Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Introduction to Stochastic Calculus"

Transcription

1 Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Director Chennai Mathematical Institute Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 1

2 The notion of Conditional Expectation of a random variable given a σ-field confuses many people who wish to learn stochastic calculus. What does given a σ-field mean? Thus we begin with a discussion on Conditional Expectation. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 2

3 Let X be a random variable. Suppose we are required to make a guess for the value of X, we would like to be as close to X as possible. Suppose the penalty function is square of the error. Thus we wish to minimize E[(X a) 2 ] (1) where a is the guess. The value of a that minimizes (1) is the mean µ = E[X ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 3

4 Let Y be another random variable which we can observe and we are allowed to use the observation Y while guessing X, i.e. our guess could be a function of Y - g(y ). We should then choose the function g such that E[(X g(y )) 2 ] (2) takes the minimum possible value. When Y takes finitely many values, the function g can be thought of as a look-up table. Assuming E[X 2 ] <, it can be shown that there exists a function g (Borel measurable function from R to R) such that E[(X g(y )) 2 ] E[(X f (Y )) 2 ]. (3) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 4

5 H = L 2 (Ω,F,P) - the space of all square integrable random variables on (Ω,F,P) with norm Z = E[Z 2 ] is an Hilbert space and K = {f (Y ) : f measurable, E[(f (Y )) 2 ] < } is a closed subspace of H and hence given X H, there is a unique element in g K that satisfies Further, E[(X g(y )) 2 ] E[(X f (Y )) 2 ]. E[(X g(y ))f (Y )] = f K. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 5

6 For X H, we define g(y ) to be the conditional expectation of X given Y, written as E[X Y ] = g(y ). One can show that for X,Z H and a,b R, one has E[aX + b Z Y ] = ae[x Y ] + b E[Z Y ] (4) and X Z implies E[X Y ] E[Z Y ]. (5) Here and in this document, statements on random variables about equality or inequality are in the sense of almost sure, i.e. they are asserted to be true outside a null set. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 6

7 If (X,Y ) are independent, then Y does not contain any information on X and E[X Y ] = E[X ]. This can be checked using the definition. If (X,Y ) has bivariate Normal distrobution with means zero, variances 1 and correlation coefficient r, then from properties of Normal distribution, it follows that X ry is independent of Y. It follows that g(y) = ry is the choice for conditional expectation in this case: E[X Y ] = ry. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 7

8 Now if instead of one random variable Y, we were to observe Y 1,...,Y m, we can similarly define E[X Y 1,...Y m ] = g(y 1,...Y m ) where g satisfies E[(X g(y 1,...Y m )) 2 ] E[(X f (Y 1,...Y m )) 2 ] = measurable functions f on R m. Once again we would need to show that the conditional expectation is linear and monotone. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 8

9 Also if we were to observe an infinite sequence, we have to proceed similarly, with f, g being Borel functions on R, while if were to observe an R d valued continuous stochastic process {Y t : t < }, we can proceed as before with f, g being Borel functions on C([, ),R d ). In each case we will have to write down properties and proofs thereof and keep doing the same as the class of observable random variables changes. A different approach helps us avoid this. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 9

10 For a random variable Y, (defined on a probability space (Ω,F,P)), the smallest σ-field σ(y ) with respect to which Y is measurable (also called the σ-field generated by Y ) is given by σ(y ) = { A F : A = {Y B}, B B(R) }. An important fact: A random variable Z can be written as Z = g(y ) for a measurable function g if and only if Z is measurable with respect to σ(y ). In view of these observations, one can define conditional expectation given a sigma field as follows. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 1

11 Let X be a random variable on (Ω,F,P) with E[ X 2 ] < and let G be a sub-σ field of F. Then the conditional expectation of X given G is defined to be the G measurable random variable Z such that E[(X Z) 2 ] E[(X U) 2 ], U G -measurable r.v. (6) The random variable Z is characterized via E[X 1 A ] = E[Z1 A ] A G (7) It should be remembered that one mostly uses it when the sigma field G is generated by a bunch of observable random variables and then Z is a function of these observables. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 11

12 We can see that information content in observing Y or observing Y 3 is the same and so intutively E[X Y ] = E[X Y 3 ] This can be seen to be true on observing that σ(y ) = σ(y 3 ) as Y is measurable w.r.t. σ(y 3 ) and Y 3 is measurable w.r.t σ(y ). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 12

13 We extend the definition of E[X G ] to integrable X as follows. For X, let X n = X n. Then X n is square integrable and hence Z n = E[X n G ] is defined and Z n Z n+1 as X n X n+1. So we define Z = limz n and since E[X n 1 A ] = E[Z n 1 A ] A G monotone convergence theorem implies E[X 1 A ] = E[Z1 A ] A G and it follows that E[Z] = E[X ] < and we define E[X G ] = Z. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 13

14 Now given X such that E[ X ] < we define E[X G ] = E[X + G ] E[X + G ] where X + = max(x,) and X = max( X,). It follows that E [ ] [ ] E[X G ]1 A = E X 1A. A G (8) The property (8) characterizes the conditional expectation. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 14

15 Let X,X n,z be integrable random variables on (Ω,F,P) for n 1 and G be a sub-σ field of F and a,b R. Then we have (i) E[aX + b Z G ] = ae[x G ] + b E[Z G ]. (ii) If Y is G measurable and bounded then E(XY G ) = Y E(X G ). (iii) X Z E(X G ) E(Z G ). (iv) E [ E[X G ] ] = E[X ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 15

16 (v) For a sub-sigma field H with G H F one has E [ E[X H ] G ] = E[X G ] (vi) E[X G ] E[ X G ] (vii) If[ E[ X n X ] then ] E E[X n G ] E[X G ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 16

17 Consider a situation from finance. Let S t be a continuous process denoting the market price of shares of a company UVW. Let A t denote the value of the assets of the company, B t denote the value of contracts that the company has bid, C t denote the value of contracts that the company is about to sign. The process S is observed by the public but the processes A,B,C are not observed by the public at large. Hence, while making a decision on investing in shares of the company UVW, an investor can only use information {S u : u t}. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 17

18 Indeed, in trying to find an optimal investment policy π = (π t ) (optimum under some criterion), the class of all investment strategy must be taken as all processes π such that for each t, π t is a (measurable) function of {S u : u t} i.e. for each t, π t is measurable w.r.t. the σ-field G t = σ(s u : u t). In particular, the strategy cannot be a function of the unobserved processes A,B,C. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 18

19 Thus it is useful to define for t, G t to be the σ- field generated by all the random variables observable upto time t and then require any action to be taken at time t (an estimate of some quantity or investment decision) should be measurable with respect to G t. A filtration is any family {F t } of sub-σ- fields indexted by t [, ) such that F s F t for s t. A process X = (X t ) is said to be adapted to a filtration {F t } if for each t, X t is F t measurable. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 19

20 While it is not required in the definition, in most situations, the filtration (F t ) under consideration would be chosen to be {F Z t : t } where F Z t = σ(z u : u t) for some process Z, which itself could be vector valued. Sometimes, a filtration is treated as a mere technicality. We would like to stress that it is not so. It is a technical concept, but can be a very important ingredient of the analysis. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 2

21 For example in the finance example, we must require any investment policy to be adapted to F t = σ(s u : u t). While for technical reasons we may also consider H t = σ(s u,a u,b u,c u : u t) an (H t ) adapted process cannot be taken as an investment strategy. Thus (F t ) is lot more than mere technicality. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 21

22 A sequence of random variables {M n : n 1} is said to be a martingale if E[M n+1 M,M 1,...,M n ] = M n, n 1. An important property of martingale: E[M n ] = E[M 1 ]. The process D n = M n M n 1 is said to be a martingale difference sequence. An important property of martingale difference sequence: E[(D 1 + D D n ) 2 ] = E[(D 1 ) 2 + (D 2 ) (D n ) 2 ] as cross product terms vanish: for i < j, E[D i D j ] = E [ D i E[D j M 1,M 2,...,M j 1 ] ] = as {D j } is a martingale difference sequence. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 22

23 Thus martingale difference sequence shares a very important property with mean zero independent random variables: Expected value of square of the sum equals Expected value of sum of squares. For iid random variables, this property is what makes the law of large numbers work. Thus martingales share many properties with sum of iid mean zero random variable, Law of large numbers, central limit theorem etc. Indeed, Martingale is a single most powerful tool in modern probability theory. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 23

24 Let (M n ) be a martingale and D n = M n M n 1 be the martingale difference sequence. For k 1, let g k be a bounded function on R k and let G k = g k (M,M 1,...,M k 1 )D k. Then it can be seen that G k is also a martingale difference sequence and hence N n = n k=1 g k(m,m 1,...,M k 1 )D k is a martingale. Note that the multiplier is a function of M,M 1,...,M k 1 and NOT of M,M 1,...,M k. In the later case, the result will not be true in general. Hence E[(G 1 + G G n ) 2 ] = E[(G 1 ) 2 + (G 2 ) (G n ) 2 ] Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 24

25 The processes {N n } obtained via N n = n k=1 g k(m,m 1,...,M k 1 )(M k M k 1 ) is known as the martingale transform of M. We have seen that the martingale transform {N n } is itself a martingale and so E[N n ] =. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 25

26 Note that E(N n ) 2 = = n k=1 n k=1 E[(g k (M,M 1,...,M k 1 )(M k M k 1 )) 2 ] E[(g k (M,...,M k 1 ) 2 E[(M k M k 1 ) 2 σ(m 1,...,M k 1 )] and hence if g k is bounded by 1, then E(N n ) 2 = n k=1 E[(M k M k 1 )) 2 ] n E[E[(M k M k 1 ) 2 σ(m 1,...,M k 1 )] k=1 Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 26

27 A digression: Consider a discrete model for stock prices: Say S k denotes the price on k th day. Let us assume for the sake of clarity, that the price changes at 2pm and trading is allowed at 11am. Thus, on k th day, the number of shares that an investor could buy can use the information S,S 1,S 2,...,S k 1 (and other publicly available information). On k th day the trisection takes place at the price S k 1. Let us denote by ξ k the number of shares that an investor decides to buy. Then ξ k should be a function of S,S 1,S 2,...,S k 1, say ξ k = g k (S,S 1,S 2,...,S k 1 ). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 27

28 The collection of functions {g k : 1 k N} can be considered as an investment strategy. For such a strategy, on k th day the gain (loss) would be ξ k (S k S k 1 ). Thus the net gain (loss) from the strategy {g k : 1 k N} would be N G N = ξ k (S k S k 1 ). k=1 For simplicity let us assume that rate of interest is, else we can replace S k by S k = S k (1 + r) k, where r is the rate of interest. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 28

29 Suppose there exist functions {g k : 1 k N such that P(G N ) = 1 and P(G N > ) >. Such a strategy is called an arbitrage opportunity. In a market in equilibrium, arbitrage opportunities cannot exist for if they did, all investors would like to follow the same, multiple times over, disturbing the equilibrium. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 29

30 If {S k } were a martingale, then the gains process {G n } is a martingale transform and hence a martingale, and so E[G N ] =. As a result, P(G N ) = 1 implies P(G N = ) = 1 and so arbitrage opportunity cannot exist. Suppose there exists a probability Q such that P(E) = if and only if Q(E) =. Such a Q is called an Equivalent probability measure. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 3

31 For an Equivalent probability measure Q P(E) > if and only if Q(E) > and P(E) = 1 if and only if Q(E) = 1. So a strategy {g k } is an arbitrage opportunity under P if and only if it is an arbitrage opportunity under Q. Thus even if the stock price is not a martingale under the model probability measure P, but there exists an equivalent probability measure Q under which it is a martingale (Q is then called an Equivalent Martingale Measure - EMM), then arbitrage opportunities do not exist. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 31

32 Interesting thing is that when each {S k : k N} takes finitely many values, the converse is also true- No Arbitrage holds if and only if EMM exists. The result is also essentially true in great generality in continuous time too, one needs some technical conditions. This result is called Fundamental theorem of Asset Pricing. This shows a deep relation between Martingales and Mathematical Finance. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 32

33 A process (M t ) adapted to a filtration (F t ), ( for s < t, F s is sub-σ field of F t and M t is F t measurable) is said to be a martingale if for s < t, E [ M t F s ] = Ms. For = t < t 1 <... < t m, in analogy with the discrete case one has E [ (M tm M t ) 2] = E [ m 1 j= (M t j+1 M tj ) 2] Under minimal conditions one can ensure that the paths t M t (ω) are right continuous functions with left limts (r.c.l.l.) for all ω Ω. So we will only consider r.c.l.l. martingales. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 33

34 For any integrable random variable Z on (Ω,F,P), the process Z t = E[Z F t ] is a martingale. This follows from the smoothing property of conditional expectation: for G H Here H = F t and G = F s. E [ E[Z H ] G ] = E[X G ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 34

35 One of the most important result on Martingales is: Doob s Maximal inequality For an r.c.l.l. Martingale (M t ), for all λ >, and P ( sup t T M t > λ ) 1 λ 2 E ( M 2 T E ( sup t T M t 2 ) 4E ( M 2 T ). ) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 35

36 It can be shown that for any t n 1 k= (M t(k+1) M tk ) 2 A t n n where A t is an increasing r.c.l.l. adapted process, called the quadratic variation of M. Further, when E[MT 2 ] < for all T, then ) n 1 k= ((M E t(k+1) M tk ) 2 F tk B t n n n where B t is also an increasing r.c.l.l. adapted processand M 2 t A t and M 2 t B t are martingales. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 36

37 The quadratic variation process (A t ) of M is written as [M,M] t and B t is written as M,M t. M,M t is called the the predictable quadratic variation of M. When M has continuous paths (t M t (ω) is continuous for all ω) then M,M t =[M,M] t. For Brownian motion (β t ), [β,β] t = σ 2 t and β,β t = σ 2 t, while for a Poisson process (M t ) with rate λ, N t = M t λt is a martingale with then [N,N] t = λt and N,N t = M t. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 37

38 A stopping time τ is a [, ] valued random variable such that {ω : τ(ω) t} F t, t} The idea behind the concept: Whether the event {τ t} has happened or not should be known at time t, when one has observed {X u : u t.}. If (X t ) is an continuous adapted process then τ = inf{t : X t θ} is a stopping time : for any θ R. For example, {τ 7} has happened iff {sup s 7 X s θ}. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 38

39 In real life we are used to talking in terms of time in reference to time of occurence of other events, such as meet me within five minutes of your arrival or let us meet as soon as the class is over, or sell shares of company X as soon as its price falls below 1. Thse are stopping times Of course a statement like buy shares of company X today if the price is going to increase tomorrow by 3 is meaningless. One can talk but cannot implement. The time specified in the statement is not a stopping time. The time at which an americal option can be exercised has to be a stopping time as the decision to exercise the option at a given time or not has to depend upon the observations upto that time. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 39

40 Martingales and stopping times: Let (M t ) be a martingale, τ be a stopping time and (X t ),(Y t ) be r.c.l.l. adapted processes and Y be bounded. 1 (X t ) is a martingale if and only if E[X τ ] = E[X ] for all bounded stopping times τ 2 N t = M t τ is a martingale. 3 U t = Y t τ ( Mt M t τ ) is also a martingale. A martingale (M t ) is said to be a square integrable martingale if E[M 2 t ] < for all t <. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 4

41 A process (X t ) is said to be locally bounded if there exists an increasing sequence of stopping times {τ n } increasing to such that X n t = X t τ n is bounded for every n. It can be seen that every (X t ) such that X is bounded and (X t ) is continuous is locally bounded. Likewise, an adapted process (M t ) is said to be a local martingale (or locally square integrable martingale) if there exists an increasing sequence of stopping times {τ n } increasing to such that M n t = M t τ n is a martingale (is a square integrable martingale) for every n. The sequence {τ n } is called a localizing sequence. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 41

42 Let M be a local martingale with localizing sequence {τ n }. Thus E[M t τ n F s ] = M s τ n. So if M is bounded then M is a martingale. Other sufficient conditions for a local martingale to be a martingale are [ ] E sup s T M s < [ E M T 2] <, T < [ ] E M T 1+δ <, T <, for some δ >. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 42

43 Let M be a [, ) valued local martingale with localizing sequence {τ n }. Then since E[M t τ n] = E[M ] using Fatou s lemma it follows that for all t >, E[M t ] E[M ]. If E[M t ] = E[M ] it is a martingale. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 43

44 When (M t ) is a locally square integrable martingale, it can be shown that for any t n 1 k= (M t(k+1) M tk ) 2 A t n n where again A t is an increasing adapted process such that M 2 t A t is a local martingale. A is again called quadratic variation process, written as [M,M] t. One can also show that there is an increasing adapted r.c.l.l. process B such that M n t = M t τ n, M n,m n t = B t τ n. and then B t is written as M,M t. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 44

45 Let (M t ) be a locally square integrable martingale with M = and let {τ n } be a localizing sequence such that M n t = M t τ n is a martingale for every n. Then, using E[Mt τ 2 n] = E[ M,M t τ n] = E[[M,M] t τn] and Doob s inequality, one has E ( sup M s 2) 4E[ M,M t τ n] (9) s t τ n as well as E ( sup M s 2) 4E[[M,M] t τ n] (1) s t τ n Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 45

46 A Brownian motion (β t ) is a continuous process with β = and such that for t 1 < t 2 <... < t m ; m 1; (β t1,β t2,...,β tm ) has a multivariate Normal distribution with mean vector and variance co-variance matrix Σ = ((σ ij )) given by σ ij = min(t i,t j ) It can be checked that (with t = ) β t1 β t,β t2 β t1,...,β tm β tm 1 are independent Normal random variables, with mean and Var(β tj β tj 1 ) = t j t j 1. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 46

47 One of the most important properties of a Brownian motion is that (β t ) is a martingale with [β,β] t = β t,β t t = t. Thus, βt 2 t is a martingale and ( ) 2 Qt n = k=1 β k 2 n t β k 1 2 n t t where the convergence is in probability. The Qt n for a fixed n,t is a finite sum, indeed it has j = [2 n t] + 1 terms, where [2 n t] is the integer part of 2 n t since for k such that [2 n t] + 1 < k, k 1 2 n t = t and 2 k n t = t. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 47

48 Let Uk n = ( β k 2 n t β ) 2 k 1 2 n t ( k 2 n t k 1 2 n t) Then W n t = [2n t]+1 k=1 U n k = Qn t t and using properties of Normal distribution, it follows that for each n, {U n k : 1 k [2n t]} are i.i.d. random variables, with mean and variance 2 2 2n. Hence and hence Wt n in probability. Variance(Wt n ) ([2 n t] + 1) 2 2t+1 2 2n 2 n converges to zero in probability and so Q n t t With little work, it can be shown that Q n t converges to t, uniformly on t [,T ] for all T < almost surely. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 48

49 In fact, for a continuous process (X t ), if X = and if (X t ) and (Y t = X 2 t t) are martingales then (X t ) is Brownian motion (Levy s characterization). For this, continuity of (X t ) is very important. Result not true for r.c.l.l. martinagles. X t = N t t is a counter example where (N t ) is a poisson process with parameter 1. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 49

50 Let us fix an observable process (Z t ) (it could be vector valued) with Z t denoting the observation at time t and let F t = σ(z u : u t) denote the filtration generated by observations. A Brownian motion w.r.t. this filtration (F t ) means that β t and β 2 t t are martingales w.r.t. this filtration (F t ). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 5

51 Let (β t ) be a Brownian motion w.r.t. a filtration (F t ). There are occasions when one needs to consider limits of expressions that are similar to Riemann-Steltjes sums for the integral t Y s dβ s where (Y s ) is say a continuous (F t ) adapted process: Rt n = k=1 Y s k,n t ( β k 2 n t β k 1 2 n t ) where k 1 2 n s k,n k 2 n. For Riemann-Steltjes integral t Y s dβ s to exist, the above sums (R n t ) should converge (as n ) for all choices of s k,n satisfying k 1 2 n s k,n k 2 n. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 51

52 Let Y = β. Let us choose s k,n to be the lower end point in every interval : s k,n = k 1 2 n and for this choice let us denote the Riemann sums Rt n by A n t. Thus A n ( ) t = β k 1 2 k=1 n t β k 2 n t β k 1 2 n t Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 52

53 Let us now choose s k,n to be the upper end point in every interval : s k,n = 2 k n and for this choice let us denote the Riemann sums Rt n by Bt n. Thus Bt n ( ) = β k 2 n t β k 2 n t β k 1 2 k=1 n t Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 53

54 Recall while and hence A n t = k=1 β k 1 2 n t B n t = k=1 β k 2 n t B n t A n t = k=1 ( ) β k 2 n t β k 1 2 n t ( ) β k 2 n t β k 1 2 n t ( ) 2 β k 2 n t β k 1 2 n t = Q n t. Since Qt n t, A n t and Bt n cannot converge to the same limit and hence the integral t Y s dβ s cannot be defined as a Riemann-Steltjes integral. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 54

55 Indeed, Brownian motion is not an exception but the rule. It can be shown that if a continuous process is used to model stock price movements, then it can not be a process with bounded variation as that would imply existence of arbitrage opportunities. Hence, we cannot use Riemann-Steltjes integrals in this context. The Riemann like sums appear when one is trying to compute the gain/loss from a trading strategy, where the process used to model the stock price appears as an integrator. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 55

56 It turns out that in the context of construction of diffusion processes, Riemann sums, where one evaluates the integrand at the lower end point, are appropriate. So taking that approach, Ito defined stochastic integral (in 4s). It so happens that in the context of applications to finance, the same is natural and so Ito Calculus could be used as it is. This was observed in the early 8s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 56

57 Let X t denote the stock price at time t. Consider a simple trading strategy, where buy-sell takes place at fixed times = s < s 1 <... < s m+1. Suppose the number of shares held by the investor during (s j,s j+1 ] is a j. The transaction takes place at time s j and so the investor can use information available to her/him before time t, so a j should be F sj measurable. So the trading strategy is given by: at time t hold f t shares where f s = a 1 {} (s) + m j= a j1 (sj,s j+1 ](s) and then the net gain/loss for the investor due to trading in shares upto time t is given by V t = m j= a j(x sj+1 t X sj t) = t f u dx u Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 57

58 Now suppose (X t ) is a square integrable martingale with r.c.l.l. paths (right continuous with left limits). Recalling f s = a 1 {} (s) + m j= a j1 (sj,s j+1 ](s), V t = m j= a j(x sj+1 t X sj t). it follows that (V t ) is also a martingale and [V,V ] t = Hence, using (1) [ E sup( t T = t m 1 j= t a 2 j ([X,X ] s j+1 t [X,X ] sj t) f 2 u d[x,x ] u ] [ T f u dx u ) 2 4E fu 2 d[x,x ] u ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 58

59 The estimate [ E sup( t T t ] [ T ] f u dx u ) 2 4E fu 2 d[x,x ] u for simple integrands f can be used to extend the integral to integrands g that can be approximated by simple functions in the norm X given by RHS above: [ T ] f 2 X = E fu 2 d[x,x ] u Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 59

60 Let (Y t ) be a bounded adapted continuous process and (X t ) be a square integrable martingale. Let tm n = m n. Then it can be shown that (Y t ) can be approximated in the norm X by simple processes Y n defined by Yt n = Y t n m t1 (t n m, tm+1 n ] (t) m= and hence the stochastic integral t Y u dx u is defined and is given by t Y u dx u = lim n Y t n m t m= ( ) X t n m+1 t X t n m t. The two infinite sums above are actually finite sums for every n,t (if m > tn the terms are zero). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 6

61 Also, the limit t Y u dx u = lim n Y t n m t m= ( ) X t n m+1 t X t n m t. is in the sense of convergence in probability, uniformly in t [,T ] (follows from Doob s inequality). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 61

62 In other words, for every ε >, as n tends to infinity [ t ) P Y u dx u Y t n m t( ] Xt n m+1 t X t n m t > ε. sup t T m= This shows that the stochastic integral t Y u dx u is a process with r.c.l.l.paths. Further, if X is a continuous process then so is t Y u dx u continuous process. Of course, when X is a process with bounded variation the integral t Y u dx u is defined as the Riemann-Steltjes integral. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 62

63 One can directly verify that when X is a square integrable martingale, t Y n u dx u = ) Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t m= is a square integrable martingale. Then convergence of t Y n u dx u in L 2 to t Y u dx u for every t implies that M t = t Y u dx u is also a square integrable martingale. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 63

64 One of the important properties of the integral Z t = t Y u dx u so defined is that for a stopping time τ, defining X [τ] t = X t τ, t Y u dx [τ] u = Z t τ. This can be seen to be true for simple integrands and hence for bounded continuous processes Y. Thus if X is a locally square integrable martingale so that for stopping times {τ n } increasing to, X n = X [τn] are square integrable martingales, then Z n = YdX n satisfy Zt n = Zt τ m n, for m n. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 64

65 Thus we can define Z t = Zt n for τ n 1 < t τ n and we would have Zt n = Z t τ n. Thus we can define Z = YdX. Thus for a locally square integrable martingale X, for all continuous adapted processes Y we continue to have for every ε >, as n tends to infinity P [ sup t T t Y u dx u m= ) Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t > ε By construction, each Z n is a martingale and hence Z is a local martingale. ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 65

66 If X were a process with bounded variation paths on [,T ] for every T, of course t YdX is defined as Riemann Steltjes integral and we have P [ sup t T t Y u dx u m= ) Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t > ε ] and then t Y u dx u is a process with bounded variation paths. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 66

67 An r.c.l.l. process X is said to be a semimartingale if it admits a decomposition X t = M t + A t, where (M t ) is a locally square integrable martingale and (A t ) is an adapted process whose paths t A t (ω) have bounded variation on [,T ] for every T < for every ω. Such a process A will be called process with bounded variation paths. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 67

68 Let X be a semimartingale, with X = M + A, M a locally square integrable martingale and A a process with bounded variation paths. For a bounded continuous adapted process Y, the integral t Y s dx s can be defined as the sum of t Y s dm s and t Y s da s and again one has every ε >, as n tends to infinity P [ sup t T t Y u dx u m= ) Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t > ε Thus the integral YdX does not depend upon the decomposition X = M + A. ]. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 68

69 We have seen that for a semimartingale X and a bounded continuous adapted process Y, the integral t Y s dx s can be defined on the lines of Riemann-Steltjes integral, provided we always evaluate the integrand at the lower end point while taking the Riemann sums: t Y u dx u = lim n m= ) Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t. Further, if X is a local martingale, then so is Z t = t Y u dx u and if X is a process with bounded variation paths, then so is Z and as a result, Z is always a semimartingale. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 69

70 Question: Just like one extends Riemann integral 1 f (x)dx defined for say continuous functions g on [,1] to Lebesgue integral 1 gdλ for all bounded measurable functions, can we extend t Y s dx s defined for all bounded continuous adapted processes to a larger class of integrands? The natural class of processes is then the class that is closed under bounded pointwise convergence and contains all bounded continuous adapted processes. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 7

71 If we think of every process Y t as a function on Ω = [, ) Ω, then the required class is the collection of all P-measurable bounded functions, where P is the σ-field generated by bounded continuous adapted processes. P is called the predictable σ-field and P measurable processes are called predictable processes. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 71

72 A left continuous adapted process (Z t ) is predictable, but an r.c.l.l. (right continuous with left limits) adapted process (V t ) need not be predictable. (V t ) is predictable if for all t, V t is F t ε measurable. If (Z t ) is predictable with respect to a filtration (F t ) then for each t, Z t is measurable w.r.t. F t = σ ( s<t F s ). This justifies the use of the name predictable. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 72

73 Thus we require a mapping J X from the class of bounded predictable process f into r.c.l.l. processes such that for adapted continuous processes f, J X (f ) t = t fdx (as defined earlier) and if f n converges to f bounded pointwise, then [ ] P sup t T J X (f n ) t J X (f ) t > ε. When X is a semimartingale, then such an extension exists and we denote it as J X (f ) t = t fdx. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 73

74 The Bichteller-Dellacherie-Meyer-Mokodobodski Theorem states that for an r.c.l.l. process X, existence of mapping J X from the class of bounded predictable process f into r.c.l.l. processes such that for adapted continuous processes f, J X (f ) t = t fdx (as defined earlier) and if f n converges to f bounded pointwise, then [ ] P sup t T J X (f n ) t J X (f ) t > ε implies that X s a semimartingale. We will not discuss proof of this. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 74

75 Let X be a semimartingale. It can be shown that (f,x ) fdx is linear. Important fact: If τ is a stopping time, then g t = 1 [,τ] (t) is predictable (as it is adapted, left continuous). Now for a bounded predictable process (f t ), h t = f t 1 [,τ] (t) is predictable and t h s dx s = t τ f s dx s = f s dx s [τ] where X [τ] s = X s τ. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 75

76 Localization: An adapted process (f t ) is said to be locally bounded if there exists an increasing sequence of stopping times {τ n } increasing to such that ft n = f t 1 [,τ n ](t) is bounded for every n. Here, for a stopping times τ, the stochastic intervals [, τ], play the role of compact sets [ K,K] in R. Recall definition of local martingale. Given f, {τ n } as above, for a semimartingale X, let Then for m n Z n t = t f 1 [,τ n ](s)dx s Z n t = Z m t τ n Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 76

77 Hence we piece together the pieces to define t f s dx s = Z n t for τ n 1 < t τ n. Thus for a semimartingale X and for locally bounded process f, we have defined stochastic integral Z t = t f s dx s. It is an r.c.l.l. process. Moreover, ( Z) t = f t ( X ) t. One can verify this for simple f and then for general f via approximation. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 77

78 If X is a square integrable local martingale, then so is Z, if X has bounded variation paths then so does Z and in general, Z is a semimartingale with decomposition Z t = t f s dx s = t t f s dm s + f s da s = N t + B t where X = M + A, M a locally square integrable martingale, A a process with bounded variation paths and N t = t f s dm s is a locally square integrable martingale and B t = t f s da s is a process with bounded variation paths. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 78

79 Further if g is a locally bounded predictable process, then t gdz = t gfdx. One can verify this first when f,g are simple functions and then for a fixed g simple one can first verify it for all f and then the general case. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 79

80 An r.c.l.l. adapted process Y need not be predictable. However, the process Y defined by Yt = Y t (left limit at t for t > ), Y = is predictable. It is also locally bounded and with tm n = m n one has lim n m= Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t ) t = Yu dx u Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 8

81 Note that (using b 2 a 2 = 2a(b a) + (b a) 2 ) X 2 t X 2 = = m= m= + ( X 2 t n m+1 t X t 2 ) m t n ) 2X t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t m= Hence for a semimartingale X, ( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t ( ) t 2 Xt n m+1 t X t n m t X 2 t X 2 2 m= ) 2 X u dx u. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 81

82 We denote the limit of 2 m=( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t) by [X,X ]t and note that it is an increasing adapted process. Further we have t Xt 2 = X Xu dx u + [X,X ] t. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 82

83 For semimartingales X,Y let us define [X,Y ] by the parallelogram identity [X,Y ] t = 1 4 ([X + Y,X + Y ] t [X Y,X Y ] t ) It follows that [X,Y ] t is a process with bounded variation paths and [X,Y ] t = lim n ) ) m=( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t (Yt n m+1 t Y t n m t Also, it follows that X t Y t = X Y + t Y s dxs + t X s dy s + [X,Y ] t. This is called the integration by parts formula. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 83

84 Like Lebesgue integrals, we have a Dominated Convergence Theorem for stochastic integrals: Let (X t ) be a semimartingale and let f n,f be predictable processes such that f n g where g is some locally bounded predictable process and such that f n converges pointwise to f. Then [ t t ] P fu n dx u f u dx u > ε. sup t T Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 84

85 Some Facts: Let X be a semimartingale, with X t = M t + A t, where (M t ) is a locally square integrable martingale and (A t ) is a process with bounded variation paths. Let ( X ) t = X t X t, (jump at t) [X,X ] t = ( X ) 2 t, ( X ) 2 s [X,X ]t. <s t If A has bounded variation paths then [A,A]t = ( A) 2 s. <s t Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 85

86 Moreover, if X is a semimartingale and A is a continuous process with bounded variation paths, then [X,A] t =. To see this t ) X s da s = X t n m t( At n m+1 t A t n m t m= and t X s da s = ) X t n m+1 t( At n m+1 t A t n m t m= as the integral t X s da s is the Riemann-Steltjes and thus [X,A] t = As a result ( )( ) Xt n m+1 t X t n m t At n m+1 t A t n m t =. m= [A,A] t =. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 86

87 For a continuous semimartingale (X t ) the decomposition X t = M t + A t into a continuous local martingale (M t ) with M = and a continuous process A with bounded variation paths is unique. The uniqueness is proven as follows. If X t = M t + A t = N t + B t with M,N continuous local martingales, M = N = and A, B processes with bounded variation, then U t = M t N t = B t A t is a continuous local martingale with U =, and has bounded variation paths. Thus, [U,U] t =. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 87

88 As a result (recall integration by parts formula) U 2 t = t U s du s and hence Ut 2 is a continuous local martingale with U 2 =. If {τ n } is a localizing sequence, then Ut τ 2 n is a martingale and so E[Ut τ 2 n] =, n and as a result U 2 t τ n = for all t,n. This proves (X t) the decomposition X t = M t + A t into a continuous local martingale (M t ) with M = and a continuous process A with bounded variation paths is unique. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 88

89 If X is a semimartingale and f is a locally bounded predictable process, then V t = t f s dx s is also a semimartingale with decomposition V t = N t + B t where X t = M t + A t is a decomposition of X, with M a locally square integrable martingale, A a process with bounded variation paths, and N t = B t = Further, t t f s dn s is a locally square integrable martingale f s da s is a process with bounded variation paths. [V,V ] t = t f 2 s d[x,x ] s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 89

90 Ito formula or Change of variable formula Let f be a smooth function on R and let (G t ) be a continuous function with bounded variation paths. If G were continuously differentiable with derivate g, then h(t) = f (G(t)) is differentiable with continuous derivative f (G(t))g(t) and hence t f (G(t)) =f (G()) + f (G(s))g(s)ds =h() + t f (G(s))dG(s) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 9

91 Even if G is not differentiable, one still has t f (G(t)) = f (G()) + f (G(s))dG(s). Assume that f is bounded. The proof uses taylor s expansion: f (b) = f (a) + f (a)(b a) f (c)(b a) 2 where c belongs to the interval {a,b}, i.e. c (a,b) or c (b,a) according as a < b or b < a Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 91

92 Another fact that is needed is: If G is a continuous function with bounded variation: then there exists a function H(t) such that for any partition for = t < t 1 <... < t m = T of [,T ], m 1 ( ) m i= G(t i+1) G(t i ) H(T ) <, then with tm n = m n ( 2 G(tm n t) G(tm 1 n ( t)) H(t)sup G(t n m t) G(tm 1 n t) ) m m as n as G being continuous on [,t] is uniformly continuous on [,t] and hence sup m ( G(t n m t) G(t n m 1 t) ). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 92

93 Observe that for every n with t n m = m n f (G(t)) f (G()) = = m=1 m= one has ( f (G(t n m t)) f (G(t n m 1 t)) ) f (G(t n m 1 t)) ( G(t n m t) G(t n m 1 t) ) m=1 f (θ n,m ) ( G(t n m t) G(t n m 1 t) ) 2 Here θ n,m belongs to the interval {G(t n m 1 t),g(tn m t)}. Since G is a continuous function with bounded variation, the second term goes to zero and first term goes to t f (G(s))dG(s). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 93

94 Ito s formula Let X be a continuous semimartingle and let f be a thrice continuously differentiable function on R with f bounded. Then f (X t ) = f (X ) + t f (X s )dx s t f (X s )d[x,x ] s This time we need Taylor s expansion with two terms: f (b) = f (a) + f (a)(b a) f (a)(b a) f (c)(b a) 3 where c belongs to the interval {a,b}, i.e. c (a,b) or c (b,a) according as a < b or b < a. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 94

95 We will also need that since X has finite quadratic variation, with tm n = m n one has m X t n m t X t n m 1 t 3 m ( 2 X t n m t X t n m 1 t) sup [X,X ] t sup m as n m ( X t n m t X t n m 1 t ( ) X t n m t X t n m 1 t as uniformly continuity of paths s X) s (ω) of X on [,t] implies sup m ( X t n m t(ω) X t n m 1 t(ω) converges to for every ω. ) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 95

96 Recall: we have seen that for every continuous adapted process Y Also that, lim n m= Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t ) t = Yu dx u (11) ( ) 2 Xt n m+1 t X t n m t [X,X ]t. (12) m= On similar lines it can be shown that lim n m= Y t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t The relation (13) is a weighted version of (12). ) t 2 = Yu d[x,x ] u. (13) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 96

97 As in deterministic case, let us write f (X t ) f (X ) = f (X t n m t) ( X t n m+1 t X t n m t m f (X t n m t) ( ) 2 X t n m+1 t X t n m t m f (θ n,m ) ( ) 3 X t n m+1 t X t n m t As noted earlier, the first term converges to t f (X s )dx s and the second term to 2 1 t f (X s )d[x,x ] s. Using boundedness of f and the fact (proven earlier) that Xt n m+1 t X t n m t 3 goes to zero, it follows that third term goes to zero. This completes the proof. ) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 97

98 The Ito formula is true even when f is just twice continuously differentiable function. For the proof, one just uses a version of Taylor s theorem with a different remainder form: f (b) =f (a) + f (a)(b a) f (a)(b a) (f (c) f (a))(b a) 2 where c belongs to the interval {a,b}, i.e. c (a,b) or c (b,a) according as a < b or b < a. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 98

99 Ito s formula for Brownian motion Let (β t ) be a standard Brownian motion. Then we have noted that [β,β] t = t and hence for a twice continuously differentiable function f, one has t f (β t ) =f (β ) t f (β s )dβ s f (β s )ds Taking f (x) = exp(x) we get, writing Y t = exp(β t ) t Y t = 1 + Y s dβ s + 1 t Y s ds. 2 The last term is the Ito correction term. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 99

100 The same proof as outlined earlier, yields for a continuous semimartingale X the second version of Ito formula. Here one uses, for an r.c.l.l. process Z, and semimartingales X,Y t Z u d[x,y ] u n m= = lim ) ) Z t n m t( Xt n m+1 t X t n m t (Yt n m+1 t Y t n m t Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 1

101 Ito s formula-2 Let X be a continuous semimartingle and let f function on [, ) R such that f t = t f, f x = x f and f xx = 2 2 x f exist and are continuous. Then t t f (t,x t ) =f (,X ) + f t (s,x s )ds + f x (s,x s )dx s t f xx (s,x s )d[x,x ] s Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 11

102 Let (β t ) be a Brownian motion. Let f (t,x) = exp(σx 1 2 σ 2 t). Let Y t = f (t,β t ). Then noting that f t = t f = 1 2 σ 2 f and f xx = 2 2 x f = σ 2 f, one has Y t = Y + σ In particular, (Y t ) is a martingale. t Y s dβ s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 12

103 If (X t ) takes values in an open convex set U and f is a twice continuously differentiable function, then the same version of Ito formula is valid. In particular, if (X t ) is a (, ) valued continuous semimartingale, then taking f (x) = log(x) we get t log(x t ) = log(x ) + Xs 1 dx s 1 t Xs 2 d[x,x ] s. 2 Once again the last term is the Ito correction term. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 13

104 Let us write Y t = t Xs 1 dx s. Then Hence, recalling, we get [Y,Y ] t = t X 2 s d[x,x ] s. t log(x t ) = log(x ) + Xs 1 dx s 1 t 2 log(x t ) = log(x ) + Y t 1 2 [Y,Y ] t Xs 2 d[x,x ] s and hence X t = X exp ( Y t 1 2 [Y,Y ] ) t Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 14

105 Further, if X is a (, ) valued continuous local martingale, then t M t = Xs 1 dx s is also a local martingale and then X admits a representation X t = X exp ( M t 1 2 [M,M] ) t So every positive continuous local martingale is of the form given above for a local martingale M. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 15

106 Ito s formula-3 Let X be a continuous semimartingle, A be a continuous process with bounded variation and let f = f (a,x) function on R R such that f a = a f, f x = x f and f xx = 2 2 x f exist and are continuous. Then t t f (A t,x t ) =f (A,X ) + f a (A s,x s )das + f x (A s,x s )dx s t f xx (A s,x s )d[x,x ] s Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 16

107 In typical applications of Ito s formula, one needs to show a certain process is a martingale. First one shows that it is a local martingale by expressing it as an integral w.r.t. a locally square integrable martingale and then uses other methods to show it is a martingale. Let (M t ) be a continuous locally square integrable martingale and let (h s ) be a locally bounded predictable process. Question: for what values of λ is Z a martingale where { t t Z t = exp σ h s dm s + λ hs 2 d[m,m] s }. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 17

108 Let Y t = t h s dm s and V t = t h 2 s d[m,m] s. Note that (Y t ) is a square integrable local martingale and V t = [Y,Y ] t. Let f (a,x) = exp(σx + λa). Then Z t = f (V t,y t ). Now noting that f a = a f = λf and f xx = 2 2 x f = σ 2 f, one has Z t = Z + σ t Z s dy s + (λ + 1 t 2 σ 2 ) Z s dv s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 18

109 Hence if λ = 1 2 σ 2, it follows that Z t = Z + σ t Z s dy s. Hence for λ = 1 2 σ 2, Z is a local martingale. It can be shown that this is a necessary and sufficient condition. Of course, we will need some other way to prove that the local martingale is a martingale. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 19

110 Levy s characterization of Brownian motion. Suppose M is a continuous local martingale with M = and such that Z t = (M t ) 2 t is also a local martingale, or [M,M] t = t, then M is a brownian motion. Apply Ito formula to (for a fixed real number λ) { f (t,x) = exp iλx + λ 2 t 2 We note that 1 2 f xx = f t and hence Z t = exp { iλm t + λ 2 } t 2 is a local martingale. Since Z is bounded, it is a martingale. }. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 11

111 As a result, E[Z t F s ] = Z s i.e. [ E exp { iλm t + λ 2 t } ] Fs = exp { iλm s + λ 2 s 2 }. 2 2 Hence [ E exp { iλ(m t M s ) + λ 2 (t s) } ] Fs = 1. 2 or E [exp { iλ(m t M s ) } ] F s = exp { λ 2 (t s) }. 2 Thus [ E exp { iλ(m t M s ) }] = exp { λ 2 (t s) } 2 and so (M t M s ) has normal distribution, mean Variance t s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 111

112 Further, E [exp { iλ(m t M s ) } ] F s = E [exp { iλ(m t M s ) }] implies that (M t M s ) is independent of any set of F s measurable random variables. In particular, (M t M s ) is independent of M u1,m u2,...,m uk. Thus M t is a Brownian motion. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 112

113 Sometimes, given a process (Z t ) one needs to find a process (A t ) with bounded variation paths such that M t = Z t A t is a local martingale or a martingale (U t ) such that N t = Z t U t is a local martingale. Example: Let (β t ) be the standard Brownian motion and for σ > and µ R let S t = S exp{σβ t + µt}. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 113

114 We need to find a local martingale (U t ) such that Z t = S t U t is a martingale. Let us try U t = exp{λβ t 1 2 λ 2 t}. We know this is a martingale. Now { Z t = S exp (σ + λ)β t 1 } 2 (λ 2 2µ) Thus (Z t ) would be a martingale if (σ + λ) 2 = (λ 2 2µ). Thus σ 2 + 2σλ = 2µ and hence. λ = µ+ 1 2 σ 2 σ In this case, (U t ) and (Z t ) turn out to be martingales. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 114

115 Ito s formula-4 Let X 1,X 2,...,X d be a continuous semimartingles and let f function on [, ) R d such that f t = t f, f i = x i f and f ij = 2 x i x j f exist and are continuous. Let X t = (X 1 t,...,x d t ). Then t f (t,x t ) =f (,X ) f t (s,x s )ds + d t i=1 d t f ij (s,x s )d[x i,x j ] s i,j=1 f i (s,x s )dx i s Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 115

116 Often one needs to compute the part with bounded variation paths separately. In light of this, we can recast the formula showing the (local) martingale part and the part with bounded variation paths separately. Let X 1,...,X d be continuous semimartingales with X i = M i + A i where M i are continuous local martingales and A i be processes with bounded variation paths. Let f C 1,2 ([, ) R d b ). Then Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 116

117 where and N t = t B t =f (,X ) d j=1 d k=1 f (t,x t ) = N t + B t d t f j (s,x s )dms j j=1 f t (s,x s )ds + d j=1 t t f jk (s,x s )d[m j,m k ] s f j (s,x s )da j s Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 117

118 Ito s formula for r.c.l.l. semimartingales. Let X 1,...,X d be semimartingales, X t := (X 1 t,...,x d t ). Let f C 1,2 ([, ) R d ). t f (t,x t ) =f (,X ) + + d j=1 t d j=1 d k=1 f t (s,x s )ds f j (s,x s )dx j s t f jk (s,x s )d[x j,x k ] + <s t {f (s,x s ) f (s,x s ) d j=1 f j(s,x s ) Xs j d j=1 d 1 } k=1 2 f jk(s,x s )( Xs j )( Xs k ). Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 118

119 Martingale representation theorem Let (β t ) be a standard Brownian motion. Let F t = σ{β u : u t} Let (M t ) be a martingale w.r.t. (F t ). Then M admits a representation t M t = M + h s dβ s, t T for some predictable process (h s ) such that T h 2 s ds < a.s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 119

120 For T >, let Z be any random variable such that E[ Z ] <. Then taking the martingale M t = E[Z F t ], we can get predictable process (h s ) such that T h 2 s ds < a.s. and t Z = M T = M + h s dβ s. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 12

121 Martingale representation theorem- multidimensional Let (β 1 t,...,β d t ) be d- independent standard Brownian motions. Let F t = σ{β j u : u t,1 j d} Let (M t ) be a martingale w.r.t. (F t ). Then M admits a representation M t = M + d t j=1 h j sdβ j s, t T for some predictable process (h s ) such that T (h j s) 2 ds < a.s., 1 j d. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 121

122 Suppose X is a continuous process on (Ω,F,P) and let Q be an equivalent probability measure on (Ω,F ) such that X is a martingale on (Ω,F,Q). Equivalent means P(A) = if and only if Q(A) =. Such a Q is called an Equivalent Martingale Measure, written as EMM, for X and is of great importance in Mathematical finance. Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 122

123 Let R denote the Radon-Nikodym derivative of Q w.r.t. P, em i.e. Q(A) = RdP. Equivalence of P and Q means P(R > ) = 1. Let R t = E P [R F t ]. Then as noted earlier (R t ) is a martingale. Moreover, for A F t Q(A) = RdP A = E[R F t ]dp. A = R t dp Thus R t is the R-N derivative of Q w.r.t. P on F t. A A Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 123

124 Now, (X t ) being a martingale on (Ω,F,Q) means A X t dq = A X s dq for s < t and a F s. But this is same as X t R t dp = X s R s dp A since R u is the R-N derivative of Q w.r.t. P on F u. A Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 124

125 Hence, (X t R t ) is a martingale on (Ω,F,P). Further, R t being a positive martingale implies Rt 1 is a semimartingale and thus X t = X t R t.r 1 t is a semimartingale. Suppose X t = N t + B t is the decomposition of X with local martingale N. We have seen that where M t = t R 1 s dr s. R t = R exp(m t 1 2 [M,M] t) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 125

126 Hence Z t = (N t + B t )exp(m t 1 2 [M,M] t) is a martingale. So we see that if an EMM exists for X, then X must be a semimartingale and further the R-N derivative for the EMM w.r.t. the model probability measure on F t is R t = R exp(m t 1 2 [M,M] t) where M is a local martingale such that is a martingale. Z t = (N t + B t )exp(m t 1 2 [M,M] t) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 126

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Director Chennai Mathematical Institute rlk@cmi.ac.in rkarandikar@gmail.com Introduction to Stochastic Calculus - 1 A Game Consider a gambling house. A fair coin is

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Department of Banking and Finance University of Zurich April 22 2013 Math Finance Colloquium USC Change of the probability measure Change of

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Thursday, 5 June, 214 1:3 pm to 4:3 pm PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry

More information

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Michael Perlmutter Department of Mathematics Purdue University 1 M. Perlmutter(Purdue) Brownian Motion and Martingales Outline Review of Basic Probability

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar BROWNIAN MOTION II D.Majumdar DEFINITION Let (Ω, F, P) be a probability space. For each ω Ω, suppose there is a continuous function W(t) of t 0 that satisfies W(0) = 0 and that depends on ω. Then W(t),

More information

Martingale representation theorem

Martingale representation theorem Martingale representation theorem Ω = C[, T ], F T = smallest σ-field with respect to which B s are all measurable, s T, P the Wiener measure, B t = Brownian motion M t square integrable martingale with

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance Stochastic Finance C. Azizieh VUB C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 1/91 Agenda of the course Stochastic calculus : introduction Black-Scholes model Interest rates models C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

More information

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5. MATH136/STAT219 Lecture 21, November 12, 2008 p. 1/11 Last Time Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.3 MATH136/STAT219

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets Markus Pelger October 21, 2016 Abstract We model asset prices in the most general sensible form as special semimartingales. This approach allows

More information

Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II)

Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II) Advanced Probability and Applications (Part II) Olivier Lévêque, IC LTHI, EPFL (with special thanks to Simon Guilloud for the figures) July 31, 018 Contents 1 Conditional expectation Week 9 1.1 Conditioning

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Bernard Bercu Bordeaux University, France IFCAM Summer School Bangalore, India, July 2015 Bernard Bercu Asymptotic results for discrete

More information

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model MATHEMATICAL COMMUNICATIONS 231 Math. Commun. 18(2013, 231 239 The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model Tatjana Slijepčević-Manger 1, 1 Faculty of Civil Engineering, University

More information

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction M. Kazim Khan Kent State University. UET, Taxila August 15-16, 17 Outline 1 From R.W. to B.M. B.M. 3 Stochastic Integration 4 Ito s Formula 5 Recap Random Walk Consider

More information

S t d with probability (1 p), where

S t d with probability (1 p), where Stochastic Calculus Week 3 Topics: Towards Black-Scholes Stochastic Processes Brownian Motion Conditional Expectations Continuous-time Martingales Towards Black Scholes Suppose again that S t+δt equals

More information

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS Stat 391/FinMath 346 Lecture 8 STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS X t = CONTINUOUS PROCESS θ t = PORTFOLIO: #X t HELD AT t { St : STOCK PRICE M t : MG W t : BROWNIAN MOTION DISCRETE TIME: = t < t 1

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Enlargement of filtration

Enlargement of filtration Enlargement of filtration Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 6, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Enlargement of Filtration Enlargement of Filtration ([1] 5.9) If G is a

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model Heikki ikanmäki Jena, March 29, 211 Fractional Lévy processes 1/36 Outline of the talk 1. Introduction 2. Main results 3. Methodology 4. Conclusions

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Remarks: 1. Often we shall be sloppy about specifying the ltration. In all of our examples there will be a Brownian motion around and it will be impli

Remarks: 1. Often we shall be sloppy about specifying the ltration. In all of our examples there will be a Brownian motion around and it will be impli 6 Martingales in continuous time Just as in discrete time, the notion of a martingale will play a key r^ole in our continuous time models. Recall that in discrete time, a sequence ; 1 ;::: ; n for which

More information

MTH The theory of martingales in discrete time Summary

MTH The theory of martingales in discrete time Summary MTH 5220 - The theory of martingales in discrete time Summary This document is in three sections, with the first dealing with the basic theory of discrete-time martingales, the second giving a number of

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.65/15.070J Fall 013 Lecture 11 10/9/013 Martingales and stopping times II Content. 1. Second stopping theorem.. Doob-Kolmogorov inequality. 3. Applications of stopping

More information

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 5 Haijun Li An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Week 5 1 / 20 Outline 1 Martingales

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. 3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time. Orientation. In the examples studied in Chapter 1, we worked with a single period model and Gaussian returns; in this Chapter, we shall drop these assumptions

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

The value of foresight

The value of foresight Philip Ernst Department of Statistics, Rice University Support from NSF-DMS-1811936 (co-pi F. Viens) and ONR-N00014-18-1-2192 gratefully acknowledged. IMA Financial and Economic Applications June 11, 2018

More information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Magnus Wiktorsson September 27, 2018 Magnus Wiktorsson L8 September 27, 2018 1 / 14 The risk neutral valuation formula Let X be contingent claim with maturity T.

More information

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Lecture 1: Lévy processes Lecture 1: Lévy processes A. E. Kyprianou Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Bath 1/ 22 Lévy processes 2/ 22 Lévy processes A process X = {X t : t 0} defined on a probability space (Ω,

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

Random Time Change with Some Applications. Amy Peterson

Random Time Change with Some Applications. Amy Peterson Random Time Change with Some Applications by Amy Peterson A thesis submitted to the Graduate Faculty of Auburn University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Master of Science

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Joint work with Ernst Eberlein Croatian Quants Day University of Zagreb, 9th

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS MATHEMATICAL TRIPOS Part III Friday, 27 May, 2016 1:30 pm to 4:30 pm PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS Attempt no more than FOUR questions. There are SIX questions in total. The questions carry equal

More information

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Gennady Shaikhet supervised by Dr. Gady Zohar The model Market with two securities: b(t) - bond without interest rate p(t) - stock, an Ito process db(t)

More information

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs. Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs Andrea Cosso LPMA, Université Paris Diderot joint work with Francesco Russo ENSTA,

More information

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation 3.1 Itô Integral 3.1.1 Convergence in the Mean and Stieltjes Integral Definition 3.1 (Convergence in the Mean) A sequence {X n } n ln of random

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics and Statistics Washington State University Lisbon, May 218 Haijun Li An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Lisbon,

More information

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 MSc Financial Engineering 2012-13 CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 Department EMS, Birkbeck Introduction The assignment consists of Reading

More information

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Advanced Stochastic Processes. Advanced Stochastic Processes. David Gamarnik LECTURE 16 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Lecture outline Trading strategies Black Scholes option pricing formula 16.1. Security price processes,

More information

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Jhonny Gonzalez School of Mathematics The University of Manchester Magical books project August 23, 2012 Clip for this slide Pricing

More information

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Kyiv, June 19-23, 2006 Tommi Sottinen, University of Helsinki Based on a joint work No-arbitrage pricing beyond semimartingales with C. Bender, Weierstrass

More information

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut Financial Mathematics Spring 22 Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut These notes are c 22 by Richard Bass. They may be used for personal use or class use, but not for commercial

More information

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model Chapter 4 Black-Scholes Model In this chapter we consider a simple continuous (in both time and space financial market model called the Black-Scholes model. This can be viewed as a continuous analogue

More information

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011 Brownian Motion Richard Lockhart Simon Fraser University STAT 870 Summer 2011 Richard Lockhart (Simon Fraser University) Brownian Motion STAT 870 Summer 2011 1 / 33 Purposes of Today s Lecture Describe

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s An Informal Introduction Olav Kallenberg Graduate Student Seminar, April 18, 2012 1 / 33 2 / 33 Simple recursion: Deterministic system, discrete time x n+1 = f (x

More information

4 Risk-neutral pricing

4 Risk-neutral pricing 4 Risk-neutral pricing We start by discussing the idea of risk-neutral pricing in the framework of the elementary one-stepbinomialmodel. Supposetherearetwotimest = andt = 1. Attimethestock has value S()

More information

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS ADRIAN D. BANNER INTECH One Palmer Square Princeton, NJ 8542, USA adrian@enhanced.com DANIEL FERNHOLZ Department of Computer Sciences University

More information

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes Math 6810 (Probability) Fall 2012 Lecture notes Pieter Allaart University of North Texas April 16, 2013 2 Text: Introduction to Stochastic Calculus with Applications, by Fima C. Klebaner (3rd edition),

More information

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications Fima C Klebaner University of Melbourne \ Imperial College Press Contents Preliminaries From Calculus 1 1.1 Continuous and Differentiable Functions.

More information

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard Indifference pricing and the minimal entropy martingale measure Fred Espen Benth Centre of Mathematics for Applications

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon basso@unive.it, mnardon@unive.it Department of Applied Mathematics University Ca Foscari Venice Brownian motion p. 1 Brownian motion Brownian motion plays

More information

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model A Quasi-Likelihood Approach Ziliang Li University of Maryland, College Park GEE RIT, Spring 28 Outline 1 Model Review The Big Model in Mind: Signal + Noise

More information

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This question paper consists of 3 printed pages FinKont KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 211/212) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This exam paper

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 13 Haijun Li Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Week 13 1 / 28 Outline 1 Simulation

More information

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12 Lecture 11: Ito Calculus Continuous time models We start with the model from Chapter 3 log S j log S j 1 = µ t + p tz j Sum it over j: log S N log S 0 = NX µ t + NX p tzj j=1 j=1 Can we take the limit

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension Kristoffer Lindensjö Research Report 216:21 ISSN 165-377

More information

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES D. S. SILVESTROV, H. JÖNSSON, AND F. STENBERG Abstract. A general price process represented by a two-component

More information

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property u n i v e r s i t y o f c o p e n h a g e n d e p a r t m e n t o f m a t h e m a t i c a l s c i e n c e s Faculty of Science Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property Alexander Sokol Department

More information

Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem

Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem Alexander Schied Mannheim University PRisMa Workshop Vienna, September 28, 2009 Joint work with Aurélien Alfonsi and Alla

More information

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies George Tauchen Duke University Viktor Todorov Northwestern University 2013 Motivation

More information

Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena

Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore What is? The definition of volatility may vary wildly around the idea of the standard deviation of price movements

More information

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES from BMO martingales MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES CNRS - CMAP Ecole Polytechnique March 1, 2007 1/ 45 OUTLINE from BMO martingales 1 INTRODUCTION 2 DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES Time Consistency

More information

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval A. N. Shiryaev M. V. Zhitlukhin arxiv:1212.379v1 [math.st] 15 Dec 212 December 18, 212 Abstract We consider optimal

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V Hariharan Narayanan December 7, 2014 Martingales 1 Introduction Martingales were originally introduced into probability theory as a model for fair betting games. Essentially

More information

Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio

Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio Hideaki Miyata Department of Mathematics, Kyoto University Jun Sekine Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University Jan. 6, 2009, Kunitachi, Tokyo 1

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets Chapter 10 From Chapter 9: Pricing Rules: Market complete+nonarbitrage= Asset prices The idea is based on perfect hedge: H = V 0 + T 0 φ t ds t + T 0 φ 0 t ds

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets FREDDY DELBAEN 1 Department of Mathematics Vrije Universiteit Brussel and HIROSHI SHIRAKAWA 2 Department of Industrial and Systems

More information

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 3 - Derivatives with averaging style payoffs 3.1 Pricing models of Asian options Partial differential approach for continuous models Closed form pricing

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information