WORKING PAPER SERIES. No 36 / Investment-Specific Shocks, Business Cycles, and Asset Prices

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "WORKING PAPER SERIES. No 36 / Investment-Specific Shocks, Business Cycles, and Asset Prices"

Transcription

1 BANK OF LITHUANIA. WORKING PAPER SERIES No 1 / 28 SHORT-TERM FORECASTING OF GDP USING LARGE MONTHLY DATASETS: A PSEUDO REAL-TIME FORECAST EVALUATION EXERCISE 1 WORKING PAPER SERIES Investment-Specific Shocks, Business Cycles, and Asset Prices By Giuliano Curatola, Michael Donadelli, Patrick Grüning and Christoph Meinerding No 36 / 216

2 ISSN (ONLINE) WORKING PAPER SERIES No 36 / 216 INVESTMENT-SPECIFIC SHOCKS, BUSINESS CYCLES, AND ASSET PRICES Giuliano Curatola *, Michael Donadelli *, Patrick Grüning ** and Christoph Meinerding * * Faculty of Economics and Business Administration and Research Center SAFE, Goethe University Frankfurt. s: curatola@safe.uni-frankfurt.de, donadelli@safe.uni-frankfurt.de, meinerding@finance.uni-frankfurt.de. ** Center for Excellence in Finance and Economic Research (CEFER), Bank of Lithuania, and Faculty of Economics, Vilnius University. PGruening@lb.lt. The authors acknowledge helpful discussions with Mykola Babiak, Roberto Casarin, Alain Coën, Fulvio Corsi, Ana-Maria Fuertes, Roberto Pancrazi, Antonio Paradiso, Aurelija Proškutė, Christian Schlag, Ctirad Slavík, and Peter Zorn. Moreover, we thank the seminar participants at the 11th Dynare Conference, the 19th Conference of the Swiss Society for Financial Market Research, the 5th Annual Lithuanian Conference on Economic Research, the 216 World Finance Conference, the 23rd Annual Meeting of the German Finance Association (DGF), and the University of Venice for their helpful comments. We gratefully acknowledge research and financial support from the Research Center SAFE, funded by the State of Hessen initiative for research LOEWE. The views expressed herein are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Bank of Lithuania or the Eurosystem. This paper is also available on SSRN as SAFE Working Paper No. 129:

3 Lietuvos bankas, 216 Reproduction for educational and non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged. Address Totorių g. 4 LT-1121 Vilnius Lithuania Telephone (8 5) Internet Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to stimulate discussion and critical comments. The Series is managed by Applied Macroeconomic Research Division of Economics Department. The views expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the Bank of Lithuania. ISSN (ONLINE)

4 Investment-Specific Shocks, Business Cycles, and Asset Prices November 24, 216 Abstract This paper proposes and tests a new source of time variation in real investment opportunities, namely long-run shocks to the productivity of the investment sector, to explain the joint behavior of macroeconomic quantities and asset prices. A twosector general equilibrium model with long-run investment shocks and wage rigidities produces both positive co-movement among key macroeconomic variables and a sizable return volatility differential between the investment and consumption sector. Moreover, positive long-run investment shocks are associated with low marginal utility and thus command a positive risk premium. We test our model using data on sectoral TFP and find evidence in support of our theoretical predictions. Keywords: General Equilibrium Asset Pricing, Production Economy, Long-Run Risk, Investment-Specific Shocks, Wage Rigidities. JEL: E32, G12. 4

5 1 Introduction Recent research has shown that investment-specific shocks play a key role in explaining the dynamics of business cycles and asset prices. 1 Typically, in the associated equilibrium models, investment-specific shocks affect the formation of new capital goods by changing the marginal efficiency of new investments (MEI) and, thus, they are often referred to as MEI shocks. Although this approach contributes a great deal to our understanding of the role of investment-specific shocks, it leaves some questions open. First, models that attribute a central role to MEI shocks tend to produce a counterfactual negative co-movement among macroeconomic variables (the so-called co-movement puzzle ). Second, with few exceptions, this literature focuses on the ability of investment-specific shocks to explain either macroeconomic dynamics or time-series and cross-sectional properties of stock returns. The joint implications of investment-specific shocks for asset prices and macroeconomic quantities are, however, not yet fully understood and appreciated. We argue that a consistent explanation of macroeconomic co-movements, relying on investment shocks, should also be able to provide a reasonable fit for key asset pricing moments and the dynamics of stock returns, and vice versa. In this paper we propose a different source of time variation in investment opportunities, namely long-run risk (LRR) in the total factor productivity (TFP) of the investment sector, and analyze its performance with respect to the two issues outlined above. We introduce LRR in a general equilibrium model with two sectors (consumption and investment), assuming that the TFP processes of both sectors are driven by short-run (SR) and long-run (LR) components. We show, both theoretically and empirically, that our decomposition of investment-specific shocks into SR and LR components makes a substantial 1 The different strands of literature on investment-specific shocks are summarized in Section 2. 5

6 contribution towards understanding and solving the issues described above. The co-movement of macroeconomic variables can be quantified in several ways. We start by looking at impulse response functions from our model and find that only SR investment shocks are responsible for the co-movement puzzle while LR investment shocks do not induce any negative co-movement between macroeconomic quantities. Moreover, in the long run (from about 5 quarters after the shock onwards), the responses of macro variables to LR investment shocks are all positive. The intuition behind this result is as follows. SR investment shocks increase the current profitability of the investment sector relative to the consumption sector. As a result, they naturally generate a substitution effect that induces households to reallocate resources towards the investment sector, thus inducing a negative co-movement among macroeconomic variables. Differently, LR investment shocks affect the future profitability of investment. In addition to the substitution effect, positive news about future investment profitability generate an additional wealth effect that creates positive conditional co-movement among macroeconomic variables in the long run. The conditional analysis using impulse responses illustrates only one aspect of the co-movement puzzle. The unconditional correlation of macro quantities, which comprises their response to all shocks in the economy, represents the other equally important aspect. Since SR shocks are quantitatively more important for unconditional correlations, our baseline model with SR and LR shocks still suffers from an unconditional co-movement puzzle. The typical way to fix this is to assume rigidities of some kind, for instance wage rigidities, and we follow the same route in this paper. However, since we do not include MEI shocks, which exacerbate the co-movement puzzle, the degree of wage rigidities necessary to match empirical moments in our benchmark model is much smaller and 6

7 more realistic than in a model with MEI shocks. The degree of wage rigidities necessary to make unconditional correlations positive is important because wage rigidities induce a trade-off between matching macroeconomic quantities and matching the equity return volatilites of the two sectors. More specifically, high wage rigidities imply a low volatility spread between the investment and consumption sector. First and foremost, they impair the ability of the productive sector to react to macroeconomic shocks and thus make firms cash flows riskier. On top, however, this additional cash flow risk spills over from the investment sector to the consumption sector through the formation of capital goods, and so the increase of the consumption sector volatility is higher than that of the investment sector volatility, which makes the volatility spread unrealistically low. LR investment risk offers a way out of this tension. It improves the model s ability to generate realistic properties of sectoral stock returns while at the same time not inducing negative co-movement among macroeconomic variables. MEI shocks also have the potential to induce a high volatility spread between the investment and consumption sector as Papanikolaou (211) shows. However, we document that MEI shocks induce negative co-movement between consumption and investment growth. From this point of view, LR investment shocks are, therefore, better able to jointly improve the dynamics of macroeconomic quantities and asset prices. The ability not to generate negative co-movement implies that LR investment risk needs to be associated with only a moderate degree of wage rigidities in order to obtain positive unconditional correlations among macroeconomic variables, thus preserving the asset pricing properties of the model. We also verify the main economic mechanism of our model empirically. We estimate the TFP processes of the consumption and the investment sector and extract their LR 7

8 component by applying a standard state-space approach to sectoral TFP data. We then estimate the dynamic impulse responses of consumption, output, investment, and labor to SR and LR sectoral shocks in a VAR model and find that LR investment shocks have a positive long-run impact on macro variables as predicted by our theoretical model. Moreover, we document that the SR and LR components of sectoral TFP are also quantitatively important. For instance, over a horizon of one quarter, SR shocks (together) account for 58 percent while LR shocks account for 12 percent of output fluctuations. The predictive power of SR shocks tends to decrease with the forecasting horizon while the predictive power of LR shocks tends to increase: over a horizon of 2 quarters SR shocks account for 48 percent while LR shocks account for 16 percent of output fluctuations. Our evidence also suggests that LR investment shocks are quantitatively more important than LR consumption shocks in explaining macroeconomic fluctuations. In fact, we find that LR investment shocks explain a fraction of output variance that can be up to 13 times bigger than the fraction of output variance explained by LR consumption shocks. The empirical identification strategy is also useful to test the cross-sectional asset pricing implications of LR investment shocks. In our model, these shocks are associated with economic states with low marginal utility and thus command a positive risk premium. We confirm this prediction empirically. Using the standard two-stage Fama-MacBeth procedure we document that LR investment shocks are priced in the cross-section of stock returns and carry a positive and significant risk premium. These results taken together suggest that LR investment risk is a plausible candidate to explain not only fluctuations of macroeconomic quantities, but also key asset pricing moments. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the relevant literature on this topic. Our two-sector production economy is presented in Section 3 8

9 and its quantitative implications are analyzed in Section 4. Section 5 provides empirical evidence on the main mechanism of the paper. Section 6 documents the cross-sectional asset pricing performance of LR investment shocks. Section 7 concludes. 2 Related Research This paper links two strands of literature. The first strand of literature argues that investment shocks are important drivers of business cycle fluctuations: Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krussel (1997, 2), Christiano and Fisher (23), Fisher (26), Jaimovich and Rebelo (29), Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (21, 211). Recently, a branch of this literature focuses on the co-movement puzzle generated by MEI shocks that represent the most popular way of modelling investment shocks: Khan and Tsoukalas (211), Furlanetto and Seneca (214a,b). A second strand of literature analyzes the asset pricing implications of investment shocks: Li (214), Kogan and Papanikolaou (214), Kogan, Papanikolaou, and Stoffman (215), Garlappi and Song (216b). Similarly to our paper, Papanikolaou (211) and Segal (215) analyze the joint implications of investment-specific shocks for macro quantities and asset prices. Our two-sector model is similar to that of Jaimovich and Rebelo (29), Papanikolaou (211), and Segal (215). We differ from Jaimovich and Rebelo (29) with respect to two important aspects: the utility function and the structure of sectoral shocks. Jaimovich and Rebelo (29) assume that the representative agent features habit formation in consumption and that the level of sectoral TFP is subject to permanent shocks which implies that the growth rate of sectoral TFP is a random walk. Differently, in our model the growth rate of sectoral TFP processes follows a random walk with time-varying drift. 9

10 Time variation in the drift induces long-run risk in consumption and investment. Therefore, we assume that the representative agent has Epstein-Zin preferences to ensure that sectoral long-run risk is priced in equilibrium. We also differ from Papanikolaou (211) with respect to investment-specific shocks: we consider LR shocks to the TFP process of the investment sector while Papanikolaou (211) considers MEI shocks. Segal (215) focuses on shocks to the conditional volatility of the investment sector TFP, while we analyze shocks to its conditional mean growth rate. Solutions for the co-movement problem have been proposed in the literature recently. Khan and Tsoukalas (211) show that the co-movement problem can be solved when the depreciation rate of capital is a convex function of its utilization or when the households preferences are such that there is no wealth effect of labor. 2 Furlanetto and Seneca (214a,b) solve the co-movement problem using a Calvo-style mechanism of price and wage rigidities, respectively. Similarly to Furlanetto and Seneca (214a,b), we also use wage rigidities to induce the right co-movement between macroeconomic variables, but differently from them we use wage rigidities as proposed by Uhlig (27). More technically, the presence of the LR components in sectoral TFP processes creates long-run consumption and investment risk that are both priced in our economy because the representative agent has Epstein-Zin preferences. In our framework, the SR and LR components of sectoral TFP processes are exogenous quantities that drive the dynamics of all endogenous variables (consumption, output, investment, and labor). Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer (21) take a different perspective and analyze the conditions under which 2 More precisely, Khan and Tsoukalas (211) assume that the representative agent features habit formation in consumption as in Jaimovich and Rebelo (29). They eliminate the wealth effect of labor by assuming that consumption habits depend on past consumption only, but not on current consumption. 1

11 long-run risk arises endogenously in a one-sector production economy with Epstein-Zin preferences. They show that the consumption-savings decisions of households endogenously produces long-run risk in consumption even when the (log of) TFP follows a random walk. Besides the main research question we also differ from Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer (21) with respect to the model characteristics. They consider a one-sector model where production depends on capital only. Differently, we build a two-sector model where production depends on both capital and labor. Thus, our equilibrium dynamics are also affected by the households labor choice and by the interactions between the two sectors. At the moment, there is no clear consensus in the literature concerning the implications of investment-specific shocks for the cross section of stock returns. Papanikolaou (211) and Kogan and Papanikolaou (213) find that investment-specific shocks are negatively priced in the cross section of stock returns. Differently, Li (214) and Segal (215) argue in favor of a positive market price of risk. Garlappi and Song (216a) suggest potential measurement problems in the existing proxies of investment specific shocks that might contribute to these mixed results. With respect to this literature we show both theoretically and empirically that LR investment shocks command a positive risk premium and we use the different TFP components themselves in the empirical tests, instead of other proxy variables. In summary, we contribute to these strands of literature by showing that a new, previously disregarded source of investment-specific technical change, namely LR investment risk, has important implications for asset prices and macroeconomic fluctuations. 11

12 3 The Model In the following subsections, we develop a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with two sectors that allows us to study the asset pricing implications of various shocks to investment good productivity and efficiency. The first sector is the consumption good sector. It admits a standard competitive representative firm that uses capital and labor to produce consumption goods which are supplied to the representative household for consumption. The second sector is the investment good sector that uses labor to produce investment goods which are then sold to the consumption good sector and used in the production of the consumption good. The representative household owns both sectors, has recursive preferences over consumption and leisure, and it freely allocates labor to the two sectors. The wage is subject to frictions in the form of sticky wages. The production technologies in both sectors are subject to both SR and LR productivity shocks. A summary of the equilibrium conditions and details about the solution of the model are provided in Appendix A. 3.1 Representative household Because we want to focus on the trade-off between short-run and long-run shocks, we assume that the representative agent has recursive preferences of the Epstein and Zin (1989) type: U t = [ (1 β)v 1 1 ψ t + β ( E t [ U 1 γ t+1 ] ]) 1 1/ψ 1 1 1/ψ 1 γ, (1) where γ denotes the relative risk aversion (RRA), ψ measures the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS), and β (, 1) is the household s time discount factor. Note that this preference specification allows to separate the relative risk aversion from the elasticity 12

13 of intertemporal substitution. The utility flow v t is a Cobb-Douglas index of aggregate consumption C t and leisure L L t : v t := v(c t, L t ) = C ν t ( AC,t ( L L t ) ) 1 ν, where ν (, 1) reflects preferences for consumption versus leisure. A C,t (to be defined later) is the productivity of the consumption good sector and can be interpreted as the household s standard of living in the spirit of Croce (214). 3 In each period, the representative household chooses consumption C t and labor L t to maximize (1) subject to the following budget constraint: C t + B t+1 + ϑ C,t+1 (V C,t D C,t ) + ϑ I,t+1 (V I,t D I,t ) = W u t L t + B t R f t + ϑ C,t V C,t + ϑ I,t V I,t, (2) where ϑ C,t (ϑ I,t ) denotes equity shares held from time t 1 to time t in the representative firm producing the consumption (investment) good. V C,t (V I,t ) and D C,t (D I,t ) is the cum-dividend market value and the dividend of the firm producing the consumption (investment) good. B t denotes bond holdings from time t 1 to time t, R f t is the gross risk-free rate, and W u t represents the frictionless wage. Hence, the household chooses the amount of hours allocated to labor as if the wage was not sticky (wage rigidities are introduced later in Section 3.4). The first-order conditions of the maximization problem lead to the following expression for the stochastic discount factor (SDF): M t,t+1 = β ( Ct+1 C t ) 1 ( vt+1 v t ) ( 1 1 ψ U t+1 (E t [U 1 γ t+1 ]) 1 1 γ ) 1 ψ γ. (3) 3 Multiplying leisure by productivity in the utility flow also guarantees balanced growth. Defining the utility flow alternatively as either C t ( L L t ) ν or C ν t (A C,t 1 ( L L t )) 1 ν does not change the predictions of the model qualitatively, and the quantitative changes to the model-implied moments are relatively small. These results are available upon request. 13

14 The usual Euler equations of cum-dividend asset prices can be written as: V C,t = D C,t + E t [M t,t+1 V C,t+1 ], V I,t = D I,t + E t [M t,t+1 V I,t+1 ], 1 R f t = E t [M t,t+1 ]. Finally, the household s optimal labor allocation leads to the following condition: W u t = 1 ν ν C t L L t. 3.2 Consumption goods sector The consumption goods sector admits a representative perfectly competitive firm utilizing capital and labor to produce the consumption goods. The production technology is given by: Y C,t = K α C C,t (A C,tL C,t ) 1 α C, where α C is the capital share, labor L C,t is supplied by the household, and A C,t is the exogenous labor-augmenting productivity. We assume that A C,t is subject to both shortrun and long-run shocks: A C,t = e a C,t, a C,t = µ C + x C,t 1 + a C,t 1 + σ C ε C,t, x C,t = ρ C x C,t 1 + σ x,c ε x,c,t. The unconditional expected growth rate of productivity is µ C. Short-run productivity shocks are induced by ε C,t, whereas ε x,c,t indicates long-run shocks which affect the stochastic component in expected productivity growth x C,t. The persistence of long-run productivity shocks is measured by ρ C. Moreover, capital K C,t accumulates according to: 14

15 K C,t+1 = (1 δ K )K C,t + G (i C,t ) K C,t. (4) Here, i C,t = I C,t K C,t, and δ K is the depreciation rate of capital. The function G captures adjustment costs of investments as in Jermann (1998): G t := G (i C,t ) = α τ (i C,t ) 1 1 τ + α2, where the constants α 1 and α 2 are chosen such that there are no adjustment costs in the deterministic steady state. The net profit of the consumption goods sector D C,t is given by output minus the expenditure on investment goods and wages: D C,t = Y C,t P I,t I C,t W t L C,t. (5) The representative firm chooses labor, capital, and investment to maximize its value, i.e., the firm solves: V C, = max {K C,t+1,I C,t,L C,t } t= t= t= E [M,t D C,t ], (6) subject to the capital accumulation constraint (4). The first-order condition with respect to K C,t+1, [ ( )] 1 1 = E αc Y C,t+1 P I,t+1 I C,t+1 t Mt,t+1 + λ t+1 (G t δ K ), (7) λ t K C,t+1 determines the price of the investment good P I,t. The Lagrange multiplier attached to the capital accumulation constraint λ t is pinned down by the first-order condition with 15

16 respect to investment: λ t = P I,t, (8) G t where G t is the derivative of G t with respect to the investment-to-capital ratio i C,t. Finally, the first-order condition with respect to labor L C,t implies the following condition that determines the wage W t : W t L C,t = (1 α C )Y C,t. (9) 3.3 Investment goods sector The investment goods sector supplies investment goods to the consumption goods sector. It is populated by a representative firm that sells the demanded goods at the price P I,t. Investment goods are produced according to the technology: Y I,t = A I,t L 1 α I I,t, where L I,t is labor supplied by the household, 1 α I is the labor share, and A I,t is the stochastic total factor productivity of the investment goods sector, whose dynamics are given by the following process: A I,t = e a I,t, a I,t = µ I + x I,t 1 + a I,t 1 + σ I ε I,t, x I,t = ρ I x I,t 1 + σ x,i ε x,i,t. Thus, as in the consumption goods sector, the productivity of the investment goods sector is subject to both short-run (ε I,t ) and long-run (ε x,i,t ) shocks. The unconditional expected growth rate of investment goods sector s productivity is denoted by µ I, and ρ I denotes the persistence of long-run investment shocks. In Section 5.1 we provide empirical evi- 16

17 dence for the presence of LR components in the TFP processes of the consumption and investment sector. The LR component in the productivity of investments also captures the idea of investment hysteresis originally proposed by Dixit (1992). Classic theory postulates that firms should invest (or enter the market) when the price exceeds the average variable costs and disinvest (or exit the market) when the price falls below the average variable costs. However, empirical evidence indicates that, once firms have invested in a project, they tend to stay in business and continue their investment even when the underlying causes of investment are fully reversed. 4 This suggests that investment drivers may have long-lasting effects that, in our model, are captured by time variation in x I,t. The investment goods sector pays wages to the household and its total output Y I,t is sold to the consumption goods sector at the price P I,t. The net profit of the investment goods sector is therefore given by: D I,t = P I,t Y I,t W t L I,t. (1) The investment goods sector firm chooses labor L I,t to maximize the firm value: V I, = max {L I,t } t= t= { t= E [M,t D I,t ] The first-order condition with respect to labor L I,t is given by: }. (11) W t L I,t = (1 α I )P I,t Y I,t. (12) 4 The empirical evidence on investment hysteresis is still fragmented. A review of sectoral and experimental evidence on this topic can be found in Kogut and Chang (1996) and Bragger, Bragger, Hantula, and Kirnan (23). A deep economic motivation for a delayed exit strategy is provided by Bernanke (1983). Further theoretical studies that point to the importance of long-term trends in investment dynamics are provided by Dixit (1989), Bar-Ilan and Strange (1996), Bar-Ilan and Strange (1999), and Kogan (21). 17

18 3.4 Labor market frictions We assume that the labor supply is subject to frictions. In the spirit of Blanchard and Galí (27) and Uhlig (27), we impose that a fraction of the labor supply does not reach the market. As shown by Uhlig (27), this results in sticky wages, i.e., households wages are given by: W t = ( ) ξ A C,t 1 W t 1 (Wt u ) 1 ξ, A C,t 2 where W u t represents the frictionless wage. The intuition is that the household chooses labor hours as if there were no labor market frictions. Hence, W u t appears in the household budget constraint (2). However, the actual salary paid to households is W t, which therefore appears in the definition of firm s dividends (5), (1), and (14). The term A C,t 1 /A C,t 2 captures the fact that the wage is indexed to aggregate productivity if it cannot be chosen optimally. The parameter ξ controls the degree of wage rigidities. In particular, ξ = implies the absence of labor market rigidities. 3.5 Market clearing conditions and aggregate dividends The household supplies labor to the consumption and the investment goods sector. Thus, market clearing in the labor market dictates: L t = L C,t + L I,t. Equating the supply and demand for investment goods implies: I C,t = Y I,t. (13) 18

19 The output of the consumption goods sector is fully consumed by the household and therefore the consumption good market clears when: C t = Y C,t = W t L t + D M,t = W t L t + D C,t + D I,t. (14) The second equality is obtained by assuming that i) bonds are in zero net supply and the stocks of the consumption and the investment goods sector firms are in unit net supply (i.e., B t and ϑ C,t ϑ I,t 1), and ii) households receive the actual wage W t in exchange for their labor supply and not the frictionless wage W u t. The aggregate ( market ) dividends, D M,t = D C,t +D I,t, are given by the sum of the dividends distributed by the consumption and the investment goods sector. The market value at time, which defines the aggregate equity premium in our economy, is consequently given by: V M, = t= E [M,t D M,t ]. 3.6 Stochastic marginal efficiency of investment Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (21) and Papanikolaou (211) introduce a stochastic marginal efficiency of investment (MEI) in order to explain macroeconomic fluctuations and the main features of asset prices. To highlight the different implications of MEI shocks and LR investment shocks, we therefore also analyze an augmented economy with stochastic MEI. This comparison helps us to assess how our model with LR investment specific shocks performs relative to Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (21) and Papanikolaou (211). In the augmented economy, the marginal efficiency of investment goods is governed by 19

20 the stochastic process Z M,t. In order to increase the future capital stock by an absolute amount G(i c,t )K C,t, the representative firm needs to buy Z 1 M,t I C,t units of the investment good (and not I C,t as in our benchmark economy) at the relative price P I,t. Therefore, the total investment cost is given by Z 1 M,t I C,tP I,t. The log marginal efficiency of investment goods is stochastic and follows a strictly stationary AR(1) process: log(z M,t ) = ρ M log(z M,t 1 ) + σ M ε M,t. When the marginal efficiency of investment is stochastic some equations of our benchmark economy need to be changed. First, the net profit of the consumption goods sector D C,t is now given by: D C,t = Y C,t Z 1 M,t P I,tI C,t W t L C,t, (15) rather than by Equation (5). Correspondingly, the consumption goods firm s first-order condition with respect to capital (7) is replaced by: [ ( 1 1 = E t M αc Y C,t+1 Z 1 M,t+1 P )] I,t+1I C,t+1 t,t+1 + λ t+1 (G t δ K ), λ t K C,t+1 and the consumption goods firm s first-order condition with respect to investment, i.e., Equation (8), needs to be replaced by: λ t = Z 1 M,t P I,t G t. (16) Finally, the market clearing condition of the investment market (13) becomes: Z 1 M,t I C,t = Y I,t. 2

21 4 Quantitative Analysis We calibrate the model at quarterly frequency, consistent with the frequency of available data on sectoral output that we use to validate the empirical predictions of our model in Section 5. Our benchmark economy features SR and LR TFP shocks only, but no MEI shocks. We analyze the role of MEI shocks in the augmented economy in Section Calibration Our calibration is summarized in Table 1. The preference parameters are set in accordance with the long-run risk literature. The subjective discount factor β is set to.993 to help the model match the relatively low level of the risk-free rate observed in the data. We set the coefficients of relative risk aversion and elasticity of intertemporal substitution to values of 1 and 2, respectively. Similar values can be found in Bansal and Yaron (24), Croce (214), and Kung and Schmid (215). Note that γ > 1/ψ, i.e. our representative agent has a preference for early resolution of uncertainty, which is also in line with the recent experimental evidence of Brown and Kim (214). Following standard practice, the consumption share in the utility bundle ν is chosen such that the steady state supply of labor is one third of the total time endowment of the household. Given the other parameters, this is achieved by setting ν = The parameters of the sectoral TFP processes are selected to match as closely as possible the moments of asset prices and macroeconomic quantities as well as the empirical estimates of Section 5.1. µ C and µ I are such that the average annual growth rate of output is around.2, consistent with US data. We fix the persistence of sectoral LR components (i.e., ρ C,t and ρ I,t ) at.95 which corresponds to an annualized persistence of.8. This 21

22 Table 1: Quarterly benchmark calibration Parameter Description Source Value Preference parameters β Subjective discount factor γ Risk aversion 2 1 ψ Elasticity of intertemporal substitution 2 2 ν Consumption share in utility bundle Consumption goods sector Technology parameters α C Capital share in consumption good production 1.3 δ K Depreciation rate of physical capital 1.2 τ Elasticity of adjustment costs in investment 4.98 TFP parameters µ C Long-run mean of consumption goods sector TFP 2.18/4 σ C Volatility of short-run shocks to consumption goods sector TFP ε C 4.32/ 4 ρ C Autocorrelation of long-run shocks to consumption goods sector TFP x C 4.95 σ x,c Volatility of long-run shocks to consumption goods sector TFP ε x,c σ C Investment goods sector Technology parameters α I One minus the labor share in investment good production 1.1 TFP parameters µ I Long-run mean of investment goods sector TFP 2.18/4 σ I Volatility of short-run shocks to investment goods sector TFP ε I 4.32/ 4 ρ I Autocorrelation of long-run shocks to investment goods sector TFP x I 4.95 σ x,i Volatility of long-run shocks to investment goods sector TFP ε x,i σ I Labor market ξ Wage rigidities parameter 3.35 Notes: Parameters sources: 1=Papanikolaou (211), 2=Croce (214), 3=Uhlig (27), 4=own calibration. is also in line with Croce (214). Our empirical estimates and the previous literature (Croce, 214) suggest that the volatility of the LR shocks is a small percentage of the volatility of the SR shocks. Thus, we impose σ x,c =.1125 σ C and σ x,i =.1125 σ I. Finally, we set σ C = σ I =.32/ 4 to match the annualized volatility of output growth in the US for the period (i.e., 3.24 percentage points). The depreciation rate of physical capital in the consumption goods sector is standard and set to.2, similarly to Papanikolaou (211). On the production side, also in line with Papanikolaou (211), we set the capital share in consumption goods production α C equal to.3. The labor share in investment goods production, i.e., 1 α I, is equal to.9. 22

23 The elasticity of the supply curve of capital τ is equal to.98, a value in line with existing empirical evidence. 5 Finally, following Uhlig (27), we assume a moderate degree of wage stickiness by imposing ξ =.35 in the benchmark case. We also present robustness checks where we vary the parameter ξ. The model is solved in dynare using a second-order approximation. 4.2 Macro quantities and asset prices Table 2 reports key unconditional moments of macroeconomic and asset pricing quantities, obtained from model simulations. We consider several sub-cases that allow us to highlight the role played by sectoral SR and LR shocks. In column [1] we report the main features of an economy without long-run risk. Then, we introduce long-run risk in the consumption sector only (column [2]), and finally we allow for long-run risk in both the consumption and the investment sector (column [3]). In all of these cases, we assume the absence of wage rigidities. In the absence of long-run risk the model has difficulties in matching the basic properties of stock returns, most importantly the equity premium. The model reproduces the positive co-movement between consumption and output, but fails on all the other macroeconomic co-movements. Introducing long-run risk in the consumption sector (column [2]) makes this sector relatively riskier (as compared to the case of no long-run risk), which leads to a substantial increase in the risk premium required to hold the consumption sector equity. As a result, the market equity premium increases from 1.2 to 3.69 percentage points. However, longrun risk in the consumption sector produces even more counterfactual results for the 5 Eberly (1997), for instance, reports estimates that range between 1.8 and In an earlier empirical work, Abel (198) reports values for τ between.5 and

24 co-movement of consumption and investment and the co-movement of consumption and labor, as those numbers turn negative in column [2]. Introducing long-run risk in the investment sector (column [3]) further improves asset pricing quantities, especially the stock return volatility of the investment sector and the return differential between the two sectors. More precisely, the volatility spread between the investment and the consumption sector increases from 1.21 to 4.25 percentage points and gets closer to the value observed in the data (1.96 percentage points). Nevertheless, the risk premium of the consumption sector is higher than that of the investment sector. This can be explained by differences in the cyclical variation between the two sectors: due to adjustment costs, consumption is much more pro-cyclical than investments, i.e. corr( c, y) > corr( i, y). Therefore, the consumption sector equity exhibits more systematic risk and earns a higher risk premium in equilibrium. The correlations among macroeconomic variables remain basically unaffected, in particular the correlation between consumption and investment and the correlation between consumption and labor remain slightly negative. This means that LR investment risk improves the model s ability to fit sectoral stock returns but to explain the unconditional correlations among macroeconomic variable we need an additional ingredient, namely wage rigidities. Columns [4], [5], and [6] report results for the economy with long-run risk in both sectors and progressively higher degrees of wage rigidities, where column [5] refers to our benchmark economy with ξ =.35. The introduction of wage rigidities solves the comovement problem and the unconditional correlations between consumption and investment and between consumption and labor switch sign and turn positive. Wage rigidities also have implications for asset prices. They prevent wages from perfectly adjusting to TFP changes and thus impair the ability of firms to react to macroeconomic shocks. As 24

25 a result, firms equity becomes riskier. The equity volatility increases and households require a higher risk premium to hold stocks in equilibrium. Table 2: Model versus Data: Macroeconomic Quantities and Asset Prices The Role of LRR The Role of Wage Rigidities Model Data [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] ASSET PRICES E[R M R f ] σ[r M R f ] E[R f ] σ[r f ] E[R I R C ] σ[r I ] σ[r C ] MACRO QUANTITIES σ( y) σ( y)/σ( c) σ( i)/σ( y) σ( l)/σ( y) σ( l) ρ( c, y) ρ( c, i) ρ( c, l) ρ( i, l) ρ( i, y) Notes: This table reports the main annual moments for the benchmark calibration ([5]) and five other model specifications. Means and volatilities are reported in percentage points. Model 1: No LRR in either sector (i.e., σ x,c = σ x,i = ) and no wage rigidities (i.e., ξ = ). Model 2: LRR in the consumption sector only (i.e., σ x,c >, σ x,i = ) and no wage rigidities (i.e., ξ = ). Model 3: LRR in both sectors (i.e., σ x,c >, σ x,i > ) and no wage rigidities (i.e., ξ = ). Models 4, 5, and 6: LRR in both sectors (i.e., σ x,c >, σ x,i > ) and different degrees of wage rigidities (ξ =.1, ξ =.35, and ξ =.5, respectively). The entries for the models are obtained by repetitions of small-sample simulations. All empirical moments are from Papanikolaou (211) for the time period Overall, our model is able to produce realistic moments for both macroeconomic and asset pricing quantities. Our benchmark calibration produces an equity premium of 3.97 percentage points and a low and stable risk-free rate (2.2 percentage points with a volatility of 1.5 percentage points). The model also succeeds in generating the average return spread between the investment and consumption sector (-1.44 percentage points vs percentage points in the data). Admittedly, like most DSGE models, our models encounters some difficulties in generating high stock return volatilities. Nevertheless, 25

26 our model generates the right sign for the volatility spread between the investment and consumption sector equity, and this spread is much larger than in any of the cases without LR investment shocks (see also Table 3 below). 6 The standard deviation of output growth is exactly as in US macroeconomic data. In addition, the relative standard deviations of consumption, investment, and labor to output are not far from their empirical counterparts. Finally, the model-implied correlations among macroeconomic variables are positive, ranging from.3 to.99, and are all close to the values in the data. 4.3 Impulse response analysis Figure 1 depicts the theoretical impulse response functions. 7 Our model features four types of shocks, and the four shocks contribute to the macroeconomic co-movement in different ways. It is instructive to start looking at the two investment-specific shocks. After a positive SR investment shock, the investment sector becomes relatively more profitable immedi- 6 The very recent asset pricing literature shows promising new economic channels which enable DSGE models to produce reasonable levels of return volatility. For instance, Nezafat and Slavík (215) develop a rich model that generates a sizeable stock market volatility through financial shocks affecting the tightness of firms financing constraints. Croce (214) obtains a volatility of about 11 percentage points by assuming a high persistence of long-run productivity shocks (.95 annually). Favilukis and Lin (216) obtain values of similar magnitude with stochastic firm leverage and labor rigidities in the form of infrequent renegotiation of wages. The model of Papanikolaou (211) generates high values of the stock market volatility when the volatility of shocks to the marginal efficiency of investments is set to 13.5 percentage points or the volatility of investment productivity shocks is set to 2 percentage points, but the volatility spread between the investment and consumption sectors is very similar to what we report in Table 2. 7 The impulse response functions are computed in dynare by perturbing the equilibrium system around the steady state. An alternative way to study the theoretical responses of equilibrium variables is to compute population impulse response functions (Carlstrom, Fuerst, and Paustian (29) and Hussain and Liu (216)) obtained by applying a VAR on model generated data. As the results from both approaches are similar, we discuss the impulse-response functions from perturbation here only. The results for the simulated VAR obtained from a long sample of model generated data are reported in Appendix B. Since we have long-run consumption and investment shocks in our model, using a number of short samples of model generated data (equal to the length of the empirical data) to estimate the VAR can be problematic (see, for instance, Colacito and Croce, 211). Therefore, we do not follow this approach. 26

27 ately. Households, thus, find it optimal to increase investment immediately. Consumption also increases slightly in the period of the shock, and it continues to fluctuate until period 5, whereas investment reverts to the steady state already in period 2. This diverging behavior of consumption and investment after period 1 in response to SR investment shocks causes negative conditional co-movement. To ensure that the consumption stream remains smooth over time, households decrease labor today and then gradually readjust their labor supply toward the steady state. SR investment shocks also have a negative initial impact on total output Y t = C t + P I,t I C,t. Given that consumption and investment both increase initially after the shock, the drop in output is fully explained by the decline in the price of investment goods. After a positive LR investment shock, the expected future profitability of the investment sector increases and households decide to invest more today and in the following periods. At the same time, households perceive themselves to be richer and want to increase current consumption. However, contrary to the reaction to short-run shocks, since the positive effect of LR investment shocks will materialize only over time, households have to finance their desired level of consumption by working more today. This increase in labor supply stimulates the total output of the economy. In summary, SR and LR investment shocks have different implications for the comovement of macroeconomic quantities. SR investment shocks affect the current profitability of the investment sector and generate a substitution effect that is the source of the negative co-movement among macroeconomic variables. Differently, LR investment shocks affect the future profitability of the investment sector and generate a positive wealth effect that induces positive co-movement among macroeconomic variables. The other two sources of variation have been studied extensively in the literature, and 27

28 our results basically replicate the ones by Croce (214). After a positive shock to the SR component of consumption TFP, households find it optimal to increase consumption, investment, and labor simultaneously. As a result, total output also increases. Shortrun consumption TFP shocks thus induce positive macroeconomic co-movement. The responses to LR shocks are slightly different and depend on the relation between the substitution effect and the wealth effect, which itself depends mainly on the IES. After a positive shock to the long-run consumption TFP, the continuation value of utility increases. In our parametrization, the IES is larger than one. Therefore, the substitution effect dominates the wealth effect, current consumption and continuation utility are substitutes, and households find it optimal to decrease consumption today and invest instead. However, consumption growth decreases only by a small amount and increases again after one quarter. The unconditional correlations among macroeconomic quantities result from the interaction of all four types of shocks described above. Since the positive co-movement induced by SR consumption shocks and LR investment shocks is quantitatively smaller than the negative co-movement induced by the other shocks (SR investment shocks and LR consumption shocks), the unconditional correlations between consumption and investment and between consumption and labor remain slightly negative unless we introduce wage rigidities. So, how do wage rigidities help reproducing the positive correlation between consumption and investment and between consumption and labor? As one can see from Figure 1, where the solid lines refer to the case with wage rigidities and the dotted lines to the case without them, the main effect comes from SR consumption TFP shocks. After such a shock, firms find it optimal to increase their labor demand. When the labor market is fully flexible this leads to an increase in wages that almost completely offsets 28

29 the incentive of firms to hire more workers. With wage rigidities, firms face an increase in the labor demand and a relatively smaller increase in salary, which increases the desire of firms to hire more workers. As a result, in the economy with wage rigidities the positive responses of labor, investment, and consumption with respect to SR shocks to the TFP process of the consumption sector are amplified as compared to an economy with fully flexible wages. In other words, with wage rigidities the negative co-movement between macroeconomic variables induced by SR shocks to the TFP of the investment sector is overcompensated by the positive co-movement resulting from SR shocks to the TFP of the consumption sector, and the overall correlation among key macroeconomic variables turns positive. 29

30 Figure 1: Impulse response functions Consumption Sector (SRR) Consumption Sector (LRR) Investment Sector (SRR) x Investment Sector (LRR) c x y i x l m Notes: This figure depicts the impulse-response functions for a length of 2 quarters of log consumption growth c, log output growth y, log investment growth i, log labor growth l, and log stochastic discount factor m. Impulse-response functions with respect to i) a positive one-standard deviation SR shock to the consumption sector TFP (ɛc), ii) a positive one-standard-deviation LR shock to consumption sector TFP (ɛx,c), iii) a positive one-standard deviation SR shock to investment sector TFP (ɛi) and iv) a positive one-standard-deviation LR shock to investment sector TFP (i.e., ɛx,i) are depicted in columns 1, 2, 3, and 4, respectively. The solid black line refers to the case with wage rigidities (ξ =.35) while the dotted blue line refers to the case with the absence of wage rigidities (ξ = ). The values reported are deviations from the steady state in percentage points. 3

31 4.4 Stochastic marginal efficiency of investment We argue that shocks to the TFP process of the investment sector are an alternative way to capture time variation in real investment opportunities. Thus, at this point it is instructive to compare the implications of SR and LR investment shocks with those of more established MEI shocks. In this section, we analyze an augmented economy that features MEI shocks in addition to SR and LR shocks to the TFP processes of consumption and investment sectors. The parameters related to the marginal efficiency of investment are calibrated following the recent literature. We fix σ M to an annualized value of.12 which is within the confidence intervals estimated by Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (21). Moreover, we assume that the persistence of MEI shocks equals the persistence of the LR components of the sectoral TFP processes and therefore set ρ M =.95, similarly to Furlanetto and Seneca (214b). In Table 3, we compare our benchmark economy that features only SR and LR shocks in the sectoral TFP processes (column [1]) with an economy that features also MEI shocks in addition to sectoral SR and LR shocks (column [2]). MEI shocks decrease the correlation among key macroeconomic variables: the correlation between consumption and investment decreases from.3 to.1 (vs..39 in the data), the correlation between investment and labor decreases from.53 to.16 (vs..83 in the data) and the correlation between investment and output decreases from.36 to.1 (vs..67 in the data). The reasons for these results are illustrated in Figure 2 which depicts the impulse responses to MEI shocks. One can see that MEI shocks induce a negative co-movement between consumption, output, and labor. Actually, the impulse responses are similar to the impulse responses to short-run investment shocks depicted in Figure 1. This result suggests that MEI shocks and SR investment shocks have similar implications for the co-movement 31

Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel

Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel 1 Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel Robert Kollmann Université Libre de Bruxelles & CEPR World business cycle : High cross-country

More information

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

Volatility Risk Pass-Through Volatility Risk Pass-Through Ric Colacito Max Croce Yang Liu Ivan Shaliastovich 1 / 18 Main Question Uncertainty in a one-country setting: Sizeable impact of volatility risks on growth and asset prices

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns and Monetary Policy

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns and Monetary Policy Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns and Monetary Policy Erica X.N. Li and Francisco Palomino May 212 Abstract We analyze the asset pricing implications of price and wage rigidities and monetary policies

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

More information

Monetary Policy and the Great Recession

Monetary Policy and the Great Recession Monetary Policy and the Great Recession Author: Brent Bundick Persistent link: http://hdl.handle.net/2345/379 This work is posted on escholarship@bc, Boston College University Libraries. Boston College

More information

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns, and Monetary Policy

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns, and Monetary Policy Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns, and Monetary Policy Erica X.N. Li and Francisco Palomino June 30, 2013 Abstract We analyze the asset pricing implications of price and wage rigidities and monetary policies

More information

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Conférence organisée par la Chaire des Amériques et le Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne, Université Paris I Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles Sarquis J. B. Sarquis

More information

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco John Taylor s Contributions to Monetary Theory and Policy Federal

More information

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Alexandre Dmitriev University of New South Wales Ivan Roberts Reserve Bank of Australia and University of New South Wales February 2, 2011 Abstract Two-country,

More information

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy Iklaga, Fred Ogli University of Surrey f.iklaga@surrey.ac.uk Presented at the 33rd USAEE/IAEE North American Conference, October 25-28,

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns, and Monetary Policy

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns, and Monetary Policy Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns, and Monetary Policy Erica X.N. Li and Francisco Palomino June 16, 2014 Abstract Asset-return implications of nominal price and wage rigidities are analyzed in general

More information

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853 yw57@cornell.edu Abstract

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility Comment Martín Uribe, Columbia University and NBER This paper represents the latest installment in a highly influential series of papers in which Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier shed light on the empirics

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

Toward a Quantitative General Equilibrium Asset Pricing Model with Intangible Capital

Toward a Quantitative General Equilibrium Asset Pricing Model with Intangible Capital Toward a Quantitative General Equilibrium Asset Pricing Model with Intangible Capital PRELIMINARY Hengjie Ai, Mariano Massimiliano Croce and Kai Li 1 January 2010 Abstract In the US, the size of intangible

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand Susanto Basu Boston College NBER Brent Bundick Boston College Preliminary Can Higher Uncertainty Reduce Overall Economic Activity? Many think it is an

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial

More information

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Takashi Kano Hitotsubashi University @HIAS, IER, AJRC Joint Workshop Frontiers in Macroeconomics and Macroeconometrics November 3-4, 2017

More information

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences p. 1/3 International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences Riccardo Colacito Prepared for Tom Sargent s PhD class (Part 1) Roadmap p. 2/3 Today International asset pricing (exchange

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Leisure Preferences, Long-Run Risks, and Human Capital Returns

Leisure Preferences, Long-Run Risks, and Human Capital Returns Leisure Preferences, Long-Run Risks, and Human Capital Returns Robert F. Dittmar Francisco Palomino Wei Yang February 7, 2014 Abstract We analyze the contribution of leisure preferences to a model of long-run

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory

Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory Ric Colacito, Eric Ghysels, Jinghan Meng, and Wasin Siwasarit 1 / 26 Introduction Long-Run Risks Model:

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Oil Volatility Risk. Lin Gao, Steffen Hitzemann, Ivan Shaliastovich, and Lai Xu. Preliminary Draft. December Abstract

Oil Volatility Risk. Lin Gao, Steffen Hitzemann, Ivan Shaliastovich, and Lai Xu. Preliminary Draft. December Abstract Oil Volatility Risk Lin Gao, Steffen Hitzemann, Ivan Shaliastovich, and Lai Xu Preliminary Draft December 2015 Abstract In the data, an increase in oil price volatility dampens current and future output,

More information

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence Insu Kim University of California, Riverside October 29 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/18345/ MPRA Paper No.

More information

Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy

Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy R. Colacito M.M. Croce F. Gavazzoni R. Ready NBER SI - International Asset Pricing Boston July 8, 2015 Motivation The literature has identified

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44 TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Marija Vukotić Banque de France NBS, April 27, 2012 NBS, April 27, 2012 1 / 44 Motivation 1 Well Known Facts about the

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money

More information

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Proceedings of 3th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Introduction Miroslav Hloušek Abstract. Czech data shows positive

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Georg Kaltenbrunner and Lars Lochstoer yz First draft: 31 May 2006. COMMENTS WELCOME! October 2, 2006 Abstract Whenever agents have access to a production technology

More information

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle Nir Jaimovich and Sergio Rebelo September 2006 Abstract We explore the business cycle implications of expectation shocks and of two well-known psychological biases,

More information

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Virginia Olivella and Jose Ignacio Lopez October 2008 Motivation Menu costs and repricing decisions Micro foundation of sticky

More information

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern. , JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 13, 2009 Outline 1 Motivation Production-Based Asset Pricing Framework 2 Assumptions Firm s Problem Equilibrium 3 Main Findings Mechanism Testable

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Long-Run Productivity Risk: A New Hope for Production-Based Asset Pricing

Long-Run Productivity Risk: A New Hope for Production-Based Asset Pricing Long-Run Productivity Risk: A New Hope for Production-Based Asset Pricing Mariano Massimiliano Croce Abstract This study examines the intertemporal distribution of productivity risk. Focusing on post-war

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy Yusuf Soner Başkaya Timur Hülagü Hande Küçük 6 April 212 Oil price volatility is high and it varies over time... 15 1 5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (a) Mean.4.35.3.25.2.15.1.5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (b) Coefficient

More information

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Jerry Tsai University of Oxford Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 12, 2014 and NBER A The iid model This section

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate

Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate Riccardo Colacito - NYU and UNC Kenan-Flagler Mariano M. Croce - NYU Risks for the Long Run and the Real Exchange Rate, UCLA, 2.22.06 p. 1/29 Set the stage

More information

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Michael Reiter 1 Leopold Zessner 2 1 Instiute for Advances Studies, Vienna 2 Vienna Graduate School of Economics Barcelona GSE Summer Forum ADEMU,

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting RIETI Discussion Paper Series 9-E-3 The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies NUTAHARA Kengo Senshu

More information

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012 Comment on: Structural and Cyclical Forces in the Labor Market During the Great Recession: Cross-Country Evidence by Luca Sala, Ulf Söderström and Antonella Trigari Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis

More information

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS 1 / 24 EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS WITH FINANCE CONSTRAINTS THROUGH THE LENS OF ASSET PRICING Lars Peter Hansen Benheim Lectures, Princeton University EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS WITH FINANCING CONSTRAINTS

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Giancarlo Corsetti Luca Dedola Sylvain Leduc CREST, May 2008 The International Consumption Correlations Puzzle

More information

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets Andrey Ermolov Columbia Business School April 24, 2014 1 / 41 Stylized Facts about Bond Markets US Fact 1: Upward Sloping Real Yield Curve In US, real long

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Adaptive Beliefs in RBC models

Adaptive Beliefs in RBC models Adaptive Beliefs in RBC models Sijmen Duineveld May 27, 215 Abstract This paper shows that waves of optimism and pessimism decrease volatility in a standard RBC model, but increase volatility in a RBC

More information

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES KRISTOFFER P. NIMARK Lucas Island Model The Lucas Island model appeared in a series of papers in the early 970s

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Risk Aversion Sensitive Real Business Cycles

Risk Aversion Sensitive Real Business Cycles Risk Aversion Sensitive Real Business Cycles Zhanhui Chen NTU Ilan Cooper BI Paul Ehling BI Costas Xiouros BI Current Draft: November 2016 Abstract We study endogenous state-contingent technology choice

More information

Long-Run Risks, the Macroeconomy, and Asset Prices

Long-Run Risks, the Macroeconomy, and Asset Prices Long-Run Risks, the Macroeconomy, and Asset Prices By RAVI BANSAL, DANA KIKU AND AMIR YARON Ravi Bansal and Amir Yaron (2004) developed the Long-Run Risk (LRR) model which emphasizes the role of long-run

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1 Contents Preface xvii 1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1 1.1 Measuring Business Cycles 1 1.2 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 4 1.3 Business Cycles in Poor, Emerging, and Rich Countries 7 1.4

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Christopher J. Erceg and Jesper Lindé Federal Reserve Board October, 2012 Erceg and Lindé (Federal Reserve Board) Fiscal Consolidations

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

Asset Prices and Business Cycles with. Financial Frictions

Asset Prices and Business Cycles with. Financial Frictions Asset Prices and Business Cycles with Financial Frictions Pedram Nezafat Ctirad Slavík November 21, 2009 Job Market Paper Abstract. Existing dynamic general equilibrium models have failed to explain the

More information

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and investment is central to understanding the business

More information

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases Vincent Sterk and Silvana Tenreyro UCL, LSE September 2015 Sterk and Tenreyro (UCL, LSE) OMO September 2015 1 / 28 The

More information

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice for Emerging Market Countries Masato Takahashi Master of Philosophy University of York Department of Economics and Related Studies July 2011 Abstract This thesis includes

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle Theory Paul Scanlon November 29, 2010 1 Introduction The emphasis here is on technology/tfp shocks, and the associated supply-side responses. As the term suggests, all the shocks are

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II Chao Wei Department of Economics George Washington University Washington, DC 20052 January 2007 1 1 Deterministic Dynamic Programming Below I describe a typical dynamic

More information

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks Princeton University Press, 217 Motivation Interest-rate shocks are generally believed to be a major source of fluctuations for emerging countries. The next slide

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Capital Utilization, Market Power, and the Pricing of Investment Shocks

Capital Utilization, Market Power, and the Pricing of Investment Shocks Capital Utilization, Market Power, and the Pricing of Investment Shocks Lorenzo Garlappi University of British Columbia Zhongzhi Song Cheung Kong GSB February 3, 2016 We are grateful to Paul Beaudry, Jules

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Ctirad Slavík, CERGE-EI, Prague (with Hakki Yazici, Sabanci University and Özlem Kina, EUI) January 4, 2019 ASSA in Atlanta 1 / 31 Motivation Optimal

More information

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

1. Money in the utility function (continued) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (continued) a. Welfare costs of in ation b. Potential non-superneutrality

More information