Introduction to Finance

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Introduction to Finance"

Transcription

1 Introduction to Finance Cours de L2 DEMI2E donné en par Eric Séré Département MIDO, Université Paris-Dauphine Notes prises en cours et mises en forme par Robin Michard

2 Contents Financial markets and instruments 2 2 Interest rates 3 2. Simple interest rate Compound interest Short compounding periods Some useful summation formulas Loans 6 3. Notations Repayment methods Repayment of capital in fine Constant amortization Constant annuity Investment choice 2 4. Present values, future values Present value of a sequence of cash flows The Internal Rate of Return (IRR) Bonds 4 5. Introduction The arbitrage price of a bond Pricing of a bond using zero-coupon bonds Derivatives Futures and forwards Options The binomial model with one time step Multistep binomial model:

3 Chapter Financial markets and instruments See slides 2

4 Chapter 2 Interest rates Note that in this course, all amounts of money and values of assets are expressed in the same unit or currency, for instance the Euro. A unit of time also has to be chosen: unless otherwise stated, it will be a year. Interest is an amount I charged by a lender to a borrower for the use of an amount of money S(0), called the principal, over a period of time T. The amount I depends on the principal and on an interest rate. From the point of view of the lender, the amount of moneygrowswithtime. Indeed,thelenderinvestsS(0)attime0andownsS(T) = S(0)+I at time T. Let S(t) be the value of the lender s investment at time 0 t T. This value is called the accumulated or future value of S(0) at time t. The quotient a(t) = S(t)/S(0) is called accumulation factor or accumulation function. We always have a(0) =. Usually a is a nondecreasing function of time, however in some exceptional situations the interest rate is negative and a is decreasing: 2. Simple interest rate Simple interest rates correspond to affine accumulation functions: a(t) = +tr, 0 t T. So at time T, the borrower has paid the total interest I = TrS(0), and must repay the principal S(0). The number r is the simple interest rate per unit of time. In practice, simple interest is applied for loans over short periods of time T, usually less than a year. 2.2 Compound interest In the case of simple interest, the interest earned is not invested to earn additional interest. In contrast, in the case of compound interest, the duration T of the loan is divided into equal elementary compounding periods T. At the end of each compounding period, the interest earned is reinvested to earn additional interest. As a result, the accumulation factor grows exponentially with time: after n periods of compounding, the accumulation factor is a(n T) = a n where a is the accumulation factor at the end of the first compounding period. As an example, consider a loan with annual interest rate r, compounded annually over N years (taking one year as unit of time, this corresponds to T = ). Assume that this loan is reimbursed in one payment made at the end of the N-th year. At time 0 the lender invests the principal S = S 0. 3

5 At time the interest on S is I = rs. This interest is reinvested, so the basis for calculation of interest over the next period is S = S 0 +I = (+r)s. At time 2 the interest over the period 2 is I 2 = rs = r(+r)s. This interest is reinvested, so the basis for calculation of interest over the next period is S 2 = S +I 2 = (+r)s = (+r) 2 S. At time N the interest over the period N N is I N = rs N = r(+r) N S. The final cash flow received by the investor is S N = S N +I N = (+r)s N = (+r) N S. 2.3 Short compounding periods Notation S will be the principal. r the nominal annual interest rate. m the number of compounding periods per year (for instance m = 2 for monthly compounding, m = 360 for daily compounding). t the number of years (our unit of time is one year). i = r m the interest rate per compounding period. n = mt the number of compounding periods over t years. S n/m the future value (also called accumulated value) of S, after n periods, corresponding to time n/m (in years). r eff the effective annual interest rate. As in 2.2, we see that S n/m = (+i) n S in other words, the future value after t years is S t = (+ r m )mt S We define r eff by the condition S = (+r eff )S 4

6 This means that after year, the accumulated value is the same as for an investment of the principal S with simple annual interest rate r eff. Then, after t years, the accumulated value will be the same as for an investment of the principal with annual interest rate r eff and annual compounding: S t = (+r eff ) t S. In order to determine r eff we have to solve (+r eff )S = (+ r m )m S +r eff = (+ r m )m r eff = (+ r m )m Continuous compounding is a mathematical concept which consists in letting m + : extremely short compounding periods. The result is S t = (+ r m )mt S m ert S So if we have continuous compounding at the nominal annual rate r, the future value after t years is e rt S. In this case r eff = e r. 2.4 Some useful summation formulas arithmetic series: a n = nα+β a k = α k=0 geometric series: g k = r k g 0 with r. k=0 k +(n+)β k= = α n(n+) 2 k=0 +(n+)β ( r g k = g 0 r k n+) = g 0 r g k = krk g 0 with r. g k = rg 0 k=0 k=0 kr k ( ) = rg 0 d r k dr k=0 ( ) = rg 0 d r n+ dr r ( nr n+ (n+)r n ) + = rg 0 ( r) 2 5

7 Chapter 3 Loans A loan takes place between two agents at time t = 0. A : borrower B : lender To reimburse the loan, A will make a sequence of payments to B separated by equal time intervals. Such a sequence is called an annuity. To simplify our notations, the interval of time between successive payments will coincide with the compounding period, and will be our unit of time. 3. Notations S is the principal amount, also called initial capital: the amount borrowed by A at t = 0. n is the maturity, or duration, of the loan. This means the time delay between the beginning of the loan (time 0) and the last payment made by A (at time n). It will be an integer, since our time unit is the interval between successive payments. r is the interest rate of the loan per unit of time. Since we have decided that the compounding period coincides with the unit of time, r is a nominal rate as well as an effective rate, relative to the unit of time which can be a day, a week, a month, a semester, a year... I k is the amount of interest corresponding to the interval of time [k,k] (usually I k is payed at the end of the period k). A k is the amortization: the part of capital refunded at time k. a k = A k +I k is the annuity payed by A at time k. V k is the outstanding capital at time k: the amount of capital still due at the end of the year k, after payment of the annuity a k. We have V k = V k A k At maturity, after payment of the last annuity, we must have V n = 0. 6

8 But V n = V n A n = V n 2 A n A n = S A A 2... A n So S = i= A i Then with S = V 0 The total cost of the loan is I k = rv k Cost = k= I k 3.2 Repayment methods 3.2. Repayment of capital in fine This means that A k = 0 k {0,,...,n } A n = S Then V k = V 0 = S k {0,,...,n } V n = 0 I = I 2 =... = I n = rs = rv 0 We can summarize this in an amortization table k V k I k A k a k 0 V V 0 rv 0 0 rv k V 0 rv 0 0 rv n V 0 rv 0 0 rv 0 n 0 rv 0 V 0 (+r)v 0 Total nrv 0 V 0 (nr+)v Constant amortization This means that A 0 = 0 A k = A k {,2,...,n} 7

9 So So V 0 = na A = V 0 n V k = V k A = V k 2 2A = V ( 0 ka = k ) V 0 n So I k = rv k = r(v 0 (k )A) ( = r k ) V 0 n a k = A+I ( k ) = n +rn k+ V 0 n +(n k +)r = V 0 n k V k I k A k a k 0 ( V 0 ) V n V0 rv 0 0 n. k. ( k n.. n n n 0 V 0 ). ) V0 r ( k n. 2 n rv 0. ) V0 V 0 n. +nr n V 0. +r(n k+) n V 0 V 0 n +2r n V 0 V 0 n V 0 n +r n V 0 Total Cost V 0 Cost+V 0 Cost = I k = k= k=0 = r n V 0 = r n V 0 ( r k ) V 0 n n k+ k= j j= = r n V 0 n(n+) 2 = r(n+)v

10 3.2.3 Constant annuity We borrow an amount of capital S = V 0 at time 0 at an annual rate r > 0. Repayment will take place at the end of each year and annuity will be constant: Question : Find the value of a. The method of present value a = a 2 =... = a n = a Suppose we borrow S = V 0 and the annuities are a,a 2...a n. At the end of the period n I n = rv n a n = I n +A n So So A n = V n a n = rv n +V n = (+r)v n V n = a n (+r) }{{} discount factor Similarly, at the end of period k+. (k n ) I k+ = rv k a k+ = I k+ +A k+ So A k+ = V k V k+ a k+ = rv k +V k V k+ = (+r)v k V k So So V k = discount factor {}}{ (+r) (a k+ +V k+ ) In particular V k = (+r) a k+ +(+r) V k+ = (+r) a k+ +(+r) ((+r) a k+2 +(+r) V k+2 ) = (+r) a k+ +(+r) 2 a k+2 +(+r) 2 V k+2. = (+r) a k (+r) (n k+) a n +(+r) (n k) a n S = V 0 = (+r) k a k k= The interpretation of this formula is that S must equal the present value of the annuity. The notion of present value will be discussed in more detail in the next chapter. One can even allow r >. 9

11 Application to constant annuity a = a 2 =... = a n = a So So Now k {,...,n} ( ) S = a (+r) k = a +r = a +r k= ( n ( ) ) k +r k=0 ( ) n +r +r = a (+r) n r a = rs (+r) n I k = rv k a = I k +A k So We now compute V k : V k = n k i= a k+i (+r) i = a +r So, replacing a by its expression, A k = a rv k n k j=0 ( ) ( j = a ( ) ) n k +r r +r ) n k ( +r V k = S ( +r The above formulas allow us to compute A k : ) n k+ +( +r A k = a rv k = rs ) n ( So A = rs (+r) n = rs = and, for any k n: ( +r ) n +r ) n k+ ( +r ) n rs (+r) n (+r)k A k = (+r) k A We have proved that (A k ) k,...,n is a geometric sequence of multiplier (+r). 0

12 Finally, we compute the cost of the loan: Cost = I k = (a A k ) = na k= k= k= A k So Cost = nrs ( +r ) n S = S nr ( +r ) n Comment : If we assume that payments are made at the end of each year, then r is both the effective and the nominal annual rate. But for a loan with monthly payments and nominal annual rate R, the monthly interest rate is r = R 2, and the number of annuities is n = 2T where T is the maturity of the loan expressed in years.

13 Chapter 4 Investment choice 4. Present values, future values Let A be an actor on the market. Assume that at time t it receives a cash flow a, with the natural convention a > 0 if A receives money, a < 0 if A pays an amount of money. Consider a date s < t. Assume that we are given an effective interest rate r per unit of time; The present value at time s of the future cash flow a is PV(a) = (+r) s t a The factor ( + r) s t is called a discount factor. This notion already appeared in the preceding chapter, in the context of loans. If s > t then the cash flow at time t has a future value at time s > t, given by FV s (a) = (+r) s t a Thefactor (+r) s t is called anaccumulation factor (notion already definedinthechapter on interest rates). 4.2 Present value of a sequence of cash flows If we have an effective interest rate playing the role of a reference, we can evaluate and compare investments using r. Usually, one takes the effective risk-free interest rate per unit of time available on the market. Note, however, that the existence of an interest rate common to all risk-free investments independently of their duration is not very realistic. Givenr,thenetpresentvalueattime0ofasequenceofcashflowsC = (c t0,c t,...,c tn ) occurring at nonnegative times t 0 <... < t N is NPV 0 r (C) = N i=0 c ti (+r) t i This gives us a criterion for comparison between two investments generating the sequences of cash flows C,C 2. We will prefer C if NPV 0 r (C ) > NPV 0 r (C 2 ). If NPV 0 r (C ) = NPV 0 r (C2 ) we say that C and C 2 are indifferent. We will prefer C 2 if NPV 0 r (C ) < NPV 0 r (C 2 ). Limit of the criterion : 2

14 It does not take risk into account. Maturity should play a role. For instance, if NPV 0 r (C ) = NPV 0 r (C2 ) we should prefer the investment with small maturity N. The interest rate r is not easy to choose. 4.3 The Internal Rate of Return (IRR) Definition : Consider a sequence of cash flows C = (c t0,c t,...,c tn ) occurring at nonnegative times t 0 <... < t N. The Internal Rate of Return (IRR) of C is the interest rate r > solution of NPV 0 r (C) = 0 Note that r = IRR(C) is intrinsic: it does not depend on another interest rate r. Unfortunately it can happen that IRR(C) does not exist, or is not unique. Theorem : Consider a sequence of nonzero cash flows C = (c t0,c t,...,c tn ) occurring at nonnegative times t 0 <... < t N. Assume that c t0,c t,...,c tp have the same sign and that c tp+,...,c tn all have the opposite sign to c t0,c t,...,c tp. Then the IRR of C exists and is unique. Proof : We only treat the case c t0,c t,...,c tp < 0 and c tp+,...,c tn > 0 since the other case follows, replacing C by C. Let τ = tp+t p+ 2. Consider the function F(r) = (+r) τ NPV 0 r (C) = p (+r) τ t i c ti + i=0 N i=p+ c ti (+r) t i τ, r >. Obviously, the possible values of the IRR are the solutions of the equation F(r) = 0. Now, the fonction F is well defined and continuous on ],+ [. Moreover r > (+r) τ t i c ti is decreasing for 0 i p. r > ct i (+r) t i τ is decreasing for p+ i N. As a consequence, F is decreasing and continuous on ], + [. Moreover lim r r> lim r + F(r) = + F(r) = So the equation F(r) = 0 has an unique solution, and the theorem is proved. 3

15 Chapter 5 Bonds 5. Introduction Definition A bond is a part of the debt of an institution called the issuer (see slides of Chapter ). It is a debt security, that is, a contract between the owner of the bond and the issuer, which specifies the repayment rules. It has: a face value or nominal value N an annual nominal interest rate z a periodicity of coupon delivery (i.d. payment of interest): if the periodicity is /m year, there are m coupons per year. each year, the amount of interest paid is zn. If the periodicity is /m year, each coupon equals C = z m N. a date of issue (beginning of the contract) and an issue price E. If E = N the bond is issued at par If E < N the bond is issued at a discount If E > N the bond is issued at a premium a maturity date (end of the contract), and a refund price R that the owner receives at maturity. If R = N refund is at par If R < N refund is at a discount If R > N refund is at a premium Sincethe nominal value N, thenominal rate z, theperiodicity of coupons, theduration (also called maturity) and the refund price R are known in advance, bonds are called fixedincome securities. But a bond can be exchanged many times on the secondary market between its date of issue and its date of maturity. Its price on the secondary market varies in an unpredictable way along this period. Question: How can one choose between different bonds? 4

16 Example: Take two bonds A, B each of maturity 2 years, with the same nominal N A = N B = 000 Assume that A delivers two coupons at the end of years, 2, each of value C A = 00. Assume that B delivers only coupon of C B = 000 at the end of year. Assume that both A, B are refunded at par: R A = R B = N = 000 time 2 A B Assume that A is issued at E A = 000, and B at E B = 735 Comparison of A and B Choose an interest rate r, considered as reference(for instance the interest rate of American Treasury Bonds) Then NPV(A) = r + 00 (+r) 2 NPV(B) = r (+r) 2 If NPV(A) > NPV(B), you should prefer A to B (occurs here for r < 0%) NPV(A) < NPV(B), you should prefer B to A (occurs here for r > 0%) NPV(A) = NPV(B), A,B are indifferent (occurs here for r = 0%) 5.2 The arbitrage price of a bond Definition : An arbitrage at time t is a set of financial operations, corresponding to cash flows adding to zero at time t, and which will necessarily generate nonnegative cash flows in the future, with a positive probability that at least one of the future cash flows will be positive. In an ideal market, arbitrage is impossible. This means that the market fixes the prices of assets in such a way that no arbitrage can occur. Our goal is to compute the value of a bond under the no arbitrage hypothesis. This value will be called the arbitrage price of the bond. Another simplifying assumption we make is the perfect liquidity of the market: actors on the market can buy or short-sell arbitrary quantities of securities at any moment without paying trading fees (even non-integer quantities will be allowed, to simplify the arguments). Short-selling means selling a security you do not own. Algebraically, this is equivalent to buying unit of the security.then, in the future, you will have to cancel your short position by buying the same security. If an investor short sells a security that generates an income I in the interval of time before the negative position is closed, he will receive the negative cash flow I (in other words, he will have to pay the amount I). Simplified (and unrealistic) case : Take a market with only two kinds of securities : A risk-free bond (e.g. American Treasury Bonds) at a fixed annual interest rate r, independent of maturity. A (possiblyrisky)bondbthat generates futurecash flow at times t+,...,t+n, F t+,...,f t+n (consisting of coupons and refund at maturity). 5

17 Claim : The arbitrage price of bond B at time t is P arbitrage (B) = i= F t+i (+r) i In other words, P arbitrage (B) is such that NPV r (B,t) = 0 where NPV r (B,t) = P arbitrage (B,t)+ n i= F t+i (+r) i Proof of the claim : we argue by contradiction. Let P = n i= Assume that P B < P. Then we can do the following : F t+i (+r) i At time t, we buy one bond B at price P B, and we sell a fraction f of Treasury Bond A, such that Unit price(a) f = P B (this is equivalent to borrowing the amount P B at interest rate r) At time 0, our net cash flow is P B +P B = 0 at time t+i, we plan to do the following : we receive the amount F i and we reinvest it in Treasury Bonds, for i = t+,...,t+n net cash flow =0. At time t+n, we receive F t+n and we close our line of treasury bonds A. The amount we receive from Treasury Bonds at time t+n is P B (+r) n +F t+ (+r) n +...+F t+i (+r) n i +...+F t+n (+r) So our net cash flow at time t+n is n P B (+r) n + F i (+r) n i +F t+n = (+r) n ( P B +P ) > 0 i= Arbitrage is impossible, so P B P. Similarly, if P B > P we do exactly the opposite operations : we get an arbitrage, which is forbidden. So P B = P, in absence of arbitrage. 5.3 Pricing of a bond using zero-coupon bonds Definition : A zero-coupon bond is a bond that delivers no coupon. At maturity, the owner of the zero-coupon bond receives an amount R equal to its nominal N by convention. So a zero-coupon bond is characterized at time t by: Its date of maturity T t Its nominal N whichis equal toits refundpricer(r is payed at timet). Inthe sequel, we will use the normalization N = R = 00 for one unit of zero-coupon bond. Its price Z(t,T) at time t 6

18 Example : Suppose that on the markets, there are bonds A,B,C,D available at time t = 0. C, D are zero-coupon bonds. Bond t = 0 t = t = 2 A B C D C has price 95 at time 0, it maturity date is and its refund value is 00. D has price 80 at time 0, it maturity date is 2 and its refund value is 00. Using the zero-coupon bonds C and D, we can replicate bond A : We buy unit of bond C + units of bond D, at time 0. We pay = = 975 At time, we receive = 00. At time 2, we receive 00 = 00. Using this replication, we can construct an arbitrage ( free lunch ): Actions t=0 t= t=2 Short-sell unit of A Buy unit of C Buy units of D Invest (+r) 2 Net balance (+r) 2 > 0 Conclusion : considering C and D, the price of A at time 0 is above its arbitrage price P arbitrage (A) = 975. You should not buy bond A, instead you should short-sell it and do the arbitrage. Similarly, we can replicate bond B as follows : Buy 0 C +0 D at time 0. You pay = 750. This is higher than the price of bond B. So we can make an arbitrage: Actions t=0 t= t=2 Buy unit of B Sell 0 unit of C Sell 0 units of D Net balance P arbitrage (B) = 750 > 735 = P B is a market abnormality. General case : on a financial market at time t, we will admit that there are zero-coupon bonds of all maturities T t. We will normalize them so that for each unit of such bonds, the value at maturity is N = R = 00. The price of the zero-coupon bond of maturity date T and nominal N = 00 is Z(t,T) at time t T. 7

19 One defines an interest rate per year z(t,t) of this zero-coupon bond by the formula 00 = (+z(t,t)) T t Z(t,T). In fact, z(t,t) is the I.R.R. of the zero-coupon bond of maturity date T. Indeed, if you buy this bond at time t, the present value at time t of your cash flow with actualization rate z(t,t) is: PV z(t,t) (zero coupon) = Z(t,T)+(+z(t,T)) t T N = 0 Then one can draw the so-called zero-rate curve at time t which is the graph of the function T z(t,t). Usually this function is increasing, due to the preference of investors for short-term investments. But when the market anticipates lower interest rates in the near future, the curve can become flat or even decreasing. The formula for z(t,t) in terms of t,t and Z(t,T) is : z(t,t) = ( ) 00 T t. Z(t,T) Now, take a bond B delivering future cash flows F t,f t2,...,f tn at future times t < t 2 <... < t n = T. Its arbitrage price at time t < t is : P arbitrage (B) = i= F ti (+z(t,t i )) t i t = i= Z(t,t i )F ti 00 Let us prove this equation. To do so, we replicate the bond B using zero-coupon bonds. We remind that F ti is the cash flow at time t i by an owner of one unit of bond B. The replication works as follows: At time t, one buys F t /00 unit of zero-coupon bond of maturity t, F t2 /00 unit of zero-coupon bond of maturity t 2,. F tn /00 unit of zero-coupon bond of maturity t n. For i n, at time t i the only cash flow provided by this replication is coming from step i: F ti /00 units of Z B of maturity t i and nominal N = 00 provide the cash flow (F ti /00) 00 = F ti. This is exactly the cash flow provided by B at time t. This shows that we have built a replication R of B. At time t, the price of R is: P repl = Z(t,t )F t Z(t,t n)f tn = F ti (+z(t,t i )) t i t i= Assume that the price: P of one unit of bond B is smaller than P repl. Then one could : At time t : buy one unit of B, short sell one unit of R. The net cash flow at time t is P(B)+P repl > 0 8

20 At time t i ( i n) : receive F ti from bond B and pay F ti coming from F ti /00 short positions on the Z B of maturity t i NET = 0 This is an arbitrage in the generalized sense : Positive cash flow at time t Nonnegative cash flow in the future Similarly, if we assume that P(B) > P repl we could short sell one unit of B and buy one unit of R. We would get P(B) Prepl at time t, and no cash flow in the future. This shows that P arbitrage (B) = P repl = i= Z(t,t i )F ti 00 = i= F ti (+z(t,t i )) t i t 9

21 Chapter 6 Derivatives Definition : A derivative is a contract on an underlying object, which can be a currency exchange rate, an interest rate, a bond, a stock, or any kind of asset. So the derivative itself is a security, its value at a given time depends on the underlying and on the market. 6. Futures and forwards Definition : in a future/forward contract, two parties A, B decide the following at time 0 : At time T > 0, A will buy from B one unit of a specified underlying asset at a fixed price K. Note that T, the asset and the price K are known at time 0. What is unknown is the price S T of the asset X at time T on the market. By assumption, S T is unpredictable. Note that this contract is symmetric : A will have to buy X from B at price K at time T B will have to sell X to A at price K at time T Forward contracts are traded over the counter, while futures are traded on regulated markets. In their simplest version, forward contracts generate only one cash flow, at time T. In contrast, futures can generate daily cash flows on a margin account, depending on the variation of value of the underlying and the interest rates on the market. The role of these cash flows is to reduce the risk of default of a counterparty at time T. For simplicity, we will focus on forward contracts in the sequel. Notion of payoff : Thepayoff foraat timet willbes T K. SinceP T isunpredictable, Payoff(A) is unpredictable. Payoff(A) is the net cash flow that A will get, buying X from B at price K, and selling it immediately on the market price S T. Similarly, the payoff of B at time T is K S T. This is the cash flow that B will get, buying X on the market at price S T and selling it to A at price K. At time 0, T is known but S T is unknown. So the future payoff is unknown at time 0. Question : can one compute the value of a forward contract for A/B? In other words, should A/B pay a compensation to B/A, at time 0? At time 0, the future value S T of the underlying is unknown, but the present value S 0 of the underlying is known. 20

22 Proposition : In the absence of arbitrage opportunity, the value at time 0 of the forward contract for A is FC 0 = S 0 (+r) T K where r is the interest rate per compounding period (=) for an risk-free investmenton the market (which is assumed to be the same as the interest rate for loans). In other words, if S 0 (+r) T K > 0, then A should pay P 0 = S 0 (+r) T K to B. If S 0 (+r) T K < 0 then B should pay P 0 = (+r) T K S 0 to A (at time 0). Proof : Let P 0 be the algebraic price payed by A to B, in order to sign the contract at time 0. We want to show that P 0 = S 0 (+r) T K. If P 0 < S 0 (+r) T K, A can do the following At t = 0: Sign the contract with B and pay P 0 to B Take a short position on the underlying : cash flow =S 0 Invest the amount (+r) T K (with no risk) at interest rate r The net cash flow of A at time 0 is then : At t = T, A : S 0 P 0 (+r) T K > 0 Buys the underlying from B at price K and sell it immediately : cash flow= K +P T Closes the short position on the underlying (give back the underlying at price P T ) Closes the investment at rate r : cash flow=k This is an arbitrage in the general sense. So we cannot have P 0 < S 0 ( + r) T K. 2. If P 0 > S 0 (+r) T K, B can do the following At t = 0: Sign the contract with A and receive P 0 from A Take a long position on the underlying : cash flow = S 0 Borrow the amount (+r) T K (with no risk) at interest rate r The net cash flow of B at time 0 is then : At t = T, B : S 0 +P 0 +(+r) T K > 0 SellstheunderlyingtoAatpriceK andbuyitimmediately: cashflow=k P T Closes the long position on the underlying(get back the underlying at price P T ) Reimburses the loan at rate r : cash flow=k This is an arbitrage in the general sense. So we cannot have P 0 > S 0 ( + r) T K. 2

23 Definition : The forward price of the underlying X at time 0 is the amount K forward, solution of the equation S 0 (+r) T K = 0 So we have K forward = (+r) T S 0. If the forward contract is such that K = K forward then FC 0 = 0 : there is no cash flow between A and B at time 0. In general, a forward contract does not generate any cash flow between the counterparties at t = 0. This means that K = K forward at time 0. But as t variesintheintervaloftimebetween0andt,theprices t oftheunderlyingandtheinterest rater t (forrisk-freeinvestments andloansofmaturity datet)canvaryinanunpredictable way. This results in a nonzero value FC t of the forward contract, which varies in an unpredictable way according to the no-arbitrage formula FC t = S t ( + r t ) t T K. At time T, this value becomes FC T = S T K : we recognize the payoff of the forward contract. 6.2 Options An option is a contract between two parties A and B, which is not symmetric. As in a forward, there is an underlying asset X. We will only consider European options, for which the future date T of exercise of the option is fixed. There are two kinds of (European) options : Call options : At time 0 A pays an amount P 0 > 0 to B, and gets the right to buy the underlying X from B at time T, at strike price K. B receives P 0 at time 0, but at time T, if A decides to buy X, B will be forced to sell it at price K. In that case, we will say that the option is exercised. We say that the buyer A of the call option is long on the call option, and that the sell B is short on the option. Put options : At time 0, A pays an amount P 0 > 0 to B, and gets the right to sell X to B at time T at the strike price K. B receives P 0 but will be forced to buy X from A at price K at time T. A is long, B is short on the put option. At time T, the value of underlying asset is S T. The strike price is K. Call options : If S T > K we should exercise the option. In this case the call is in the money. If S T = K the call is at the money. If S T < K we should not exercise the option. In this case the call is out of the money. In terms of value: the value of the call at time T is zero if S T K, and equal to S T K > 0 when S T > K. In all case the value or payout of the call at time T is were x + = x if x > 0, x + = 0 if x 0. (S T K) + 22

24 Put options : If S T < K we should exercise the option. In this case the put is in the money. If S T = K the put is at the money. If S T > K we should not exercise the option. In this case the put is out of the money. In terms of value: the value of the put at time T is zero if S T K, and equal to K S T > 0 when S T < K. In all case the value or payout of the put at time T is (K S T ) + Question : How much should one pay for a call? For a put? Let C 0, P 0, V 0 be the value at time 0 of a call, a put and a forward on the same underlying asset X, with same T > 0, same K > 0. Theorem (put-call parity): In the absence of arbitrage opportunity, C 0 P 0 = V 0 Proof: Assume for instance that C 0 P 0 < V 0. At time 0, for the same underlying asset X with same T > 0 and K > 0, you can: Take a long position on a call. Take a short position on a put. Take a short position on a forward. The resulting cash flow is C 0 +P 0 +V 0 > 0 At time T: If S T K you do not exercise the call. But the buyer of the put will decide to sell you X at price K, and you will sell X at price K to the buyer of the forward. Your cash flow is K +K = 0 If S T > K, you exercise the call, but the buyer of the put does not exercise it. You sell X at price K to the buyer of the forward. Your cashflow at time T is then K +K = 0 So, whatever S T is, your cash flow at time T is zero : this is an arbitrage. Similarly, if C 0 P 0 > V 0, at time 0 you can : Take a short position on a call. Take a long position on a put. Take a long position on a forward. The resulting cash flow is C 0 P 0 V 0 > 0 At time T: If S T K you do not exercise the put. But the buyer of the call will decide to buy X from you at price K, and you will buy X at price K to the seller of the forward. Your cash flow is K K = 0 If S T > K, you exercise the put, but the buyer of the call does not exercise it. You buy X at price K to the seller of the forward. Your cash flow at time T is then K K = 0 So, whatever S T is, your cash flow at time T is zero : this is an arbitrage. 23

25 Explanation : behind the proof is the equality In other words : At time T : x + ( x) + = x x R Payoff(call) Payoff(put) = Payoff(forward) This holds for any value of S T. The remaining question is : how can one compute C 0? Naive approach (which fails) Suppose we can only trade the option and the asset X at time t = 0 and t =. One can also lend/borrow cash between t = 0 and t = at interest rate r > 0. At time 0 the asset X has value S 0. At time, it can have three possible values, each with probability 3 : S = 40,70 or 0. We also assume that K = 60 and +r = 0,95 Then +r E((S K) + ) = 9 is the present value of the expected payoff of the call option. A natural idea would be to choose C 0 = 9 as price of the call option at time 0. The problem is that, if C 0 = 9 then an arbitrage is possible. Indeed, at time 0 you could : Sell one call option. Borrow 3 at interest rate r. Buy one underlying asset. Net cash flow at time 0: At time : C 0 +3 S 0 = = 0 If S = 0 or 70 the call option is exercised : you have to sell the asset at price K = 60, and you reimburse 3 (+r) = 3 0,95 = 32,63 Net cash flow = 60 32,63 > 0 Is S = 40, the option is not exercised. You sell your asset on the market at price 40 and you reimburse 32,63. Net cash flow = 40 32;63 > The binomial model with one time step As in the example above, we consider a simplified market with only two dates of trade: t = 0 and t =, and only two assets: a risk-free asset, which is equivalent to the possibility of lending or borrowing cash at a deterministic interest rate r = 0% between t = 0 and t =, and a risky asset X. At time 0 the asset X has value S 0 = 00. The expression binomial model means that at time, the market price S of X can take exactly two possible values, each with nonzero probability : S = 90 or

26 Let K = 0 be the strike price of a call option on the asset. What is the no arbitrage price C(0,) of this option at time 0? It will turn out that one can determine this price without knowing the probability law of S. In order to find it, let us try to replicate the option. Suppose that at time 0 you buy λ units of the underlying asset and you lend µ (euros) without risk at rate r. Here, λ,µ R At time 0 your net cash flow is λs 0 µ = 00λ µ At time, you receive the reimbursement µ(+r) =,µ So : If S = 20 you sell your λ units of asset and receive S λ = 20λ If S = 90 you sell λ assets and receive 90λ If S = 20 your net cash flow is 20λ+,µ If S = 90 your net cash flow is 90λ+,µ If, instead, you buy unit of option at time 0, your cash flow at time 0 is C(0,). At time : If S = 20 you buy the asset at K = 0, you sell it on the market at S = 20: net cash flow = 0. If S = 90 you do nothing : net cash flow = 0. A replication must provide the same future cash flow as the call option, in any situation : { 20λ+,µ = 0 L Subtracting L L 2, we get 90λ+,µ = 0 L 2 30λ = 0 λ = 3 L 2 µ = 90, λ = 30, of asset and in borrowing µ = 30, (euros) So the replication corresponds to buying 3 at interest rate r. General principle : If two investment strategies deliver exactly the same cash flows in the future, then their price at time 0 should be the same; otherwise an arbitrage would be possible. Consequence : the no arbitrage price C(0,) of the option is the price of its replication at time 0: C(0,) = 00λ+µ = , One can give general formulas taking r > 0 arbitrary and S = u S 0 or S = d S 0, with 0 < d < u. Assume that ds 0 < K < us 0. If we buy λ units of asset and lend µ euros at time 0, then at time : If S = us 0 we receive S 0 uλ+(+r)µ 25

27 If S = ds 0 we receive S 0 dλ+(+r)µ So { S0 uλ+(+r)µ = us So : 0 K S 0 dλ+(+r)µ = 0 λ = us 0 K S 0 (u d) µ = d us 0 K u d +r C(0,) = S 0 λ+µ C(0,) = S 0 λ+µ = us 0 K u d = us 0 K u d d us 0 K ( u d +r d ) +r Risk-neutral probability : Let us look for a probability law P on the issues us 0, ds 0 such that +r E P ((S K) + ) = C(0,). In other words, we look for P, probability law on the random variable S, such that the present value of the call s expected payoff is the same as its no arbitrage price. It turns out that this problem has a unique solution P, which is called the risk-neutral probability law. Let us compute P. Let p = P (S = us 0 ). Then So the condition on p is : +r E P ((S K) + ) = p +r (us 0 K) p +r (us 0 K) = us 0 K u d ( d ) +r p = +r ( d ) +r d = u d +r u d In order to guarantee 0 < p < we must have which is equivalent to 0 < +r d < u d d < +r < u Note that the assumption d < +r < u is necessary if we want to forbid arbitrage. Indeed if, for instance, +r d, then at time 0, we can borrow the amount S 0 at rate r and buy one unit of asset at price S 0 net cash flow = S 0 S 0 = 0 At time, we reimburse (+r)s 0 and we sell the asset at price ds 0 net cash flow (+r)s 0 +ds 0 = (d (+r))s 0 Moreover, the price of the asset at time is us 0 with positive probability net cash flow = (u (+r))s 0 > 0 with positive probability (here we refer to the true probability law). 26

28 Similarly, if u +r, we can do the opposite (lend S 0 and short sell one unit of asset) and we obtain an arbitrage. This ends the argument. so Coming back to the risk-neutral probability, we have seen that P (S = us 0 ) = p = +r d u d P (S = ds 0 ) = p = u (+r) u d meaning that the price of the call on the asset at time 0 Now, we compute C(0,) = +r E P ((S K) + ) +r E P (S ) = +r (p u+( p )d)s 0 = S 0 Finally, consider an amount A 0 invested at time 0 at rate r. Since its value at time is deterministic, we have +r E(A ) = +r (+r)a 0 = A 0. So any contract consisting of a linear combination of the underlying asset X, the option and the risk-free asset will have the property V 0 = +r E P (V ) Note that this property implies that no arbitrage is possible. Indeed, an arbitrage would be a linear combination of contracts with value V 0 = 0 at time 0. By the property, its value V at time would satisfy S 0 E P (V ) = 0, so either V is identically zero or it can have two opposite signs, each with positive probability (even if P is not the true probability, an event has nonzero probability for P if and only if it has nonzero true probability). This shows that no arbitrage is possible!!! 6.4 Multistep binomial model: Now we consider a more complex model involving n + dates of trade: 0,,,n but only two assets as before: a riskless asset with is equivalent to the possibility of borrowing or lending cash at a deterministic rate r per unit of time, with compounding period equal to ; and a risky asset X of known value S 0 at time 0. We assume that, if the value S i of X is known at time i, then S i+ can only take two values : us i or ds i, 0 < d < +r < u. After n iterations, the possible values of S n are u k d n k S 0, where k is the number of times i such that the asset price varies from S i to us i. Question : What is the price C(0,n) at time 0 of a European call on one unit of asset X, with exercise date n and strike price K? As often in Mathematics, it is easier to solve a more general question : Take 0 i n. What is the price C(i,n) at time i of a call on one unit of asset X with exercise date n and strike price K? One can determine C(i,n) going backwards, from i = n to i = 0. 27

29 What is C(n,n)? We can consider the one-step binomial model of evolution from the (known) value S n to the random value S n. This amount to consider the risk-neutral probability law of S n conditional to S n. We get C(n,n) = +r E P ((S n K) + S n ) = +r E P (C(n,n) S n ) Similarly, at each step, knowing C(i+,n) in all possible situations occuring at time i+, we can compute C(i,n) = +r E P (C(i+,n) S i ) = p +r uc(i,n)+ p +r dc(i,n) in all situations occuring at time i. In fact there is even a global formula: C(0,n) = (+r) ne P ((S n K) + ) Note that, under P, the event { S n = u k d n k S 0 } has probability C k n pk ( p ) n k so we find the following formula for the no arbitrage price at time 0 of our European call option: C(0,n) = (+r) ne P ((S n K) + ) = (+r) n Cnp k k ( p ) n k (S 0 u k d n k K) + +r d p = u d Now, we take a time unit such that the time delay between step k and k + is T, very small, with T = n T fixed, and n. Note that ln(s k+ ) = ln(s k )+ln(u) or ln(s k )+ln(d) Denote ( ) Sk Y k = ln k n S k Then Y k is a random variable which equals ln(u) with probability p and ln(d) with probability ( p ), and Y,...,Y n are independent. Then ln( Sn S 0 ) = Y +...+Y n hence k=0 C(0,n) = +r E P ((S 0 e Y +...+Y n K) + ) As n, ) it seems reasonable to expect that the mean and variance of the random variable ln( Sn S 0 remain finite. This is achieved if for some fixed σ > 0 and some fixed real number µ, Then ( u = exp µ T +σ ) T ( d = exp µ T +σ ) T { ln(u) = µ T +σ T ln(d) = µ T σ T = +(µ+ σ2 2 ) T +σ T +o( T) = +(µ+ σ2 2 ) T σ T +o( T) 28

30 Moreover, the compounding period is now T, so the interest rate for this period should behave like r T instead of r. This gives a formula for p. We find p = +r T d u d = (r µ σ2 ) 2 T +O( T). σ hence E P (Y k ) = T(r σ2 2 )+o( T) and Var P (Y k ) = σ 2 T +o( T). So, by the central limit theorem, the random variable W n = Y +...+Y n T(r σ 2 ) σ converges in law to N(0,) as n goes to infinity (remarkably, µ has now disappeared from the T formulas). As a result, one finds, for n very large, the approximation ( ) ( ST ln N (r ) 2 σ2 )T,σ 2 T hence, in the limit n, S 0 C(0,T) = e rt E P ((S T K) + ) = e rt σ 2πT + where ν = ln(s 0 )+(r σ2 ) 2 )T. This is the Black-Scholes formula for European option pricing. lnk e (y ν)2 2σ 2 T (e y K)dy 2 29

Introduction to Financial Mathematics

Introduction to Financial Mathematics Introduction to Financial Mathematics MTH 210 Fall 2016 Jie Zhong November 30, 2016 Mathematics Department, UR Table of Contents Arbitrage Interest Rates, Discounting, and Basic Assets Forward Contracts

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Fixed-Income Options

Fixed-Income Options Fixed-Income Options Consider a two-year 99 European call on the three-year, 5% Treasury. Assume the Treasury pays annual interest. From p. 852 the three-year Treasury s price minus the $5 interest could

More information

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Appendix A Financial Calculations Derivatives Demystified: A Step-by-Step Guide to Forwards, Futures, Swaps and Options, Second Edition By Andrew M. Chisholm 010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appendix A Financial Calculations TIME VALUE OF MONEY

More information

2 The binomial pricing model

2 The binomial pricing model 2 The binomial pricing model 2. Options and other derivatives A derivative security is a financial contract whose value depends on some underlying asset like stock, commodity (gold, oil) or currency. The

More information

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13 Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree An over-simplified model with surprisingly general extensions a single time step from 0 to T two types of traded securities: stock S and a bond

More information

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3 Chapter 3 The Binomial Model In Chapter 1 the linear derivatives were considered. They were priced with static replication and payo tables. For the non-linear derivatives in Chapter 2 this will not work

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58-6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15-19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9-31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36-37)

More information

fig 3.2 promissory note

fig 3.2 promissory note Chapter 4. FIXED INCOME SECURITIES Objectives: To set the price of securities at the specified moment of time. To simulate mathematical and real content situations, where the values of securities need

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance Lecture 1 s from finance Financial market instruments can be divided into two types. There are the underlying stocks shares, bonds, commodities, foreign currencies; and their derivatives, claims that promise

More information

CONTENTS Put-call parity Dividends and carrying costs Problems

CONTENTS Put-call parity Dividends and carrying costs Problems Contents 1 Interest Rates 5 1.1 Rate of return........................... 5 1.2 Interest rates........................... 6 1.3 Interest rate conventions..................... 7 1.4 Continuous compounding.....................

More information

The Multistep Binomial Model

The Multistep Binomial Model Lecture 10 The Multistep Binomial Model Reminder: Mid Term Test Friday 9th March - 12pm Examples Sheet 1 4 (not qu 3 or qu 5 on sheet 4) Lectures 1-9 10.1 A Discrete Model for Stock Price Reminder: The

More information

Chapter 2: BASICS OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES

Chapter 2: BASICS OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES Chapter 2: BASICS OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES 2.1 DISCOUNT FACTORS 2.1.1 Discount Factors across Maturities 2.1.2 Discount Factors over Time 2.1 DISCOUNT FACTORS The discount factor between two dates, t

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Department of Mathematics MA408 Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Thursday 15th January, 2009 2pm 4pm Duration: 2 hours Attempt THREE questions MA408 Page 1 of 5 1. (a) Suppose 0 < E 1 < E 3 and E 2

More information

1 Interest Based Instruments

1 Interest Based Instruments 1 Interest Based Instruments e.g., Bonds, forward rate agreements (FRA), and swaps. Note that the higher the credit risk, the higher the interest rate. Zero Rates: n year zero rate (or simply n-year zero)

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/33 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/33 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher) Advanced Corporate Finance 5. Options (a refresher) Objectives of the session 1. Define options (calls and puts) 2. Analyze terminal payoff 3. Define basic strategies 4. Binomial option pricing model 5.

More information

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis Contents 2 Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 2.1 Definitions.................................... 16 2.1.1 Rate of

More information

Deterministic Cash-Flows

Deterministic Cash-Flows IEOR E476: Foundations of Financial Engineering Fall 215 c 215 by Martin Haugh Deterministic Cash-Flows 1 Basic Theory of Interest Cash-flow Notation: We use (c, c 1,..., c i,..., c n ) to denote a series

More information

6. Pricing deterministic payoffs

6. Pricing deterministic payoffs Some of the content of these slides is based on material from the book Introduction to the Economics and Mathematics of Financial Markets by Jaksa Cvitanic and Fernando Zapatero. Pricing Options with Mathematical

More information

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis Contents 2 Interest Rates 16 2.1 Definitions.................................... 16 2.1.1 Rate of Return..............................

More information

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis Help Session 2 David Sovich Washington University in St. Louis TODAY S AGENDA 1. Refresh the concept of no arbitrage and how to bound option prices using just the principle of no arbitrage 2. Work on applying

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/27 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/27 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives M. Vidyasagar Cecil & Ida Green Chair The University of Texas at Dallas Email: M.Vidyasagar@utdallas.edu October

More information

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 3: Term structure of interest rates

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 3: Term structure of interest rates MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 3: Term structure of interest rates A. Salo, T. Seeve Systems Analysis Laboratory Department of System Analysis and Mathematics Aalto University, School of Science Overview

More information

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS May/June 2006 Time allowed: 2 HOURS. Examiner: Dr N.P. Byott This is a CLOSED

More information

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Basic Concepts and Techniques of Risk Management Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA School of Mathematics Main Series UG Examination 2016 17 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A Time allowed: 3 Hours Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other

More information

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Financial Derivatives Section 5 Financial Derivatives Section 5 The Black and Scholes Model Michail Anthropelos anthropel@unipi.gr http://web.xrh.unipi.gr/faculty/anthropelos/ University of Piraeus Spring 2018 M. Anthropelos (Un. of

More information

Reading. Valuation of Securities: Bonds

Reading. Valuation of Securities: Bonds Valuation of Securities: Bonds Econ 422: Investment, Capital & Finance University of Washington Last updated: April 11, 2010 Reading BMA, Chapter 3 http://finance.yahoo.com/bonds http://cxa.marketwatch.com/finra/marketd

More information

Investment Science. Part I: Deterministic Cash Flow Streams. Dr. Xiaosong DING

Investment Science. Part I: Deterministic Cash Flow Streams. Dr. Xiaosong DING Investment Science Part I: Deterministic Cash Flow Streams Dr. Xiaosong DING Department of Management Science and Engineering International Business School Beijing Foreign Studies University 100089, Beijing,

More information

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options These notes 1 introduce forwards, swaps, futures and options as well as the basic mechanics

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Discrete time interest rate models

Discrete time interest rate models slides for the course Interest rate theory, University of Ljubljana, 2012-13/I, part II József Gáll University of Debrecen, Faculty of Economics Nov. 2012 Jan. 2013, Ljubljana Introduction to discrete

More information

Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Kyle Hambrook

Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Kyle Hambrook Introduction to Financial Mathematics Kyle Hambrook August 7, 2017 Contents 1 Probability Theory: Basics 3 1.1 Sample Space, Events, Random Variables.................. 3 1.2 Probability Measure..............................

More information

The Theory of Interest

The Theory of Interest The Theory of Interest An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2010 Simple Interest (1 of 2) Definition Interest is money paid by a bank or other financial institution

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Derivative Instruments

Derivative Instruments Derivative Instruments Paris Dauphine University - Master I.E.F. (272) Autumn 2016 Jérôme MATHIS jerome.mathis@dauphine.fr (object: IEF272) http://jerome.mathis.free.fr/ief272 Slides on book: John C. Hull,

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives Lecture 9 Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives 9.1 Forward risk adjusted probability measures This section is a preparation for valuation of fixed-income derivatives.

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

2.6.3 Interest Rate 68 ESTOLA: PRINCIPLES OF QUANTITATIVE MICROECONOMICS

2.6.3 Interest Rate 68 ESTOLA: PRINCIPLES OF QUANTITATIVE MICROECONOMICS 68 ESTOLA: PRINCIPLES OF QUANTITATIVE MICROECONOMICS where price inflation p t/pt is subtracted from the growth rate of the value flow of production This is a general method for estimating the growth rate

More information

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS 1 2 FAIR PRICING There is a market for an object called S. The prevailing price today is S 0 = 100. At this price the object S can be bought or sold by anyone for any

More information

Term Structure Lattice Models

Term Structure Lattice Models IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models These lecture notes introduce fixed income derivative securities and the modeling philosophy used to

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves

1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves Risk Management Topic One Credit yield curves and credit derivatives 1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves 1.2 Credit default swaps 1.3 Credit spread and bond price based pricing 1.4

More information

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments Valuing fixed cash flows Two basic rules: - Value additivity: Find the portfolio of zero-coupon bonds which replicates the cash flows of the security, the price

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

************************

************************ Derivative Securities Options on interest-based instruments: pricing of bond options, caps, floors, and swaptions. The most widely-used approach to pricing options on caps, floors, swaptions, and similar

More information

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005 Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation Practice Problems (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005 {This posting has more information than is needed for the corporate

More information

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives In these lecture notes we introduce the main approaches to credit modeling and we will largely

More information

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences. Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences. Futures, and options on futures. Martingales and their role in option pricing. A brief introduction

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

Page 1. Real Options for Engineering Systems. Financial Options. Leverage. Session 4: Valuation of financial options

Page 1. Real Options for Engineering Systems. Financial Options. Leverage. Session 4: Valuation of financial options Real Options for Engineering Systems Session 4: Valuation of financial options Stefan Scholtes Judge Institute of Management, CU Slide 1 Financial Options Option: Right (but not obligation) to buy ( call

More information

MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management

MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management William C. H. Leon Nanyang Business School January 16, 2018 1 / 63 William C. H. Leon MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management 1 Overview Value of Cash Flows Value of a Bond

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 Stochastic Financial Modelling Time allowed: 2 hours Candidates should attempt all questions. Marks for each question

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE81.98 School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology January Semester Presented by Dr. Thitisak Boonpramote Department

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10.

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10. IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models Fall 2013, Professor Whitt Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10. The Central Limit Theorem and Stock Prices 1. The Central Limit Theorem (CLT See

More information

MAFS Computational Methods for Pricing Structured Products

MAFS Computational Methods for Pricing Structured Products MAFS550 - Computational Methods for Pricing Structured Products Solution to Homework Two Course instructor: Prof YK Kwok 1 Expand f(x 0 ) and f(x 0 x) at x 0 into Taylor series, where f(x 0 ) = f(x 0 )

More information

MS-E2114 Investment Science Exercise 10/2016, Solutions

MS-E2114 Investment Science Exercise 10/2016, Solutions A simple and versatile model of asset dynamics is the binomial lattice. In this model, the asset price is multiplied by either factor u (up) or d (down) in each period, according to probabilities p and

More information

MAT25 LECTURE 10 NOTES. = a b. > 0, there exists N N such that if n N, then a n a < ɛ

MAT25 LECTURE 10 NOTES. = a b. > 0, there exists N N such that if n N, then a n a < ɛ MAT5 LECTURE 0 NOTES NATHANIEL GALLUP. Algebraic Limit Theorem Theorem : Algebraic Limit Theorem (Abbott Theorem.3.3) Let (a n ) and ( ) be sequences of real numbers such that lim n a n = a and lim n =

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

Principles of Financial Computing

Principles of Financial Computing Principles of Financial Computing Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu Dept. Computer Science & Information Engineering and Department of Finance National Taiwan University c 2008 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University

More information

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money Lecture 1 Pre- Derivatives Basics Stocks and bonds are referred to as underlying basic assets in financial markets. Nowadays, more and more derivatives are constructed and traded whose payoffs depend on

More information

Slides for Risk Management

Slides for Risk Management Slides for Risk Management Introduction to the modeling of assets Groll Seminar für Finanzökonometrie Prof. Mittnik, PhD Groll (Seminar für Finanzökonometrie) Slides for Risk Management Prof. Mittnik,

More information

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline Lattice Model of System Evolution Richard de Neufville Professor of Engineering Systems and of Civil and Environmental Engineering MIT Massachusetts Institute of Technology Lattice Model Slide 1 of 48

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

American options and early exercise

American options and early exercise Chapter 3 American options and early exercise American options are contracts that may be exercised early, prior to expiry. These options are contrasted with European options for which exercise is only

More information

Global Financial Management. Option Contracts

Global Financial Management. Option Contracts Global Financial Management Option Contracts Copyright 1997 by Alon Brav, Campbell R. Harvey, Ernst Maug and Stephen Gray. All rights reserved. No part of this lecture may be reproduced without the permission

More information

Actuarial and Financial Maths B. Andrew Cairns 2008/9

Actuarial and Financial Maths B. Andrew Cairns 2008/9 Actuarial and Financial Maths B 1 Andrew Cairns 2008/9 4 Arbitrage and Forward Contracts 2 We will now consider securities that have random (uncertain) future prices. Trading in these securities yields

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

The Theory of Interest

The Theory of Interest The Theory of Interest An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2014 Simple Interest (1 of 2) Definition Interest is money paid by a bank or other financial institution

More information

Binomial Option Pricing

Binomial Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing The wonderful Cox Ross Rubinstein model Nico van der Wijst 1 D. van der Wijst Finance for science and technology students 1 Introduction 2 3 4 2 D. van der Wijst Finance for science

More information

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS QRMC07 9/7/0 4:45 PM Page 5 CHAPTER SEVEN ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS 7. AN INTRODUCTION TO MATRICES Investors frequently encounter situations involving numerous potential outcomes, many discrete periods

More information

Sequences, Series, and Limits; the Economics of Finance

Sequences, Series, and Limits; the Economics of Finance CHAPTER 3 Sequences, Series, and Limits; the Economics of Finance If you have done A-level maths you will have studied Sequences and Series in particular Arithmetic and Geometric ones) before; if not you

More information

Problems and Solutions

Problems and Solutions 1 CHAPTER 1 Problems 1.1 Problems on Bonds Exercise 1.1 On 12/04/01, consider a fixed-coupon bond whose features are the following: face value: $1,000 coupon rate: 8% coupon frequency: semiannual maturity:

More information

Mathematics 102 Fall Exponential functions

Mathematics 102 Fall Exponential functions Mathematics 102 Fall 1999 Exponential functions The mathematics of uncontrolled growth are frightening. A single cell of the bacterium E. coli would, under ideal circumstances, divide about every twenty

More information

Credit Risk. June 2014

Credit Risk. June 2014 Credit Risk Dr. Sudheer Chava Professor of Finance Director, Quantitative and Computational Finance Georgia Tech, Ernest Scheller Jr. College of Business June 2014 The views expressed in the following

More information

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives

Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives Lecture 9 Forward Risk Adjusted Probability Measures and Fixed-income Derivatives 9.1 Forward risk adjusted probability measures This section is a preparation for valuation of fixed-income derivatives.

More information

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps A derivative asset is any asset whose payoff, price or value depends on the payoff, price or value of another asset. The underlying or primitive asset may be almost

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205 Option Pricing Models c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205 If the world of sense does not fit mathematics, so much the worse for the world of sense. Bertrand Russell (1872 1970)

More information

MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I

MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I Albert Cohen Actuarial Sciences Program Department of Mathematics Department of Statistics and Probability C336 Wells Hall Michigan State University East

More information

Econometrica Supplementary Material

Econometrica Supplementary Material Econometrica Supplementary Material PUBLIC VS. PRIVATE OFFERS: THE TWO-TYPE CASE TO SUPPLEMENT PUBLIC VS. PRIVATE OFFERS IN THE MARKET FOR LEMONS (Econometrica, Vol. 77, No. 1, January 2009, 29 69) BY

More information

Monte Carlo Simulation in Financial Valuation

Monte Carlo Simulation in Financial Valuation By Magnus Erik Hvass Pedersen 1 Hvass Laboratories Report HL-1302 First edition May 24, 2013 This revision June 4, 2013 2 Please ensure you have downloaded the latest revision of this paper from the internet:

More information

A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD

A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD 1. INTRODUCTION This document lays out some of the basic definitions of terms used in financial markets. First of all, the

More information