The Economics of Severance Pay

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Economics of Severance Pay"

Transcription

1 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No The Economics of Severance Pay Tito Boeri Pietro Garibaldi Espen Moen June 2013 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

2 The Economics of Severance Pay Tito Boeri Bocconi University and IZA Pietro Garibaldi Collegio Carlo Alberto and IZA Espen Moen Norwegian Business School Discussion Paper No June 2013 IZA P.O. Box Bonn Germany Phone: Fax: Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

3 IZA Discussion Paper No June 2013 ABSTRACT The Economics of Severance Pay All OECD countries have either legally mandated severance pay or compensations imposed by industry-level bargaining in case of employer initiated job separations. According to the extensive literature on Employment Protection Legislation such transfers are either ineffective or highly distortionary. In this paper we show that mandatory severance is optimal in presence of wage deferrals when there is moral hazard of employers and workers, notably when employers cannot commit not to fire a non-shirker and shirkers can also get away with it. Our model also accounts for two neglected features of EPL. The first is that dismissal costs depend not only on whether the dismissal is deemed fair or unfair, but also on the nature, economic vs. disciplinary, of the layoff. The second feature is that compensation for unfair dismissal or severance is generally increasing with tenure. JEL Classification: J63, J65, J33 Keywords: severance, unfair dismissal, graded security Corresponding author: Tito Boeri Department of Economics Università Bocconi Via Roentgen Milano Italy tito.boeri@unibocconi.it

4 Introduction Most OECD countries have legally mandated severance pay in case of employer initiated job separations. Such transfers from the employer to the worker are a very important component of dismissal costs as they account for almost 50% per cent of the cross-country variation in the OECD index of the strictness of employment protection legislation (EPL) for regular workers, the reference measure of EPL in the literature. When rules for compensations to workers are not specified by the law, it is collective bargaining at the industry or national level to mandate severance to individual employers. According to the literature on EPL, severance pay is either neutral with respect to labor market outcomes or it is more distortionary than other institutions in providing insurance against labor market risk. It is neutral when wages are flexible and agents are risk neutral (Lazear, 1990). Under rigid wages, severance pay generates unemployment (Garibaldi and Violante, 2005) operating de facto as a firing tax. With riskaverse employees, severance is less efficient than other institutions such as experience-rated unemployment benefits in providing insurance to workers against the risk of job loss (Blanchard and Tirole, 2008). Why do we need then severance pay? In this paper we show that severance pay is efficient under risk neutrality and flexible (entry) wages, even in presence of unemployment benefits, provided that there are wage deferrals and the worker can decide not to invest in the productivity of the job. Under these conditions, severance deals with the moral hazard problem related to investment in job-specific productivity. The result is general as wage deferrals are a common feature of labor markets: most firms allow for a significant component of remuneration to be postponed for incentive purposes and these tenure-related components of compensation are agreed in advance, conditional on the continuation of a job, but independent of productivity. Our model also allows to explain two neglected features of EPL. The first relates to the role played by the nature of the dismissal. Compensation offered to workers in case of dismissals varies depending on the alleged reasons for the layoff as well as its fairness. Compensation is generally not offered to workers being fired for disciplinary reasons unless a court ruling declares that the dismissal is unfair. When the individual layoff is instead motivated by the economic conditions of the firm, that is, it occurs independently of the behavior of the worker, compensation is typically offered also for fair dismissals, that is, cases where there is no evidence of opportunistic behavior of the employer. In the case of unfair dismissals, however, compensation is often higher than the severance for fair economic dismissals. There are also countries in which compensation is provided only for unfair and fair economic dismissals do not involve mandated severance to the workers. Due to these wide differences in the levels of compensation related to the nature of dismissals, there are strong incentives for the employee or the employer to bring the case before a Court. Involvement of judges in the determination of the level of severance cannot be avoided by state contingent contracts, and could concern not only the fairness of the layoff, but also its nature, economic or disciplinary (let alone discriminatory). Since workers effort and employers investments in the duration of the job are not perfectly observable, the decisions of the judges will tend to be imperfect. Shirkers may receive the compensation offered for unfair disciplinary or economic dismissals, while opportunistic employers claiming that the dismissal is either disciplinary or due to objective economic circumstances may get away without paying the higher severance required for unfair dismissals or not paying severance at all. The stochastic court ruling clearly affects also private settlements out of court, as such settlements will be based on the expected costs had the case gone to court. The second neglected characteristic of EPL is the tenure profile of severance pay. Most countries allow for mandated severance pay to be increasing with tenure. A very few countries provide compensation to workers independently of tenure. We show that these design features are efficient in dealing with moral hazard of workers and employers. Severance is needed as moral hazard of employers prevent them from committing not to fire workers investing in the productivity of the job. At the same time, the stochastic nature of dismissal costs and the distinction between economic and disciplinary dismissals increases the moral hazard problem of workers as they can get away with it even when they shirk. Our model shows under which conditions in terms of productivity, monitoring technologies, jurisprudence, and design of unemployment benefit systems tenure-related severance pay increases productivity, reduces inefficient firing and induces an efficient allocation of labor. In particular, optimal severance is 2

5 according to our model related to the efficiency of the judicial system: the larger the probability that a worker can get away with it, the larger is severance pay. This also rationalizes why small firms are typically exempted from the strictest EPL regulations: it is easier for employers in small firms to prove opportunistic behavior of workers before Courts as they can better monitor and document the effort made by their workers in increasing the productivity of a job. Our results are relevant in evaluating proposals to introduce mandatory compensation increasing steadily with tenure in countries characterized by contractual dualism, that is, the coexistence of a highly protected segment of the workforce and one segregated into temporary jobs providing low, if any, employment protection. The plan of the paper is as follows. Part one discusses the relevance of severance pay and characterizes neglected features of EPL, notably the treatment of fair vs. unfair economic and disciplinary dismissals, and the tenure profile of severance pay. Part two develops a simple two-period model and evaluates optimal severance pay. Part three extends the model to three periods and endogenizes the detection probability. Finally, part four summarizes our key results and discusses their empirical relevance. 1 Why Severance Matters Employment protection legislation is one of the most widely investigated institutions in the labor market 1. The theoretical literature, pioneered by Bentolila and Bertola (1990) and Bertola (1990), typically treats EPL as a firing tax to be paid to a third party by the employer in case of a layoff. Severance pay, that is, a transfer from the employer to the worker contingent on employer initiated separations 2 is generally not framed in these models, as Lazear (1990) neutrality result indicates that, with wage flexibility and risk neutrality, it only affects the tenure profile of wages leaving employment, hiring and separations unaffected. However, severance pay account for a very large share of the costs of dismissals. According to Garibaldi and Violante (2005) who carefully estimate the red tape costs of layoffs in countries like Italy, severance pay accounts for about 2/3 of total dismissal costs. Severance also explains about 50 per cent of the total cross-country variation in the OECD strictness of EPL Severance pay differs from firing taxes in at least two important dimensions. The first is that its amount depends both on the nature disciplinary vs. economic of the dismissal, and on whether it is deemed fair or unfair by a court ruling. This is very important in assessing the incentives associated with the provision of severance pay. The second distinguishing feature of severance pay is that it is generally dependent of tenure, while firing taxes are independent of tenure and are indeed modeled by the literature as a flat payment. 1.1 Stochastic severance The severance pay levels used so far in characterizing the tenure profile of employment protection are those established by the law in case of fair economic individual dismissals. Fairness in the case of economic dismissals refers to the behaviour of the employer: she should have tried as much as possible to avoid this outcome. Although the definition of fair economic dismissal differs quite considerably from country to country, it generally implies that some genuine and serious exogenous shocks in firm s performance require operational changes in the scale, and possibly, nature of the work organization, making the worker involved redundant. Often evidence of economic difficulties or technological change is explicitly required. In the case of disciplinary dismissals, the fairness refers to the behavior of the worker. Fair disciplinary dismissals are those for which there is evidence of misconduct on the part of the worker, where misconduct is often not defined, and the burden of proof typically falls onto the employer. When the economic or disciplinary dismissal is found to be unfair, the employer in some countries is forced to reinstate the worker. Generally the reinstatement does not take place, but the costs of unfair dismissals are significantly higher than those of fair economic dismissals. Moreover, the employer, in addition to providing severance pay, typically has to pay the legal costs of the employee and compensate for the foregone months of pay 1 See Boeri and vanours (2013) [3] for a review of this literature. 2 Our definition of severance clearly does not encompass deferred compensation schemes, such as private pension arrangements, which are paid at retirement or even in case of a voluntary separation of the worker. 3

6 during the legal procedure. The decisions as to the nature of the dismissal (economic vs. disciplinary) and its fairness require some Court ruling. In practice, disputes are mostly settled before the Court ruling, taking in consideration the nature of the dismissal, the probability that is considered fair and the severance and additional compensations envisaged under the different circumstances. Thus, in practice the level of severance ultimately depends on decisions made by third parties having limited information on the behavior of workers and employers. For all of these reasons the actual costs of layoffs are stochastic, and generally dependent on the evidence that the employer can provide for a disciplinary or economic dismissal. The theoretical literature on EPL, recently reviewed by Boeri and vanours [3] generally treats severance as a deterministic transfer from the employer to the employee. In the few cases where stochastic severance is allowed ( Garibaldi [8], Malo [11]), it is modeled more as an option to fire (a firing permission) than as a distribution of alternative costs of dismissals. Moreover, no reference is made by this literature to the moral hazard problem related to the distinction between economic and disciplinary dismissals. Two partial exceptions are Galdon-Sanchez [7] and Boeri [4]. However, Galdon-Sanchez [7] operates on a reduced form model and both Boeri [4] and Galdon-Sanchez [7] do not address the efficiency of severance pay, but only consider its effects on unemployment and the layoff behavior of firms of different size. Uncertainty as to the actual costs of the dismissal is increasing, inter alia, in differences in the level of mandatory compensation required under the three types of dismissals discussed above, that is, fair economic, fair disciplinary, and unfair dismissals. Table 1 displays the maximum compensation required under unfair, fair economic and fair disciplinary dismissals in OECD countries. The table is based on the analysis of the country files used by the OECD in building up the summary measure of strictness of EPL, a report prepared for a European conference of labor lawyers [6] and a study by the ILO [2]. As shown by Table 1, in all countries even fair dismissals command some compensation to the worker, either in terms of strictly severance pay or of a minimum notice period (de facto an extension of pay after the date when the worker is made redundant). The severance for unfair dismissals (first column) is, however, always higher than that provided in case of fair dismissals (second and third columns). One of the reasons why unfair dismissals cost more than fair dismissals is that in several countries (see Table A2 in the Annex), in addition to a monetary compensation, an unfair dismissal may also be sanctioned with the reinstatement of the worker in the ranks of the firm. Thus, in these countries, the costs of unfair dismissals should also include the duration of the trial period, as reinstated workers should be back paid the full wage between the date of the dismissal and that of the Court ruling. An additional compensation should also be considered as the worker and the employer generally agree on a monetary transaction in lieu of an actual reinstatement after the Court ruling. This compensation will be clearly related to the protection provided to job-holders, that is, to the severance in case of unfair dismissals in that specific country. Thus the costs of unfair dismissals in countries with reinstatement include the average length of the trial period (d) plus notice period and actual compensation for unfair dismissal at 20 years as an alternative (C) to the reinstatement itself, multiplied by the likelihood that a reinstatement is actually granted (π), i.e.: T U = S + π(d + S) (1) where T U are the costs of unfair dismissals, and S as usual includes both notice period and actual severance. Moreover, fair economic dismissals generally involve a higher compensation that fair disciplinary dismissals (fourth column displaying the difference between the two). Typically, only a relatively short notice period is required in the case of firm initiated job separations when they are due to workers misconduct. As detailed in Table A2 in the annex, we attribute to π the value obtained by standardizing in the unit interval the 0-3 OECD index on the likelihood of the reinstatement, where clearly 0 means never reinstatement and values close to one denote a frequent reinstatement. Finally, in the fourth and fifth columns of Table 2, we provide a summary measure of dispersion given by the weighted coefficient of variation of the compensation required for economic and disciplinary dismissals. In defining the weights, that is, the probability that a dismissal is ruled as unfair, we consider whether the burden of proof is on the employer or, at least partly, on the worker (see Table A2). In the former case, we arbitrarily assume that the probability, p that a dismissal is ruled as unfair is.5. This probability is arbitrarily reduced to.25 when the burden of proof is on the worker. An intermediate value is taken in the only case (Japan) where the burden of proof may fall either on the worker or the employer. All in all, our measure of uncertainty in the costs of dismissals (CV ) is given 4

7 in each country by CV J = p(t U T ) 2 + (1 p)(t J F T ) 2 where the superscript J denotes either disciplinary (D) or economic (E) dismissals and T is the weighted average of the compensation when the dismissal is considered as unfair (T U ) or fair (TF J ) respectively. The last two columns on the right-hand-side of Table 1 suggest that there is considerable uncertainty as to the actual costs of dismissal: the cross-country average for the coefficients of variation is 1.5 in case of economic dismissals and 1.9 in case of disciplinary dismissals. Moreover, uncertainty increases if the employers takes the route of the disciplinary dismissals, involving in some countries a standard deviation three times as large as the average, than that of economic dismissals. Consistently with these facts, the model developed in the next section will allow for both economic and disciplinary dismissals and address the moral hazard problem related to potential workers misconduct and the nature, economic vs. disciplinary, of the dismissals. We will initially assume that the probability of proving the case before a Court is exogenous and show that in a model with wage deferrals (e.g., related to career concerns), a properly designed severance scheme maximizes the joint surplus from a match. We will also show that, under some configurations of inter-temporal productivity and probability that the dismissal is treated as fair, this optimal severance is increasing with tenure. Later on, we will endogenize the probability that a Court rules in favor of the employer, based on the evidence that can be provided by the firm on the productivity of the worker and evaluate the optimal severance under this endogenous probability of getting away with it. T (2) 1.2 The elasticity of severance to tenure In order to characterize the severance-tenure profile of EPL in different countries, we developed a simple measure of graded security for regular workers, that is workers with open-ended contracts. The index is obtained by adding up mandatory severance and notice periods for private sector workers at different tenure lenghts, drawing on institutional information gathered by the ILO (EPLex project) and the OECD. In particular, we considered the following tenure classes for which cross-country comparable information has been gathered: tenure at nine months; at one, five, ten and twenty years. At each tenure lenght, we computed an apparent elasticity of severance to tenure (plus notice) in between any two consecutive tenure levels and the ratio of tenure to the number of months in that interval. The largest and the lowest of these elasticities (and their correspondent tenure levels) are displayed in the first two columns of Table 2. This suggests that there is significant cross-country variation in the slope of the severance-tenure profile, but only two countries (Austria and Japan) where the elasticity is zero throughout a 20 years tenure lenght, denoting a flat severance-tenure profile. In Denmark, New Zealand and the US, there is no mandatory severance, hence the elasticity is not defined. In the other countries a flat severance-tenure profile is observed only limited to some tenure lenghts. As there is an apparent elasticity per period, we also developed a summary measure of graded security, by adding up the elasticities using weights proportional to the lenght of each tenure interval. Finally we normalized these overall apparent elasticities to obtain a unit value for a proportional severance scheme at all tenure lenghts (one having always a unit apparent elasticity). Formally, denoting by S the months of mandatory severance (and compulsory notice period), by τ months of tenure, and by indexing the tenure classes by subscript t, our index of Graded Security is given in each country by GS = 5 t=0 S t τ t (τ t τ t 1 ) τ t S t 240 where t = 0 denotes the beginning of the tenured contract, t = 1 denotes 9 months of tenure, t = 2 corresponds to one year of tenure, t = 3 to five years, t = 4 to ten years and, finally, t = 5 to twenty years (3) 5

8 Table 1: Severance and nature of dismissal Country T U TF E TF D TF E T F D CV E CV D p Australia Austria Belgium Canada (Federal) Czech Republic Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Japan Korea Luxembourg Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Portugal Slovak Republic Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey United Kingdom United States Sources: EPLex; OECD (2013); See equations 1 and 2 in the main text and table A2 in annex for details. Time is expressed in months. Reference is made to a worker with 20 years of tenure. 6

9 Figure 1: Severance payments and tenure Australia Austria Belgium Canada Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Severance (weeks) Ireland Israel Italy Japan Korea Luxembourg Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Portugal Slovak Republic Slovenia Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey United Kingdom United States Tenure (months) of tenure. The last column on the right-hand-side of Table 2 provides the value of this index for the OECD countries. Figure 1 displays the severance tenure profiles for the same set countries. We find that 18 countries out of 29 display an index above 50 per cent. In the two countries paying the same severance at all tenure levels (Austria and Japan), the index is clearly zero and the country-specific diagram displays a flat line. Relatively low levels for GS would also be observed in case of a markedly concave severance - tenure profile, as severance at longer tenures has a larger weight in our index. Both Figure 1, and Table A1 in the Annex displaying the apparent elasticities at each tenure lenght, suggest that a number of countries starting up with a relatively high level of severance and then experiencing a mild, but steady, increase of severance with tenure. This generates a relatively low GS. Finally, in Denmark, New Zealand, and the US no index is computed as in these countries costs of dismissals can only be imposed via collective bargaining (OECD Indicators of Employment Protection, 2008). In other words, there is no legally mandated severance pay at all. Overall, the GS index documents that most countries have mandated severance pay (and statutory notice periods) increasing with tenure. Why do regulations in so many countries allow for severance graded with tenure? Is this profile efficient from the standpoint of the individual worker and firm involved? There may social efficiency considerations for having employment protection increasing with tenure, e.g. related to the fiscal externalities associated to layoffs in presence of tenure-related unemployment benefit systems and/or job finding rates declining with age. There can also be equity considerations for offering stronger protection against layoffs to older workers, but we are not aware of theories rationalizing these arrangements from the standpoint of purely private efficiency. Personnel economics offers explanations for why firms offer tenured jobs, that is, positions that cannot 7

10 Table 2: Min and max apparent elasticity and related tenure and GS Index Minimum Related Maximum Related Elasticity Elasticity Tenure (months) Elasticity Tenure (months) Range GS Index Australia Austria 0.0 each tenure lenght 0.0 each tenure lenght Belgium Canada , Czech Republic , 60,120, Denmark * * * * - - Estonia , Finland France Germany Greece , Hungary 0.0 9, Ireland Israel Italy 0.0 9, 12, Japan 0.0 each tenure lenght 0.0 each tenure lenght Korea, Rep Luxembourg 0.0 9, , Mexico Netherlands 0.0 9, New Zealand * * * * - - Norway 0.0 9, 12, Poland 0.0 9, 12, 120, Portugal 0.5 9, Slovak Republic , Slovenia Spain , 120, Sweden , Switzerland , Turkey United Kingdom 0.0 9, United States * * * * - - Source: OECD (2012), World Bank Data (2012) Notes: * : No mandatory severance 8

11 Figure 2: An illustrative example be severed under any set of circumstances. Tenured jobs can be rationalized as the result of learning about match quality, building on Jovanovic (1979) [9] matching model, thereby firms, after observing a sufficiently long string of positive signals on the productivity of a worker decide to retain the employee, irrespective of future negative signals. Another explanation provided for offering tenured jobs is in terms of hiring incentives in organisations where incumbents have control over hirings, e.g., in academic institutions. Tenure prevents the strategic choice of incumbents of hiring only low quality workers in order to reduce competition with outsiders (Carmichael, 1988)[5]. These theories explain why employers may decide to commit not to layoff some workers, but do not explain why a mandated profile of severance increasing with tenure is chosen for potentially all private firms, irrespective of whether incumbents in these organizations play any role in hiring decisions or there is substantial heterogeneity in the quality of applicants. Moreover, these models do not address problems of commitment: private firms generally cannot credibly commit not to layoff some workers, irrespective of their performance. In the model presented in Section 2, a privately efficient and positive severance-tenure profile emerges as a result of moral hazard related to the stochastic nature of severance pay and the difference between disciplinary and economic dismissals. The stochastic nature of severance is due to the fact that both the fairness and the nature (economic vs. disciplinary) of the dismissal have to be proved before a Court. 2 The Basic Economics of Severance Payments with Unfair Dismissal 2.1 A model without specific investment A simple motivating example, illustrated in Figure 2, delivers our key intuition as to the inefficiency of separations without severance. Consider a two periods model, where the workers outside option is b in both periods. To keep things simple, assume that there is no discounting and there is no specific investment. Wages are given, but for some exogenous reasons, are deferred. Denote the first period and the second period wages by w 1 < b and w 2 > b respectively. Productivity is y 1 in the first period while in the second period is stochastic: it can take value y2 h with probability δ and value y2 l with probability 1 δ. Assume that w 2 > y l 2 > b 9

12 Firms can fire in the second period conditional on the realization of the shock. Firing requires a severance payment T 0. It follows that expected profits of the firm (the surplus of the employer) are given by: Π = y 1 w 1 + (1 δ)[y h 2 w 2 ] + δmax[y l 2 w 2, T ] The total surplus is given in each period by y b. Since y2 l > b by assumption, the joint surplus is positive in the second period whatever the realization of the shock, and hence, for efficiency reasons, production should take place (both y2 h and y2 l are above the horizontal line at b in Figure 2. However, since w 2 > y 2, when T = 0,firms always fire conditional on a adverse shock. The following remarks and proposition then immediately follow. Remark 1 A severance payment T w 2 y l 2 prevents inefficient separation. Proposition 2 When there are wage deferrals, a severance payment can prevent inefficient separation for senior workers 2.2 Two periods model of specific investments Consider now a more general two-period setting with endogenous wages being set in the initial period and moral hazard related to the decision of the worker to invest in firm-specific training. In our setup, workers may undertake a costly specific investment with uncertain return. We will keep our assumption that firms cannot commit not to fire, thus workers expect that firms will always fire when -ex post- returns are too low, even when they have invested in the job. We are not aware of employers in the private sector signing contracts that do not allow them to layoff workers in case of exogenous shocks. At the same time, a worker who does not invest can legitimately be dismissed as a shirker. This firm initiated dismissal is disciplinary, but such a case must be proved before a court and there is a certain probability that a disciplinary firing is deemed unfair by judges and a shirking worker can get away with it. We thus have a moral hazard problem, since shirking workers can obtain severance payments. The model is partial equilibrium: one worker and one firm have a job opportunity that lasts two periods. We also impose that the worker and the firm are risk neutral. As in the illustrative example above, there is no discounting between periods, and the worker s outside option is b in every period. Denote the baseline productivity on the job as y > b in every period. Assume further that wages are unilaterally set by the firm at the beginning of the contract. There is full commitment on the wage schedule and the firm cannot renegotiate ex post on the promised wage. The per period wage is indicated with w i, i = {1, 2} In period 1 the worker faces a specific investment opportunity s = {0, 1}. The investment opportunity costs to the worker C in the first period. It is only the worker who can undertake the investment opportunity. In other words, s is privately known by the worker in the first period, and revealed to the firm in the second period. Conditional on the investment being undertaken, productivity in the second period will be y + ε, where ε is the specific component of productivity and it is drawn from a continuous distribution F (ε) defined over the support ε [ε l, ε u ] with ε l < 0. The specific component of productivity is observed only by the firm. Since ε is only known to the firm, wages cannot be contingent on the specific component of productivity. In the second period, conditional on having observed the ε draw, the firm can unilaterally fire the worker. The second period wage is therefore a compensation contingent on not having shirked in the first period. There are two types of dismissals in the model. Economic and Disciplinary dismissals. Definition 3 Disciplinary Dismissal. In period 2, a firm is entitled to freely dismiss a shirking worker that did not invest in the first period. Definition 4 Economic Dismissal. In period 2, when productivity is sufficiently low, a firm is entitled to dismiss a worker by paying a severance T 10

13 Figure 3: Timeline In terms of employment protection legislation, a worker that does not invest is fired for disciplinary reasons while a productivity related firing is a fair economic dismissal. In our model, in the absence of publicly imposed severance payment the worker will not receive any severance payment if fired. The severance payment is a pure transfer to the worker. The severance payment T is set by the government. The firm can not commit to a severance payment because a problem of adverse selection stands on the way of a private contractual arrangement of this type. If a firm unilaterally commits to a severance payment, it would end-up selecting a group of shirkers. A mandatory severance solves this co-ordination problem. The realism of this assumption can be assessed considering that severance is either legislated or established within collective agreements at the industry, state or national level. Over and beyond economic and disciplinary dismissals, we have to distinguish between fair and unfair dismissals. In our setup the distinction is particularly relevant for disciplinary dismissals. Whether a disciplinary dismissal can be defined as fair can only be proven in court. The court ruling is stochastic. In period 2 the firm observes if the worker has invested or not, but cannot necessarily prove insufficient investments (hereafter shirking) in a court of law. We assume that there is a probability 1 q that the court of law observes shirking and declares the firing as fair. In such a case, the firm is exempted from paying severance payments. Hence, there is a probability q that a shirking worker gets away with it and receives severance payment. When this happens, the disciplinary dismissal in defined as unfair, and a severance payment is due. The realization of q is made after the firm has fired the worker, hence the expected severance payment for the firm when firing a shirking worker is qt. The timeline of the model in periods 1 and 2 is described in Figure 3. In the case of an economic dismissal, we assume that severance payment is always due, and there is no distinction between fair and unfair dismissals. Definition 5 The equilibrium is obtained by a set of wages w 1, w 2, an investment decision s of the worker and a firing policy ε d that satisfy Firm s participation constraint (non-negative expected profit in period 1) Worker s optimal investment 11

14 Firm optimal firing in period 2 Incentive compatible wage in period 2 Worker s participation constraint 2.3 Basic Value Functions Let us indicate with W (s=0) the value of the job to the worker in case she does not invest. In this case the shirking worker gets the first period wage and will be fired in period 2 for disciplinary reasons. Since in the court of law the firing may be defined as unfair, the cumulative wage bill problem is totally trivial and the worker will be paid its outside option in both periods so that W (s=0) = w 1 + b + qt where b is the flow outside option and qt is the expected severance payment in case of shirking. The worker s value function if she invests is then W (s=1) = w 1 C + (1 F (ε d ))w 2 + F (ε d )[b + T ] where F (ε d ) is the probability of being fired in the second period for economic reasons. Firms expected profits in the first period if the worker invest are Π 1(s=1) = y w 1 + Max[y + x w 2 ; T ]df (x) x where y w 1 is the operational profits in the first period while the integral in the second period is the expected profit conditional on a destruction/firing decision. Since the firing decision is clearly described by a reservation productivity, the expected profits are Π 1(s=1) = y w 1 + Π 1(s=1) = y w 1 + εu ε d [y + x w 2 ]df (x) T F (ε d ) εu ε d xdf (x) + (y w 2 )(1 F (ε d ) T F (ε d ) Finally, if the worker does not invest, and the firm fires the worker in period 2, its expected cumulative profits are Π 1(s=0) = y w 1 (1 q)t where (1 q)t is the expected severance payment for a fair dismissal 2.4 The reservation productivity When the worker invests, in the second period the firm has to select a reservation productivity. Profits in the second period are conditional on a specific component of productivity and can be written as Π 2 (ε) = Max[y + ε w 2 ; T ]. Since the outside option of the firm in period 2 is an economic dismissal with full severance payment, the reservation productivity solves Π 2 (ε d ) = T and its expression reads ε d = w 2 y T (4) Firing increases with wages while it decreases with productivity and severance payment. For a given wage, severance payments reduce firing in the second period. Substituting back into the profit functions Π 1(s=1) = (y w 1 ) + (1 F (ε d ))(y w 2 ) + 12 εu ε d xdf (x) T F (ε d )

15 Integrating by parts ε u ε d xdf (x) and using equation4, the expected profits are Π 1(s=1) = y w 1 + (1 F (ε d ))(y w 2 ) + ε d (1 F (ε d )) + εu Π 1(s=1) = y w 1 + (1 F (ε d ))[(y w 2 )+](y w 2 + ε d + T )] + Since y w 2 + ε d + T = 0, the last expression is simply Π 1(s=1) = y w 1 + εu. The firm participation constraints requires that Π 1 > 0 ε d (1 F (x))dx T ε d (1 F (x))dx T F (ε d ) εu ε d (1 F (x))dx T 2.5 Information structure, contract space, and restrictions on parameter values As mentioned in the introduction, the firm offers the worker a contract (w 1, w 2 ). The firm cannot commit to a firing policy. Hence if the firm finds it profitable to fire the worker ex post for economic reasons, it cannot commit not to do so. To ease the exposition of the model, we assume that the firm can commit to fire a worker that has not invested. In what follows we assume that y < b+c and that there exists a wage w 2 such that (1 F (ε d ))w 2 b+c. The latter is a necessary requirement for investments to be implementable from the firm standpoint. We also assume that (w 2 b)[1 F (ε d )] is increasing on the relevant intervals. 2.6 Efficient Separation Separation in the second period is efficient when it maximises the joint surplus from the job. Denote worker surplus at time t = 2 with S w,2 and the firm surplus with S f,2. Clearly S w,2 = w 2 (b + T ) S f,2 = y + ε w 2 ( T ) where b + T is the worker s outside option while T is the firm outside option. The joint surplus reads S 2 = S w,2 + S f,2 = y + ε b where both wages and severance payments do not enter in the joint surplus, as they are a simple transfer between the two parties. Firing is efficient if and only if S 2 (ε ) = 0 ε = b y (5) Firing is efficient whenever the productivity from the job (y + ε ) falls below the worker s outside option b. We call ε the efficient reservation productivity 2.7 The optimal contract Given the reservation productivity in equation 4, the firm has to select optimally the wage in period 1 and 2. In general, the wage in period 2 will be determined by the worker s incentive compatibility constraint, while the wage in period 1 will be determined by the workers participation constraint. The firm must necessarily increase the second period wage in order to incentivate the worker to undertake the investment. Since the wage in period 1 will be identical for both shirker and non shirker workers, the worker will invest if and only if W (s = 1) W (s = 0) 13

16 The firm has to fire the shirker in the second period, otherwise the incentive compatibility constraint cannot be satisfied. The incentive compatibility constraint thus reads or (1 F (ε d ))w 2 + F (ε d )(b + T ) C b + qt (w 2 b)[1 F (ε d )] C + [q F (ε d )]T (6) Given our assumptions, (6) with equality defines a unique value of w 2. The general expression for the second period wage is thus w 2 = b + C + [q F (ε d)]t (7) 1 F (ε d ) Given the second period wage, the first period wage is set so as to ensure that the worker participation constraint is satisfied. The workers has an outside option equal to b per period, so that the worker participation constraint is W (s = 1) = w 1 C + w 2 (1 F (ε d )) + F (ε d )(b + T ) 2b (8) Given w 2, the solution of the participation constraint with equality gives the first period wage. The reservation productivity of equation 4 completes the solution of the model. 2.8 Wages, Dismissals and Severance Payments The first result that we can establish concerns the firing policy of the firm. Recalling that the reservation productivity in period 2 is ε d = w 2 y T, its equilibrium level reads ε d = b y + C + [q F (ε d)]t 1 F (ε d ) From the above equation, we get a first result when there are no severance payments, Proposition 6 If there are no severance payments (T = 0), firing is too high in the second period For a general value of C, there is too much firing in the second period, as ε d(t =0) = b y + C 1 F (ε d ) > ε d. Recalling that the reservation productivity is ε d = b y, in the model there is too much firing as long as C > 0. This result is the essence of the firm non commitment policy vis-a-vis separations. As second period wages need to pay for the worker s investments effort in the first period, the firm has a tendency to over dismiss in the second period a worker that did not shirk and invested in the first period. With severance payments several features emerge. To understand firm behavior and the link between wages and severance payments, we need to study the relationship of the wage with respect to the probability q. Assume first that q = 0, so that shirking workers never gets away with it, and disciplinary firing is perfectly detected. It follows that w 2(q=0) b = C F (ε d)t (9) 1 F (ε d ) In this case, there is a perfect court monitoring and we can say that severance payment acts as a discipline device. Indeed, with perfect court monitoring, the firm needs to use less of the wage to induce workers investment and the period 2 wage turns out to be decreasing in the severance pay, for two reasons. First, for a given ε d, severance payments make investments more attractive, while they do not influence the pay-off for shirking workers (who get only b). Second, severance pay (and lower wages) makes firms more reluctant to fire, which also makes investing more attractive (since w 2 > b + T ). 14

17 On the other extreme, if q = 1 (shirking workers always get severance pay), severance payments are neutral. In this case the second period wage is increasing in the severance payment w 2(q=1) b = Substituting this wage in the reservation productivity we get ε d(q=1) = b y + C 1 F (ε d ) + T (10) C 1 F (ε d ) In this case, the severance payment is neutral in terms of allocation of labor. For a given ε d, a severance pay now increases wages by the same amount. Furthermore, when dt = dw, ε d stays constant. It follows that dw2 dt = 1. This is a version of the Lazear (1990) neutrality result. Proposition 7 When severance payments are paid to the worker under any type of separation, they are neutral vis-a-vis the firms firing allocation of labor and they simply make the wage profile steeper To sum up, for the general expression, by comparing (5) and (6) we derived the following set of results Proposition 8 a) If there are no severance payments (T = 0) then the firm fires workers too frequently (ε d is too high) b) In case of perfect court monitoring (q = 0), severance payment T reduces w 2, and hence reduces firing. In other words, severance payments act as discipline device c) If workers always get severance payments (q = 1), then severance increases w 2 but is neutral in terms of dismissal probabilities. In this case, dw 2 /dt = 1 severance payments do not influence ε d, and have no welfare implications. It only influences the wage profile by making it steeper. d) Severance payment reduces the period 2 wage if and only if q < F (ε d ) 2.9 Efficient Severance Payments Our next step is to derive the optimal severance payment T. From (4) and (5) it follows that the optimal T solves ε d = ε which implies that w 2 (ε d ) y T = b y T = w 2 (ε d ) b i.e., is equal to the wedge between the inside and the outside wage. Inserting from (6) with equality gives the following expression for the optimal T, denoted by T T = C + [q F (ε )]T 1 F (ε ) q < 1 Solving this for T gives T = C 1 q When q = 1,an increase in T directly increases w 2 unit by unit. In addition, increased T (and w 2 ) increases ε d, which again increases w 2. Finally, to solve for w 1, we utilize that w 2 = b + T, whic inserted into (8) gives that q < 1 w 1 + b + T C = 2b 15

18 or w 1 = b + C T = b + C C 1 q = b qc 1 q Proposition 9 The optimal severance pay policy can be summarized as follows: i) If q = 1 (shirkers always get severance pay) the optimal severance pay is undefined and there is no welfare loss in setting T = 0. ii) For all other values of q, the optimal severance pay is strictly positive and given by 3 Extensions 3.1 Three periods T = C 1 q > 0 Suppose now that the contract has three periods. The output of the worker in period i is y i + ε i for i = 2, 3. Our set-up is robust enough to allow a general stochastic structure for the terms ε 2, ε 3, but for simplicity we now assume that they are iid. The outside option in all periods is b. 3.2 No investment cost in period 2 We first assume that workers do not undertake any costly investments in period 2. We also assume that if a worker is fired in period 2, he cannot be rehired in period 3. Note that the interim participation constraint of the non-shirker in period 2 is satisfied with slack and will not be discussed. The participation constraint of a non-shirking worker reads The value to a shirker reads W e = w 1 C + (1 F (ε d 2))[w 2 + (1 F (ε d 3))w 3 + F (ε d 3)T 3 ] + F (ε d 2)T 2 3b (11) W s = w 1 + qt 2 + 2b W e (12) The latter inequality is to avoid shirking. The joint surplus in period 3 is given by S 3 = max[y + ε b, 0]. Efficient separation in period 3 thus requires that ε = ε 3 = b y It follows that S 3 = ε b y (y + ε 3 b)dε. Suppose the efficient separation rate is imposed in period 3. The maximum joint surplus in period 2 is then Efficient separation in period 2 thus requires that S 2 = max[y + ε 2 + S 3 b, 0] ε 2 = b y S 3 (13) Since the firm cannot re-hire the worker, there is an option value of keeping her. Note that adding one more period gives two more instruments, T 3 and w 3. There is one more choice variable, ε d 3. Since we have two more instruments and only one more variable, we have one degree of freedom to obtain efficiency. 16

19 In period 3, the firm retains the worker if y + ε 3 w 3 T 3. In order to implement the efficient separation rule ε d 3 = b y, we must have that T 3 = w 3 b. The resulting expected period 3 profit (with T 3 = w 3 b) reads EΠ 3 = (y + ε w 3 )df (ε) + F (b y)(w 3 b) ε b y = S (w 3 + b) In period 2, the firm keeps the worker if and only if or In order to implement (13) it follows that y + ε 2 + EΠ 3 = y + ε 2 + S 3 (w 3 b) w 2 + T 2 ε 2 w 2 + w 3 b y S T 2 T 2 = w 2 + w 3 2b (14) Given optimal values of T 1 and T 2, the worker is indifferent between being retained and being fired, both in period 1 and in period 2. It follows from (11) that Or that W e = w 1 + T + 2b C (15) w 1 + qt + 2b (16) T 2 C 1 q as before. To find the period 1 wage, plug in for (15) and (17) to get into the participation constraint (11) The incentive compatibility constraint (12) inserted thus gives that or w 1 + C 1 q C b w 1 = b q 1 q C as before. What about the wage-tenure profile and the severance pay-tenure profile? In our model this is indeterminate. The worker is indifferent between wages in period 2 and 3, and the profile does not influence T 2. However, T 2 > T 3 unless w 2 < b. Proposition 10 Suppose that the employment relationship involves three periods, and that workers only invest in the first period. Then the following is true a) The severance pay in period 2, T 2, is given by T 2 C 1 q b) Optimal firing decisions in period 3 requires that T 3 = w 3 b c) Given optimal period 3 severance pay, the participation constraint gives a constraint on w 2 + w 3, but not on the wage-tenure profile. The severance pay T 2 is independent of the wage-tenure profile (as long as the participation constraint of the worker is satisfied). d) If w 2 b, then T 2 > T 3 (17) 17

20 3.3 Investment costs in period 2 Suppose now that the worker has to invest C in period 2 as well in order to maintain the high productivity in period 3. Again we assume that a shirker will be fired. If the worker shirks in period 2, the probability that she gets away with it is q 2 > q (courts are more lenient towards senior workers). As in the previous subsection, we assume that efficiency is implemented. Again we require that T 3 = w 3 b in order to obtain efficient separation in period 3. A period 2 non-shirker has a continuation pay-off in period 2 given by W e 2 = w 2 + F (ε 3)(T 2 + b) + (1 F (ε 3))w 3 C = w 2 + T 3 + b The second period shirker, by contrast, receives Incentive compatibilty again requires that W s 2 = w 2 + q 2 T 3 + b T 3 C 1 q 2 Consider then period 2. The joint value of continuing the match is The value to the firm (given efficient T 3 ) is given by Efficiency requires that It follows that efficiency is implemented whenever It follows that S 2 (ε) = y + ε 2 b + S C Π 2 = y + ε 2 w 2 S T 3 + T 2 ε 2 = ε 2 = b + C S y T 2 = (w 2 b) + T 3 C (18) W e = w 1 C + (1 F (ε d 2))[w 2 + W 3 C] + F (ε d 2)T 2 (19) = w 1 C + T 2 + 2b where W 3 is the expected pay-off to the worker if employed in period 3. By using exactly the same logic as above, it follows that IC in period 2 requires that T 2 C 1 q We have now pinned down the severance payments. Consider the wage-tenure profile starting from period 1 wage. It follows from (19) that w 1 C + T 2 + 2b = 3b or In period 3, we have that w 1 = b w 3 = q 1 q C C 1 q 2 + b 18

The Economics of Severance Pay

The Economics of Severance Pay The Economics of Severance Pay Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen Moen*** January 31, 2014 Abstract All OECD countries have either legally mandated severance pay or compensations imposed by industry-level

More information

Severance Pay. Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen R. Moen*** July 29, Abstract

Severance Pay. Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen R. Moen*** July 29, Abstract Severance Pay Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen R. Moen*** July 29, 2014 Abstract All OECD countries have either legally mandated severance pay or compensations imposed by industry-level bargaining

More information

Severance Pay. Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen R. Moen*** February 11, Abstract

Severance Pay. Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen R. Moen*** February 11, Abstract Severance Pay Tito Boeri*, Pietro Garibaldi**, Espen R. Moen*** February 11, 2015 Abstract All OECD countries have either legally mandated severance pay or compensations imposed by industry-level bargaining

More information

Inside Severance Pay

Inside Severance Pay Inside Severance Pay Tito Boeri a, Pietro Garibaldi b, Espen R. Moen c November 4, 2016 Abstract All OECD countries have either legally mandated severance pay or compensations imposed by industry-level

More information

Generation Indebted Jobless

Generation Indebted Jobless Generation Indebted Jobless Tito Boeri Fondazione RODOLFO DEBENEDETTI Università Bocconi Istanbul, May 9th, 2013 Outline A global rise but not uniform across the board Should we worry about it? The key

More information

Chapter 7. Employment protection

Chapter 7. Employment protection Chapter 7 Employment protection This chapter heavily borrows from courses and slides by Tito Boeri, Professor of Economics at Bocconi University, Milan, Italy Protecting jobs Losing a job is always a bad

More information

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4691 How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment Jan C. van Ours Sander Tuit January 2010 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries PAOLA PROFETA RICCARDO PUGLISI SIMONA SCABROSETTI June 30, 2015 FIRST DRAFT, PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT THE AUTHORS PERMISSION Abstract Focusing

More information

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2521 Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model Vincent Bodart Olivier Pierrard Henri R. Sneessens December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI:   ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012 OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/9789264169401-en ISBN 978-92-64-16939-5 (print) ISBN 978-92-64-16940-1 (PDF) OECD 2012 Corrigendum Page 21: Figure 1.1. Average annual real net investment

More information

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD Approach to (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD The benefits of protection can be divided in three main groups. The cash benefits include disability pensions, survivor's pensions and other short-

More information

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions Statistical annex Sources and definitions Most of the statistics shown in these tables can be found as well in several other (paper or electronic) publications or references, as follows: the annual edition

More information

EARLY RETIREMENT IN OECD COUNTRIES: THE ROLE OF SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEMS

EARLY RETIREMENT IN OECD COUNTRIES: THE ROLE OF SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEMS OECD Economic Studies No. 29, 1997/II EARLY RETIREMENT IN OECD COUNTRIES: THE ROLE OF SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEMS Sveinbjörn Blöndal and Stefano Scarpetta TABLE OF CONTENTS The issue and key results... 8 Old-age

More information

Crowdfunding, Cascades and Informed Investors

Crowdfunding, Cascades and Informed Investors DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7994 Crowdfunding, Cascades and Informed Investors Simon C. Parker February 2014 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Crowdfunding,

More information

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth Lorenzo Burlon August 11, 2014 In this note we report the empirical exercises we conducted to motivate the theoretical insights

More information

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. It reproduces an OECD Legal Instrument

More information

Generation Indebted Jobless

Generation Indebted Jobless Generation Indebted Jobless Tito Boeri Fondazione RODOLFO DEBENEDETTI Università Bocconi A European Labor Market with Full Employment, More Income Security and Less Income Inequality in 2020 Bonn, IZA/VEF

More information

Key Elasticities in Job Search Theory: International Evidence

Key Elasticities in Job Search Theory: International Evidence DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1314 Key Elasticities in Job Search Theory: International Evidence John T. Addison Mário Centeno Pedro Portugal September 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries Teresa Curristine, Budgeting and Public Expenditures Division, Public Governance Directorate, OECD 6 th Annual Meeting of Latin American Senior Budget Officials

More information

WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION?

WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION? INDICATOR WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION? Not only does education pay off for individuals ly, but the public sector also from having a large proportion of tertiary-educated individuals

More information

(III) Debating the Minimum Wage. Bocconi University,

(III) Debating the Minimum Wage. Bocconi University, (III) Debating the Minimum Wage Bocconi University, 2017-18 Outline Definition and cross-country comparisons Theory Competitive labor market Dual labor market Noncompetitive labor market Empirical evidence

More information

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017 FISCAL FACT No. 557 Aug. 2017 A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017 Jose Trejos Research Assistant Kyle Pomerleau Economist, Director of Federal Projects Key Findings: Average wage

More information

Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting

Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting ACTION 13: 2014 Deliverable ANNEX II TO CHAPTER V. TRANSFER PRICING DOCUMENTATION

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy ECO 209Y Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Lecture 3: Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Income Gustavo Indart Slide 1 Assumptions We will assume that: There is no depreciation There are no indirect taxes

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016 FISCAL FACT No. 517 July, 2016 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016 By Kyle Pomerleau Director of Federal Projects Kevin Adams Research Assistant Key Findings OECD countries rely heavily on

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018 FISCAL FACT No. 581 Mar. 2018 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018 Amir El-Sibaie Analyst Key Findings In 2015, OECD countries relied heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value-added tax,

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

EMPLOYABILITY AND LABOUR MARKET

EMPLOYABILITY AND LABOUR MARKET EMPLOYABILITY AND LABOUR MARKET POLICIES Guillermo MONTT Division for Employment, Analysis and Policy Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs guillermo.montt@oecd.org July 3, 2014 Skill levels

More information

Tax Working Group Information Release. Release Document. September taxworkingroup.govt.nz/key-documents

Tax Working Group Information Release. Release Document. September taxworkingroup.govt.nz/key-documents Tax Working Group Information Release Release Document September 2018 taxworkingroup.govt.nz/key-documents This paper contains advice that has been prepared by the Tax Working Group Secretariat for consideration

More information

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate, 8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate, 1975-2005 2005 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 Australia 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 48% 49% 49% Austria

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY Neil R. Mehrotra Brown University Peterson Institute for International Economics November 9th, 2017 1 / 13 PUBLIC DEBT AND PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting

Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project Guidance on Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting ACTION 13: 2014 Deliverable ANNEX III TO CHAPTER V. A MODEL TEMPLATE FOR THE

More information

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons Standard Note: SN/EP/3235 Last updated: 15 October 2008 Author: Bryn Morgan Economic Policy & Statistics Section This note presents data comparing the national

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017 FISCAL FACT No. 558 Aug. 2017 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017 Amir El-Sibaie Analyst Key Findings: OECD countries rely heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value-added tax, and social

More information

DESIGNING GOOD TAX POLICY: A PRIMER

DESIGNING GOOD TAX POLICY: A PRIMER DESIGNING GOOD TAX POLICY: A PRIMER Bert Brys, Ph.D. Senior Tax Economist ADB Workshop on Tax Policy for Domestic Resource Mobilisation, 20-23 September 2018 Outline of the presentation 1 Introduction

More information

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government?

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government? What are the sources of revenue for the federal government? FEDERAL BUDGET 1/4 Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government? A. About 48 percent of federal revenue comes from individual

More information

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. It reproduces

More information

The OECD s Society at a Glance Simon Chapple OECD ELS/SPD Villa Vigoni, Italy, 9-11 th March 2011

The OECD s Society at a Glance Simon Chapple OECD ELS/SPD Villa Vigoni, Italy, 9-11 th March 2011 The OECD s Society at a Glance 2 Simon Chapple OECD ELS/SPD Villa Vigoni, Italy, 9- th March 2 Reconceptualisation for 2: Internal reasons OECD growth from 3 to 34 countries Other major economies (e.g.

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

Investing for our Future Welfare. Peter Whiteford, ANU

Investing for our Future Welfare. Peter Whiteford, ANU Investing for our Future Welfare Peter Whiteford, ANU Investing for our future welfare Presentation to Jobs Australia National Conference, Canberra, 20 October 2016 Peter Whiteford, Crawford School of

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014 FISCAL FACT Nov. 2014 No. 443 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014 By Kyle Pomerleau Economist Key Findings OECD countries rely heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value added tax, and

More information

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension? Private pensions A growing role Private pensions play an important and growing role in providing for old age in OECD countries. In 11 of them Australia, Denmark, Hungary, Iceland, Mexico, Norway, Poland,

More information

V. MAKING WORK PAY. The economic situation of persons with low skills

V. MAKING WORK PAY. The economic situation of persons with low skills V. MAKING WORK PAY There has recently been increased interest in policies that subsidise work at low pay in order to make work pay. 1 Such policies operate either by reducing employers cost of employing

More information

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012 OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012 Emily Hewlett OECD Health Data National Correspondents and Health Accounts Experts Meeting, 17 th October 2013 Health System Characteristics Survey 2012 HSC

More information

Fiscal Policy in Japan

Fiscal Policy in Japan Fiscal Policy in Japan - Issues and Future Directions- June 10th, 2015 Ministry of Finance General Government Gross Debt and Financial Balances (International Comparison) (%) 240 210 General Government

More information

Declaration on Environmental Policy

Declaration on Environmental Policy Declaration on Environmental Policy OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. It reproduces an OECD Legal Instrument and may contain

More information

Statistical Annex. Sources and definitions

Statistical Annex. Sources and definitions Statistical Annex Sources and definitions Most of the statistics shown in these tables can also be found in two other (paper or electronic) publication and data repository, as follows: The annual edition

More information

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES AVAILABLE ON LINE DIS P O NIB LE LIG NE www.sourceoecd.org E N STATISTICS Taxing Wages «SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES 2004-2005 2005 Taxing Wages SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND

More information

Indicator B3 How much public and private investment in education is there?

Indicator B3 How much public and private investment in education is there? Education at a Glance 2014 OECD indicators 2014 Education at a Glance 2014: OECD Indicators For more information on Education at a Glance 2014 and to access the full set of Indicators, visit www.oecd.org/edu/eag.htm.

More information

On Minimum Wage Determination

On Minimum Wage Determination On Minimum Wage Determination Tito Boeri Università Bocconi, LSE and fondazione RODOLFO DEBENEDETTI March 15, 2014 T. Boeri (Università Bocconi) On Minimum Wage Determination March 15, 2014 1 / 1 Motivations

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem?

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem? November 15, 2006 Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem? by Patrick Fleenor Fiscal Fact No. 71 Introduction Double taxation is a common and often misused expression in tax policy discussions.

More information

Budget repair and the size of Australia s government. Melbourne Economic Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute December 2015

Budget repair and the size of Australia s government. Melbourne Economic Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute December 2015 Budget repair and the size of Australia s government Melbourne Economic Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute December 2015 Budget repair and the size of Australia s government Attitudes to the best approach

More information

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland Ageing and employment policies: Ireland John Martin 1 Director for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD FÁS Annual Labour Market Conference, Dublin, 5 December 2005 OECD has carried out a major

More information

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018. The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, th September 08. This note reports estimates of the economic impact of introducing a carbon tax of 50 per ton of CO in the Netherlands.

More information

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016 Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to.4% in the third quarter of 26 Growth in unit labour costs (ULCs) in the OECD area slowed to.4% in the third quarter of 26 (compared with.6% in the previous quarter)

More information

Discussion (in progress) of

Discussion (in progress) of Discussion (in progress) of Incentive Effects of Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts: Evidence from Chile by Gonzalo Reyes Hartly, Jan van Ours and Milan Vodopivec Very relevant very timely In the

More information

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary Low employment among the + population in Hungary The role of incentives, health and cognitive capacities Janos Divenyi (Central European University) and Gabor Kezdi (Central European University and IE-CRSHAS)

More information

Fair taxation of the digital economy

Fair taxation of the digital economy Contribution ID: 13311b6b-0b4c-4bf0-a3d9-c6b94f5ab400 Date: 02/01/2018 21:27:35 Fair taxation of the digital economy Fields marked with * are mandatory. 1 Introduction The objective of the initiative is

More information

Monetary policy regimes and exchange rate fluctuations

Monetary policy regimes and exchange rate fluctuations Seðlabanki Íslands Monetary policy regimes and exchange rate fluctuations The views are of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of Iceland Thórarinn G. Pétursson Central

More information

THE GROSS AND NET RATES OF REVENUES REPLACEMENT WITHIN THE RETIRING PENSIONS

THE GROSS AND NET RATES OF REVENUES REPLACEMENT WITHIN THE RETIRING PENSIONS THE GROSS AND NET RATES OF REVENUES REPLACEMENT WITHIN THE RETIRING PENSIONS Tudor Colomeischi Department of Computer Science, Stefan cel Mare University of Suceava, ROMANIA. tudorcolomeischi@yahoo.ro

More information

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS Marius Lüske Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD Lisbon, 28.09.2018 Marius.LUSKE@oecd.org www.oecd.org/els OUTLINE Talk based

More information

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES Nick Malyshev, OECD Conference on the Further Development of Impact Assessment in the European Union Brussels, RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES Regulatory Impact

More information

The Coalition s Policy to Lower Company Tax

The Coalition s Policy to Lower Company Tax 1 Our Plan Real Solutions for all Australians The direction, values and policy priorities of the next Coalition Government. The Coalition s Policy to Lower Company Tax August 2013 Our Plan s Real Solution

More information

Recommendation of the Council on Establishing and Implementing Pollutant Release and Transfer Registers (PRTRs)

Recommendation of the Council on Establishing and Implementing Pollutant Release and Transfer Registers (PRTRs) Recommendation of the Council on Establishing and Implementing Pollutant Release and Transfer Registers (PRTRs) OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

WHAT WOULD THE NEIGHBOURS SAY?

WHAT WOULD THE NEIGHBOURS SAY? WHAT WOULD THE NEIGHBOURS SAY? HOW INEQUALITY MEANS THE UK IS POORER THAN WE THINK High Pay Centre About the High Pay Centre The High Pay Centre is an independent non-party think tank established to monitor

More information

Pension Fund Investment and Regulation - An International Perspective and Implications for China s Pension System

Pension Fund Investment and Regulation - An International Perspective and Implications for China s Pension System Pension Fund Investment and Regulation - An International Perspective and Implications for China s Pension System Yu-Wei Hu, Fiona Stewart and Juan Yermo Financial Affairs Division OECD, Paris OECD/IOPS

More information

Collective Bargaining in OECD and accession countries

Collective Bargaining in OECD and accession countries Collective Bargaining in OECD and accession countries www.oecd.org/employment/collective-bargaining.htm The, ultra-activity and retro-activity of collective agreements The detailed description of the building

More information

Third Revised Decision of the Council concerning National Treatment

Third Revised Decision of the Council concerning National Treatment Third Revised Decision of the Council concerning National Treatment OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. It reproduces an OECD

More information

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances Enrique G. Mendoza University of Maryland, IMF & NBER Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR & NBER José-Víctor Ríos-Rull

More information

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System Sources of Federal Receipts Projected for 2016 Excise Taxes 2.9% Estate & Gift Taxes 0.6% Corporate Income Taxes 9.8% Other Taxes

More information

TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL. An Opportunity For Foreign Residents. Dr. Avi Nov

TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL. An Opportunity For Foreign Residents. Dr. Avi Nov TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL An Opportunity For Foreign Residents Dr. Avi Nov Short Bio Dr. Avi Nov is an Israeli lawyer who represents taxpayers, individuals and entities. Areas of Practice: Tax Law,

More information

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Prices and Output in an Open conomy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply chapter LARNING GOALS: After reading this chapter, you should be able to: Understand how short- and long-run equilibrium is reached

More information

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD Revenue Statistics 2017 Tax revenue trends in the OECD OECD 2017 The OECD freely authorises the use of this material for non-commercial purposes, provided that suitable acknowledgment of the source and

More information

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015 FISCAL FACT Apr. 2015 No. 465 Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015 By Kyle Pomerleau Economist Key Findings OECD countries rely heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value added tax,

More information

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries OECD Centres Germany Berlin (49-30) 288 8353 Japan Tokyo (81-3) 5532-0021 Mexico Mexico (52-55) 5281 3810 United States Washington (1-202) 785 6323 AUSTRALIA AUSTRIA BELGIUM CANADA CZECH REPUBLIC DENMARK

More information

OECD Recommendation on Consumer Dispute Resolution and Redress

OECD Recommendation on Consumer Dispute Resolution and Redress OECD Recommendation on Consumer Dispute Resolution and Redress ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT The OECD is a unique forum where the governments of 30 democracies work together to

More information

Major Trends in Pension Reforms. Ambrogio Rinaldi Director, COVIP, Italy Chair, OECD Working Party on Private Pensions

Major Trends in Pension Reforms. Ambrogio Rinaldi Director, COVIP, Italy Chair, OECD Working Party on Private Pensions Major Trends in Pension Reforms Ambrogio Rinaldi Director, COVIP, Italy Chair, OECD Working Party on Private Pensions 6th Global Pension & Savings Conference the World Bank - Washington, DC April 2-3,

More information

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people Press release Date 9 November 2015 Contact Mihnea Anastasiu Pages 5 Media Relations Manager Tel: +40 21 225 3546 Email: mihnea.anastasiu@ro.pwc.com Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index

More information

MICRO-LEVEL CONSEQUENCES OF FLEXIBILITY-ENHANCING REFORMS: WORK IN PROGRESS. 22 June 2015

MICRO-LEVEL CONSEQUENCES OF FLEXIBILITY-ENHANCING REFORMS: WORK IN PROGRESS. 22 June 2015 MICRO-LEVEL CONSEQUENCES OF FLEXIBILITY-ENHANCING REFORMS: WORK IN PROGRESS 22 June 2015 Looking beneath the positive net effects of flexibility-enhancing reforms OECD and other empirical work has documented

More information

MODULE 9. Guidance to completing the Maturity Analysis module of BSL/2

MODULE 9. Guidance to completing the Maturity Analysis module of BSL/2 MODULE 9 Guidance to completing the Maturity Analysis module of BSL/2 MATURITY ANALYSIS Overview The Commission recognises that banks may not measure their liquidity using the particular maturity ladder

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

FCCC/SBI/2010/10/Add.1

FCCC/SBI/2010/10/Add.1 United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change Distr.: General 25 August 2010 Original: English Subsidiary Body for Implementation Contents Report of the Subsidiary Body for Implementation on its

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

HEALTH LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

HEALTH LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES HEALTH LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES Michael Schoenstein, OECD Health Division 3 rd Global Health Workforce Alliance Forum Recife, 11 November 2013 Main health labour market issues in OECD countries

More information

TAX POLICY: RECENT TRENDS AND REFORMS IN OECD COUNTRIES FOREWORD

TAX POLICY: RECENT TRENDS AND REFORMS IN OECD COUNTRIES FOREWORD TAX POLICY: RECENT TRENDS AND REFORMS IN OECD COUNTRIES FOREWORD This publication provides an overview of recent trends in domestic taxation in OECD countries over the period 1999 to 2002, and a summary

More information

Pension Taxes versus Early Retirement Rights

Pension Taxes versus Early Retirement Rights DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 536 Pension Taxes versus Early Retirement Rights Mike Orszag Dennis Snower July 2002 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Pension

More information

HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting

HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting This booklet presents highlights from the 2016 OECD performance budgeting survey. The data is preliminary

More information

Lecture 3 Shapiro-Stiglitz Model of Efficiency Wages

Lecture 3 Shapiro-Stiglitz Model of Efficiency Wages Lecture 3 Shapiro-Stiglitz Model of Efficiency Wages Leszek Wincenciak, Ph.D. University of Warsaw 2/41 Lecture outline: Introduction The model set-up Workers The effort decision of a worker Values of

More information

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July Statistics Brief Infrastructure Investment July 2015 Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low The latest update of annual transport infrastructure investment and maintenance data collected

More information

IDA13. Further Options for IDA13 Grant Financing

IDA13. Further Options for IDA13 Grant Financing IDA13 Further Options for IDA13 Grant Financing International Development Association January 2004 1. During the IDA13 Mid-Term Review discussions on November 4-5, 2003, Deputies considered several approaches

More information

Weighting issues in EU-LFS

Weighting issues in EU-LFS Weighting issues in EU-LFS Carlo Lucarelli, Frank Espelage, Eurostat LFS Workshop May 2018, Reykjavik carlo.lucarelli@ec.europa.eu, frank.espelage@ec.europa.eu 1 1. Introduction The current legislation

More information

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE 7. FINANCES OF RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE Key results Public spending on pensions has been on the rise in most OECD countries for the past decades, as

More information

Gross Domestic Expenditures on Research and Development in Canada (GERD), and the Provinces

Gross Domestic Expenditures on Research and Development in Canada (GERD), and the Provinces Catalogue no. 88-221-X Gross Domestic Expenditures on Research and Development in Canada (GERD), and the Provinces National estimates 2002 to 2012 / estimates 2006 to 2010 How to obtain more information

More information

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada?

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 10178 Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada? Aysit Tansel Zeynel Abidin Ozdemir Emre Aksoy August 2016 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information Making Money out of Publicly Available Information Forthcoming, Economics Letters Alan D. Morrison Saïd Business School, University of Oxford and CEPR Nir Vulkan Saïd Business School, University of Oxford

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

The Chilean Pension System: Favorable Results in International Comparison

The Chilean Pension System: Favorable Results in International Comparison ISSN 0717-1528 The an Pension System: Favorable Results in International Comparison The pension system has been questioned Recently, the an pension system has shown an increasing dissatisfaction level,

More information