Portfolio Optimization with Higher Moment Risk Measures

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Portfolio Optimization with Higher Moment Risk Measures"

Transcription

1 Portfolio Optimization with Higher Moment Risk Measures Pavlo A. Krokhmal Jieqiu Chen Department of Mechanical and Industrial Engineering The University of Iowa, 2403 Seamans Center, Iowa City, IA Version: April 2006 Abstract The paper considers modeling of risk-averse preferences in stochastic programming problems using risk measures. We utilize the axiomatic foundation of coherent risk measures and deviation measures in order to develop simple representations that express risk measures via solutions of specially constructed stochastic programming problems. Using the developed representations, we introduce a new family of higher-moment coherent risk measures that measures, and, in particular, the second-moment coherent risk measure (SMCR). It is demonstrated that the SMCR measure is compatible with the second order stochastic dominance, and can be efficiently used in portfolio optimization, especially by investors with aggressive risk preferences. Keywords: Risk measures, portfolio optimization, stochastic programming, stochastic dominance 1 Introduction Research and practice of portfolio optimization is driven to a large extent by tailoring the measures of reward (satisfaction) and risk (unsatisfaction/regret) of the investment venture to the specific preferences of an investor. While there exists a common consensus that an investment s reward may be adequately associated with its expected return, the methods for proper modeling and measurement of an investment s risk are subject to much more pondering and debate. In fact, the risk-reward or mean-risk models constitute a major part of the areas of portfolio optimization and, more generally, decision making under uncertainty. The cornerstone of modern portfolio analysis was set up by Markowitz (1952, 1959), who advocated identification of the portfolio s risk with the volatility (variance) of its returns. More importantly, Markowitz s work led to formalization of the fundamental view that any decision under uncertainties may be evaluated in terms of its risk and reward. The seminal Markowitz s ideas are still widely used today in many areas of decision making, and the entire paradigm of bi-criteria risk-reward optimization received extensive development in both directions of increasing the computational efficiency and enhancing the models for risk measurement and estimation. For example, the linear Corresponding author. krokhmal@engineering.uiowa.edu 1

2 Mean-Absolute Deviation model (Konno and Yamazaki, 1991) targeted simplifications in dealing with risk-constrained problems, where risk is estimated similarly to the Markowitz Mean-Variance (MV) methodology. At the same time, it has been recognized that the symmetric attitude of the classical MV approach, where both the positive and negative deviations from the expected level are penalized equally, does not always yield an adequate estimation of risks induced by the uncertainties. Hence, significant effort has been devoted to the development of downside risk measures and models. Replacing the variance by the lower standard semi-deviation as a measure of investment risk so as to take into account only negative deviations from the expected level, has been proposed as early as by Markowitz (1959); see also more recent works by Ogryczak and Ruszczyński (1999, 2001, 2002). Among the popular downside risk models we mention the lower partial moment, or Expected Regret, in stochastic programming also known as integrated chance constraint (Bawa, 1975; Dembo and Rosen, 1999; Testuri and Uryasev, 2003; van der Vlerk, 2003). Widely known in finance and banking industry is the Value-at-Risk measure (JP Morgan, 1994; Jorion, 1997; Duffie and Pan, 1997; Larsen et al., 2002). Being simply a quantile of loss distribution, the Value-at-Risk (VaR) concept has its counterparts in stochastic optimization (probabilistic, or chance programming, see Prékopa, 1995), reliability theory, etc. Yet, minimization or control of risk using the VaR measure proved to be technically and methodologically difficult, mainly due to VaR s notorious non-convexity as a function of decision variables. A downside risk measure that circumvents the shortcomings of VaR while offering the same quantile approach to estimation of risk, is the Conditional Value-at-Risk measure (Rockafellar and Uryasev, 2000, 2002; Krokhmal et al., 2002a). Risk measures that are similar to CVaR and/or in some cases coincide with it, are Expected Shortfall and Tail VaR (Acerbi et al., 2001; Acerbi and Tasche, 2002), see also Conditional Drawdown-at-Risk (Chekhlov et al., 2005; Krokhmal et al., 2002b). A simple yet effective risk measure closely related to CVaR is the so-called Maximum Loss, or Worst-case risk (Young, 1998; Krokhmal et al., 2002b), also known as the robust optimization concept (see, e.g., Kouvelis and Yu, 1997), etc. In the last few years, the formal risk theory received a major impetus from the works of Artzner et al. (1997, 1999, 2001) and Delbaen (2000), who introduced an axiomatic approach to definition and construction of risk measures by developing the concept of coherent risk measures. Among the risk measures that satisfy the coherency properties, there are Conditional Value-at-Risk, Maximum Loss (Pflug, 2000; Acerbi and Tasche, 2002), coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments (Fischer, 2003), etc. Recently, Rockafellar et al. (2002, 2004) have extended the formal theory of risk measures to the case of deviation measures, and demonstrated a close relationship between coherent risk measures and deviation measures; spectral measures of risk have been proposed by Acerbi (2002). An approach to decision making under uncertainty, different from the risk-reward paradigm, is embodied by the von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944) utility theory, which utilizes a mathematically sound axiomatic approach to description of risk-averse and construction of corresponding decisions. Along with its numerous modifications and extensions, the vnm utility is widely adopted as a basic model of rational choice, especially in economics and social sciences (see, among others, Fishburn, 1970, 1988; Karni and Schmeidler, 1991, etc). Thus, substantial attention has been paid in the literature to development of risk-reward optimization models and risk measures that are consistent with the vnm utility theory. In particular, it has been shown that under certain conditions the Markovitz MV framework is consistent with the von Neumann & Morgenstern theory (Kroll et al., 1984). Ogryczak and Ruszczyński (1999, 2001, 2002) developed mean-semideviation models that are 2

3 consistent with stochastic dominance concepts (Fishburn, 1964; Rothschild and Stiglitz, 1970; Levy, 1998, etc.) Optimization with stochastic dominance constraints was considered by Ruszczyński and Dentcheva (2003), etc. In this paper we aim to offer an additional insight into the properties of axiomatically defined risk measures by developing a number of representations that express risk measures via solutions of stochastic programming problems. Using the developed representations, we construct a new family of highermoment coherent risk measures that are compatible with the vnm utility theory via the second-order stochastic dominance. In particular, we focus on the second-moment coherent risk measure (SMCR) that quantifies risk using second moments of the tail of the loss distribution, and is of particular interest in the context of portfolio optimization. The conducted case study indicates that the SMCR measure has a high potential for practical application in portfolio selection problems, and may be particularly attractive to investors with aggressive risk preferences. 2 Modeling of risk measures as stochastic programs The discussion in the Introduction section has illustrated the variety of approaches to definition and estimation of risk. Arguably, the recent advances in risk theory are associated with the axiomatic approach to construction of risk measures pioneered by Artzner et al. (1997, 1999, 2001). The present endeavor essentially exploits this axiomatic approach in order to devise simple computational recipes for dealing with several types of risk measures by representing them in the form of stochastic programming problems. These representations can be used to create new risk measures to be tailored to specific risk preferences, as well as to incorporate these preferences in stochastic programming problems. In particular, we present a new family of Higher -Moment Coherent Risk measures (HMCR), and discuss in detail its member, the Second-Order Coherent Risk measure (SMCR). It will be shown that the SMCR measure is well-behaved in terms of theoretical properties, and demonstrates very promising performance in test applications. Within the axiomatic framework of risk analysis, risk measure R(X) of a random outcome X from some probability space (, F, µ) may be defined as a mapping R : X R, where X is a linear space of F -measurable functions X : R. In a more general setting one may assume X to be a separated locally convex space; for our purposes it suffices to consider X = L p (, F, P), 1 p, where the particular value of p shall be clear from the context. Traditionally to convex analysis, we call function f : X R proper if f (X) > for all X X and dom f, i.e., there exists X X such that f (X) < + (see, e.g., Rockafellar, 1970; Zălinescu, 2002). In the remainder of the paper, we confine ourselves to risk measures that are proper and not identically equal to +. Throughout the paper, it is assumed that X represents a loss function, i.e., small values of X are good, and large values are bad. 2.1 Coherent risk measures A coherent risk measure, according to Artzner et al. (1999) and Delbaen (2000), is defined as a mapping R : X R that further satisfies the next four properties (axioms): (A1) monotonicity: X 0 R(X) 0 for all X X, 3

4 (A2) sub-additivity: R(X + Y ) R(X) + R(Y ) for all X, Y X, (A3) positive homogeneity: R(λX) = λr(x) for all X X, λ > 0, (A4) translation invariance: R(X + a) = R(X) + a for all X X, a R. Since axioms (A2) and (A3) immediately yield convexity of coherent risk measures, little will be lost in the generality of the above definition if one replaces the sub-additivity requirement (A2) with the stronger requirement of convexity: (A2 ) convexity: R ( λx + (1 λ)y ) λr(x) + (1 λ)r(y ), X, Y X, 0 λ 1. From the axioms (A1) (A4) one can easily derive the following useful properties of coherent risk measures (see, for example, Delbaen, 2000): (C1) R(0) = 0 [A1+A2 or A3], (C2) X Y R(X) R(Y ) [A1+A2], (C3) R(a) = a, a R [A4+C1], (C4) X a R(X) a, a R [C2+C3], (C5) R ( X R(X) ) = 0 [A4+C3], (C6) R(X) is continuous in its effective domain, where the expressions in brackets indicate the axioms or properties that support the given statement. Also, throughout the paper the inequalities X a, X Y, etc., are assumed to hold almost surely. From the definition of coherent risk measures it is easy to see that, for example, EX and ess.sup X, where min{ η R X η }, if { η R X η }, ess.sup X =, otherwise, are coherent risk measures; more examples can be found in Rockafellar et al. (2002). Below we present simple computational formulas that aid in construction of coherent risk measures and their incorporation into stochastic programs. Namely, we execute the idea that one of the axioms (A3) or (A4) can be relaxed and then reinforced by solving an appropriately defined mathematical programming problem. In other words, one can construct a coherent risk measure via solution of a stochastic programming problem that involves a function φ : X R satisfying only three of the four axioms (A1) (A4). First we present a representation for coherent risk measures that is based on relaxation of the translation invariance axiom (A4). The next theorem shows that if one selects a function φ : X R satisfying axioms (A1) (A3) along with additional technical conditions, then there exists a simple stochastic optimization problem involving φ whose optimal value would satisfy (A1) (A4). 4

5 Theorem 1 Let function φ : X R satisfy axioms (A1) (A3), and be a lsc function such that φ(η) > η for all real η 0. Then the optimal value of the stochastic programming problem ρ(x) = inf η η + φ(x η) (1) is a proper coherent risk measure, and the infimum is attained for all X, so inf η in (1) may be replaced by min η R. Proof. Convexity, lower semicontinuity, and sublinearity of φ in X imply that function φ X (η) = η + φ(x η) is also convex, lsc, and proper in η R for each fixed X X. For the infimum of φ X (η) to be achievable at finite η, its recession function has to be positive: φ X 0 + (±1) > 0, which is equivalent to φ X 0 + (ξ) > 0, ξ 0, due to the positive homogeneity of φ X. By definition of the recession function (Rockafellar, 1970; Zălinescu, 2002) and positive homogeneity of φ, we have that the last condition holds if φ(ξ) > ξ for all ξ 0: φ X 0 + η + τξ + φ(x η τξ) η φ(x η) (ξ) = lim = ξ + φ( ξ). τ τ Hence, ρ(x) defined by (1) is a proper lsc function, and minimum in (1) is attained at finite η for all X X. Below we verify that ρ(x) satisfies axioms (A1) (A4). Indeed, properness of representationlinear. (A1) Let X 0. Then φ(x) 0 as φ satisfies (A1), which implies min η R η + φ(x η) 0 + φ(x 0) 0. (A2) For any Z X let η Z arg min η R {η + φ(z η)} R, then ρ(x) + ρ(y ) = η X + φ(x η X ) + η Y + φ(y η Y ) η X + η Y + φ(x + Y η X η Y ) η X+Y + φ(x + Y η X+Y ) = ρ(x + Y ). (A3) For any fixed λ > 0 we have ρ(λx) = min η R (A4) Similarly, for any fixed a R, ρ(x + a) = min η R { η + φ(λx η) } = λ min η R = a + min η R { } η + φ(x + a η) { η/λ + φ(x η/λ) } = λρ(x). (2) { (η a) + φ ( X (η a) )} = a + ρ(x). (3) Thus, ρ(x) defined by (1) is a proper coherent risk measure. Remark 1.1 It is all-important that the stochastic programming problem (1) is convex, due to the convexity of function φ. Also, note that one cannot substitute a coherent risk measure itself for function φ in (1), as it will violate the condition φ(η) > η of the Theorem. 5

6 Corollary 1.1 The set arg min η R { η + φ(x η) } R of optimal solutions of (1) is closed. Example 1.1 (Conditional Value-at-Risk) A famous special case of (1) is the optimization formula for Conditional Value-at-Risk (Rockafellar and Uryasev, 2000, 2002): CVaR α (X) = min η R η + (1 α) 1 E(X η) +, 0 < α < 1, (4) where (X) ± = max{±x, 0}, and function φ(x) = (1 α) 1 E(X) + evidently satisfies the conditions of Theorem 1. The space X in this case can be selected as L 2 (, F, P). One of the many appealing features of (4) is that it has a simple intuitive interpretation: if X represents loss/unsatisfaction, then CVaR α (X), is, roughly speaking, the conditional expectation of losses that may occur in (1 α) 100% of the worst cases. In the case of a continuously distributed X, this rendition is exact: CVaR α (X) = E [ X X VaR α (X) ], where VaR α (X) is defined as VaR α (X) = inf { ζ P[X ζ ] > α }, i.e., the α-quantile of X. In the general case, the formal definition of CVaR α (X) becomes more intricate (Rockafellar and Uryasev, 2002), but the representation (4) still applies. Example 1.2 A generalization of (4) can be constructed as R α,β (X) = min η R η + α E(X η)+ β E(X η), (5) where, in accordance with the conditions of Theorem 1, one has to put α > 1 and 0 β < 1. Example 1.3 (Maximum Loss) If the requirement of finiteness of φ in (1) is relaxed, i.e., the image of φ is (, + ], then the optimal value of (1) still defines a coherent risk measure, but the infimum may not be achievable. An example is served by the so-called MaxLoss measure, MaxLoss(X) = ess.sup X = inf η η + φ (X η), where φ (X) = { 0, X 0,, X > 0. It is easy to see that φ is positive homogeneous convex, non-decreasing, lsc, and satisfies φ (η) > η for all η 0, but is not finite. Example 1.4 (Higher Moment Coherent Risk Measures) Let X = L p (, F, P), and for some 0 < α < 1 consider φ(x) = (1 α) 1 (X) + p, where X p = ( E X p) 1/p. Clearly, φ satisfies the conditions of Theorem 1, thus one can define a family of higher-moment coherent risk measures (HMCR) as HMCR p,α (X) = min η R η + (1 α) 1 (X η) + p, p 1, α (0, 1). (6) Of special interest is the case p = 2 that defines a second-moment coherent risk measure (SMCR): SMCR α (X) = min η R η + (1 α) 1 (X η) + 2, 0 < α < 1. (7) We will see below that SMCR α (X) is quite similar in properties to CVaR α (X), yet it measures the risk in terms of the second moments of losses. Implementation-wise, the SMCR measure can be incorporated in a mathematical programming problem via the second order cone constraints (see Section 3). The second order cone programming (SOCP) is a well-developed topic in the area of convex optimization, and a number of commercial off-the-shelf software packages are available for solving convex problems with second-order cone constraints. 6

7 Example 1.5 (Composition of risk measures) Formula (1) readily extends to the case of multiple functions φ i, i = 1,..., n, that are cumulatively used in measuring the risk of element X X and conform to the conditions of Theorem 1. Namely, one has that ρ n (X) = min η i R, i=1,...,n n ( ) η i + φ i (X η i ), (8) i=1 is a proper coherent risk measure. The value of η that delivers minimum in (1) does also possess some noteworthy properties as a function of X. In establishing of these properties the following notation is convenient. Assuming that the set arg min x R f (x) is closed for some function f : R R, we denote its left endpoint as Arg min x R f (x) = min { y y arg min x R f (x) }. Theorem 2 Let function φ : X R satisfy the conditions of Theorem 1. Then function η(x) = Arg min η R η + φ(x η) (9) exists and satisfies properties (A3) and (A4). If, additionally, φ(x) = 0 for every X 0, then η(x) satisfies (A1), along with inequality η(x) ρ(x), where ρ(x) is the optimal value of (1). Proof. Conditions on function φ ensure that the set of optimal solutions of problem (1) is closed and finite, whence follows the existence of η(x) in (9). Property (A3) is established by noting that for any λ > 0 equality (2) implies η(λx) = Arg min η R { } η + φ(λx η) { } = Arg min η R η/λ + φ(λx η/λ), from which follows that η(λx) = λη(x). Similarly, by virtue of (3), we have { } { η(x + a) = Arg min η + φ(x + a η) = Arg min (η a) + φ ( λx (η a) )}, η R η R which leads to the sought relation (A4): η(x + a) = η(x) + a. To validate the remaining statements of the Theorem, consider φ to be such that φ(x) = 0 for every X 0. Then, (C2) immediately yields φ(x) 0 for all X X, which proves By the definition of η(x), we have for all X 0 η(x) η(x) + φ ( X η(x) ) = ρ(x). η(x) + φ ( X η(x) ) 0 + φ(x 0) = 0, or η(x) φ ( X η(x) ). (10) Assume that η(x) > 0, which implies φ ( η(x) ) = 0. From (A2) it follows that φ ( X η(x) ) φ(x) + φ ( η(x) ) = 0, leading to φ ( X η(x) ) = 0, and, consequently, to η(x) 0 by (10). The contradiction furnishes the statement of the theorem. 7

8 Remark 2.1 If φ satisfies all conditions of Theorem 2, the optimal solution η(x) of the stochastic optimization problem (1) complies with all axioms for the coherent risk measures, except (A2), thereby failing to be convex. Example 2.1 (Value-at-Risk) A well-known example of two risk measures obtained by solving a stochastic programming problem of type (1) is again provided by formula (4) due to Rockafellar and Uryasev (2000, 2002), and its counterpart VaR α (X) = Arg min η R η + (1 α) 1 E(X η) +. The Value-at-Risk measure VaR α (X) (JP Morgan, 1994; Jorion, 1997; Duffie and Pan, 1997, etc), despite being adopted as the de facto standard for measurement of risk in finance and banking industries, is notorious for its poor behavior in risk estimation and control. In fact, the recent developments in axiomatic risk theory can be viewed as attempts of constructing risk management concepts that circumvent the failings of VaR. Example 2.2 (Second-Moment Coherent Risk Measure) For higher-moment coherent risk measures, the function φ in (9) is taken as φ(x) = (1 α) 1 (X) + p, and the corresponding optimal η p,α (X) satisfies the equation (1 α) 1/p = ( X η p,α (X) ) + p ( X η p,α (X) ) + p 1, p > 1. (11) Although the optimal η p,α (X) in (11) is determined implicitly, Theorem 2 ensures that it has properties similar to VaR α (monotonicity, positive homogeneity, etc). Moreover, using (11) with p = 2, the second-moment coherent risk measure (SMCR) can be presented in the form that involves only the first moment of losses in the tail of the distribution: SMCR α (X) = η 2,α (X) + (1 α) 2 ( X η 2,α (X) ) + 1 = η 2,α (X) + (1 α) 2 E ( X η 2,α (X) ) +. (12) Note that in (12), the second-moment information is concealed in the η 2,α (X). Further, by taking a CVaR measure with the confidence level α = 2α α 2, we can write SMCR α (X) = η SMCR α E( X η SMCR ) + η CVaR α E( X η CVaR ) + = CVaRα (X), (13) where η SMCR = η p,α (X) as in (11) with p = 2, and η CVaR = VaR α (X). In other words, with the above selection of α and α, expressions for SMCR α (X) and CVaR α (X) differ only by the choice of η that delivers minimum to the corresponding expressions (6) and (4). For Conditional Value-at- Risk, it is the α-quantile of the distribution of X, whereas the optimal η 2,α (X) for SMCR measure incorporates the information on the second moment of losses X. The developed results can be efficiently applied in the context of stochastic optimization, where the random outcome X is a function of the decision vector x R m, X = X (x, ω). Firstly, representation 8

9 (1) allows for efficient minimization of risk in stochastic programs. For a function φ that complies with the requirements of Theorem 1, denote (x, η) = η + φ ( X (x, ω) η ) and R(x) = ρ ( X (x, ω) ) = min η R (x, η). (14) Then, clearly, min ρ( X (x, ω) ) min x C (x,η) C R (x, η), (15) in the sense that both problems have the same optimal objective values and optimal vector x. Secondly, the representation (1) also admits implementation of risk constraints in stochastic programs. Namely, let C R m be a convex closed set, and g(x) a function that is convex on C. Then, the following two problems are equivalent, as demonstrated by Theorem 3 below: min { g(x) R(x) c}, (16a) x C min { g(x) (x, η) c}. (16b) (x,η) C R Theorem 3 Optimization problems (16a) and (16b) are equivalent in the sense that their objectives achieve the same minimum values. Further, if risk constraint in (16a) is active, (x, η ) achieves the minimum of (16b) if and only if x is an optimal solution of (16a) and η arg min η (x, η). The proof relies on the Kuhn-Tucker necessary and sufficient conditions for convex optimization problems (Pshenichnyi, 1971, Theorem 2.5) Theorem 4 (Kuhn-Tacker) Let ψ i (x), i = m,..., n, be functionals defined on a linear space E such that the ψ i are convex for i 0 and linear for i > 0. Then, in order for a point x E to deliver the minimum to the problem min x C ψ 0 (x) s. t. ψ i (x) 0, i = m,..., 1, ψ i (x) = 0, i = 1,..., n, where C is a given convex set in E, it is necessary that there exist constants λ i, i = m,..., n, such that n n λ i ψ i (x ) λ i ψ i (x) for all x C. i= m i= m Moreover, λ i 0 for each i 0, and λ i ψ i (x ) = 0 for each i 0. If λ 0 > 0, then these conditions are also sufficient. Proof of Theorem 3: Let (x, η ) be an optimal solution of (16b). Theorem 4 maintains that in this case there exists λ 0 such that g(x ) + λ (x, η ) g(x) + λ (x, η) for all (x, η) C R, λ ( (x, η ) c ) = 0. (17) For z C denote η(z) arg min η (z, η), then, obviously, (x, η(x )) (x, η ). On the other hand, for λ > 0 from (17) it follows that g(x ) + λ (x, η ) g(x ) + λ (x, η(x )), 9

10 whereby η arg min η (x, η). Then, for any x C, g(x ) + λ R(x ) = g(x ) + λ (x, η ) g(x) + λ (x, η(x)) = g(x) + λ R(x), λ ( (x, η ) c ) = λ ( R(x ) c ) = 0, proving that x solves (16a). In a similar fashion, if x is an optimal solution of (16a) and η arg min η (x, η), there exists λ 0 such that for any x from C g(x ) + λ R(x ) g(x) + λ R(x), λ ( R(x ) c ) = 0, Then for any pair (x, η) C R one has g(x ) + λ (x, η ) = g(x ) + λ R(x ) g(x) + λ R(x) = g(x) + λ ( x, η(x) ) g(x) + λ (x, η), and λ ( (x, η ) c ) = λ ( R(x ) c ) = 0. Hence, (x, η ) delivers the minimum to problem (16b). Now, observe that formula (1) in Theorem 1 is analogous to the operation of infimal convolution, well-known in convex analysis: ( f g)(x) = inf y f (x y) + g(y). Continuing the analogy between representation (1) and the operation of infimal convolution, consider the operation of right scalar multiplication (φη)(x) = η φ(η 1 X), η 0, where for η = 0 we set (φ0)(x) = (φ0 + )(X). If φ is proper and convex, then it is known that (φη)(x) is a convex proper function in η 0 for any X dom φ (see, for example, Rockafellar, 1970). Interestingly enough, this fact can be pressed into service to formally define coherent risk measure as the optimal value of stochastic programming problem ρ(x) = inf η 0 η φ( η 1 X ), (18) if function φ, along with some technical conditions similar to those of Theorem 1, satisfies axioms (A1), (A2 ), and (A4), but not (A3). Note that excluding the positive homogeneity (A3) from the list of properties of φ denies also its convexity, thus one must replace (A2) with (A2 ) to ensure that (18) is a convex programming problem. In the terminology of convex analysis the function ρ(x) defined by (18) is known as the positively homogeneous convex function generated by φ. Likewise, by direct verification of conditions (A1) (A4) it can be demonstrated that ρ(x) = sup η > 0 η φ(η 1 X), (19) is a proper coherent risk measure, provided that φ(x) satisfies (A1), (A2), and (A4). By (C1), axioms (A1) and (A2) imply that φ(0) = 0, which allows one to rewrite (19) as ρ(x) = sup η > 0 φ(ηx + 0) φ(0) η = φ0 + (X), (20) 10

11 where the last inequality in (20) comes from the definition of the recession function (Rockafellar, 1970; Zălinescu, 2002). Note that quantities defined by (18) and (19) coincide when function φ is positive homogeneous, i.e., it is a coherent risk measure itself: inf η η > 0 φ(η 1 X) = sup η > 0 η φ(η 1 X) = φ(x). (21) Yet, the practical usefulness of representations (18) or (19) for coherent risk measures seems rather questionable, as (18) (19) would generally lead to non-convex programming problems, should X parametrically depend on a decision vector x R n. On the contrary, representation (1) yields a nice convex optimization problem, provided that X is convex in x. 2.2 Deviation measures Since being introduced in Artzner et al. (1999), the axiomatic approach to construction of risk measures has been repeatedly employed by many authors for development of other types of risk measures, tailored to specific preferences and applications (see Rockafellar et al., 2002, 2004; Acerbi, 2002; Ruszczyński and Shapiro, 2004). In this subsection we consider deviation measures as introduced by Rockafellar et al. (2002). Namely, a deviation measure is a mapping D : X [0, + ] that satisfies (D1) D(X) > 0 for any non-constant X X, whereas D(X) = 0 for constant X, (D2) D(X + Y ) D(X) + D(Y ) for all X, Y X, 0 λ 1, (D3) D(λX) = λd(x) for all X X, λ > 0, (D4) D(X + a) = D(X) for all X X, a R. Again, from axioms (D1) and (D2) follows convexity of D(X). In Rockafellar et al. (2002) it was shown that deviation measures that further satisfy (D5) D(X) ess.sup X EX for all X X, are characterized by the one-to-one correspondence D(X) = R(X EX) (22) with expectation-bounded coherent risk measures, i.e., risk measures that satisfy (A1) (A4) and an additional requirement (A5) R(X) > EX for all non-constant X X, whereas R(X) = EX for all constant X. Using this result, it is easy to provide an analog of formula (1) for deviation measures. Theorem 5 Let function φ : X R satisfy axioms (A1) (A3), and be a lsc function such that φ(x) > EX for all X 0. Then the optimal value of the stochastic programming problem D(X) = EX + inf η { η + φ(x η) } is a deviation measure, and the infimum is attained for all X, so inf η in (23) may be replaced by min η R. (23) 11

12 Proof. Since formula (23) differs from (1) by the constant summand ( EX), we only have to verify that R(X) = inf η { η + φ(x η) } satisfies (A5). As φ(x) > EX for all X 0, we have that φ(x η X ) > E(X η X ) for all non-constant X X, where η X arg min η {η + φ(x η)}. From the last inequality it follows that η X + φ(x η X ) > EX, or R(X) > EX for all non-constant X X. Thus, D(X) > 0 for all non-constant X. For a R, inf η { η + φ(a η) } = a, whence D(a) = 0. Given the close relation between deviation measures and coherent risk measures, it is straightforward to apply the above results to deviation measures. 2.3 Connection with utility theory and second-order stochastic dominance As it has been mentioned in the Introduction, substantial attention has been devoted in the literature to the development of risk models and measures compatible with the utility theory of von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944), which represents one of the cornerstones of the decision-making science. The vnm theory argues that when the preference relation of the decision-maker satisfies certain axioms (completeness, transitivity, continuity, and independence), there exists a function u : R R, such that an outcome X is preferred to outcome Y ( X Y ) if and only if E[u(X)] E[u(Y )]. If function u is non-decreasing and concave, the corresponding preference is said to be risk averse. Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) have bridged the vnm utility theory with the concept of second-order stochastic dominance, by showing that X dominating Y by the second-order stochastic dominance, X SSD Y, is equivalent to the relation E[u(X)] E[u(Y )] holding true for all concave non-decreasing functions u, where the inequality is strict for at least one such u. Recall that a random outcome X dominates outcome Y by the second order stochastic dominance if z P[X t] dt z P[Y t] dt for all z R. Since coherent risk measures are generally inconsistent with the second-order stochastic dominance (see an explicit example in De Giorgi, 2005), it is of interest to introduce risk measures that comply with this property. To this end, we replace the monotonicity axiom (A1) in the definition of coherent risk measures by the requirement of SSD isotonicity (Pflug, 2000; De Giorgi, 2005): ( X) SSD ( Y ) R(X) R(Y ). Namely, we consider risk measures R : X R that satisfy the following set of axioms: (A1 ) SSD isotonicity: ( X) SSD ( Y ) R(X) R(Y ) for X, Y X, (A2 ) convexity: R ( λx + (1 λ)y ) λr(x) + (1 λ)r(y ), X, Y X, 0 λ 1, (A3) positive homogeneity: R(λX) = λr(x), X X, λ > 0, (A4) translation invariance: R(X + a) = R(X) + a, X X, a R. Again, it is possible to develop an analog of formula (1), which would allow for construction of risk measures with the above properties using functions that comply with (A1 ), (A2 ), and (A3). 12

13 Theorem 6 Let function φ : X R satisfy axioms (A1 ), (A2 ), and (A3), and be a lsc function such that φ(η) > η for all real η 0. Then the optimal value of the stochastic programming problem ρ(x) = min η R exists and is a proper function that satisfies (A1 ), (A2 ), (A3), and (A4). η + φ(x η) (24) Proof. The proof of existence and all properties except (A1 ) is identical to that of Theorem 1. Property (A1 ) follows elementarily: if ( X) SSD ( Y ), then ( X + c) SSD ( Y + c), and consequently, φ(x c) φ(y c) for c R, whence ρ(x) = η X + φ(x η X ) η Y + φ(x η Y ) η Y + φ(y η Y ) = ρ(y ), where, as usual, η Z arg min η {η + φ(z η)} R, for any Z X. Obviously, by solving a risk-minimization problem min ρ( X (x, ω) ) x C where ρ is a risk measure that is both coherent and SSD-compatible in the sense of (A1 ), one obtains a solution that is SSD-efficient, i.e., is acceptable to any risk-averse rational utility maximizer, and also bears the lowest risk in terms of coherence preference metrics. Below we illustrate that functions φ satisfying the conditions of Theorem 6 can be easily constructed in the scope of the presented approach. Example 6.1 Let φ(x) = E[u(X)], where u : R R is a convex, positively homogeneous, nondecreasing function such that u(η) > η for all η 0. Obviously, function φ(x) defined in this way satisfies the conditions of Theorem 6. Since u( η) is concave and non-decreasing, one has that E[u(X)] E[u(Y )], and, consequently, φ(x) φ(y ), whenever ( X) SSD ( Y ). It is easy to see that, for example, function φ of the form φ(x) = αe(x) + βe(x), α (1, + ), β [0, 1), satisfies the conditions of Theorem 6. Thus, in accordance to Theorems 1 and 6, the coherent risk measure R α,β (5) is also consistent with the second-order stochastic dominance. A special case of (5) is the Conditional Value-at-Risk, which is known to be compatible with the second-order stochastic dominance (Pflug, 2000). Example 6.2 (Second-Moment Coherent Risk Measure) The SMCR and, in general, the family of higher-moment risk measures consitute another example of risk measures that are both coherent and compatible with second-order stochastic dominance. Indeed, function u(x) = ( (η) +) p is convex and non-decreasing, whence ( E[u(X)] ) 1/p ( E[u(Y )] ) 1/p for any ( X) SSD ( Y ). Thus, the HMCR family, defined by (24) with φ(x) = (1 α) 1 (X) + p, HMCR p,α = min η R η + (1 α) 1 (X η) + p, p 1, is both coherent and SSD-compatible, by virtue of Theorems 1 and 6. Implementation of such a risk measure in stochastic programming problems enables one to introduce risk preferences that are consistent with both concepts of coherence and second-order stochastic dominance. 13

14 Thus, the developed SMCR measure (7), and, generally, the family of higher-moment risk measures (6) possess all the nice properties that are sought after in the realm of risk management and decision making under uncertainty: compliance with the coherence principles, amenability for an efficient implementation in stochastic programming problems (via second-order cone programming), and compatibility with second-order stochastic dominance and utility theory. The question that remains to be answered is whether these superior properties translate into equally superior performance in practical risk management applications. The next section reports a pilot study intended to investigate the performance of the SMCR measure in real-life risk management applications. It shows that SMCR is a promising tool for tailoring risk preferences to specific needs of decision-makers, and can be compared favorably with some of the most widely used risk management frameworks. 3 Case study: Portfolio Optimization with SMCR measure In this section we illustrate the practical merits of the developed SMCR risk measure on the example of portfolio optimization, a typical testing ground for many risk management and stochastic programming techniques. To this end, we compare portfolio optimization models that use the SMCR risk measure against portfolio allocation models based on two well-established, and theoretically as well as practically proven methodologies, namely, the Conditional Value-at-Risk measure and Markowitz Mean-Variance framework. This choice of benchmark models is further supported by the fact that SMCR is similar in construction and properties to CVaR, but, while CVaR measures risk in terms of the first moment of losses residing in the tail of the distribution, the SMCR measure quantifies risk using the second moments, in this way relating to the MV paradigm. To illuminate the effects of taking into account the second-moment information in estimation of risks using the SMCR measure, as compared to CVaR measure that utilizes the first-moment information, in this case study we consider SMCR measure with parameter α = 0.90, and CVaR measure with confidence level α = 0.99, so that the relation α = 2α α 2 holds (see the discussion in Example 2.2). The portfolio optimization models used in this case study have the form min x R ( r, x ) (25a) s. t. e, x = 1, (25b) Er, x r 0, x 0, (25c) (25d) where x = (x 1,..., x n ) T is the vector of portfolio weights, r = (r 1,..., r n ) T is the random vector of assets returns, and e = (1,..., 1) T. The risk measure R in (25a) is taken to be either SMCR (7), CVaR (4), or variance of the negative of the portfolio return, r, x = X. The corresponding solutions of (25) are therefore denoted as SMCR, CVaR, and MV optimal portfolios, respectively. In the above portfolio optimization problem, (25b) represents the budget constraint, which, together with the no-short-selling constraint (25d) ensures that all the available funds are invested, and (25c) imposes the minimal required level r 0 for the expected return of the portfolio. Traditionally to stochastic programming, we modeled the distribution of random return r i of asset i using a set of J discrete equiprobable scenarios {r i1,..., r i J }. Then, the optimization problem (25) reduces to a linear pro- 14

15 gramming problem if CVaR is selected as the risk measure R in (25). Within the Mean-Variance framework, (25) becomes a quadratic optimization problem with the objective R ( r, x ) = n i,k=1 σ ik x i x k, where σ ik = 1 J 1 J (r i j r i )(r kj r k ), r i = 1 J j=1 J r i j. (26) j=1 In the case of R(X) = SMCR α (X), problem (25) reduces to a linear programming problem with one second-order cone constraint: min η t 1 α J n s. t. x i = 1, i=1 1 J J j=1 i=1 w j n r i j x i r 0, (27a) (27b) (27c) n r i j x i η, j = 1,..., J, (27d) i=1 t J w 2 j, j=1 (27e) x i 0, i = 1,..., n, (27f) w j 0, j = 1,..., J. (27g) The resulting mathematical programming problems have been implemented in C++, and we used CPLEX 10.0 for solving the LP and QP problems, and MOSEK 4.0 for solving the SOCP problem (27). It is necessary to emphasize that we have deliberately chosen not to include any additional trading or institutional constraints (transaction costs, liquidity constraints, etc.) in the portfolio allocation problem (25) so as to make the effect of risk measure selection in (25) more marked and visible. The data set used in this case study contained daily closing prices, from October 23, 2003 to Jan 16, 2006, of 100 stocks selected at random from the S&P 500 index (as of January 2006). For scenario generation we used 10-day historical returns over three hundred overlapping periods (J = 300). 15

16 Expected return CVaR SMCR MV Standard deviation Figure 1: Expected return vs standard deviation for the SMCR-, CVaR-, and MV-optimal portfolios. The SMCR-optimal portfolio was calculated with R( ) = SMCR 0.90 ( ) in (25a), and the CVaR-optimal portfolio was calculated with R( ) = CVaR 0.90 ( ) in (25a). 3.1 In-Sample Optimization: Efficient Frontier The first set of experiments conducted in this case study involves construction of efficient frontiers for the portfolios defined by (25), and is otherwise known as in-sample optimization. Figures 1, 2, and 3 display the so-called risk-reward curves of the SMCR-, CVaR-, and MV-optimal portfolios, which allow for comparing the risk borne by each of the three portfolios in the same scale. The procedure for construction of these risk-reward curves is as follows. For a given level of expected return r 0, let x smcr (r 0), x cvar (r 0), and x mv (r 0) denote the corresponding SMCR-, CVaR-, and MV-optimal portfolios. Then, for each choice of risk measure R in (25a), the corresponding risk-reward curves are traced by pairs ( R [ x smcr (r 0) ], r 0 ), ( R [ x cvar (r 0 ) ], r 0 ), and ( R [ x mv (r 0 ) ], r 0 ), respectively; observe that one of the three risk-reward curves would necessarily represent an efficient frontier of one of the portfolios. For example, the dashed curve in Figure 1 represents the efficient frontier of the MV-optimal portfolio plotted in the (standard deviation, expected return) scale. The other two curves in Fig. 1 are traced by pairs ( σ [ x smcr (r 0) ], r 0 ) and ( σ [ x cvar (r 0 ) ], r 0 ), where σ [ ] is the standard deviation operator. In other words, the three curves in Fig. 1 report the standard deviations of the SMCR-, MV-, and CVaRoptimal portfolios that have equal expected return. Of course, it is not surprising that the SMCR- and CVaR-optimal portfolios exhibit higher standard deviation than the MV-optimal portfolio. Similarly, Figs. 2 and 3 demonstrate the risk borne by the SMCR-, CVaR-, and MV-optimal portfolios with equal expected return when the risk is measured using the SMCR measure with α = 0.90, and CVaR with 0.99 confidence level, respectively. Again, in Fig. 2 the SMCR curve represents the efficient frontier of the SMCR-optimal portfolio, and the CVaR curve is the efficient frontier of the CVaR-optimal portfolio in Fig. 3. From Figures 1 3 we observe that the risk-reward curves generated by the SMCR- and CVaR-optimal portfolios are very similar in all three cases. In fact, in Fig. 2 these two virtually coincide; however, the graphs in Figures 1 and 3 indicate that the SMCR- and CVaR-optimal portfolios are nevertheless different. Although these results are data-dependent, they generally confirm the conjecture that for certain values of parameters, namely, α = 2α α 2, the SMCR α and CVaR α measures may lead 16

17 Expected return CVaR SMCR MV SMCR Figure 2: Expected return vs SMCR (α = 0.90) for the SMCR-, CVaR-, and MV-optimal portfolios. The SMCR-optimal portfolio was calculated with R( ) = SMCR 0.90 ( ) in (25a), and the CVaR-optimal portfolio was calculated with R( ) = CVaR 0.90 ( ) in (25a) Expected return CVaR SMCR MV CVaR Figure 3: Expected return vs 99%-CVaR for the SMCR-, CVaR-, and MV-optimal portfolios. The SMCRoptimal portfolio was calculated with R( ) = SMCR 0.90 ( ) in (25a), and the CVaR-optimal portfolio was calculated with R( ) = CVaR 0.90 ( ) in (25a). 17

18 to close estimates of risk. Recall that for such values of parameters, the expressions for SMCR α and CVaR α take almost identical forms, differing only in the values of η that deliver the minima in the corresponding representations (7) and (4): in the case of SMCR, the optimal η contains the second-moment information via (11), whereas in the case of CVaR the corresponding η represents a quantile. In particular, the presented results suggest that in the in-sample setting the effects of second-moment information in risk estimates produced by the SMCR risk measure, as compared to those due to CVaR measure, are almost negligible. This, however, will change in the out-of-sample setting, as we will see below. 3.2 Out-of-sample tests The out-of-sample testing allows one to shed light on the potential real-life performance of a particular decision-making strategy under uncertainty. As the name suggests, the out-of- sample testing involves construction of a solution based on a given sample of the underlying stochastic data of the problem, and then testing this solution on a different, out-of-sample, data. In the context of the present work, we employ out-of-sample optimization to compare simulated historic performances of the three self-financing portfolio rebalancing strategies based on (25) with R being taken as SMCR 0.90 ( ), CVaR 0.99 ( ), or variance σ 2 ( ). It may be argued that in practice of portfolio selection, instead of solving (25), it is of more interest to construct investment portfolios that maximize the expected return subject to constraint(s) on risk, e.g., { max E r, x ( ) } R r, x c0, e, x = 1. (28) x 0 Indeed, many investment institutions are required to keep their investment portfolios in compliance with numerous constraints, including constraints on risk. However, the primary goal of this case study is to elucidate the effectiveness of employing the SMCR risk measure in portfolio optimization by comparing it against other well-established risk management methodlogies, such as the CVaR and MV frameworks. And since these three risk measures yield risk estimates on different scales, it is not evident what risk tolerance levels c 0 should be selected in (28) to make the resulting portfolios comparable. Thus, to have a fair apple-to-apple comparison, we construct self-financing portfolio rebalancing strategies by solving the risk-minimization problem (25), so that the resulting portfolios will all have the same level r 0 of expected return, and the success of a particular portfolio rebalancing strategy will depend on the actual amount of risk borne by the portfolio due to utilization of the corresponding risk measure. The out-of-sample experiments have been set up as follows. The initial SMCR-, CVaR-, and MVoptimal portfolios were constructed on Jan 03, 2005 by solving the corresponding variant of problem (25), where the scenario set consisted of 300 overlapping bi-weekly returns covering the period from Oct 23, 2003 to Jan 03, The duration of rebalancing period for all strategies was set at two weeks (10 business days). Thus, the next rebalancing date was Jan 17, at which the 10-day out-ofsample portfolio returns were observed for each of the three portfolios by plugging the vector ˆr of Jan 03 Jan 17 returns into ˆr, x, with x being the corresponding optimal portfolio configuration obtained on January 03. Then, all the three portfolios were rebalanced by solving (25) with an updated 18

19 scenario set. Namely, we included in the scenario set the 10 vectors of overlapping biweekly returns that realized during the ten business days from Jan 03 to Jan 17, and discarded the oldest 10 return vectors from October The process was repeated on January 31, 2005, and so on. In such a way, the out-of-sample experiment consisted of 25 biweekly rebalancing periods. We ran the outof-sample tests for different values of minimal required expected return r 0, and typical results are presented in Figures 4 and 5. Figure 4 reports the portfolio values (in percent of the initial investment) for the three portfolio rebalancing strategies based on (25) with SMCR 0.90 ( ), CVaR 0.90 ( ), and variance σ 2 ( ) as R( ), and the expected return level r 0 being set at 1%. One can observe that in this case the trajectories of SMCR and CVaR portfolios virtually coincide as they both outperform the MV portfolio; this situation is typical for smaller values of r 0. An insight as to why the SMCR and CVaR portfolios have very similar out-of-sample performances at lower r 0 can be gleaned from the in-sample experiments: indeed, as evidenced by Figures 1 3, at lower values of r 0 the variations of problem (25) with R( ) = SMCR 0.90 ( ) and R( ) = CVaR 0.99 ( ) tend to produce very similar portfolios. As r 0 increases and the rebalancing strategies become more aggressive, the differences between SMCR and CVaR portfolios and the corresponding risk-reward curves become more pronounced, which translates into differing out-of-sample performance. An illustration of the typical behavior of more aggressive rebalancing strategies is presented in Figure 5, where r 0 is set at 2.5%. As a general trend, an aggressive SMCR portfolio would outperform similarly aggressive CVaR portfolio, and they both would outdo the MV portfolio. For instance, at r 0 = the SMCR portfolio outperforms the CVaR portfolio by approximately as much as CVaR outperforms the MV portfolio (see Fig. 5). Similar situations are observed for values of r 0 ranging from 2.0% to 3.0% (on the dataset used in this case study, infeasibilities in (25) began to occur for values of r ). Notwithstanding the data-specific nature of the obtained results, the conducted out-of-sample simulations suggest that the SMCR risk measure may be preferred by investors with rather aggressive risk preferences Out-of-sample results: Deviation measures In addition to out-of-sample comparison of SMCR and CVaR as coherent risk measures, we also conducted similar studies for their deviation counterparts. Recall that under certain conditions, a deviation measure can be formed from a coherent risk measure by simply subtracting the expectation of the argument: D(X) = R(X) EX. Figure 6 displays the simulated historical trajectories of the DSMCR and DCVaR portfolios obtained from (25) by plugging the expressions SMCR 0.90 ( ) E( ) and CVaR 0.90 ( ) E( ), respectively, for R( ) in (25a). The required level of expected return in of portfolios in Fig. 6 is fixed at r 0 = Again, we observe a picture that is consistent with our previous findings: for higher values of r 0, the portfolio based on second-moment deviation measure ( DSMCR ) tends to outperform the corresponding portfolio based on the Deviation CVaR ( DCVaR ) measure, which is again a typical situation for higher values of expected return r 0. 19

20 130% 125% 120% Portfolio value 115% 110% 105% 100% CVaR SMCR MV 95% 90% 29-Dec Feb-05 8-Apr May Jul-05 5-Sep Oct Dec-05 2-Feb-06 Time Figure 4: Out-of-sample performance of self-financing portfolio rebalancing strategies based on SMCR, CVaR, and MV measures of risk (r 0 = 0.01) 170% 160% 150% Portfolio value 140% 130% 120% CVaR SMCR MV 110% 100% 90% 29-Dec Feb-05 8-Apr May Jul-05 5-Sep Oct Dec-05 2-Feb-06 Time Figure 5: Out-of-sample performance of self-financing portfolio rebalancing strategies based on SMCR, CVaR, and MV measures of risk (r 0 = 0.025) 20

21 180% 170% Expected return 160% 150% 140% 130% 120% DSMCR DCVaR 110% 100% 29-Dec Feb-05 8-Apr May Jul-05 Time 5-Sep Oct Dec-05 2-Feb-06 Figure 6: Out-of-sample performance of self-financing portfolio rebalancing strategies based on deviation measures (r 0 = 0.025) Portfolio optimization with SMCR constraint Finally, we present the results of the out-of-sample simulations for self-financing portfolio rebalancing strategies with SMCR constraints, which are based on solutions of (28), where R( ) = SMCR 0.90 ( ). Due to Theorem 3, problem (28) may be formulated, similarly to (27), as a linear programming problem with a single second-order cone constraint: min s. t. 1 J J j=1 i=1 n r i j x i j n x i = 1, i=1 (29a) (29b) η t c 0, (29c) 1 α J n w j r i j x i η, j = 1,..., J, (29d) i=1 t J w 2 j, j=1 (29e) x i 0, i = 1,..., n, (29f) w j 0, j = 1,..., J. (29g) The out-of-sample tests were conducted in the same fashion as described above, with problem (29) being solved to obtain the optimal portfolio configurations. Multiple runs of the out-of-sample simulations were performed for different values of the risk tolerance c 0 in (29c). The resulting simulated historical trajectories are presented in Figure 7. It is worth noting that at higher levels of risk tolerance c 0 the portfolio model with SMCR constraint allows for achieving considerably higher out-of-sample returns comparing to models where the SMCR objective is minimized, although at the expense of 21

A Computational Study of Modern Approaches to Risk-Averse Stochastic Optimization Using Financial Portfolio Allocation Model.

A Computational Study of Modern Approaches to Risk-Averse Stochastic Optimization Using Financial Portfolio Allocation Model. A Computational Study of Modern Approaches to Risk-Averse Stochastic Optimization Using Financial Portfolio Allocation Model by Suklim Choi A thesis submitted to the Graduate Faculty of Auburn University

More information

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments T. Fischer Darmstadt University of Technology November 11, 2003 Abstract This brief paper explains how to obtain upper boundaries of shortfall

More information

VaR vs CVaR in Risk Management and Optimization

VaR vs CVaR in Risk Management and Optimization VaR vs CVaR in Risk Management and Optimization Stan Uryasev Joint presentation with Sergey Sarykalin, Gaia Serraino and Konstantin Kalinchenko Risk Management and Financial Engineering Lab, University

More information

Comparative Analyses of Expected Shortfall and Value-at-Risk (2): Expected Utility Maximization and Tail Risk

Comparative Analyses of Expected Shortfall and Value-at-Risk (2): Expected Utility Maximization and Tail Risk MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES/APRIL 2002 Comparative Analyses of Expected Shortfall and Value-at-Risk (2): Expected Utility Maximization and Tail Risk Yasuhiro Yamai and Toshinao Yoshiba We compare expected

More information

FRONTIERS OF STOCHASTICALLY NONDOMINATED PORTFOLIOS

FRONTIERS OF STOCHASTICALLY NONDOMINATED PORTFOLIOS FRONTIERS OF STOCHASTICALLY NONDOMINATED PORTFOLIOS Andrzej Ruszczyński and Robert J. Vanderbei Abstract. We consider the problem of constructing a portfolio of finitely many assets whose returns are described

More information

Maximum Downside Semi Deviation Stochastic Programming for Portfolio Optimization Problem

Maximum Downside Semi Deviation Stochastic Programming for Portfolio Optimization Problem Journal of Modern Applied Statistical Methods Volume 9 Issue 2 Article 2 --200 Maximum Downside Semi Deviation Stochastic Programming for Portfolio Optimization Problem Anton Abdulbasah Kamil Universiti

More information

Classic and Modern Measures of Risk in Fixed

Classic and Modern Measures of Risk in Fixed Classic and Modern Measures of Risk in Fixed Income Portfolio Optimization Miguel Ángel Martín Mato Ph. D in Economic Science Professor of Finance CENTRUM Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. C/ Nueve

More information

Quantitative Risk Management

Quantitative Risk Management Quantitative Risk Management Asset Allocation and Risk Management Martin B. Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Outline Review of Mean-Variance Analysis

More information

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective Finance Research Letters 2 (2005) 23 29 www.elsevier.com/locate/frl A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective Robert A. Jarrow a,b,, Amiyatosh K. Purnanandam c a Johnson Graduate School

More information

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications The School of Mathematics Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications by Jakob Kisiala s1301096 Dissertation Presented for the Degree of MSc in Operational Research August 2015 Supervised by Dr

More information

PORTFOLIO selection problems are usually tackled with

PORTFOLIO selection problems are usually tackled with , October 21-23, 2015, San Francisco, USA Portfolio Optimization with Reward-Risk Ratio Measure based on the Conditional Value-at-Risk Wlodzimierz Ogryczak, Michał Przyłuski, Tomasz Śliwiński Abstract

More information

Risk aversion in multi-stage stochastic programming: a modeling and algorithmic perspective

Risk aversion in multi-stage stochastic programming: a modeling and algorithmic perspective Risk aversion in multi-stage stochastic programming: a modeling and algorithmic perspective Tito Homem-de-Mello School of Business Universidad Adolfo Ibañez, Santiago, Chile Joint work with Bernardo Pagnoncelli

More information

Capital Allocation Principles

Capital Allocation Principles Capital Allocation Principles Maochao Xu Department of Mathematics Illinois State University mxu2@ilstu.edu Capital Dhaene, et al., 2011, Journal of Risk and Insurance The level of the capital held by

More information

Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p , Wiley 2004.

Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p , Wiley 2004. Rau-Bredow, Hans: Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p. 61-68, Wiley 2004. Copyright geschützt 5 Value-at-Risk,

More information

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Risk Measures Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com Reference: Chapter 8

More information

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION HARRY PANJER University of Waterloo JIA JING Tianjin University of Economics and Finance Abstract This paper discusses a new criterion for allocation of required capital.

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Lecture 10: Performance measures

Lecture 10: Performance measures Lecture 10: Performance measures Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev Institute for Statistics and Mathematical Economics University of Karlsruhe Portfolio and Asset Liability Management Summer Semester 2008 Prof.

More information

Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures

Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures Garud Iyengar Columbia University Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Joint work with Carlos Abad Outline Portfolio selection and risk measures

More information

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return by Lei Zhu A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfillment of the thesis requirement for the degree of Master of Mathematics

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Numerical Comparison of CVaR and CDaR Approaches: Application to Hedge Funds 1. Pavlo Krokhmal, Stanislav Uryasev, and Grigory Zrazhevsky

Numerical Comparison of CVaR and CDaR Approaches: Application to Hedge Funds 1. Pavlo Krokhmal, Stanislav Uryasev, and Grigory Zrazhevsky Numerical Comparison of CVaR and CDaR Approaches: Application to Hedge Funds 1 Pavlo Krokhmal, Stanislav Uryasev, and Grigory Zrazhevsky Risk Management and Financial Engineering Lab Department of Industrial

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management Ineffectiveness of VaR and ES constraints John Armstrong (KCL), Damiano Brigo (Imperial) Quant Summit March 2018 Are ES constraints effective against rogue

More information

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics. The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics. The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/cam

More information

Building Consistent Risk Measures into Stochastic Optimization Models

Building Consistent Risk Measures into Stochastic Optimization Models Building Consistent Risk Measures into Stochastic Optimization Models John R. Birge The University of Chicago Graduate School of Business www.chicagogsb.edu/fac/john.birge JRBirge Fuqua School, Duke University

More information

Portfolio Optimization with Alternative Risk Measures

Portfolio Optimization with Alternative Risk Measures Portfolio Optimization with Alternative Risk Measures Prof. Daniel P. Palomar The Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST) MAFS6010R- Portfolio Optimization with R MSc in Financial Mathematics

More information

Third-degree stochastic dominance and DEA efficiency relations and numerical comparison

Third-degree stochastic dominance and DEA efficiency relations and numerical comparison Third-degree stochastic dominance and DEA efficiency relations and numerical comparison 1 Introduction Martin Branda 1 Abstract. We propose efficiency tests which are related to the third-degree stochastic

More information

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Working Paper Series Department of Economics University of Verona Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note Louis Raymond Eeckhoudt, Elisa Pagani, Emanuela Rosazza Gianin WP

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

Risk Reward Optimisation for Long-Run Investors: an Empirical Analysis

Risk Reward Optimisation for Long-Run Investors: an Empirical Analysis GoBack Risk Reward Optimisation for Long-Run Investors: an Empirical Analysis M. Gilli University of Geneva and Swiss Finance Institute E. Schumann University of Geneva AFIR / LIFE Colloquium 2009 München,

More information

Data Envelopment Analysis in Finance and Energy New Approaches to Efficiency and their Numerical Tractability

Data Envelopment Analysis in Finance and Energy New Approaches to Efficiency and their Numerical Tractability Data Envelopment Analysis in Finance and Energy New Approaches to Efficiency and their Numerical Tractability Martin Branda Faculty of Mathematics and Physics Charles University in Prague EURO Working

More information

Solving real-life portfolio problem using stochastic programming and Monte-Carlo techniques

Solving real-life portfolio problem using stochastic programming and Monte-Carlo techniques Solving real-life portfolio problem using stochastic programming and Monte-Carlo techniques 1 Introduction Martin Branda 1 Abstract. We deal with real-life portfolio problem with Value at Risk, transaction

More information

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis Mario Brandtner Friedrich Schiller University of Jena,

More information

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization Enzo Busseti Stanford University April 9th, 2018 Problems portfolio management choose trades with optimization minimize risk, maximize

More information

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Tokyo, June 2015 Haijun Li Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game Tokyo, June 2015 1

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

An Asset Allocation Puzzle: Comment

An Asset Allocation Puzzle: Comment An Asset Allocation Puzzle: Comment By HAIM SHALIT AND SHLOMO YITZHAKI* The purpose of this note is to look at the rationale behind popular advice on portfolio allocation among cash, bonds, and stocks.

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Steven E. Shreve Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 USA shreve@andrew.cmu.edu A Talk in the Series Probability in Science and Industry

More information

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio International Letters of Chemistry, Physics and Astronomy Online: 2015-07-01 ISSN: 2299-3843, Vol. 53, pp 130-136 doi:10.18052/www.scipress.com/ilcpa.53.130 2015 SciPress Ltd., Switzerland Portfolio Optimization

More information

Equation Chapter 1 Section 1 A Primer on Quantitative Risk Measures

Equation Chapter 1 Section 1 A Primer on Quantitative Risk Measures Equation Chapter 1 Section 1 A rimer on Quantitative Risk Measures aul D. Kaplan, h.d., CFA Quantitative Research Director Morningstar Europe, Ltd. London, UK 25 April 2011 Ever since Harry Markowitz s

More information

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles Ka Chun Cheung Email: kccheung@math.ucalgary.ca Tel: +1-403-2108697 Fax: +1-403-2825150 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Calgary,

More information

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Log-Robust Portfolio Management Log-Robust Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Elcin Cetinkaya and Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983 Dr.

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk X Workshop on Quantitative Finance Milan, January 29-30, 2009 Agenda Coherent Measures of Risk Spectral Measures of Risk Capital Allocation Euler Principle Application Risk Measurement Risk Attribution

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Portfolio rankings with skewness and kurtosis

Portfolio rankings with skewness and kurtosis Computational Finance and its Applications III 109 Portfolio rankings with skewness and kurtosis M. Di Pierro 1 &J.Mosevich 1 DePaul University, School of Computer Science, 43 S. Wabash Avenue, Chicago,

More information

Robustness of Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) for Measuring Market Risk

Robustness of Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) for Measuring Market Risk STOCKHOLM SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS MASTER S THESIS IN FINANCE Robustness of Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) for Measuring Market Risk Mattias Letmark a & Markus Ringström b a 869@student.hhs.se; b 846@student.hhs.se

More information

Optimizing Portfolios

Optimizing Portfolios Optimizing Portfolios An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2010 Introduction Investors may wish to adjust the allocation of financial resources including a mixture

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 00: Course Logistics Introduction to Finance Optimization Problems

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 00: Course Logistics Introduction to Finance Optimization Problems CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 00: Course Logistics Introduction to Finance Optimization Problems January 26, 2018 1 / 24 Basic information All information is available in the syllabus

More information

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key 1. Exercises from MWG (Chapter 6): (a) Exercise 6.B.1 from MWG: Show that if the preferences % over L satisfy the independence axiom, then for all 2 (0; 1) and

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

The risk/return trade-off has been a

The risk/return trade-off has been a Efficient Risk/Return Frontiers for Credit Risk HELMUT MAUSSER AND DAN ROSEN HELMUT MAUSSER is a mathematician at Algorithmics Inc. in Toronto, Canada. DAN ROSEN is the director of research at Algorithmics

More information

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Alfredo Garcia and Robert L. Smith Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering Universityof Michigan, Ann Arbor MI 48109 December

More information

Dynamic Risk Management in Electricity Portfolio Optimization via Polyhedral Risk Functionals

Dynamic Risk Management in Electricity Portfolio Optimization via Polyhedral Risk Functionals Dynamic Risk Management in Electricity Portfolio Optimization via Polyhedral Risk Functionals A. Eichhorn and W. Römisch Humboldt-University Berlin, Department of Mathematics, Germany http://www.math.hu-berlin.de/~romisch

More information

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract Linear risk tolerance and mean variance preferences Andreas Wagener University of Vienna Abstract We translate the property of linear risk tolerance (hyperbolical Arrow Pratt index of risk aversion) from

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH http://www.kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp/index.html Discussion Paper No. 657 The Buy Price in Auctions with Discrete Type Distributions Yusuke Inami

More information

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Université de Lyon 1, ISFA April 23 2014 Tlemcen - CIMPA Research School Motivations Study of optimal risk transfer structures, Natural question in Reinsurance.

More information

Financial Risk Management

Financial Risk Management Financial Risk Management Professor: Thierry Roncalli Evry University Assistant: Enareta Kurtbegu Evry University Tutorial exercices #4 1 Correlation and copulas 1. The bivariate Gaussian copula is given

More information

MULTISTAGE PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION AS A STOCHASTIC OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEM

MULTISTAGE PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION AS A STOCHASTIC OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEM K Y B E R N E T I K A M A N U S C R I P T P R E V I E W MULTISTAGE PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION AS A STOCHASTIC OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEM Martin Lauko Each portfolio optimization problem is a trade off between

More information

Lecture 6: Risk and uncertainty

Lecture 6: Risk and uncertainty Lecture 6: Risk and uncertainty Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev Institute for Statistics and Mathematical Economics University of Karlsruhe Portfolio and Asset Liability Management Summer Semester 2008 Prof.

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Tel: Fax: Web:

Tel: Fax: Web: IIASA I n t e r n a t io na l I n s t i tu te f o r A p p l i e d S y s t e m s A n a l y s is A - 2 3 6 1 L a x e n b u rg A u s t r i a Tel: +43 2236 807 Fax: +43 2236 71313 E-mail: info@iiasa.ac.at

More information

RISK-REWARD STRATEGIES FOR THE NON-ADDITIVE TWO-OPTION ONLINE LEASING PROBLEM. Xiaoli Chen and Weijun Xu. Received March 2017; revised July 2017

RISK-REWARD STRATEGIES FOR THE NON-ADDITIVE TWO-OPTION ONLINE LEASING PROBLEM. Xiaoli Chen and Weijun Xu. Received March 2017; revised July 2017 International Journal of Innovative Computing, Information and Control ICIC International c 207 ISSN 349-498 Volume 3, Number 6, December 207 pp 205 2065 RISK-REWARD STRATEGIES FOR THE NON-ADDITIVE TWO-OPTION

More information

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH

INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH INSURANCE VALUATION: A COMPUTABLE MULTI-PERIOD COST-OF-CAPITAL APPROACH HAMPUS ENGSNER, MATHIAS LINDHOLM, AND FILIP LINDSKOG Abstract. We present an approach to market-consistent multi-period valuation

More information

Risk-Averse Decision Making and Control

Risk-Averse Decision Making and Control Marek Petrik University of New Hampshire Mohammad Ghavamzadeh Adobe Research February 4, 2017 Introduction to Risk Averse Modeling Outline Introduction to Risk Averse Modeling (Average) Value at Risk Coherent

More information

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index Advanced Topics in Machine Learning and Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index Lecturer: Yishay Mansour Scribe: Mariano Schain 7.1 Introduction In the Bayesian approach

More information

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory 1. Introduction 2. Portfolio Basics 3. The Feasible Set 4. Portfolio Selection Rules 5. The Efficient Frontier 6. Indifference Curves 7. The Two-Asset Portfolio 8. Unrestriceted

More information

Section B: Risk Measures. Value-at-Risk, Jorion

Section B: Risk Measures. Value-at-Risk, Jorion Section B: Risk Measures Value-at-Risk, Jorion One thing to always keep in mind when reading this text is that it is focused on the banking industry. It mainly focuses on market and credit risk. It also

More information

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs 1 Introduction Václav Kozmík 1 Abstract. This paper deals with asset allocation problems formulated as multistage stochastic programming models.

More information

Where Has All the Value Gone? Portfolio risk optimization using CVaR

Where Has All the Value Gone? Portfolio risk optimization using CVaR Where Has All the Value Gone? Portfolio risk optimization using CVaR Jonathan Sterbanz April 27, 2005 1 Introduction Corporate securities are widely used as a means to boost the value of asset portfolios;

More information

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery? Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery? Peter Forsyth 1 D.M. Dang 1 1 Cheriton School of Computer Science University of Waterloo Guangzhou, July 28, 2014 1 / 29 The Basic

More information

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking Mika Sumida School of Operations Research and Information Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York

More information

The Journal of Risk (1 31) Volume 11/Number 3, Spring 2009

The Journal of Risk (1 31) Volume 11/Number 3, Spring 2009 The Journal of Risk (1 ) Volume /Number 3, Spring Min-max robust and CVaR robust mean-variance portfolios Lei Zhu David R Cheriton School of Computer Science, University of Waterloo, 0 University Avenue

More information

Learning and Holding Periods for Portfolio Selection Models: A Sensitivity Analysis

Learning and Holding Periods for Portfolio Selection Models: A Sensitivity Analysis Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 7,, no., 98-999 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/.988/ams..78 Learning and Holding Periods for Portfolio Selection Models: A Sensitivity Analysis Francesco

More information

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1 A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model of Inequity Aversion 1 Kirsten I.M. Rohde 2 January 12, 2009 1 The author would like to thank Itzhak Gilboa, Ingrid M.T. Rohde, Klaus M. Schmidt, and

More information

Liquidity-Adjusted Risk Measures

Liquidity-Adjusted Risk Measures Liquidity-Adjusted Risk Measures S. Weber, W. Anderson, A.-M. Hamm, T. Knispel, M. Liese, T. Salfeld January 18, 213 Abstract Liquidity risk is an important type of risk, especially during times of crises.

More information

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Problem Set: Contract Theory Problem Set: Contract Theory Problem 1 A risk-neutral principal P hires an agent A, who chooses an effort a 0, which results in gross profit x = a + ε for P, where ε is uniformly distributed on [0, 1].

More information

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business An Introduction to Conic Finance A Mini Course at Eurandom January 13 2011 Outline Operationally defining

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Risk Quadrangle and Applications in Day-Trading of Equity Indices

Risk Quadrangle and Applications in Day-Trading of Equity Indices Risk Quadrangle and Applications in Day-Trading of Equity Indices Stan Uryasev Risk Management and Financial Engineering Lab University of Florida and American Optimal Decisions 1 Agenda Fundamental quadrangle

More information

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Problem Set: Contract Theory Problem Set: Contract Theory Problem 1 A risk-neutral principal P hires an agent A, who chooses an effort a 0, which results in gross profit x = a + ε for P, where ε is uniformly distributed on [0, 1].

More information

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator ISSN: 2455-216X Impact Factor: RJIF 5.12 www.allnationaljournal.com Volume 4; Issue 3; September 2018; Page No. 25-30 Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

More information

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015 Best-Reply Sets Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis This version: May 2015 Introduction The best-reply correspondence of a game the mapping from beliefs over one s opponents actions to

More information

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory A. Salo, T. Seeve Systems Analysis Laboratory Department of System Analysis and Mathematics Aalto University, School of Science Overview

More information

Dependence Modeling and Credit Risk

Dependence Modeling and Credit Risk Dependence Modeling and Credit Risk Paola Mosconi Banca IMI Bocconi University, 20/04/2015 Paola Mosconi Lecture 6 1 / 53 Disclaimer The opinion expressed here are solely those of the author and do not

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.7 Investor Utility Functions People are always asked the question: would more money make you happier? The answer is usually yes. The next question is how much more

More information

MEASURING OF SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY

MEASURING OF SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY K Y BERNETIKA VOLUM E 46 ( 2010), NUMBER 3, P AGES 488 500 MEASURING OF SECOND ORDER STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY Miloš Kopa In this paper, we deal with second-order stochastic dominance (SSD)

More information

Portfolio Optimization. Prof. Daniel P. Palomar

Portfolio Optimization. Prof. Daniel P. Palomar Portfolio Optimization Prof. Daniel P. Palomar The Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST) MAFS6010R- Portfolio Optimization with R MSc in Financial Mathematics Fall 2018-19, HKUST, Hong

More information

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory C. David Levermore University of Maryland, College Park Math 420: Mathematical Modeling January 30, 2013

More information

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall 2014 Reduce the risk, one asset Let us warm up by doing an exercise. We consider an investment with σ 1 =

More information

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Yan Zeng Version 1.0.2, last revised on 2012-05-30. Abstract A summary of mean variance analysis in portfolio management and capital asset pricing model. 1. Mean-Variance

More information

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences H. Mete Soner ETH Zürich and Swiss Finance Institute Joint with Matteo Burzoni, ETH Zürich Frank Riedel, University of Bielefeld Thera Stochastics in Honor of Ioannis

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

An Application of Extreme Value Theory for Measuring Financial Risk in the Uruguayan Pension Fund 1

An Application of Extreme Value Theory for Measuring Financial Risk in the Uruguayan Pension Fund 1 An Application of Extreme Value Theory for Measuring Financial Risk in the Uruguayan Pension Fund 1 Guillermo Magnou 23 January 2016 Abstract Traditional methods for financial risk measures adopts normal

More information

A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets

A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets PRIN Conference Stochastic Methods in Finance Torino - July, 2008 A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets Giacomo Scandolo - Università di Firenze Carlo Acerbi - AbaxBank Milano Liquidity

More information