2. By Proposition.3, SZ is a P -martingale and hence in D cf. Lemma.4. : Fix i {,..., d}. Since S i Z and Z are special semimartingales, this is also true for Y := Z S i Z S i Z From Y = S i + N it follows that = Z Z S i + [S i, Z] = S i + [S i, N]. x i + x d+ { x i +x d+ >} ν = x { x >} ν Y A loc, where ν Y denotes the compensator of the measure of jumps of Y. By JS, II.2.3 we have that x i + x d+ { x i >} ν x i + x d+ { x i +x d+ >} ν + { x >} ν A loc. Statement 2 yields that S is a Q-local martingale, which in turn implies that SZ is a P -local martingale. By Corollary.6, we have that SZ is a P -martingale. Once more applying Proposition.3 yields the claim.

20 2 Chapter. On σ-martingales and σ-martingale Measures

21 Chapter 2 Minimal Distance Martingale Measures 2. Introduction Derivative pricing in incomplete markets basically means choosing an equivalent martingale measure. Hence the problem is to determine a criterion for selecting an appropriate martingale measure. One approach is to consider the martingale measure which minimizes a certain distance: like L 2 -distance Schweizer 996, Delbaen and Schachermayer 996, Hellinger distance Keller 997, Grandits 999, entropy distance Frittelli 2000a, Chan 999, Miyahara 999, Grandits and Rheinländer 999, Rheinländer 999 and others. In this chapter we consider the class of all f-divergence distances defined by strictly convex, differentiable functions f, which includes all the distances above see e.g. Liese and Vajda 987. We obtain some necessary and some sufficient conditions for projections of the underlying measure on the set of martingale measures in general semimartingale market models. Moreover, we consider the case that there is some additional information on the prices of some derivatives. We allow to restrict the class of martingale measures to those which yield derivative prices which are consistent with observed market prices. For derivative pricing we propose the minimal distance martingale measure consistent with observed market prices. This notion is equivalent to the least favourable consistent pricing measure which is studied for a discrete setting in Kallsen 200. Related ideas of consistent derivative pricing are studied by Kallsen cf. Kallsen 998a,b and Avellaneda 998. In Kallsen 998a,b derivative prices are considered which are derived from utility maximization and which are consistent with given demand vectors in some derivatives of the market. In Avellaneda 998 probability measures are characterized which minimize the relative entropy distance between a prior measure and the class of all probability measures consistent with the observed market prices. However, the calibrated measure obtained in this way is not necessarily a martingale measure cf. Samperi 2000 in 3

22 4 Chapter 2. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures this context. The chapter is organized as follows. In Section 2.2 we recall the definition of f- divergences and some relevant results about f-projections. Section 2.3 shows how these results can be applied to minimal distance martingale measures. Some necessary and some sufficient conditions for minimal distance martingale measures are derived. Section 2.4 considers minimax measures with respect to concave utility functions and convex sets of probability measures. We show that minimax measures are equivalent to minimal distance measures with respect to f-divergences induced by the convex conjugate of the utility function. 2.2 f-divergences and Minimal Distance Measures In the following we define f-divergences and recall some relevant results about f- projections. For general reference we refer to Liese and Vajda 987 or Vajda 989. Let Ω, F, P be a probability space. Definition 2. Let Q P and let f : 0, R be a convex function. Then the f-divergence between Q and P is defined as { f dq fq P :=, if the integral exists, else, where f0 = lim x 0 fx. Examples of f-divergence distances are the Kullback-Leibler or entropy distance for fx = x logx, the total variation distance for fx = x, the Hellinger distance for fx = x, the reverse relative entropy for fx = logx, and many others. In the following we assume that f is a continuous, strictly convex and differentiable function. By f 0 we denote the right-hand derivative at 0. Let K be a convex set of probability measures on Ω, F dominated by P. A measure Q K is called an f-projection of P on K if Remarks. fq P = inf fq P =: fk P. Q K fx. The f-divergence f P takes on values in the interval [f, f0 + lim ]. x x It holds fq P = f if and only if Q = P. See Liese and Vajda 987, Theorem If fk P <, then there exists at most one f-projection of P on K. See Liese and Vajda 987, Proposition 8.2.

23 2.2. f-divergences and Minimal Distance Measures 5 fx 3. If K is closed in the variational distance topology and lim =, then there x x exists an f-projection of P on K. See Liese and Vajda 987, Proposition 8.5. Let F be a convex cone of real valued random variables on Ω, F, i.e., { k i= } α i f i : α i 0, f i F = F, and define the moment family determined by inequality constraints with respect to F as K F := {Q P : F L Q and E Q f 0 for all f F }. 2. The first part of the following Theorem was given in Rüschendorf 984, Theorem 5. The second and the third part were given in Rüschendorf 987, Theorem 2: Theorem 2.2 Let Q P satisfy fq P <. i Assume that Q K. Then Q is the f-projection of P on K if and only if dq 0 f dq dq < 2.2 for all Q K with fq P <. ii Assume that Q K F and c := E Q f dq is finite. If Q is the f-projection on K F, then dq f c F, the L Ω, F, Q -closure of F. iii Assume that Q K F and c := E Q f dq is finite. If f dq c F, then Q is the f-projection on K F. Remarks.. In Theorem 5 in Rüschendorf 984 the assumption f dq L Q was also stated for part i but was not used for the proof of this part. 2. For every Q K with fq P < the value f dq dq dq coincides with the directional derivative of the function f P see Vajda 989, Lemma 9.3.i. Hence the condition in Theorem 2.2 i can be understood as a condition on the directional derivative in Q.

24 6 Chapter 2. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures 3. Theorem 2.2 ii is a generalization of a theorem of Csiszár 975 on the entropy distance. This result was applied in recent papers on mathematical finance for the characterization of minimal entropy martingale measures by Frittelli 2000a, Grandits and Rheinländer 999, and Rheinländer 999. An important question is when the f-projection of P on K is equivalent to P. Frittelli 2000a derived a sufficient condition in the case of the relative entropy, which corresponds to fx = x logx. He showed that in this case the f-projection of P on K is necessarily equivalent to P if there is a measure Q K with Q P and fq P <. Based on Theorem 2.2 i this result can be extended to general f- projections. Corollary 2.3 Let f 0 =. Assume the existence of a measure Q K such that Q P and fq P <. If Q is the f-projection of P, then Q P. Proof. Suppose Q is not equivalent to P, i.e. P dq = 0 > 0. Because Q P this implies Q dq = 0 > 0. Since f 0 = this leads to a contradiction to the necessary condition on an f-projection of Theorem 2.2 i. 2.3 Minimal Distance Martingale Measures In this section we apply Theorem 2.2 to characterize f-projections on the set of martingale measures which may fulfill some additional constraints. Our mathematical framework is as follows. Ω, F, F t t R+, P is a filtered probability space in the sense of JS, Definition I..2, i.e. the filtration is assumed to be right-continuous but is not necessarily complete. We consider a finite time horizon T and so we assume that F T = F. Let S be a R d -valued semimartingale with deterministic S 0. Let R := {R,..., R n } be a finite, possibly empty set of F T -measurable random variables and r {0,..., n}. We define the set of absolutely continuous martingale measures under constraints as M a := {Q M a : R L Q, E Q R i 0 for i r and E Q R i = 0 for r + i n}. The class M a stands for the set of martingale measures consistent with some information on the prices of the derivatives R,..., R n. Notice that price information of the form E Q R i [q i, p i ] can also be described by inequality constraints as in the definition of M a. The sets M a loc, M a σ, M e, M e loc M e σ are defined analogously to M a. In the following we characterize the f-projection of P on M a. As we will see, the crucial property is a representation of the Radon-Nikodym-density of the following type: dq f n = c + ϕ S T + µ i R i 2.3 i=

25 2.3. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures 7 with i c = E Q f dq < ii µ,..., µ n R such that µ i 0 and µ i E Q R i = 0 for i r iii ϕ predictable and S-integrable such that ϕ S is a martingale under Q. It turns out that this representation is a necessary and under slight additional assumptions also a sufficient condition for the f-projection of P on M a. If we consider in the following a measure Q M a σ and the corresponding class of integrands with respect to Q we write LS, Q respectively L loc S, Q. Notice that if Q P one has LS = LS, P LS, Q and the stochastic integral with respect to P is a version of the stochastic integral with respect to Q see Cherny and Shiryaev 200, Theorem 4.4. The following theorem shows that the representation 2.3 is a necessary condition for the f-projection of P on M a. Theorem 2.4 Let Q M a satisfy fq P <. If Q is the f-projection of P on M a and c := E Q f dq is finite, then dq f = c + ϕ S T + n µ i R i Q -a.s. with µ,..., µ n R such that µ i 0 and µ i E Q R i = 0 for i r, and with some process ϕ L loc S, Q such that ϕ S is a martingale under Q. Proof. First we introduce a set G of random variables which determines M a as a moment family. We define the set G as G := {ϕ S T : ϕ i = Y i ]si,t i ], s i < t i, Y i bounded F si -measurable}. Let G be the convex cone generated by the set i= G {R i : i n} { R i : r + i n}. Then we have the following characterization of M a : M a = {Q P : G L Q and E Q g 0 for all g G}. The necessary condition in Theorem 2.2 ii yields: f dq c G, where G denotes the L Ω, F, Q -closure of G. By Yor 978, Corollary for a multidimensional version see Delbaen and Schachermayer 999, Theorem.6, the L Q - closure of the vector space generated by G is contained in {ϕ S T : ϕ L locs, Q such that ϕ S is a Q -martingale}.

26 8 Chapter 2. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures According to Jacod 979, Proposition., this result is valid without the assumption of a complete filtration. Extending Proposition I.3.3 in Schaefer 97 from vector spaces to the class of closed convex cones one gets dq f = c + ϕ S T + n µ i R i Q -a.s., i= where µ i 0 for i r. By the definition of c this implies that µ i E Q H i = 0 for i r. The following theorem is a variant of Theorem 2.4. It shows that the necessary condition in Theorem 2.4 is also valid for the set M a loc under the additional assumption that S is locally bounded. Note that in this case the set M a loc coincides with the set M a σ cf. Corollary.7. Theorem 2.5 Let S be locally bounded. Let Q M a loc satisfy fq P <. If Q is the f-projection of P on M a loc and c := E Q f dq is finite, then dq f = c + ϕ S T + n µ i R i Q -a.s. 2.4 with µ,..., µ n R such that µ i 0 and µ i E Q R i = 0 for i r, and with some process ϕ L loc S, Q such that ϕ S is a martingale relative to Q. Proof. Let G loc be the convex cone generated by {ϕ S T : ϕ i = Y i ]si,t i ] [[0, T i ]], s i < t i, Y i bounded F si -measurable, T i γ i } i= {R i : i n} { R i : r + i n}, where γ i := { T i stopping time : S i T i is bounded}. Then the convex cone G loc determines M a loc as a moment family M a loc = {Q P : G loc L Q and E Q g 0 g G loc }. The representation 2.4 is then obtained as in the proof of Theorem 2.4. Remark. In the unconstrained case, i.e. R =, the results of Theorem 2.4 and Theorem 2.5 are explicitly given in Goll and Rüschendorf 200. Closely related results can be found in Kramkov and Schachermayer 999, Schachermayer 999, and Grandits and Rheinländer 999. From Theorem 2.2 i we obtain the following sufficient condition for f-projections of P on M a σ.

27 2.3. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures 9 Theorem 2.6 Let Q M a σ with fq P < such that for some process ϕ LS and µ,..., µ n R the following conditions hold: i ii dq f = c + ϕ S T + n µ i R i P -a.s., i= ϕ S is bounded from below P -a.s., iii E Q ϕ S T = 0, iv µ i 0, µ i E Q R i = 0 for i r. Then Q is the f-projection of P on M a σ. Proof. It follows from Corollary.0 and condition ii that ϕ S is a supermartingale relative to any Q M a σ. Therefore, we have dq E Q f = c + E Q ϕ S T + c = E Q f dq Now the result follows from Theorem 2.2 i.. n µ i E Q R i The following proposition shows that one can transform the minimization problem inf fq P with respect to M a into a minimization problem with respect to M a Q M a including some penalty terms for violating the constraints. The coefficients γ i in the penalty terms can be interpreted as Lagrange multipliers. Proposition 2.7 Let S and R,..., R n be bounded and inf Ef dq <. Assume the existence of a measure Q 0 M a such that E Q0 R i > 0 for i r Q M a and fq 0 P <. Furthermore assume that there exists a neighbourhood V of 0,..., 0 R n r such that for all v V there exists an element Q M a with fq P < and E Q R r+,..., E Q R n = v. Then Q M a is the f-projection of P on M a, i.e., i= fq P = inf fq P, Q M a if and only if there are γ,..., γ n R such that fq P + n i= and γ i 0, γ i E Q R i = 0 for i r. { γ i E Q R i = inf fq P + Q M a n } γ i E Q R i i=

28 20 Chapter 2. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures Proof. Step : Since S is bounded, it follows that the set M a of absolutely continuous martingale measures is closed in variation. Since R,..., R n are bounded this is also true for M a := {Q M a : E Q R i = 0 for r + i n}. Since M a, M a are convex, they are also closed in σl, L if one identifies Q M a with its Radon-Nikodym density with respect to P see, for example, Schaefer 97, Proposition IV.3.. We define a function B : M a R r by BQ = E Q R,..., E Q R r. Obviously, the component mappings of B are convex and continuous with respect to σl, L. Since the weak convergence of densities is equivalent with the convergence of the corresponding measures in the weak topology of setwise convergence, we get from Liese and Vajda 987, Theorem.47, that the functional f P is lower semicontinuous. The optimization problem is the following: This problem can be written in the form inf fq P. Q M a inf fq P, Q M a BQ 0 where BQ 0 is understood componentwise. The assumption on the existence of an inner point Q 0 in M a allows to apply a Lagrange multiplier theorem see Ekeland and Temam 976, Theorem III.5., which results in the following equivalence: Q M a is the f-projection of P on M a if and only if there are γ i 0 such that fq P + r i= { γ i E Q R i = inf fq P + Q M a r γ i E Q R i }, 2.5 and γ i E Q R i = 0 for i r. Step 2: Next we follow a similar line of argument to handle the equality constraints on the right-hand side of 2.5. Since the component mappings of B are continuous and linear, the mapping J : M a R, defined by i= JQ := fq P + r γ i E Q R i, i= is lower semicontinuous and convex. We define a function B : M a R n r by B Q := E Q R r+,..., E Q R n.

29 2.4. Minimal Distance and Minimax Measures 2 The optimization problem can be written as inf JQ Q M a inf JQ. Q M a B Q=0 The perturbation function Φ : M a R n r R is chosen as { JQ, if Q M ΦQ, v := a and B Q = v, otherwise. For v R n r we define hv := inf ΦQ, v. By assumption, h0 is finite. Q Ma We observe that M a is closed, J is lower semicontinuous and convex, and B is linear and continuous. Therefore, the function h is convex see Ekeland and Temam 976, Lemma III.5.2 and Lemma III.2.. By Rockafellar 970, Theorem 23.4, h is subdifferentiable in 0. Hence, due to Ekeland and Temam 976, Proposition III.3.2, we obtain the following equivalence: Q M a solves inf JQ if and only if there are γ r+,..., γ n R such that Q M a fq P + n { γ i E Q R i = inf fq P + Q M a i= n γ i E Q R i }. Remark. Following the line of argument of the proof of Theorem 7. in Goll and Rüschendorf 200 one verifies that under the additional assumption f dq L Q the coefficients γ,..., γ n in Proposition 2.7 correspond to µ,..., µ n, where µ i are the coefficients of the characterization of Q in Theorem Minimal Distance and Minimax Measures Again Ω, F, P is a probability space, and by K we denote a convex set of probability measures on Ω, F dominated by P. K may be thought of as a subclass of M a σ. A utility function u: R R { } is assumed to be strictly increasing, strictly concave, continuously differentiable in domu := {x R ux > } and to satisfy u = lim u x = 0, x 2.6 u x = lim u x = x x 2.7 i=

30 22 Chapter 2. Minimal Distance Martingale Measures for x := inf{x R ux > }. This implies either domu = x, or domu = [ x,. By I we denote the inverse of the derivative of u. Assumption 2.6 implies that I0 =. The convex conjugate function u : R + R of u is defined by u y := sup{ux xy} x R and satisfies u y = uiy yiy. In the following we introduce minimax measures. In the case where K is the set of equivalent martingale measures they were first introduced in a stronger form in He and Pearson 99a. Recently they were studied in another modified form by Bellini and Frittelli 2000, Frittelli 2000b, and in a finite market setting by Kallsen 998a. The minimax martingale measure has an economic interpretation. It produces prices which are least favourable for an investor with a given utility profile, i.e. the maximal expected utility with respect to prices based on a martingale measure is minimal. For a brief discussion of the economical significance of the minimax martingale measure see He and Pearson 99b, who studied so-called minimax local martingale measures. To be precise, they did not consider a set of measures for their minimax problem, and hence their framework is slight different from ours. For Q K and x > x define U Q x := sup{euy : Y L Q, E Q Y x, EuY < }. 2.8 The following lemma gives a well-known representation of U Q x cf. Karatzas and Shreve 998. Lemma 2.8 Let Q K such that E Q Iλ dq < for all λ > 0. Then { i U Q x = inf } E u λ dq λ>0 + λx. ii There is a unique solution for λ in the equation E Q Iλ dq = x, denoted by λ Q x 0,, and U Q x = E[uIλ Q x dq ]. Proof. We set Z := dq. Let Y L Q with E Q Y x and EuY <. Then we have for λ > 0: EuY EuY + λx E Q Y Eu λz + λx = EuIλZ + λx E Q IλZ. The inequalities hold as equalities if and only if Y is given as Iλ Q xz. Since we have E Q IλZ < for all λ > 0, one can conclude that E Q IλZ is a continuous, monotonically decreasing function of λ with values in x,. This guarantees the

31 2.4. Minimal Distance and Minimax Measures 23 existence of λ Q x. Finally one has to check that E[uIλ Q xz] <. From the inequality one gets that The inequality ux xy uiy yiy E[uIλZ λziλz] <. [uiλz] [uiλz λziλz] + [λziλz] implies that the condition E[uIλ Q xz] < is fulfilled. Remarks.. The random variable Iλ Q x dq can be interpreted as optimal contingent claim which is financeable under the pricing measure Q. 2. Notice that if for Q K there exists λ > 0 with Eu λ dq <, then U Qx < for all x > x. Moreover, if for Q K with U Q x < the assumption of Lemma 2.8 is fulfilled, then Eu λ Q x dq <. 3. For log x, xp, p e x the corresponding convex conjugate functions are log x, p x p p p, x + x log x. Hence for ux = e x the u -divergence distance is the relative entropy, for ux = log x the reverse relative entropy, and for ux = x the Hellinger distance. Definition 2.9 A measure Q = Q x K is called minimax measure for x and K if it minimizes Q U Q x over all Q K, i.e., U Q x = Ux := inf Q K U Qx. Remark. In general the minimax measure Q will depend on x. Fortunately for the standard utility functions like ux = xp p, \ {0}, ux = log x and p ux = e px p 0, the minimax measure is independent of x. Our weak notion of minimax measures allows to formulate a complete equivalence to minimal distance measures with respect to related f-divergence distances. This is the reason why we did not use the stronger forms of this notion in He and Pearson 99a or Bellini and Frittelli Later on we will see that under weak conditions the weak notion of a minimax measure coincides with the stronger notion in He and Pearson 99a and also with that of Bellini and Frittelli 2000.

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure Yuri Kabanov 1,2 1 Laboratoire de Mathématiques, Université de Franche-Comté, 16 Route de Gray, 253 Besançon,

More information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia Marco Frittelli Università degli Studi di Firenze Winter School on Mathematical Finance January 24, 2005 Lunteren. On Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets. based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets J. Hugonnier 1 D. Kramkov 2 W. Schachermayer 3 March 5, 2004 1 HEC Montréal and CIRANO, 3000 Chemin de la Côte S te Catherine, Montréal,

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets FREDDY DELBAEN 1 Department of Mathematics Vrije Universiteit Brussel and HIROSHI SHIRAKAWA 2 Department of Industrial and Systems

More information

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Martingale invariance and utility maximization Martingale invariance and utility maximization Thorsten Rheinlander Jena, June 21 Thorsten Rheinlander () Martingale invariance Jena, June 21 1 / 27 Martingale invariance property Consider two ltrations

More information

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

The minimal entropy martingale measure

The minimal entropy martingale measure The minimal entropy martingale measure Martin Schweizer ETH Zürich Departement Mathematik ETH-Zentrum, HG G 51.2 CH 8092 Zürich Switzerland martin.schweizer@math.ethz.ch Abstract: Suppose discounted asset

More information

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Tom Hurd Financial Mathematics at McMaster www.phimac.org Thanks to Tahir Choulli and Shui Feng Financial Mathematics Seminar

More information

The Numéraire Portfolio and Arbitrage in Semimartingale Models of Financial Markets. Konstantinos Kardaras

The Numéraire Portfolio and Arbitrage in Semimartingale Models of Financial Markets. Konstantinos Kardaras The Numéraire Portfolio and Arbitrage in Semimartingale Models of Financial Markets Konstantinos Kardaras Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

Utility maximization in the large markets

Utility maximization in the large markets arxiv:1403.6175v2 [q-fin.pm] 17 Oct 2014 Utility maximization in the large markets Oleksii Mostovyi The University of Texas at Austin, Department of Mathematics, Austin, TX 78712-0257 (mostovyi@math.utexas.edu)

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval A. N. Shiryaev M. V. Zhitlukhin arxiv:1212.379v1 [math.st] 15 Dec 212 December 18, 212 Abstract We consider optimal

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Finance Stochast. 1, 251 257 1997 c Springer-Verlag 1997 A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Tina Hviid Rydberg University of Aarhus, Department of Theoretical

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Kabanov, Yuri, Kardaras, Constantinos

More information

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Kristoffer Lindensjö Research Report 216:21 ISSN 165-377

More information

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Ineffectiveness of VaR and ES constraints John Armstrong (KCL), Damiano Brigo (Imperial) Quant Summit March 2018 Are ES constraints effective against rogue

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Welsh Probability Seminar, 17 Jan 28 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model MATHEMATICAL COMMUNICATIONS 231 Math. Commun. 18(2013, 231 239 The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model Tatjana Slijepčević-Manger 1, 1 Faculty of Civil Engineering, University

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations Anne EYRAUD-LOISEL Workshop : Enlargement of Filtrations and Applications to Finance and Insurance May 31st - June 4th, 2010, Jena

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations Claudio Fontana Laboratoire de Probabilités et Modèles Aléatoires Université Paris Diderot XVI Workshop on Quantitative Finance

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Joint work with Ernst Eberlein Croatian Quants Day University of Zagreb, 9th

More information

Markets with convex transaction costs

Markets with convex transaction costs 1 Markets with convex transaction costs Irina Penner Humboldt University of Berlin Email: penner@math.hu-berlin.de Joint work with Teemu Pennanen Helsinki University of Technology Special Semester on Stochastics

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Swiss Probability Seminar, 5 Dec 2007 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Mathematical Finance in discrete time Lecture Notes for Mathematical Finance in discrete time University of Vienna, Faculty of Mathematics, Fall 2015/16 Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna christa.cuchiero@univie.ac.at Draft Version June

More information

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? A Summary of Arbitrage Restrictions and Smile Asymptotics Vimal Raval Imperial College London & UBS Investment Bank www2.imperial.ac.uk/ vr402 Joint Work with Mark

More information

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

The Birth of Financial Bubbles The Birth of Financial Bubbles Philip Protter, Cornell University Finance and Related Mathematical Statistics Issues Kyoto Based on work with R. Jarrow and K. Shimbo September 3-6, 2008 Famous bubbles

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES from BMO martingales MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES CNRS - CMAP Ecole Polytechnique March 1, 2007 1/ 45 OUTLINE from BMO martingales 1 INTRODUCTION 2 DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES Time Consistency

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

The value of foresight

The value of foresight Philip Ernst Department of Statistics, Rice University Support from NSF-DMS-1811936 (co-pi F. Viens) and ONR-N00014-18-1-2192 gratefully acknowledged. IMA Financial and Economic Applications June 11, 2018

More information

ARBITRAGE POSSIBILITIES IN BESSEL PROCESSES AND THEIR RELATIONS TO LOCAL MARTINGALES.

ARBITRAGE POSSIBILITIES IN BESSEL PROCESSES AND THEIR RELATIONS TO LOCAL MARTINGALES. ARBITRAGE POSSIBILITIES IN BESSEL PROCESSES AND THEIR RELATIONS TO LOCAL MARTINGALES. Freddy Delbaen Walter Schachermayer Department of Mathematics, Vrije Universiteit Brussel Institut für Statistik, Universität

More information

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS ADRIAN D. BANNER INTECH One Palmer Square Princeton, NJ 8542, USA adrian@enhanced.com DANIEL FERNHOLZ Department of Computer Sciences University

More information

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Department of Banking and Finance University of Zurich April 22 2013 Math Finance Colloquium USC Change of the probability measure Change of

More information

Risk measure pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

Risk measure pricing and hedging in incomplete markets Risk measure pricing and hedging in incomplete markets Mingxin Xu Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of North Carolina, 9201 University City Boulevard, Charlotte, NC 28223, USA (e-mail:

More information

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging Johannes Muhle-Karbe TU München Joint work with Jan Kallsen and Richard Vierthauer Workshop "Finance and Insurance", Jena Overview Introduction Utility-based

More information

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks Stochastic Processes and their Applications 117 (2007) 742 765 www.elsevier.com/locate/spa Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks Pierre Collin Dufresne a, Julien Hugonnier b, a Haas School

More information

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14 Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA March 1, 2012 1 Introduction Premia 14 Top-down" models for portfolio credit derivatives have been introduced as

More information

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments T. Fischer Darmstadt University of Technology November 11, 2003 Abstract This brief paper explains how to obtain upper boundaries of shortfall

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis 1/18 : estimation and model analysis, EDHEC Business School (joint work with Rama COT) Modeling and managing financial risks Paris, 10 13 January 2011 2/18 Outline 1 2 of multi-asset models Solution to

More information

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences H. Mete Soner ETH Zürich and Swiss Finance Institute Joint with Matteo Burzoni, ETH Zürich Frank Riedel, University of Bielefeld Thera Stochastics in Honor of Ioannis

More information

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration Anna Aksamit Laboratoire d'analyse & Probabilités, Université d'evry Onzième Colloque Jeunes Probabilistes et Statisticiens

More information

No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires Finance Stoch (2016) 20:1097 1108 DOI 10.1007/s00780-016-0310-6 No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires Yuri Kabanov 1,2 Constantinos Kardaras 3 Shiqi Song 4 Received: 3 October

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

PRICING CONTINGENT CLAIMS: A COMPUTATIONAL COMPATIBLE APPROACH

PRICING CONTINGENT CLAIMS: A COMPUTATIONAL COMPATIBLE APPROACH PRICING CONTINGENT CLAIMS: A COMPUTATIONAL COMPATIBLE APPROACH Shaowu Tian Department of Mathematics University of California, Davis stian@ucdavis.edu Roger J-B Wets Department of Mathematics University

More information

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging Johannes Muhle-Karbe ETH Zürich Joint work with Jan Kallsen and Richard Vierthauer LUH Kolloquium, 21.11.2013, Hannover Outline Introduction Asymptotic

More information

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation and Indifference Valuation Mitja Stadje Dep. of Econometrics & Operations Research Tilburg University joint work with Roger Laeven July, 2012 http://alexandria.tue.nl/repository/books/733411.pdf Setting

More information

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Bernard Bercu Bordeaux University, France IFCAM Summer School Bangalore, India, July 2015 Bernard Bercu Asymptotic results for discrete

More information

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs W. Schachermayer University of Vienna Faculty of Mathematics joint work with Ch. Czichowsky (Univ. Vienna), J. Muhle-Karbe (ETH Zürich) June 2012 We fix a

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

Semimartingale Modelling in Finance

Semimartingale Modelling in Finance Semimartingale Modelling in Finance Dissertation zur Erlangung des Doktorgrades der Mathematischen Fakultät der Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg i. Br. vorgelegt von Jan Kallsen Dekan: Prof. Dr. Ludger

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

Law of the Minimal Price

Law of the Minimal Price Law of the Minimal Price Eckhard Platen School of Finance and Economics and Department of Mathematical Sciences University of Technology, Sydney Lit: Platen, E. & Heath, D.: A Benchmark Approach to Quantitative

More information

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Matteo Burzoni Marco Frittelli Marco Maggis June 30, 2015 Abstract In a model independent discrete time financial

More information

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets Teemu Pennanen King s College London Ari-Pekka Perkkiö Technische Universität Berlin 1 / 35 In most models of mathematical finance, there is at least

More information

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance Chapter 1 Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance In this chapter, we give an overview of basic concepts in mathematical finance theory, and then explain those concepts in very simple cases, namely in the

More information

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications Huyen Pham Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications 4y Springer Some elements of stochastic analysis 1 1.1 Stochastic processes 1 1.1.1 Filtration and processes 1

More information

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: Fax:

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: Fax: ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS 7641 91128 PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: 01 69 33 41 50. Fax: 01 69 33 30 11 http://www.cmap.polytechnique.fr/ Bid-Ask Dynamic Pricing in

More information

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Jan Večeř, Columbia University, Department of Statistics, Mingxin Xu, Carnegie Mellon University, Department of Mathematical Sciences, Olympia

More information

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) First Name: Waterloo, April 2013. Last Name: UW ID #:

More information

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics Ralf Korn and Olaf Menkens Fachbereich Mathematik, Universität Kaiserslautern, 67653 Kaiserslautern Summary. We review recent

More information

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business An Introduction to Conic Finance A Mini Course at Eurandom January 13 2011 Outline Operationally defining

More information

Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity

Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity Teemu Pennanen August 16, 2013 Abstract We study the problem of optimal investment by embedding it in the general conjugate duality framework of convex

More information

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015 Best-Reply Sets Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis This version: May 2015 Introduction The best-reply correspondence of a game the mapping from beliefs over one s opponents actions to

More information

ON UTILITY-BASED PRICING OF CONTINGENT CLAIMS IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS

ON UTILITY-BASED PRICING OF CONTINGENT CLAIMS IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS Mathematical Finance, Vol. 15, No. 2 (April 2005), 203 212 ON UTILITY-BASED PRICING OF CONTINGENT CLAIMS IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS JULIEN HUGONNIER Institute of Banking and Finance, HEC Université delausanne

More information

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets Markus Pelger October 21, 2016 Abstract We model asset prices in the most general sensible form as special semimartingales. This approach allows

More information

Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads

Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads Stefan Gerhold TU Wien Joint work with I. Cetin Gülüm MFO, Feb 2017 (TU Wien) MFO, Feb 2017 1 / 32 Introduction The consistency problem Overview Consistency

More information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics The Third Western Conference in Mathematical Finance November 14, 2009 How should an investor trade

More information

Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes

Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes Grundlehren der mathematischen Wissenschaften 288 Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes Bearbeitet von Jean Jacod, Albert N. Shiryaev Neuausgabe 2002. Buch. xx, 664 S. Hardcover ISBN 978 3 540 43932

More information

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS David Heath 1 and Hyejin Ku 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA, email:heath@andrew.cmu.edu 2 Department of Mathematics

More information

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Working Paper Series Department of Economics University of Verona Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Louis Raymond Eeckhoudt, Elisa Pagani, Emanuela Rosazza Gianin WP

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

Regression estimation in continuous time with a view towards pricing Bermudan options

Regression estimation in continuous time with a view towards pricing Bermudan options with a view towards pricing Bermudan options Tagung des SFB 649 Ökonomisches Risiko in Motzen 04.-06.06.2009 Financial engineering in times of financial crisis Derivate... süßes Gift für die Spekulanten

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Lecture 3 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Several important concepts were illustrated in the example in Lecture 2: arbitrage; risk neutral probability

More information

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs Johannes Muhle-Karbe Universität Wien Joint work with Jan Kallsen Universidad de Murcia 12.03.2010 Outline The Merton problem The

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon basso@unive.it, mnardon@unive.it Department of Applied Mathematics University Ca Foscari Venice Brownian motion p. 1 Brownian motion Brownian motion plays

More information

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and CEREMADE, Université Paris Dauphine Collaboration with Pierre Henry-Labordère, Nizar Touzi 08 July, 2014 Second young researchers meeting on BSDEs, Numerics

More information

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility Nasir Rehman Allam Iqbal Open University Islamabad, Pakistan. Outline Mathematical

More information

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term. Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term. G. Deelstra F. Delbaen Free University of Brussels, Department of Mathematics, Pleinlaan 2, B-15 Brussels, Belgium

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property u n i v e r s i t y o f c o p e n h a g e n d e p a r t m e n t o f m a t h e m a t i c a l s c i e n c e s Faculty of Science Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property Alexander Sokol Department

More information

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG Arbitrage Theory Kabanov Yu. M. Laboratoire de Mathématiques, Université de Franche-Comté 16 Route de Gray, F-25030 Besançon Cedex, FRANCE and Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of the Russian

More information