REAL GROSS DOMESTIC INCOME, RELATIVE PRICES, AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE ACROSS THE OECD

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "REAL GROSS DOMESTIC INCOME, RELATIVE PRICES, AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE ACROSS THE OECD"

Transcription

1 roiw_ Review of Income and Wealth Series 56, Number 3, September 2010 REAL GROSS DOMESTIC INCOME, RELATIVE PRICES, AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE ACROSS THE OECD by Ryan Macdonald* Statistics Canada This paper uses OECD data to examine changes in labor productivity, real gross domestic product (GDP) and real gross domestic income (GDI), economic aggregates, and relative economic growth over time. Real GDI combines changes in production (real GDP) with a trading gain derived from relative price changes. The paper considers two sources of trading gains: the terms of trade, and the real exchange rate. For OECD countries, the terms of trade is the more important price ratio, making a contribution to real income growth that is, on average, an order of magnitude larger than the real exchange rate. Over long time periods, the most important source of real income growth is changes in production. Over shorter time horizons, however, the trading gain can make noteworthy contributions. Changes in aggregates like real private consumption, or the relative economic performance of nations, are shown to be particularly dependent on the trading gain during the large swings in resource prices that occurred post Introduction Economists examine real income differences across countries and over time in an effort to understand differences in living standards. Real gross domestic product (GDP), which is an income measure that assumes all real income change comes from changes in production, and labor productivity, which is a measure of output per hour worked, are frequently employed measures for this purpose. New processes, technological breakthroughs, or higher labor and capital inputs lead to increases in real GDP. Technological advances and increases in the capital labor ratio raise labor productivity. Through examining the production process, or the real income it generates, real GDP and labor productivity are used as a base for productivity analysis (see, e.g. Hulten, 2001), real income analysis (see, e.g. Rodgers, 2003), or to model economic aggregates such as consumption. However, relative prices also affect real income growth. Depending on how the relative prices of exports and imports change, the volume of goods and services that an economy can purchase can differ from its production. An economy may improve its labor productivity, raising the efficiency with which it produces goods and services, but if it produces goods for export whose prices are falling relative to the imported goods it purchases, it may not see much of an increase in its standard of living as measured by the purchasing power of its income. The importance of taking these factors into account for understanding the outcomes of international income comparisons, or changes in economic aggregates such as consumption or imports, increased greatly after *Correspondence to: Ryan Macdonald, Statistics Canada, 18th Floor, RH Coates Bldg, Tunney s Pasture, Ottawa, Ontario, Canada (Ryan.macdonald@statcan.gc.ca). Review of Income and Wealth 2010 International Association for Research in Income and Wealth Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA, 02148, USA. 498

2 The years cover a period of global expansion when emerging nations, particularly China, emerged as important economic centers. Prices rose sharply for most commodities while, at the same time, relative prices for many manufactured products fell (Francis, 2007). This confluence of events led to the largest relative price shifts experienced by OECD nations since the second oil shock. The years , therefore, provide a unique period when the influence of relative price change stands out. This paper uses a real income measure referred to as real gross domestic income (GDI) to examine the role of relative price changes for real income growth. Using real GDI breaks the fixed relationship between real income and production that arises when real GDP is used. Real GDI is interpreted as a measure of purchasing power, or absorption, rather than a measure of production or productivity. Growth in real GDI captures changes in the volume of goods and services available to a domestic economy, and is associated with changes in utility (Kohli, 2004). Moving from real GDP to real GDI involves accounting for relative price changes related to traded products. Two relative prices are considered here: the terms of trade, and the real exchange rate. The terms of trade is defined as the ratio of export to import prices, while the real exchange rate is defined as the ratio of traded to non-traded prices. Data for 29 OECD countries are used to examine sources of real income growth, to demonstrate the importance of commodity prices for terms of trade and real exchange rate changes, the importance of relative price adjustment for understanding movements in economic aggregates like consumption, and to examine changes in economic performance over time. The paper focuses on the period because rapid increases in commodity prices post-2002 create dramatic changes for relative prices during these years. However, the historical record is employed to provide a long-term perspective, and to provide comparisons between the resource boom and previous resource price cycles. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses real GDP, labor productivity, and real GDI, while Section 3 discusses data and methodology. Section 4 examines labor productivity, real GDI, and real GDP across OECD countries during the period. It pays particular attention to relative price changes which reflect commodity price cycles. Section 5 looks at how much cross sectional variation in real aggregates can be explained using real GDI. Section 6 contains a long-run comparison of economic performance relative to the United States for Australia, Canada, and the United Kingdom. Section 7 concludes. 2. Real Gross Domestic Product and Real Gross Domestic Income Following Diewert and Morrison (1986) and Fox et al. (2002), suppose there are N = N D + N X + N M netputs that can be divided into domestic outputs, exported outputs, and imported inputs (negative netputs) that can be represented by the following netput vector, y ( yd, yx, ym) with price vector p ( pd, px, pm) > 0. Suppose also that there is a one by M vector of primary inputs (labor and capital) 499

3 v ( v1,..., v M ) 0 with price vector w ( w1,..., w M ) > 0. It is then possible to calculate nominal GDP as the sum of final expenditures or the sum of payments to primary factors of production: GDP = y i p By assuming that y and p can be represented by indices, and letting v i w = Q, it is possible to write the relationship between nominal GDP and nominal income as: (1) GDP = y p = Q. Real GDP is calculated by removing price effects from production. This is equivalent to assuming the GDP deflator is the relevant price index for calculating real income, and leads to the interpretation of real GDP as a real income measure: (2) Q real GDP = y =. p Real income measured in this fashion associates changes in income with changes in the volume of production. Because it uses the GDP deflator to do so, real income is measured in terms of the netputs produced, and is therefore associated with movements relating to the economy s production function. As a result, changes in productivity, capacity utilization, and inputs will change real income, but movements in prices have no volume effect. This will only be the case if all prices progress at the same rate, or if the economy is closed. In an open economy where export, import, and domestic prices change at different rates, changes in production do not necessarily result in commensurate changes in real income. The relationship between GDP and nominal income can be used to form productivity measures that reflect the efficiency of production. One such measure is labor productivity which tracks the volume of output per unit of labor input. Growth in labor productivity is associated with movements in real wages, making it an attractive metric for analyzing changes in economic performance over time. When the cost of labor and capital can be represented by indices, it is possible to decompose real GDP into three volume components: labor input, capital services, and multifactor productivity. The labor index, h, is typically measured as the number of hours worked. Labor productivity is measured by factoring h out of the production function and using it to scale real GDP: (3) Labor Productivity = y h. Real GDP and labor productivity are associated with changes in an economy s production possibilities. However, it is possible to move to move to a real income concept more closely associated with a society s utility curve by using a price index other than the GDP deflator. One choice for an alternative price index is the final domestic expenditure price index. It includes private consumption, gross fixed capital formation, government consumption, and inventory prices. The final domestic expenditure price index is the broadest price index available that captures the final goods and services purchased by domestic economic agents. 500

4 When final domestic expenditure prices are used to deflate nominal income, the resulting measure is real gross domestic income: (4) real GDI y p Q = =. p p D D Real income measured using the final domestic expenditure deflator associates changes in real income with changes in the volume of production as well as relative price shifts. Changes in relative prices can behave in an analogous manner to productivity growth (Diewert and Morrison, 1986), and lead to real changes in the volume of goods and services available to an economy. To empirically analyze price and volume changes, an index number formula must be chosen. The Tornqvist (1936) index is used here. It has the attractive property of being log-additive, making it possible to interpret factors as contributions to growth. In addition to the ease of interpretation, the Tornqvist and Fisher ideal index are equivalent to a second order approximation (Diewert, 1978), which as Fox et al. (2002) point out, makes them equivalent to at least two decimal points. Define the logged Tornqvist final domestic expenditure price index between periods t and s as: (5) N ln( p p ) ν Dt, Ds, jt, j= 1 p ln p jt, js, where, j = 1,...,N D netputs, ϖ jt, + ϖ js, ν jt, = ϖ jt, yp j j y p and = i. 2 Using the final domestic expenditure price index, changes in real income are the sum of changes in real GDP (production) and relative price changes: (6) ln( Qt Qs) ln( pd, t pd, s)= ln( yt ys Real Income Change Change in Real GDP ) + ( p p ) ( p p ) ln t s ln D, t D, s. Change in Relative Prices ( Trading Gain) The relative price changes are referred to as a trading gain and represent the benefit/loss that an open economy receives from changes in price structures related to traded items. 1 1 In the literature surrounding the System of National Accounts (SNA) the trading gain is derived from deflating net exports directly rather than using an implicit price deflator. The SNA presents several options for deflating net exports, including import prices, export prices, an average of import and export prices, or a final domestic expenditure price index. No consensus has been reached about which method is most satisfactory (see Stuvel, 1956; Nicholson, 1960; Geary, 1961; Courbis, 1969; Kurabayashi, 1971; Denison, 1981; Silver and Mahdavy, 1989; SNA, 1993; Kohli, 2006a). Currently the Bureau of Economic Analysis in the United States calculates a command basis GDP that is equivalent to the real GDI discussed in the SNA using an import price deflator. A command GDP measure is also available from the Penn World Tables annually up to

5 (7) ( ) = ( ) ( ) ln Tt Ts ln pt ps ln pd, t pd, s. Change in Trading Gain Change in Relative Prices Kohli (2006a) shows that the trading gain based on a final domestic expenditure deflator can be decomposed into a terms of trade contribution and a real exchange rate contribution: (8) ln( Tt Ts) = Change in Trading Gain νxt, + νmt, 2 Average Share of Trade in GDP Terms of Trade Changes ( ) ln( ToTt ToTs) + ν ν Xt, Mt, ln( RERt RERs). Share of Net Exports in GDP Real Exchange Rate Changes Where changes in the terms of trade are calculated as the difference between export and import price changes: (9) ( )= ( ) ln ( p ) Mt, PMs, ln ToTt ToTs ln px, t px, s Terms of Trade Changes Export Price Index Changes. Import Price Index Changes And, changes in the real exchange rate are calculated as the difference between the average change in traded goods prices and domestic prices. (10) 1 ln( px, t px, s)+ ln( pm, t PMs, ) ln( RERt RERs)= 2 Export Price Index Import Price Index Changes Changes Real Exchange Rate Changes ( ) ln p D, t PD, s. Final Domestic Expenditure Price Index Changes The real exchange rate defined here is not the usual measure of the real exchange rate used in the macroeconomic literature. The more commonly employed real exchange rate adjusts a nations nominal exchange rate for domestic price differences. The real exchange rate defined here, as Kohli (2006a) notes, is consistent with the real exchange rate defined in what has become known as the Australian model (see Salter, 1959; Corden, 1960; Swan, 1960). It is also consistent with balance of payments theory since, as Corden (1992) notes, the Australian model was used by Dornbusch (1974, 1980) to integrate money into balance of payments theory, and with the booming sector, or Dutch disease, model of Corden and Neary (1982) and Corden (1984). The real GDI measure defined using the final domestic expenditure deflator is, therefore, a general equilibrium real income concept. 3. Data and Methods Calculations use national accounts data collected by the OECD. For each country the most recent data vintage is employed. This limits the span of the data for many countries. As a result, long-run calculations are reported only for 502

6 Australia, Canada, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Calculations covering the resource boom employ the widest sample of countries possible. The national accounts data contains information on private consumption, gross fixed capital formation, public consumption, and exports and imports. The domestic expenditure deflator is not provided by the OECD. It is calculated from the published data by removing the influence of export and import prices from the GDP deflator. Labor productivity measures by country are taken from the OECD. These data extend back, at most, to 1970 and in many cases cover a shorter time span. For Australia, Canada, the United Kingdom, and the United States, the data starting in 1970 are employed. For all other nations except Turkey, data for the period are available. The OECD does not provide a labor productivity measure for Turkey. Where it appears in analysis, only real GDP and real GDI are employed. Population data from the OECD are used to scale estimates of real GDP and real GDI when international comparisons are made, or where labor productivity is compared with real income statistics. Per capita measures are reported because growth in per capita terms provides a more accurate reflection of changes in living standards across countries. Per capita measures are also more appropriate for comparing with labor productivity. Trade data used to construct a measure of resource sensitivity are taken from the OECD trade database. Trade data contain information about nominal expenditures on different types of goods only. Data on resource prices are taken from the Bank of Canada s commodity price index. The index is comprised of US$ prices for a wide range of commodities (see Hirsch, 2003 for details). Because the trading gain is comprised of relative price ratios, the U.S. durable goods CPI from the Bureau of Labor Statistics is used to scale commodity prices. 4. Real GDP and Labor Productivity vs. Real GDI The years are particularly important for examining real GDI per capita changes because they cover the largest commodity boom since the end of the Second World War. The influence of commodity price changes is larger and more apparent post-2002 than at almost any time in the previous 45 years. As a consequence, real GDP per capita and labor productivity are less than ideal for understanding how the standard of living was adjusting during this period. Between 2003 and 2007, differences between real GDP per capita, labor productivity, and real GDI per capita growth arise in many OECD nations (Table 1). Real GDI per capita in resource rich, commodity exporting countries like Australia or Norway outpaces growth in real GDP per capita and labor productivity growth. In manufacturing centered, commodity importing nations like Japan or the United States, real GDP per capita and labor productivity rise faster than real GDI per capita. The different performances between measures stems in large part from terms of trade changes. The trading gain decomposition in equation (8) illustrates why. The impact of terms of trade changes on real income is proportional to the average 503

7 TABLE 1 Average Annual Real GDP, Real GDI, and Labor Productivity Growth, Labor Productivity Real GDP Per Capita Real GDI Per Capita Australia 1.2% 2.0% 3.4% Austria 1.8% 1.9% 1.8% Belgium 1.4% 1.7% 1.5% Canada 0.9% 1.7% 2.9% Czech Republic 4.6% 5.2% 5.1% Denmark 1.5% 1.8% 2.0% Finland 2.5% 3.1% 2.2% France 1.4% 1.3% 1.2% Germany 1.2% 1.5% 1.3% Greece 2.3% 3.9% 4.2% Hungary 3.7% 3.8% 3.4% Iceland 2.6% 3.6% 3.6% Ireland 2.4% 3.3% 1.8% Italy 0.0% 0.6% 0.5% Japan 2.0% 2.0% 1.4% Korea 4.5% 4.0% 2.8% Luxembourg 2.7% 3.2% 4.9% Netherlands 0.8% 2.0% 1.9% New Zealand 1.0% 1.9% 2.7% Norway 1.2% 2.0% 4.8% Poland 3.0% 5.1% 5.5% Portugal 1.5% 0.5% 0.6% Slovak Republic 5.1% 6.8% 6.3% Spain 1.0% 1.8% 1.9% Sweden 2.3% 2.7% 2.5% Switzerland 1.0% 1.6% 1.2% Turkey NA 6.3% 6.5% United Kingdom 2.1% 2.1% 2.2% United States 1.8% 1.8% 1.6% share of imports and exports in GDP while the impact of the real exchange rate is proportional to the share of net exports in GDP. Consequently, the more open a country is to trade, the more susceptible it is to terms of trade changes, while the larger a country s trade imbalance, the more susceptible it is to real exchange rate movements. On average across the OECD, the share of exports and imports in GDP between 2003 and 2007 is 44.5 percent, while the average absolute trade balance in GDP is 5.5 percent (Table 2). This roughly translates into terms of trade shifts being an order of magnitude more important for real income growth than real exchange rate changes, but about half as important as changes in production (real GDP), which has a unitary weight in the real GDI decomposition in equation (6). Most nations have an average share of imports and exports in GDP between 25 and 50 percent. However, there are some nations where real income will be more sensitive terms of trade changes, particularly Luxembourg (143.7 percent), Belgium (83.1 percent), the Slovak Republic (79.6), and the Czech Republic (69.5 percent). There are also nations where real income will be less sensitive to terms of trade shifts, notably the United States (13.0 percent) and Japan (13.3 percent). The share of net exports in GDP tends to be between 5 and 15 percent, but there are some exceptions, like Luxembourg (26.2 percent) or Italy (0.1 percent). 504

8 TABLE 2 Relative Price Change Weights and Contributions to Real GDI Per Capita Growth, Weights in GDP ( ν + ν ) 2 ν ν Xt, Mt, ( ) Xt, Mt, Contributions to Real GDI Per Capita Real GDP Per Capita Terms of Trade Real Exchange Rate Australia 20.2% -1.9% 2.0% 1.4% 0.0% Austria 50.9% 4.3% 1.9% -0.1% 0.0% Belgium 83.1% 3.9% 1.7% -0.2% 0.0% Canada 36.0% 3.5% 1.7% 1.2% -0.1% Czech Republic 69.5% 1.2% 5.2% 0.0% 0.0% Denmark 46.1% 4.5% 1.8% 0.2% 0.0% Finland 38.6% 6.1% 3.1% -0.9% 0.0% France 26.3% -0.2% 1.3% -0.1% 0.0% Germany 37.8% 5.2% 1.5% -0.1% 0.0% Greece 27.6% -12.3% 3.9% 0.2% 0.1% Hungary 68.6% -1.4% 3.8% -0.4% 0.1% Iceland 38.0% -8.7% 3.6% 0.0% 0.0% Ireland 76.4% 13.6% 3.3% -1.0% -0.5% Italy 26.2% 0.1% 0.6% -0.1% 0.0% Japan 13.3% 1.5% 2.0% -0.7% 0.1% Korea 40.4% 2.2% 4.0% -1.1% -0.1% Luxembourg 143.7% 26.2% 3.2% 0.8% 0.9% Netherlands 64.5% 7.6% 2.0% -0.1% 0.0% New Zealand 29.6% -0.7% 1.9% 0.8% 0.0% Norway 35.8% 15.1% 2.0% 2.3% 0.6% Poland 37.7% -2.1% 5.1% 0.4% 0.0% Portugal 33.2% -7.9% 0.5% 0.0% 0.1% Slovak Republic 79.6% -3.4% 6.8% 0.6% 0.1% Spain 28.5% -4.5% 1.8% 0.1% 0.1% Sweden 43.9% 7.6% 2.7% -0.1% 0.0% Switzerland 44.8% 7.1% 1.6% -0.4% 0.0% Turkey 24.3% -2.8% 6.3% 0.1% 0.1% United Kingdom 27.8% -2.9% 2.1% 0.0% 0.0% United States 13.0% -5.2% 1.8% -0.2% 0.0% The preeminence of the terms of trade changes for real income growth behoves an examination of what drives terms of trade adjustments. Movements in the terms of trade for OECD countries over the period come from relative price movements between resources and manufactured products. For nations that are relatively resource rich, the terms of trade represent the opportunity cost of manufactured goods relative to resources, while for countries that are relatively resource poor, the terms of trade capture the opportunity cost of resources in terms of manufactured products. When resource booms occur, changes in the terms of trade redistribute purchasing power across countries. The size of the redistribution depends on a country s endowments, comparative advantages, and trade openness. Plotting the terms of trade adjustments that countries experienced between 2003 and 2007 from largest to smallest illustrates the nature of the redistribution that can occur as commodity prices rise (Figure 1). Resource exporting countries like Australia, Norway, Canada, and New Zealand experienced the largest terms of trade improvements, while resource importing nations like Japan, Korea, Finland, or the United States experienced terms of trade deteriorations. 505

9 Australia Norway Canada New Zealand Poland Greece Luxembourg Turkey Denmark Spain United Kingdom Czech Republic Portugal Netherlands Iceland Belgium Austria Germany Sweden Italy France Hungary Slovak Republic Switzerland United States Ireland Finland Korea Japan Figure 1. Terms of Trade Changes Across Countries A more formal way to illustrate the relationship between resources and terms of trade shifts is to construct a measure of how important resources are to trade flows, and then compare it with changes in the terms of trade. A resource sensitivity indicator, based on 1-digit Standard International Trade Classification Codes, is constructed here. The indicator is the difference between the share of resources in exports and the share of resources in imports: (11) X resources Mresources Resource Sensitivity = 1 1. X M total total Resource activities are defined as imports or exports of food and live animals; crude materials, inedible, except fuels; and mineral fuels, lubricants, and related materials. Data are drawn from the OECD trade database. A country that exports only resources and imports only manufactured products will have a score of 1, while a country that exports only manufactured products and imports only resources will have a score of -1. A country that does not trade in resources, or has an equal share of resources in imports and exports, will have a score of 0. When nations average resource sensitivity post-2002 is compared with their average terms of trade changes, a statistically significant, positive relationship emerges (Figure 2). Approximately two-thirds of the cross sectional variation in average terms of trade changes can be explained by the resource sensitivity 506

10 Average Terms of Trade Change 8% 4% y = 0.1x R2 = 0.68 Canada Australia Norway New Zealand 0% -4% Finland United States Korea Japan -8% -40% -30% -20% -1 0% 0% 1 0% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% Resource Sensitivity Figure 2. Resource Sensitivity vs. Terms of Trade Changes, measure. The nations that experience the largest terms of trade improvements are resource rich countries like Norway or Australia. Net importers of commodities, like Japan and Korea, experience the largest terms of trade deteriorations. 5. Real Income and Economic Aggregates In the short-run, changes in real income should translate into changes in economic aggregates. As production rises, and relative prices change, the volume of goods and services available to the domestic economy changes. Increasing real GDP and trading gain growth both signal that the volume of goods and services that may be consumed or invested is rising. Real consumption and real gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) can rise faster than real GDP as a result. If the trading gain works against real GDP, then real consumption and real GFCF rise less than real GDP. The importance of the trading gain for real income growth post-2002 should make it difficult to understand changes in real private consumption, real GFCF, or real government expenditures across OECD countries without including the trading gain. The relationship between economic aggregates and the trading gain can be illustrated using linear regressions. The average changes in real production (real GDP) and the trading gain are regressed on changes in real private consumption, real GFCF, and real government consumption. If the trading does contribute to changes in domestic expenditures, then it should have a statistically significant, positive, coefficient. Table 3 presents cross section regression results for OECD countries. 2 Variation in economic aggregate growth across OECD countries is related to changes in real GDP and changes in the trading gain. For real private consumption, the 2 An examination of residual values suggested that Luxembourg is an aberrant observation. It is removed from the dataset used for regressions. 507

11 TABLE 3 Regression Results for Annual Averages of OECD Countries, Real Private Consumption Real GFCF* Real Government Consumption* Intercept P-value (0.95) (0.67) (0.93) Real GDP Growth P-value (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) Trading Gain P-value (0.00) (0) (0.01) R-squared Observations Notes: *OECD databases do not have entries for real GFCF and real Government Consumption for Greece. An unreported dummy variable is used to account for the impact of the missing data. combination of real GDP growth and changes in the trading gain explains about three-quarters of variation across the OECD countries; about two-thirds of changes in real GFCF; and about half of the changes in real government consumption. For all of the real aggregates, the coefficient on the trading gain is positive and statistically significant at the 5 percent nominal level. 3 The results can be interpreted as follows. During the years , real GDP increased in all OECD countries. At the same time, the price of commodities rose sharply, affecting terms of trade. The purchasing power of output was redistributed across nations based on their endowments. Real consumption and real gross fixed capital formation advanced more than real production in resource rich nations. In resource net importers, rising commodity prices, particularly for energy, led to lower increases in real consumption and real gross fixed capital formation than changes in the volume of production Relative to the United States Changes in GDP per capita or labor productivity over time are often interpreted as being synonymous with changes in the living standards of an economy. Cross country comparisons are made by examining changes in one country relative to another. While this is instructive, only in the event that domestic and trade prices progress at the same rate, or that both economies are closed, will the real GDP per capita measures necessarily reflect relative real income changes. Similarly, cross country comparisons made using productivity measures to examine the relative changes in efficiency only reflect changes related to production. These 3 The elasticity estimates for government consumption suggest that governments benefit from trading gains. However, the model here is a reduced form equation, and the route through which this occurs is not explained in detail. Relative price changes are expected to affect government revenues through two main channels. In those nations where governments collect resource royalties, or where rising resource prices lead to higher profits, and hence higher income tax revenue, there will be a direct effect. A second channel arises because governments levy value added taxes on consumption. As relative prices adjust, the volume of consumption adjusts, leading to two, possibly offsetting movements. First the volume of consumption changes, which, ceteris paribus changes taxable expenditures. However, taxes are levied on nominal expenditures, so it is the combination of the price and volume that matter. These movements can be reinforcing or offsetting. 508

12 Density Falling behind the US Catching up to the US 0-1.7% -1.3% -0.8% -0.4% 0.1 % 0.6% 1.0% 1.5% 2.0% 2.4% 2.9% 3.3% 3.8% 4.3% Growth Rate Relative to the United States Labor Productivity Real GDP per capita Real GDI per capita Figure 3. Distributions of Relative Growth for Labor Productivity, Real GDP Per Capita, and Real GDI Per Capita types of comparisons are unable to incorporate the role of relative price changes on purchasing power and are, therefore, less comprehensive than comparisons made using real GDI per capita. Its ability to incorporate purchasing power changes into international comparisons makes real GDI per capita a more appropriate real income statistic for international comparisons between open economies. Here, all nations are examined relative to the United States for the period The United States is often viewed as the technological frontier, and a country s performance is measured against whether or not it is catching up to or falling behind the United States. Conclusions about the relative performance of the OECD nations varies depending on whether labor productivity, real GDP per capita, or real GDI per capita is used (Figure 3 and Table 4). 4 In resource exporting nations, labor productivity and real GDI provide different outcomes relative to the United States. Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and Norway all exhibit a pattern of declining relative labor productivity but rising relative real GDI per capita. In Japan the opposite pattern exists: relative labor productivity increased, but relative real GDI per capita declined. When the nations are treated as a statistical sample, the distribution of relative performance based on labor productivity is bunched around zero. Just under half of all OECD countries saw a gain in labor productivity relative to the United States during the years The distributions of GDP per capita and GDI per capita are flatter, and skewed to the right with more countries gaining ground on the United States. When labor productivity is used as the metric for comparison, 48 percent of countries progress more rapidly than the United States. When 4 Kohli (2006b) illustrates the effect of going from real GDP to real GDI for Hong Kong. His results show that growth in real income outpaces real GDP growth on average by 0.9 percentage points per year. 509

13 TABLE 4 Average Annual Growth Relative to the United States, Labor Productivity GDP Per Capita GDI Per Capita Australia -0.6% 0.2% 1.8% Austria 0.0% 0.1% 0.2% Belgium -0.4% -0.1% -0.1% Canada -0.9% -0.1% 1.2% Czech Republic 2.7% 3.4% 3.6% Denmark -0.3% 0.0% 0.4% Finland 0.7% 1.3% 0.6% France -0.4% -0.5% -0.4% Germany -0.6% -0.3% -0.3% Greece 0.5% 2.1% 2.6% Hungary 1.9% 2.0% 1.8% Iceland 0.8% 1.8% 2.0% Ireland 0.6% 1.5% 0.2% Italy -1.7% -1.2% -1.1% Japan 0.2% 0.2% -0.2% Korea 2.6% 2.2% 1.2% Luxembourg 0.8% 1.4% 3.4% Netherlands -1.0% 0.2% 0.3% New Zealand -0.8% 0.1% 1.1% Norway -0.6% 0.2% 3.3% Poland 1.2% 3.3% 3.9% Portugal -0.3% -1.2% -1.0% Slovak Republic 3.2% 5.1% 4.8% Spain -0.8% 0.0% 0.3% Sweden 0.5% 0.9% 0.9% Switzerland -0.8% -0.2% -0.4% Turkey NA 4.6% 5.0% United Kingdom 0.3% 0.3% 0.5% Note: Bold values indicate a decline relative to the United States. relative real GDP per capita is used, 71 percent of countries advance more rapidly, while when GDI per capita is used, three-quarters of countries in the sample grow faster than the United States. The speed with which nations gain or lose ground in the short run depends on the metric used for comparison. The smallest relative gains and losses occur when labor productivity is used. Moving to real GDP per capita and real GDI per capita increases the relative changes. On average, gainers go from a relative increase of 1.2 percent per year for labor productivity to 1.6 percent and 1.9 percent for real GDP per capita and real GDI per capita, respectively. Those losing ground go from an average relative decline of -0.7 percent per year for labor productivity to -0.5 percent for real GDP per capita and real GDI per capita. For the years , moving from relative labor productivity to relative GDP per capita or real GDI per capita changes the relative performance of roughly 20 percent of OECD countries in the sample. Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Norway, and Spain go from losing ground to gaining ground, while Japan goes from gaining ground to losing ground. The metric employed alters perceptions of how a nation is performing, as well as how quickly it is catching up or falling behind. 510

14 6. Real GDP and Labor Productivity vs. Real GDI in the Long Run Between 2003 and 2007, the trading gain was an unprecedented source of real income growth that accelerated or decelerated changes in real GDI per capita relative to labor productivity and real GDP per capita. While resource prices led to significant relative price shocks in the past, notably during the oil shocks of the 1970s, their influence during the years is anomalous, as is the divergence that occurred between metrics used to compare economic performance across nations. When labor productivity, real GDP per capita, and real GDI per capita are viewed over longer time spans, the unusual nature of the years becomes apparent. The performance of Australia, Canada, and the United Kingdom relative to the United States for the period is used to illustrate the historically large impact of the trading gain post These are the four counties in the OECD database where the latest data vintage extends back to For all four countries the average annual growth rates of real GDP and real GDI are virtually identical over long time spans and do not differ greatly form long-run labor productivity growth (Table 5). Over shorter time spans differences emerge as the trading gain accelerates or decelerates real GDI growth. During the 1970s and post-2002 the trading gain is a particularly important source of real income growth. During the 1970s, real GDI growth accelerated relative to real GDP in Canada, and decelerated to real GDP in Australia, the United Kingdom, and the United States. During the 1980s and 1990s, real GDI growth fluctuates around real GDP growth. Over a period of several years real GDI will rise faster than real GDP only to fall back later. The pattern of more rapid and slower relative growth is repeated across decades for all four countries. After 2002, the largest divergence on record occurs. In Australia and Canada, real GDI growth outpaces real GDP growth, while in the United States real GDI growth does not keep pace with real GDP growth. In the United Kingdom there was little difference in real GDP and real GDI growth rates. The cyclical nature of the trading gain leads to higher volatility for real GDI than production based measures. The standard deviation of real GDI growth is higher than the standard deviation of labor productivity or real GDP per capita for all nations (Table 6). Allowing for relative price induced purchasing power changes leads to a real income measure that implies greater uncertainty for economic agents. Across countries, the starkest difference emerges for the resource exporting countries Australia and Canada. Over the long run, their real GDP per capita, real GDI per capita, and labor productivity progressed at similar rates, but with noteworthy differences in uncertainty across measures. Over the short run, real GDI per capita outpaces and then lags behind real GDP growth repeatedly, and in a predictable fashion. During periods when commodity prices rise, real GDI per capita tended to accelerate in Canada and Australia and decelerate in the United States. When commodity prices weakened, real GDI per capita performed well relative to real GDP per capita in the United States, and poorly relative to real GDP per capita in Australia and Canada. The 1970s oil shocks, the 1986 energy 511

15 TABLE 5 Real GDP Growth vs. Real GDI Growth, , for Australia, Canada, the United Kingdom, and the United States Australia Real GDP 2.2% 1.8% 3.1% 1.3% 1.7% 2.0% 1.9% 2.6% 2.0% Real GDI 2.3% 1.9% 3.1% 1.1% 1.3% 2.7% 1.8% 2.8% 3.4% Labor Productivity 1.7% 1.8% 1.4% 0.4% 2.5% 2.1% 1.2% Canada Real GDP 2.3% 1.9% 3.3% 2.9% 1.7% 1.5% 1.0% 2.9% 1.7% Real GDI 2.4% 2.2% 3.3% 3.2% 1.6% 1.9% 0.9% 2.8% 3.0% Labor Productivity 1.4% 2.0% 1.0% 0.6% 1.6% 2.0% 0.9% United Kingdom Real GDP 2.2% 2.2% 2.3% 2.2% 1.8% 2.9% 1.8% 2.8% 2.1% Real GDI 2.2% 2.2% 2.4% 1.5% 2.0% 3.1% 1.9% 3.0% 2.1% Labor Productivity 2.3% 2.3% 2.3% 1.0% 2.4% 2.3% 2.1% United States Real GDP 2.2% 2.0% 3.1% 2.4% 1.9% 2.2% 1.6% 1.8% 1.8% Real GDI 2.1% 1.9% 3.1% 2.1% 1.8% 2.0% 1.7% 1.9% 1.5% Labor Productivity 1.6% 1.5% 1.4% 1.0% 1.4% 2.3% 1.8% 512

16 TABLE 6 Percentage Point Standard Deviations of Growth Rates, * Labor Productivity Real GDP Per Capita Real GDI Per Capita Australia Canada United Kingdom United States Note: *Real GDP per capita and real GDI per capita over the entire sample period show a similar increase in volatility between production and purchasing power adjusted real income measures. Index 2002= GDP per capita GDI per capita Labor Productivity Figure 4. Long-Run Economic Performance: Australia Relative to United States price collapse, and the post-2002 commodity boom are all periods when real GDI per capita and real GDP per capita growth rates diverged. For Australia and Canada, the performance of their respective economies relative to the United States over long periods of time tended to be determined by movements associated with production from 1961 to 2001 (Figures 4 and 5). Movements in relative GDI per capita followed the same pattern as movements in relative real GDP per capita. While trading gains led to larger relative changes in GDI per capita, particularly during the first and second oil shocks, ultimately it was changes in inputs and productivity that drove differences in relative economic performance. After 2001, terms of trade improvements for Australia and Canada, coupled with terms of trade deteriorations for the United States, led to a divergence between relative labor productivity, GDP per capita, and GDI per capita. Labor productivity in the resource rich nations failed to keep pace with labor productivity growth in the United States, but real GDP per capita kept pace. Real GDI per capita for Australia and Canada, on the other hand, shows gains relative to the United States between 2002 and The long-run analysis implies that commodity price cycles have been an important source of real income fluctuations in developed countries for an 513

17 Index 2002= GDP per capital GDI per capita Labor Productivity Figure 5. Long-Run Economic Performance: Canada Relative to United States extended period of time. One way to illustrate the influence of resource cycles for terms of trade shifts is to examine the relationship between terms of trade and commodity prices for individual countries over time. Because the contention is that the terms of trade reflect the price of commodities relative to manufactured goods, a relative commodity price is employed. The commodity price index employed here covers a wide range of primary commodities priced in United States dollars (see Hirsch, 2003 for details). To generate a relative commodity price free from the influences of nominal exchange rate fluctuations, the United States CPI durable manufactured goods price index is used as a U.S. dollar measure of manufacturing prices to scale the commodity price index. Canada and Australia export a variety of commodities, which makes their terms of trade sensitive to price changes in many different types of primary products, while the United States imports many commodities, but is particularly sensitive to energy prices. 5 Between 1961 and 2007, the terms of trade for Australia and Canada followed regular commodity price cycles (Figure 6) and did not have a long-run effect on real income growth. The cyclical nature of commodity price changes led to alternating terms of trade improvements and deteriorations, which increased the volatility of real income but did not affect its trend. Between 1961 and 2007, the terms of trade for the United States reflected changes in the relative price of energy. The two largest terms of trade shifts 5 The Bank of Canada Commodity Price Index is used as a measure of resource prices. It captures movements in primary resource prices using weights appropriate for Canada. It is not the ideal measure of the commodity prices for Australia. Nevertheless, because Australia and Canada export a wide range of commodities, the index follows shifts in global commodity demand that are relevant for both countries. Similarly, the energy price index used to illustrate the relationship between U.S. terms of trade and energy prices is a sub-index of the Bank of Canada Commodity Price Index. While not ideal, it does capture the relevant energy price changes affecting the United States. 514

18 Terms of Trade (2002 = 100) Commodity Price Index / US Durables CPI Australia Canada Commodity Price Index / US Durables CPI Figure 6. Commodity Prices/U.S. Durables CPI vs. Terms of Trade for Australia and Canada Terms of Trade (2002 = 100) Energy Commodities / Durables CPI United States Energy Commodity Price Index / US Durables CPI 0 Figure 7. Energy Prices/U.S. Durables CPI vs. Terms of Trade for United States occurred during the oil shocks (Figure 7). The cumulative effect of the supply disruptions was a 35.2 percent deterioration in the United States terms of trade between 1970 and Unlike the cyclical movements in Australia and Canada, the majority of the deterioration in the United States was permanent. 6 In addition to the oil shocks, energy prices also rose sharply during the resource boom. However, the increase in energy prices did not have as large an 6 In the U.K., the first oil shock led to a 20.6 percent deterioration in the terms of trade between 1972 and The majority of the decline was unwound by the late 1970s, and the second oil shock did not generate a second due to energy exports from newly developed North Sea deposits. 515

19 impact on the United States terms of trade which declined 5.8 percent between 2002 and One reason why a difference may appear is described in Reinsdorf (2008). He argues that prices of non-energy imports supported the terms of trade during the years , partially offsetting the effect of rising energy prices. A second reason may be that energy prices did not rise by as much after From 1972 to 1981, the oil shocks led to a 720 percent rise in energy prices. From 2002 to 2007, energy prices rose 146 percent, less than a third of the increase during the oil shocks. If 1998, rather than 2002, is used as the low-point in energy price cycles, then the increase in energy prices rises to 328 percent, which is still less than half of the rise that the oil shocks of the 1970s generated. The real exchange rate can also be influenced by commodity price fluctuations, and although its effects may be more muted due to its relatively low weight in the GDI decomposition, its long run impact behavior still entreats examination. Changes in the real exchange rate over long periods of time reflect differential changes between goods and services sectors. While there is trade in services, the majority of traded items are goods. As a result, the composition of domestic purchases is weighted more toward services than the composition of traded items. Because traded items include commodities whose prices are cyclical, but without a trend, and because manufactured goods prices fall relative to services over time, traded prices do not rise as quickly as domestic prices. The real exchange rate, therefore, tends to decline over long periods. The profitability of traded and non-traded sectors changes as the real exchange rate changes. A declining real exchange rate acts to raise investment and employment in non-traded industries relative to traded industries (Corden and Neary, 1982). Shifts in the real exchange rate, in addition to their short-run influence on real income growth, influence changes in an economy s productive activity. Over shorter periods of time, movements in commodity prices and currencies can eclipse the long-run determinants of real exchange rate change. Oil shocks, currency crises, and commodity booms all lead to real exchange rate changes in the short run. In many cases, periods of real exchange rate increase are accompanied by increased uncertainty and unemployment. In Australia, Canada, and the United States, the oil shocks lead to real exchange rate increases in and an increase in (Figure 8) Conclusion In a world where international trade is an important activity, real income depends not only on the volume of production, but also on the volume of goods and services that production commands on world markets. A country may appear to better its income levels when a production based real income measure, like real GDP per capita, is used. However, if it produces items whose relative price is declining, it may not see much of an increase in the purchasing power of that income. Measures of real income that incorporate production and purchasing power changes can be formed from widely available national income statistics. Real GDI per capita is one such measure. 7 The first oil shock led to an increase in the real exchange rate for the U.K. In Korea, the oil shocks and the 1997 Asian Financial Crises lead to increases of the real exchange rate. 516

20 Index 2002 = First Oil Shock Second Oil Shock Australia Canada United States Figure 8. Real Exchange Rate Over Time: Select Countries Purchasing power is measured through a trading gain, which is composed of two related relative prices: the terms of trade, and the real exchange rate. The terms of trade is the ratio of export to import prices, and the real exchange rate is the ratio of the geometric mean of export and import prices to an index of final domestic expenditures. The terms of trade are an order of magnitude more important for real income growth than the real exchange rate for most OECD countries. The terms of trade are basically capturing a trade-off between resources and manufactured products. During the commodity boom, terms of trade changes redistributed purchasing power across the OECD: resource rich nations tended to experience increases in real consumption or real gross fixed capital formation that outpaced growth in real GDP, while resource net importers tended to experience increases in real consumption and real gross fixed capital formation that lagged behind real GDP growth. The relationship between the terms of trade and resource prices, and the effect of relative price shifts on real income growth across the OECD from 2003 to 2007, produced a short-run boost in real income growth that was large by historical standards. During the commodity boom, being a resource rich, resource exporting nation was beneficial. However, during periods when resource prices decline relative to other prices, resource rich nations will face difficulties turning production into consumption and investment. Moving to real GDI not only affects the interpretation of economic aggregates, and the role of resources in economic growth, but also influences the outcomes of international comparisons. Comparing measures of GDP per capita or labor productivity across countries over time can generate different results from trading gain adjusted real income measures during periods of rapid relative price change. 517

21 References Corden, W. M., The Geometric Representation of Policies to Attain Internal and External Balance, Review of Economic Studies, 28, 1 22, 1960., Booming Sector and Dutch Disease Economics: Survey and Consolidation, Oxford Economics Papers, 36, , 1984., Dependent Economy Model of the Balance of Payments, New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, Macmillan, London, Corden, W. M. and J. P. Neary, Booming Sector and De-Industrialization in a Small Open Economy, Economic Journal, 92, , Courbis, R. W., Compatabilitié nationale à prix constants et à la productivitié constant, Review of Income and Wealth, 15, 33 76, Denison, Edward F., International Transactions in Measures of the Nation s Production, Survey of Current Business, 61(5), 17 28, Diewert, E. W., Superlative Index Numbers and Consistency in Aggregation, Econometrica, 46, , Diewert, E. W. and C. J. Morrison, Adjusting Output and Productivity Indexes for Changes in the Terms of Trade, Economic Journal, 96, , Dornbusch, R., Real Monetary Aspects of the Effect of Exchange Rate Changes, in R. Z. Aliber (ed.), National Monetary Policies and the International Financial System, Chicago University Press, Chicago, 1974., Open Economy Macroeconomics, Basic Books, New York, Fox, K., U. Kohli, and R. Warren, Accounting for Growth and Output Gaps: Evidence from New Zealand, Economic Record, 78, , Francis, M., The Effect of China on Global Prices, Bank of Canada Review, 13, 25, Autumn Geary, R. C., Problems in Deflation of National Accounts: Introduction, Review of Income and Wealth, 9, 3 8, Hirsch, Todd, Updating the Bank of Canada Commodity Price Index, Bank of Canada Review, 31 3, Spring Hulten, C., Total Factor Productivity: A Short Biography, in C. R. Hulten, E. R. Dean, and M. J. Harper (eds), New Developments in Productivity Analysis, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Kohli, U., Real GDP, Real Domestic Income, and Terms of Trade Changes, Journal of International Economics, 62, , 2004., Real GDP, Real GDI, and Trading Gains: Canada, , International Productivity Monitor, No. 13, 46 56, Fall 2006a., Terms of Trade Changes, Real GDP and Real Value Added in the Open Economy: Reassessing Hong Kong s Growth Performance, Working Paper No. 5/2006, Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research, 2006b. Kurabayashi, Y., The Impact of Terms of Trade on a System of National Accounts: An Attempted Synthesis, Review of Income and Wealth, 17, , Nicholson, J. L., The Effects of International Trade on the Measurement of Real National Income, Economics Journal, 70, , Reinsdorf, M., Measuring the Effects of Changes in the Terms of Trade on Incomes, Exports and Prices, Presentation to the BEA Advisory Committee, November 7, Rodgers, M., A Survey of Economic Growth, Economic Record, 29, , Salter, W. E. G., Internal and External Balance: The Role of Price and Expenditure Effects, Economic Record, 35, , Silver, M. and K. Mahdavy, The Measurement of a Nation s Terms of Trade Effect and Real National Disposable Income Within a National Accounting Framework, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A, 152, , SNA, System of National Accounts, Commission of the European Communities/Eurostat, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, United Nations Secretariat, World Bank, Stuvel, G., A New Approach to Measurement of Terms of Trade Effects, Review of Economic Statistics, August, , Swan, T. E., Economic Control in a Dependent Economy, Economic Record, 36, 51 66, Tornqvist, L., The Bank of Finland s Consumption Price Index, Bank of Finland Monthly Bulletin, No. 10, 1 8,

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy ECO 209Y Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Lecture 3: Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Income Gustavo Indart Slide 1 Assumptions We will assume that: There is no depreciation There are no indirect taxes

More information

Aviation Economics & Finance

Aviation Economics & Finance Aviation Economics & Finance Professor David Gillen (University of British Columbia )& Professor Tuba Toru-Delibasi (Bahcesehir University) Istanbul Technical University Air Transportation Management M.Sc.

More information

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions Statistical annex Sources and definitions Most of the statistics shown in these tables can be found as well in several other (paper or electronic) publications or references, as follows: the annual edition

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016 FISCAL FACT No. 517 July, 2016 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016 By Kyle Pomerleau Director of Federal Projects Kevin Adams Research Assistant Key Findings OECD countries rely heavily on

More information

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries OECD Centres Germany Berlin (49-30) 288 8353 Japan Tokyo (81-3) 5532-0021 Mexico Mexico (52-55) 5281 3810 United States Washington (1-202) 785 6323 AUSTRALIA AUSTRIA BELGIUM CANADA CZECH REPUBLIC DENMARK

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY Neil R. Mehrotra Brown University Peterson Institute for International Economics November 9th, 2017 1 / 13 PUBLIC DEBT AND PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

More information

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016 Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to.4% in the third quarter of 26 Growth in unit labour costs (ULCs) in the OECD area slowed to.4% in the third quarter of 26 (compared with.6% in the previous quarter)

More information

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate, 8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate, 1975-2005 2005 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 Australia 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 47% 48% 49% 49% Austria

More information

OECD Health Policy Unit. 10 June, 2001

OECD Health Policy Unit. 10 June, 2001 The State of Implementation of the OECD Manual: A System of Health Accounts (SHA) in OECD Member Countries, 2001 OECD Health Policy Unit 10 June, 2001 TABLE OF CONTENTS Summary...3 Introduction...4 Background

More information

Payroll Taxes in Canada from 1997 to 2007

Payroll Taxes in Canada from 1997 to 2007 Payroll Taxes in Canada from 1997 to 2007 This paper describes the changes in the structure of payroll taxes in Canada and the provinces during the period 1997-2007. We report the average payroll tax per

More information

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014 UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session Geneva, 15 26 September 2014 Item 3: High-level segment Tackling inequality through trade and development:

More information

Chapter 12 Government and Fiscal Policy

Chapter 12 Government and Fiscal Policy [2] Alan Greenspan, New challenges for monetary policy, speech delivered before a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City in Jackson Hole, Wyoming, on August 27, 1999. Mr. Greenspan

More information

Exchange Rates in the Long Run

Exchange Rates in the Long Run Exchange Rates in the Long Run What determines exchange rates? Supply + Demand!» Flow models: Demand & supply of FX to purchase goods and services» Stock models, or asset models Demand & supply of available

More information

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US.

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US. A nation s economic growth is determined by the rate of utilisation of the factors of production capital and labour and the efficiency of their use. Traditionally, economic growth in Europe has been characterised

More information

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI:   ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012 OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/9789264169401-en ISBN 978-92-64-16939-5 (print) ISBN 978-92-64-16940-1 (PDF) OECD 2012 Corrigendum Page 21: Figure 1.1. Average annual real net investment

More information

WikiLeaks Document Release

WikiLeaks Document Release WikiLeaks Document Release February 2, 2009 Congressional Research Service Report RL34073 Productivity and National Standards of Living Brian W. Cashell, Government and Finance Division July 5, 2007 Abstract.

More information

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth Lorenzo Burlon August 11, 2014 In this note we report the empirical exercises we conducted to motivate the theoretical insights

More information

ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. World Economy Autumn No. 33 (2017 Q3) KIEL INSTITUTE NO. 33 (2017 Q3)

ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. World Economy Autumn No. 33 (2017 Q3) KIEL INSTITUTE NO. 33 (2017 Q3) KIEL INSTITUTE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK World Economy Autumn 7 Finalized September 6, 7 No. 33 (7 Q3) Klaus-Jürgen Gern, Philipp Hauber, Stefan Kooths, Galina Potjagailo, and Ulrich Stolzenburg Forecasting Center

More information

Who Gains Most from Trade?

Who Gains Most from Trade? Who Gains Most from Trade? Ulrich Kohli* December 2014 Abstract Although all nations engaged in international trade should benefit from it, the gains from trade vary through time as changes in the terms

More information

THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS

THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS NOV 17 1 THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS by Teresa Ghilarducci, Bernard L. and Irene Schwartz Professor of Economics at The New School for Social Research and Director of the Schwartz

More information

American healthcare: How do we measure up?

American healthcare: How do we measure up? American healthcare: How do we measure up? December 2009 September 2009 Lauren Damme Economic Growth Program Next Social Contract Initiative The U.S. is one of the only industrialized nations in the world

More information

American healthcare: How do we measure up?

American healthcare: How do we measure up? American healthcare: How do we measure up? December 2009 September 2009 Lauren Damme Economic Growth Program Next Social Contract Initiative The U.S. is one of the only industrialized nations in the world

More information

RECENT EVOLUTION AND OUTLOOK OF THE MEXICAN ECONOMY BANCO DE MÉXICO OCTOBER 2003

RECENT EVOLUTION AND OUTLOOK OF THE MEXICAN ECONOMY BANCO DE MÉXICO OCTOBER 2003 OCTOBER 23 RECENT EVOLUTION AND OUTLOOK OF THE MEXICAN ECONOMY BANCO DE MÉXICO 2 RECENT DEVELOPMENTS OUTLOOK MEDIUM-TERM CHALLENGES 3 RECENT DEVELOPMENTS In tandem with the global economic cycle, the Mexican

More information

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE 7. FINANCES OF RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE Key results Public spending on pensions has been on the rise in most OECD countries for the past decades, as

More information

Measuring National Output and National Income. Gross Domestic Product. National Income and Product Accounts

Measuring National Output and National Income. Gross Domestic Product. National Income and Product Accounts C H A P T E R 18 Measuring National Output and National Income Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano Gross Domestic Product Gross domestic product (GDP) is the total market value of all final

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014 FISCAL FACT Nov. 2014 No. 443 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014 By Kyle Pomerleau Economist Key Findings OECD countries rely heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value added tax, and

More information

Session 16. Review Session

Session 16. Review Session Session 16. Review Session The long run [Fundamentals] Output, saving, and investment Money and inflation Economic growth Labor markets The short run [Business cycles] What are the causes business cycles?

More information

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government?

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government? What are the sources of revenue for the federal government? FEDERAL BUDGET 1/4 Q. What are the sources of revenue for the federal government? A. About 48 percent of federal revenue comes from individual

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017 FISCAL FACT No. 558 Aug. 2017 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017 Amir El-Sibaie Analyst Key Findings: OECD countries rely heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value-added tax, and social

More information

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018 FISCAL FACT No. 581 Mar. 2018 Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018 Amir El-Sibaie Analyst Key Findings In 2015, OECD countries relied heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value-added tax,

More information

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States Usable Productivity Growth in the United States An International Comparison, 1980 2005 Dean Baker and David Rosnick June 2007 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Suite

More information

Statistical Annex ANNEX

Statistical Annex ANNEX ISBN 92-64-02384-4 OECD Employment Outlook Boosting Jobs and Incomes OECD 2006 ANNEX Statistical Annex Sources and definitions Most of the statistics shown in these tables can be found as well in three

More information

Capital Cost Recovery across the OECD, 2018

Capital Cost Recovery across the OECD, 2018 FISCAL FACT No. 590 May 2018 Capital Cost Recovery across the OECD, 2018 Amir El-Sibaie Economist Key Findings A capital allowance is the percentage of total investment that a business can recover through

More information

San Francisco Retiree Health Care Trust Fund Education Materials on Public Equity

San Francisco Retiree Health Care Trust Fund Education Materials on Public Equity M E K E T A I N V E S T M E N T G R O U P 5796 ARMADA DRIVE SUITE 110 CARLSBAD CA 92008 760 795 3450 fax 760 795 3445 www.meketagroup.com The Global Equity Opportunity Set MSCI All Country World 1 Index

More information

Figure 1: Growth in GDP per capita. Italy. Germany

Figure 1: Growth in GDP per capita. Italy. Germany 199: NEW PARADIGM OR NEW PARASITISM? Alan Freeman Introduction This paper is an incomplete version of a paper which will address the current state of the US and its relation to the world economy, investigating

More information

WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION?

WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION? INDICATOR WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION? Not only does education pay off for individuals ly, but the public sector also from having a large proportion of tertiary-educated individuals

More information

Health Care in Crisis

Health Care in Crisis Health Care in Crisis The Economic Imperative for Health Care Reform James Kvaal and Ben Furnas February 19, 2009 1 Center for American Progress Health Care in Crisis U.S. spends twice as much per capita

More information

Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset

Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset Stefan Thewissen,BrianNolan, and Max Roser April 2016 1Introduction How widely are the benefits of economic growth shared in advanced societies? Are the gains only

More information

Financial Implications of an Ageing Population

Financial Implications of an Ageing Population Financial Implications of an Ageing Population Presentation to Aged & Community Care Victoria s State Congress and Trade Exhibition Saul Eslake Chief Economist ANZ Flemington Racecourse Melbourne 25 th

More information

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons Standard Note: SN/EP/3235 Last updated: 15 October 2008 Author: Bryn Morgan Economic Policy & Statistics Section This note presents data comparing the national

More information

PMI Quarterly on China Manufacturing

PMI Quarterly on China Manufacturing China Federation of Logistics & Purchasing China Federation of Logistics & Purchasing (CFLP) is the logistics and purchasing industry association approved by the State Council. CFLP s mission is to push

More information

PMI Quarterly on China Manufacturing

PMI Quarterly on China Manufacturing China Federation of Logistics & Purchasing China Federation of Logistics & Purchasing (CFLP) is the logistics and purchasing industry association approved by the State Council. CFLP s mission is to push

More information

Economics Program Working Paper Series

Economics Program Working Paper Series Economics Program Working Paper Series Projecting Economic Growth with Growth Accounting Techniques: The Conference Board Global Economic Outlook 2012 Sources and Methods Vivian Chen Ben Cheng Gad Levanon

More information

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President Jason Furman Senior Fellow, PIIE SNS/SHOF Finance Panel Stockholm June 12, 2017 Peterson Institute for International Economics 1750

More information

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015 FISCAL FACT Apr. 2015 No. 465 Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015 By Kyle Pomerleau Economist Key Findings OECD countries rely heavily on consumption taxes, such as the value added tax,

More information

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point A Web-Appendix A.1 Information on data sources Individual level responses on benefit morale, tax morale, age, sex, marital status, children, education (captured by the school leaving age), household income

More information

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD Approach to (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD The benefits of protection can be divided in three main groups. The cash benefits include disability pensions, survivor's pensions and other short-

More information

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018. The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, th September 08. This note reports estimates of the economic impact of introducing a carbon tax of 50 per ton of CO in the Netherlands.

More information

Tax background paper. National Reform Summit John Daley, Grattan Institute August 2015

Tax background paper. National Reform Summit John Daley, Grattan Institute August 2015 Tax background paper National Reform Summit John Daley, Grattan Institute August 215 Summary Budget repair should include some tax increases Australia has small government by international standards Using

More information

Budget repair and the changing size of Australia s government. Crawford Australian Leadership Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute June 2016

Budget repair and the changing size of Australia s government. Crawford Australian Leadership Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute June 2016 Budget repair and the changing size of Australia s government Crawford Australian Leadership Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute June 2016 Commonwealth expenditure is high relative to history; revenue

More information

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017 FISCAL FACT No. 557 Aug. 2017 A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017 Jose Trejos Research Assistant Kyle Pomerleau Economist, Director of Federal Projects Key Findings: Average wage

More information

PMI Quarterly on China Manufacturing

PMI Quarterly on China Manufacturing China Federation of Logistics & Purchasing China Federation of Logistics & Purchasing (CFLP) is the logistics and purchasing industry association approved by the State Council. CFLP s mission is to push

More information

UK trade long-term trends and recent developments

UK trade long-term trends and recent developments UK trade long-term trends and recent developments By Andrew Dumble of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. This article examines why UK trade performance matters; in particular, it considers

More information

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people Press release Date 9 November 2015 Contact Mihnea Anastasiu Pages 5 Media Relations Manager Tel: +40 21 225 3546 Email: mihnea.anastasiu@ro.pwc.com Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index

More information

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD Revenue Statistics 2017 Tax revenue trends in the OECD OECD 2017 The OECD freely authorises the use of this material for non-commercial purposes, provided that suitable acknowledgment of the source and

More information

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary Low employment among the + population in Hungary The role of incentives, health and cognitive capacities Janos Divenyi (Central European University) and Gabor Kezdi (Central European University and IE-CRSHAS)

More information

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components Expert Journal of Economic s (2 0 1 3 ) 1, 13-18 2013 Th e Au thor. Publish ed by Sp rint In v estify. Econ omics.exp ertjou rn a ls.com Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components Simona

More information

External debt statistics of the euro area

External debt statistics of the euro area External debt statistics of the euro area Jorge Diz Dias 1 1. Introduction Based on newly compiled data recently released by the European Central Bank (ECB), this paper reviews the latest developments

More information

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK CENTRE OF PLANNING AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH Issue 29, February 2016 GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK Macroeconomic analysis and projections Public finance Human resources and social policies Development policies and

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries Davide Furceri University of Palermo Georgios Karras Uniersity of Illinois at Chicago Abstract The main purpose of this

More information

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES Nick Malyshev, OECD Conference on the Further Development of Impact Assessment in the European Union Brussels, RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES Regulatory Impact

More information

Fiscal Projections in OECD Countries: What is produced and what lessons can be learned?

Fiscal Projections in OECD Countries: What is produced and what lessons can be learned? Fiscal Projections in OECD Countries: What is produced and what lessons can be learned? James Sheppard Policy Analyst, Public Governance and Territorial Development Directorate Joint OECD-IPSASB Seminar

More information

DataWatch. International Health Care Expenditure Trends: 1987 by GeorgeJ.Schieber and Jean-Pierre Poullier

DataWatch. International Health Care Expenditure Trends: 1987 by GeorgeJ.Schieber and Jean-Pierre Poullier DataWatch International Health Care Expenditure Trends: 1987 by GeorgeJ.Schieber and JeanPierre Poullier Health spending in the continues to increase faster than in other major industrialized countries.

More information

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries:

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries: Productivity and in OECD Countries: 1980-2005 Dean Baker and David Rosnick 1 Center for Economic and Policy Research ABSTRACT Productivity growth is the main long-run determinant of living standards. However,

More information

April aid spending by DAC donors in factsheet

April aid spending by DAC donors in factsheet April 2018 aid spending by DAC donors in 2017 factsheet In this factsheet we provide an overview of key trends in official development assistance (ODA) emerging from the April 2017 Organisation for Economic

More information

Turkey s Saving Deficit Issue From an Institutional Perspective

Turkey s Saving Deficit Issue From an Institutional Perspective Turkey s Saving Deficit Issue From an Institutional Perspective Engin KURUN, Ph.D CEO, Ziraat Asset Management Oct. 25th, 2011 - Istanbul 1 PRESENTATION Household and Institutional Savings Institutional

More information

Economic Performance. Lessons from the past and a guide for the future Björn Rúnar Guðmundson, Director

Economic Performance. Lessons from the past and a guide for the future Björn Rúnar Guðmundson, Director Economic Performance Lessons from the past and a guide for the future Björn Rúnar Guðmundson, Director Analysis of economic performance Capital and labour: The raw ingredients in economic development However,

More information

Stronger growth, but risks loom large

Stronger growth, but risks loom large OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK Stronger growth, but risks loom large Ángel Gurría OECD Secretary-General Álvaro S. Pereira OECD Chief Economist ad interim Paris, 3 May Global growth will be around 4% Investment

More information

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland Ageing and employment policies: Ireland John Martin 1 Director for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD FÁS Annual Labour Market Conference, Dublin, 5 December 2005 OECD has carried out a major

More information

The construction of long time series on credit to the private and public sector

The construction of long time series on credit to the private and public sector 29 August 2014 The construction of long time series on credit to the private and public sector Christian Dembiermont 1 Data on credit aggregates have been at the centre of BIS financial stability analysis

More information

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012 OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012 Emily Hewlett OECD Health Data National Correspondents and Health Accounts Experts Meeting, 17 th October 2013 Health System Characteristics Survey 2012 HSC

More information

Coordinating Central and Local Governments Policy in Iceland. Björn Rúnar Guðmundsson Head of Economic Department Ministry of Economic Affairs

Coordinating Central and Local Governments Policy in Iceland. Björn Rúnar Guðmundsson Head of Economic Department Ministry of Economic Affairs Coordinating Central and Local Governments Policy in Iceland Björn Rúnar Guðmundsson Head of Economic Department Ministry of Economic Affairs A bird s eye view: Municipalities in Iceland Overall number

More information

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University Global Labor Markets Workshop Paris, September 1-2, 2016 1 What the paper does and why Provides estimates

More information

Annuities: a private solution to longevity risk

Annuities: a private solution to longevity risk Annuities: a private solution to longevity risk Product & Knowledge Fair 2007 Rüschlikon 30 March 2007 Thomas Hess Head of Economic Research & Consulting Veronica Scotti Client Solutions Need for private

More information

Slovak Competitiveness: Fundamentals, Indicators and Challenges

Slovak Competitiveness: Fundamentals, Indicators and Challenges Copyright rests with the author Slovak Competitiveness: Fundamentals, Indicators and Challenges Presentation by Mark De Broeck European Department, IMF Seminar Organized by the European Commission November

More information

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES ISSN 1011-8888 INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC STUDIES WORKING PAPER SERIES W17:04 December 2017 The Modigliani Puzzle Revisited: A Note Margarita Katsimi and Gylfi Zoega, Address: Faculty of Economics University

More information

Issue Brief for Congress

Issue Brief for Congress Order Code IB91078 Issue Brief for Congress Received through the CRS Web Value-Added Tax as a New Revenue Source Updated January 29, 2003 James M. Bickley Government and Finance Division Congressional

More information

January 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.2 bn euro 14.0 bn euro deficit for EU25

January 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.2 bn euro 14.0 bn euro deficit for EU25 42/2005-23 March 2005 January 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.2 14.0 deficit for EU25 The first estimate for euro-zone 1 trade with the rest of the world in January 2005 was a 2.2 billion euro

More information

1. Reassessing Japan s Economy

1. Reassessing Japan s Economy s Way toward Strong, Sustainable, and Balanced Growth: Assessment of the potential of the ese economy suggests the sun also rises Speech at meeting hosted by the Society and the City of London Corporation

More information

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. It reproduces an OECD Legal Instrument

More information

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries PAOLA PROFETA RICCARDO PUGLISI SIMONA SCABROSETTI June 30, 2015 FIRST DRAFT, PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT THE AUTHORS PERMISSION Abstract Focusing

More information

Statistics Brief. Inland transport infrastructure investment on the rise. Infrastructure Investment. August

Statistics Brief. Inland transport infrastructure investment on the rise. Infrastructure Investment. August Statistics Brief Infrastructure Investment August 2017 Inland transport infrastructure investment on the rise After nearly five years of a downward trend in inland transport infrastructure spending, 2015

More information

Fiscal Policy in Japan

Fiscal Policy in Japan Fiscal Policy in Japan - Issues and Future Directions- June 10th, 2015 Ministry of Finance General Government Gross Debt and Financial Balances (International Comparison) (%) 240 210 General Government

More information

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Prices and Output in an Open conomy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply chapter LARNING GOALS: After reading this chapter, you should be able to: Understand how short- and long-run equilibrium is reached

More information

RECENT LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS

RECENT LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS Chapter 1 RECENT LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS Special Focus on Labour Market Policies: How the Money Has Been Spent Summary The special section of this chapter describes trends in public spending

More information

EUR billions (b.kr.) 2000 Q3/2008 Q3/

EUR billions (b.kr.) 2000 Q3/2008 Q3/ 6 This chapter presents Iceland s international investment position, both gross (IIP) and net (NIIP). It discusses pre-crisis debt accumulation and post-crisis developments, describes changes in foreign

More information

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle OECD Legal Instruments This document is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. It reproduces

More information

Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend

Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend Report prepared for Australia Post 6 July 2009 Denis Lawrence Economic Insights Pty Ltd 6 Kurundi Place, Hawker, ACT

More information

HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting

HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting This booklet presents highlights from the 2016 OECD performance budgeting survey. The data is preliminary

More information

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem?

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem? November 15, 2006 Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem? by Patrick Fleenor Fiscal Fact No. 71 Introduction Double taxation is a common and often misused expression in tax policy discussions.

More information

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. Trends In The Rentier Income Share In OECD Countries, Dorothy Power Gerald Epstein Matthew Abrena

WORKINGPAPER SERIES. Trends In The Rentier Income Share In OECD Countries, Dorothy Power Gerald Epstein Matthew Abrena POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE University of Massachusetts Amherst Trends In The Share In OECD Countries, 196-2 POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE Dorothy Power Gerald Epstein Matthew Abrena 23

More information

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II 320.326: Monetary Economics and the European Union Lecture 8 Instructor: Prof Robert Hill The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II De Grauwe Chapters 3, 4, 5 1 1. Countries in Trouble in the Eurozone

More information

Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions

Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions International Comparison Program [05.01] Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions Francette Koechlin and Paulus Konijn 8 th Technical Advisory Group Meeting May 20-21, 2013 Washington

More information

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES The euro against major international currencies: During the second quarter of 2000, the US dollar,

More information

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System Sources of Federal Receipts Projected for 2016 Excise Taxes 2.9% Estate & Gift Taxes 0.6% Corporate Income Taxes 9.8% Other Taxes

More information

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS Marius Lüske Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD Lisbon, 28.09.2018 Marius.LUSKE@oecd.org www.oecd.org/els OUTLINE Talk based

More information

Growth has peaked amidst escalating risks

Growth has peaked amidst escalating risks OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK Growth has peaked amidst escalating risks 1 November 18 Ángel Gurría OECD Secretary-General Laurence Boone OECD Chief Economist http://www.oecd.org/eco/outlook/economic-outlook/ ECOSCOPE

More information

8th ASHK Appointed Actuaries Symposium Healthcare, Financing and Insurance

8th ASHK Appointed Actuaries Symposium Healthcare, Financing and Insurance 8th ASHK Appointed Actuaries Symposium Healthcare, Financing and Insurance Presentation by Thomas Chan Deputy Secretary, Food and Health Bureau 4 November 2008 Rapidly Ageing Population In 2008 1 out of

More information

Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok October, 2009

Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok October, 2009 Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok 26 28 October, 2009 Dave Turner OECD, Economics Department OECD Outlook: Outline 1. Recovery underway but will probably be slow 2. Risks and

More information