Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for No Static Arbitrage among European Calls

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for No Static Arbitrage among European Calls"

Transcription

1 Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for No Static Arbitrage among European Calls Laurent Cousot Courant Institute New York University 251 Mercer Street New York, NY, 112, USA First Version: September 15, 24. This version: October 28, 24. Abstract Under the assumption of the absence of arbitrage, European call prices on a given asset must satisfy well-known inequalities, which have been described in the landmark paper Merton (1973). If we further assume that there is no interest rate volatility and that the underlying pays continuously deterministic dividends, cross maturity inequalities must also be satisfied by the call prices. We show that there exists an arbitrage free model, which is consistent with the call prices, if these inequalities are satisfied. Furthermore, we describe an algorithm to obtain a realistic calibrated martingale Markov chain model, using the notions of entropy and of copula. JEL classification: C51, G13. AMS classification codes: 6J1, 6J2, 6J22. Key words: option pricing, arbitrage, Markov chains, entropy, copula. I am grateful to Peter Carr, Bruno Dupire, and more generally to the Bloomberg Quantitative Finance Research Team for all their insights. I am also grateful to Brian Barber for useful comments. All errors are of course my own. Extended version of a paper registered at SSRN, 9/21/24, Abstract ID

2 1 Introduction In trying to understand the dynamics of a given underlying, the financial markets only tell part of the story. For example, options quotes yield some information about the marginal distributions at specific future times. However a complete specification of the possible future behavior of the underlying remains largely undetermined. Consequently, to bet on an arbitrage strategy based on a particular market structure can be very risky as explained in the enlightening binomial-tree based example of Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor (23) (henceforth CGMY). It makes more sense to restrict oneself to static strategies in which the future behavior of the underlying is less relevant. Nevertheless, it is not sufficient to make the notion of arbitrage independent of the real statistical measure. Indeed, classical static arbitrage strategies involving vertical (or call) spreads, butterfly spreads and calendar spreads do not depend on the statistical measure. But is it possible to claim that the elimination of these strategies is sufficient to prevent static arbitrage without specifying a statistical measure? The answer is no. Indeed, if the price of a call is zero and the probability that the underlying will be greater than the strike at maturity is positive, then to buy the call is an arbitrage strategy. Likewise, if the price of a call is positive and the probability that the underlying will be greater than or equal to the strike at maturity is zero, then to sell the call is an arbitrage strategy. In this paper, we will show that these necessary conditions for the absence of static arbitrage are also sufficient for the existence of a market model which is consistent with the call quotes and further, is (static) arbitrage free. We generalize the results of Carr and Madan (24) by allowing the underlying to be a deterministic dividend paying stock, the short interest rate to be a deterministic function of time, and the grid of the available strikes to be finite and not rectangular. Furthermore, we describe an algorithm to construct a more realistic calibrated martingale Markov chain model. The structure of this paper is given as follows. Section 2 describes the assumptions we make and introduces some calendar versions of the classical vertical and butterfly spreads; Section 3 describes a way to construct a marginal distribution consistent with call quotes corresponding to a given maturity; Section 4 uses this construction to exhibit a martingale measure, which prevents arbitrage; Section 5 recalls briefly why the conditions are necessary for the absence of static arbitrage; Section 6 explains how to construct a more realistic calibrated Markov chain model; Section 7 explains how to relax some of the starting assumptions; Section 8 concludes. 2 Assumptions and definitions We assume that we have at our disposal a finite set of call quotes on a given non-dividend paying stock. The maturities, indexed in increasing order, will be denoted by (T i ) 1 i m. For a given maturity T i, n i quotes are available corresponding to the strikes K i 1 <... < K i j <... < Ki n i and will be denoted by (C i j ) 1 j n i. We also assume that there is no interest rate. For each maturity, we will add a quote corresponding to a call struck at. By convention, K i = and C i = S - the initial stock price - by arbitrage. Now we will extend the classical definitions of vertical, calendar and butterfly spreads because the grid of available strikes is not rectangular. The calendar version of a vertical (resp. butterfly) spread must be thought of as a linear combination of calendar spreads and a classical vertical (resp. butterfly) spread. Definition 2.1 (Vertical Spreads). i [1, m], V S i j Ci j 1 Ci j K i j Ki j 1 V S i 1 1 j n i Definition 2.2 (Calendar (Vertical) Spreads). i 1, i 2 [1, m] s.t. i 1 i 2, [, n i1 ], [, n i2 ] s.t. K i1 K i2 CV S i1,i2, C i2 C i1 2

3 Definition 2.3 ((Calendar) Butterfly Spreads). i, i 1, i 2 [1, m] s.t. i i 1 and i i 2, j [, n i ], [, n i1 ], [, n i2 ] s.t. K i1 < Kj i < Ki2 CBS i,i1,i2 j,, CV Si1,i,j K i1 Kj i CV Si,i2 j, K i j Ki2 3 Construction of discrete risk-neutral marginal distributions Lemma 3.1 (Discrete Distribution). If N N, k = <... < k j <... < k N are N +1 real numbers and P C : R + R is a function, which is continuous, convex, linear and decreasing on each interval [k j ; k j+1 ] with j N 1 (with a slope greater than or equal to -1 on [k ; k 1 ]) and zero after k N then the following distribution µ = q j δ kj with is such that: for all K R +. j= q = 1 P C(k ) P C (k 1 ) k 1 k q j = P C(k j 1 ) P C (k j ) k j k j 1 P C(k j ) P C (k j+1 ) k j+1 k j, 1 j N 1 q N = P C(k N 1 ) k N k N 1 g(k) (x K) + dµ = P C (K) (1) Proof. The non-negativity of q is ensured by the condition on the slope of P C on [k ; k 1 ]. Further q j (1 j N 1) due to the convexity of P C. Finally q N is non-negative because P C is also non-negative. Moreover, k= q k = q + P C(k ) P C (k 1 ) P C(k N 1 ) P C (k N ) + q N k 1 k k N k N 1 = 1 P C(k ) P C (k 1 ) k 1 k + P C(k ) P C (k 1 ) k 1 k P C(k N 1 ) P C (k N ) k N k N 1 + P C(k N 1 ) k N k N 1 = 1 + P C(k N ) k N k N 1 = 1 We now show that the distribution results in a linear call price function g between two nodes [k j ; k j+1 ], j N 1. K (k j ; k j+1 ], we have: g(k) = = q k (k k K) + k= = j+1 k N j+1 k N q k (k k K) q k k k K j+1 k N q k 3

4 Figure 1: Sketch of a possible discrete distribution. Moreover g is also right-continuous in k j. Indeed, g(k) K k + j j+1 k N q k (k k k j ) = j k N q k (k k k j ) = g(k j ) Clearly g is zero on [k N, + ). Now if we prove that the slopes are equal on each segment [k j ; k j+1 ], j N 1, we will be able to conclude that the functions g and P C are equal. Accordingly, g(k j+1 ) g(k j ) = j+1 k N = (k j k j+1 ) q k (k k k j+1 ) j+1 k N q k j+1 k N = (k j k j+1 ) P C(k j ) P C (k j+1 ) k j+1 k j = P C (k j+1 ) P C (k j ) q k (k k k j ) In the next section, we will use this lemma to construct marginal distributions. The quoted strikes will be among the k j and their corresponding prices will be given by the function P C. Consequently the distribution µ will be a risk-neutral marginal distribution for the given maturity. 4 Sufficient conditions for the existence of a martingale measure 4.1 Outline of the proof If we are able to construct marginal distributions, that are consistent with the call quotes and the initial stock price, non-decreasing in the convex order (henceforth NDCO) and have the same mean, then we can conclude that there exists a martingale consistent with all these marginal distributions due to Kellerer theorem. 4

5 Theorem 4.1 (Kellerer theorem (1972)). Let (µ t ) t [,T] be a family of probability measures on (R, B(R)) with first moment, such that for s < t µ t dominates µ s in the convex order, i.e. for each convex function φ R R µ t -integrable for each t [, T], we must have: φdµ t φdµ s R Then there exists a Markov process (M t ) t [,T] with these marginals for which it is a submartingale. Furthermore if the means are independent of t then (M t ) t [,T] is a martingale. Proof. See Kellerer (1972). 4.2 Construction of marginal distributions that are NDCO Proposition 4.2. Let us assume that: i [1, m], C i j, V S i j [, 1] R j n i 1 j n i V S i j > if 1 j n i and C i j 1 > i 1, i 2 [1, m] s.t. i 1 < i 2, [, n i1 ], [, n i2 ] CV S i1,i2, if K i1 K i2 CV S i1,i2, > if K i1 > K i2 and C i1 > i, i 1, i 2 [1, m] s.t. i i 1 and i i 2, j [, n i ], [, n i1 ], [, n i2 ] s.t. K i1 < K i j < Ki2 CBS i,i1,i2 j,, then there exists m risk-neutral distributions (φ j ) 1 j m corresponding to the different maturities. Let us define φ δ S. (φ j ) j m are NDCO and their means are all equal to S. Before proving this proposition, we would like to give some insight on the required conditions. If a martingale is consistent with the quoted call prices, then the general call price function would be nonincreasing and convex in the strike, as well as non-decreasing in the maturity. For example, we can easily conclude that a situation as the one described in Table 1 is not compatible with the existence of a pricing martingale. Indeed if there was a pricing martingale, then x 3 and x 2, which is impossible. Maturity \ Strike month x 3 3 months 2 Table 1 Another more complicated example is given by Table 2. Maturity \ Strike month 37 3 months x 1 x months 4 Table 2 5

6 Here the condition on the calendar butterfly spread is violated and this can be explained as follows: if there was a pricing martingale, then we would have: 4 x 1 (The price is non-decreasing with maturity.) x x 2 2 (The price is convex with respect to the strike.) x 2 37 (The price is non-decreasing with maturity.) and this would result in 35 = This last example allows us to understand why the strike corresponding to the nearest maturity is always between the two other strikes in the definition of the calendar butterfly spread. The same kind of conclusions could not be drawn in a situation such as the one described in Table 3. Maturity \ Strike month 4 3 months 3 6 months 37 Table 3 Proof. Lemma 3.1 tells us how to associate in a one-to-one way a distribution with a T i -call price function if the latter respects the given conditions. Consequently, to construct the marginal distributions, we will construct call price functions which have the right properties and which go through the call quotes at T i. Finally we will consider the corresponding distributions as candidates. The distributions must be NDCO. Notably the corresponding call price functions must be non-decreasing with maturity. By only considering the quotes at a given maturity, it is possible that the corresponding constructed distributions will not possess this characteristic (See Figure 2). Nevertheless, observe that if we add the points corresponding to quotes of longer maturities to the quotes of maturity T i, the frontier of their convex hull 1 seems to have all of the features we are looking for. Figure 2: Frontier at T i1. To ensure the monotonicity of the distributions, we must also properly specify the call price function to the right of the greatest quoted strike - if the corresponding price is not zero. Let us determine the maximum of the non-zero slopes between two points, which could be consecutive on the frontier a priori. 1 In the definition of the convex hull we should restrict the slopes of the linear functions to be non-positive. 6

7 We adopt the following notation: ({ MaxSlope max CV Si1,i2, K i1 K i2 1 i 1, i 2 m, n i1, n i2 s.t. K i1 } ) > K i2 R If Cn i i >, we will add a point (Kn i, ) such that the slope between i+1 (Ki n i, Cn i i ) and (Kn i i+1, ) is equal to MasSlope/2. By convention, if Cn i i = then Kn i i+1 Kn i i + 1. i [1, m], j [, n i ], A i j (K i j, C i j) K i n i+1 K i n i 2C i n i /MaxSlope A i n i+1 (K i n i+1, ) A i n i+1 j= A i j B i Convex hull of m j=i A i We will show that the frontier of B i corresponds to a risk-neutral distribution for the calls of maturity T i and furthermore that these distributions are NDCO. It is obvious that Fr(B i ), the frontier of B i, is continuous, piece-wise linear, convex and that the nodes are among the K k j (with corresponding value Ck j ), i k m, j n k + 1. Let us show that the slope of the frontier on the first segment is greater than or equal to -1. The value of the frontier in K i = is clearly C i = S. Let us denote by K i1 the smallest non-zero node of the frontier. C i1 C i K i1 = C i 1 C i1 K i1 = 1 K i1 k=1 V Si1 K i1 V S i1 k (Ki1 k Ki1 k 1 ) k=1 Ki1 K i1 K i1 1 (K i1 k Ki1 k 1 ) (V Si1 j V S i1 j+1, j < n i 1 by convexity.) We now show that the frontier is zero after a given value. Since (Kn i i+1, ) is a point in the convex hull B i and the linear functions involved in the definition of the convex hull have non-positive slopes, the frontier is zero on [Kn i, ). Denote by i+1 Ki the smallest strike which corresponds to a node of the frontier whose call value is zero. Let us examine the monotonicity of Fr(B i ). We consider two consecutive nodes of the frontier K i1 and K i2 with K i1 < K i2. Since we know that the frontier is flat at the right of K i, we only need to prove that the segment [A i1 ; A i2 ] is decreasing if K i2 K i. If C i2 =, then by definition of K i, we have Ki2 = K i. Because Ki1 < K i2 = K i, Ci1 >, i.e. the slope is negative. If C i2 > and i 2 i 1, then the condition on the (calendar) vertical spreads shows the monotonicity. (i 1 n i1 + 1 and i 2 n i2 + 1 since the two call prices are positive). If C i2 > and i 2 > i 1, [A i1 ; A i2 ] is below the segment [A i1 ; A i1 +1 ] because Ai2 is on the frontier. (Remember that i 1 n i1 + 1). Since [A i1 ; A i1 +1 ] is decreasing (because of the condition on the vertical spreads if < n i1 and the definition of MaxSlope if = n i1 ), the segment [A i1 ; A i2 ] must be decreasing as well. 7

8 We now show that the frontier goes through the points A i j for j n i. For j =, it is obvious since all the A i correspond to the same point. Let us consider a point Ai j that does not belong to the frontier (1 j n i ). Denote by K i1 (resp. K i2 ) the greatest (resp. smallest) node of the frontier which is less (resp. greater) than Kj i. (Ki2 exists since Kn i is on the frontier). Recall that i i i+1 1 and i i 2. If n i1 and n i2, then the non-negativity of the (calendar) butterfly spreads contradicts the fact that A i j does not belong to the frontier. If n i1 and = n i2 + 1, then we have the following two cases: If Cn i2 i2 =, then A i2 n i2 is also on the frontier. Since A i1 n i1 and A i2 n i2 +1 are consecutive on the frontier, C i1 =. The condition on the (calendar) vertical spreads between the points A i1 and A i j imposes that Ci j. Combined with the non-negativity condition on call quotes, this ensures us that the point A i j lies in the flat frontier, which is a contradiction. If Cn i2 i2 >, then the slope of the segment [A i1 ; A i2 n i2 +1 ] must be less than the slope of the segment [A i2 n i2 ; A i2 n i2 +1 ], since Ai1 and A i2 n i2 are two consecutive nodes on the frontier. Its slope is therefore greater than MaxSlope/2. But the slope of the segment [A i1 ; A i j ] is greater than the slope of [A i1 ; A i2 n i2 +1 ], since Ai j does not belong to the frontier. Consequently, the slope of [Ai1 ; A i j ] is greater than MaxSlope/2. We can exclude the case where Cj i =, since in this case Ai j always belong to the frontier. If Cj i >, then the slope of [Ai1 ; A i j ] is strictly negative because of the condition on the (calendar) vertical spread and must therefore be less than or equal to M axslope, which is a contradiction. If = n i1 + 1, then C i2 = because the corresponding point belongs to the frontier, which is flat at the right of K i1 n i1 +1. We have the following two cases: If Cn i1 i1 =, the condition on the (calendar) vertical spread between the points A i1 and A i j imposes that Cj i. Combined with the non-negativity condition on call quotes, this ensures that the point A i j lies in the flat frontier, which is a contradiction. If Cn i1 i1 >, then the slope of the segment [A i1 n 1 ; A i j ] is greater than the slope of [Ai1 n 1 ; A i1 n ], 1+1 which is given by MaxSlope/2. But this slope is strictly negative because of the condition on the vertical (calendar) spread (Cj i > since Ai j does not belong to the frontier). Consequently, it must be less than or equal to MaxSlope. This is a contradiction We have proved that Fr(B i ) satisfies all the conditions of Lemma 3.1. Therefore we can associate to it a distribution µ i satisfying (1). Moreover this distribution is risk-neutral for the calls of maturity T i since Fr(B i ) goes through the points A i j. We still have to prove that these distributions are NDCO and that their mean is constant over time. For a given strike, the prices are non-decreasing with the maturity since B i+1 B i implies that Fr(B i ) Fr(B i+1 ), 1 i < m. The call price function corresponding to the distribution φ δ S starts at S, has a slope of -1 until S and is zero after. Consequently, it is less than the one corresponding to φ 1, which starts at S, has a starting slope greater than or equal to -1 and is convex. The prices of European put options are also non-decreasing with maturity because of put-call parity. Since any convex function can be approximated by linear combinations with positive weights of put and call functions, the distributions are NDCO. Finally the means of the different distributions are constant over time because all the calls struck at have the same price. 5 Necessity of the conditions The conditions of Proposition 4.2 are of course necessary for the existence of a pricing martingale but they are also necessary for the absence of static arbitrage. 8

9 First of all, let us be precise in what we mean by static strategies. At the initial time, one is allowed to take long and short positions in the options and in the stock. Furthermore, as explained in CGMY (23), one has the possibility to short the stock for a given future period of time if the stock is greater than a specified value at the beginning of the period. Under the assumption of no static arbitrage and of a frictionless market, it is costless. In other words, at the initial time, one can purchase at zero cost, a security whose payoff at time T 2 (> T 1 > ) is: 1 {ST1 >K}(S T1 S T2 ) The inequalities of Proposition 4.2 are classic necessary conditions and will not be detailed in this paper. We just consider, as an example, the case of a (vertical) calendar spread constructed from the call of strike K 1, maturity T 1 and price C 1, and the call of strike K 2, maturity T 2 and price C 2 (K 1 K 2 and T 1 < T 2 ). The strategy is to sell the call of maturity T 1, buy the call of maturity T 2 and short one share if the stock at T 1 is greater than K 1. The price of this strategy is of course C 2 C 1 and its payoff at T 2 is: (S T1 K 1 ) {ST1 >K 1}(S T1 S T2 ) + (S T2 K 2 ) + 1 {ST1 >K 1}(K 1 K 2 ) We remark that the payoff of this strategy is always non-negative. Consequently, its price should also be non-negative, i.e. C 1 C 2. Moreover, if the probability that S T1 > K 1 is positive and K 1 > K 2, then the payoff is non-negative and positive with positive probability. Therefore, in this case, the price of this strategy should be positive and we notice that the condition P(S T1 > K 1 ) > is equivalent to C 1 >, since we assumed no static arbitrage. 6 Construction of a more intuitive and realistic model The previous construction of the pricing martingale offers little intuition and may result in an unrealistic model for the stock. In this section, we will construct a martingale Markov chain model, which will be calibrated to the quoted call prices. First we will describe an algorithm based on entropy maximization to construct more realistic, NDCO, marginal distributions. Once these distributions are constructed, we will be able to claim the existence of martingale transition matrices due to the Sherman-Stein-Blackwell theorem, as explained for example in Davis (24). To choose realistic transition matrices, we will once again describe an algorithm based on the notion of entropy and of Brownian copula. 6.1 Construction of marginal distributions The marginal distributions we have constructed may be quite unrealistic. Indeed, the number of possible states for the stock may be decreasing with maturity. We will describe here, an algorithm allowing to construct more realistic discrete marginal distributions. Let (k i ) i N be a finite subset of R + containing all the (Kj i) 1 i m, j n i+1. This set will be the support of the marginal distributions. In the proof of Proposition 4.2, we have already constructed some marginal distributions having the required features and (k i ) i N as a support. To choose a more realistic set of marginal distributions, we will use the notion of entropy, which is appealing for several reasons. One reason is that the less information a discrete distribution contains, the higher the entropy - the maximum being reached for a uniform distribution. A direct consequence is that the entropy maximization will distribute the masses among all the (k i ) in a more uniform manner. Let us denote by P the set of the call price functions satisfying the assumptions of Lemma 3.1 and by Q the set of the corresponding distributions, whose support is consequently (k i ). Let us denote by PC i the call price function corresponding to the maturity T i constructed in the proof of Proposition 4.2. The new call price function, PC,new 1, corresponding to the maturity T 1, is obtained by maximizing the entropy 2 : max q C Q ( ) q C (k i )log(q C (k i )) i= 2 By convention log () = in the definition of entropy. 9

10 s.t. P C P 1 C and j [, n 1 ], P C (K 1 j ) = P 1 C(K 1 j ) Now, let us assume that we have constructed the new marginal distributions until the maturity T i 1. is obtained by maximizing: P i C,new max q C Q ( ) q C (k i )log(q C (k i )) i= s.t. P i 1 C,new P C P i C and j [, n i], P C (K i j ) = P i C (Ki j ) We remark that the new distributions are risk neutral since: i [1, m], j [, n i ], P i C,new (Ki j ) = P i C (Ki j ) = Ci j Moreover these distributions are NDCO by construction. A numerical example is given in Appendix Construction of martingale transition matrices Now that we have constructed risk neutral marginal distributions, which are NDCO, we will focus on the construction of martingale transition matrices. The Sherman-Stein-Blackwell theorem ensures the existence of such matrices. This theorem is a generalization to the N-dimensional case of the Hardy-Littlewood-Polya theorem (1929) and has been generalized by Strassen (1965) to probability measures in R N. The Kellerer theorem (1972), which we stated in section 4.1 is a continuous time version of the latter. Theorem 6.1 (Sherman-Stein-Blackwell theorem). If X = (a 1,..., a n ) is a finite set in R N, and q 1 and q 2 are probability measures on X such that n φ(a i )q 1 (a i ) i=1 n φ(a i )q 2 (a i ) for every continuous convex function φ defined on the convex hull of X, then there is a martingale transition matrix (q i,j ) 1 i,j n such that: i=1 q i,j n q i,j = 1 i=1 n q i,j q 1 (a i ) = q 2 (a j ) i=1 n q i,j a j = a i i=1 for 1 i, j n for 1 j n for 1 j n for 1 i n Proof. See Davis (24) for Strassen s proof restricted to the finite case. Now that the existence of the transition matrices is established, we would like to have at our disposal an extra criterion to choose realistic ones. Once again we will minimize under constraints the Kullback-Leibler distance of the joint distributions: ) D(J i J i,prior ) = 1 α,β N J i α,β log ( J i α,β J i,prior α,β 1

11 (where Jα,β i P(S T i = k α, S Ti+1 = k β ) is the joint distribution of (S Ti, S Ti+1 ) and (J i,prior α,β ) 1 α,β N is a given prior joint distribution), under the following constraints 1 β N 1 α N 1 β N J i α,β J i α,β = q i (α) J i α,β = q i+1 (β) k β J i α,β = q i (α)k α 1 α N (Law of total probability) 1 β N (Chapman-Kolmogorov equations) 1 α N (Martingale conditions) where the T i marginal distribution obtained in Section 6.1 is denoted by (q i (α)) 1 α N. As explained in Cover and Thomas (1991) or in Avellaneda et al (2), this problem can be reduced to the unconstrained maximization problem in (λ, µ, ν) of: W(λ, µ, ν) = log 1 α,β N J i α,β eλα+ναk β+µ β + 1 α N q i (α)(λ α + ν α k α ) + Indeed, if (λ, µ, ν ) is a critical point of W, the joint distribution defined by: J i, α,β = J i,prior α,β e λ α +ν α k β+µ β 1 α,β N Ji α,β eλ α +ν α k β+µ β a=1 1 β N µ β q i+1 (β) is a solution of the initial problem, provided that J i,prior α,β. We now need to specify a prior joint distribution. One way is to discretize the Brownian copula as explained in Carr and Cousot (24). Recall that once the marginal distributions are specified, the knowledge of the copula of (S Ti, S Ti+1 ), C STi,S Ti+1, and of the joint distribution are equivalent (See Darsow, Nguyen and Olsen (1992)). Indeed, under ( the assumption of bilinear interpolation, the copula is uniquely determined by its values at the points α a=1 qi (a), ) β b=1 qi+1 (b) : ( α ) β α β Cα,β i C STi,S Ti+1 q i (a), q i+1 (b) = b=1 a=1 b=1 Conversely, if the copula is given, the joint distribution is uniquely specified by: J i α,β = C i α,β C i α 1,β C i α,β 1 + C i α 1,β 1 for 1 α, β N. We would like the joint distribution to imply a realistic copula. Consequently, one way is to choose as a prior joint distribution the one implied by the Brownian copula characterized in Darsow et al (1992): x ( Ti+1 Φ 1 (y) ) T i Φ 1 (u) C BTi,B Ti+1 (x, y) = Φ du Ti+1 T i where Φ is the cumulative normal distribution. ( α ) β Cα,β B C BTi,B Ti+1 q i (a), q 2 (b) J i,prior α,β a=1 b=1 = C B α,β C B α 1,β C B α,β 1 + C B α 1,β 1 We remark that this so defined joint distribution (J i,prior α,β ) has the right marginal distributions, but unfortunately does not infer a martingale. That is why we need to minimize the Kullback-Leibler distance. A numerical example is given in Appendix 2. J i a,b 11

12 7 Generalization to the case of a deterministic dividend paying stock in presence of deterministic interest rates In this section we generalize the results of Section 4 by assuming that the stock pays continuously a deterministic dividend q and that the short interest rate is a deterministic function r. By convention, we will add a call struck at for each maturity T i : K i = and C i = S e R T i q udu with S the initial stock price. Proposition 7.1. If the following conditions are fulfilled i [1, m], j [, n i ] C i j i [1, m],, s.t. < n i Cj i 1 Cj i 2 Kj i 2 Kj i [, e R Ti r udu ] 1 C i C i K i K i > if C i > i 1, i 2 [1, m] s.t. i 1 i 2, [, n i1 ], [, n i2 ] e R T i 2 q udu C i2 e R Ti 1 q udu C i1 e R T i 2 q udu C i2 > e R Ti 1 q udu C i1 if K i1 = K i2 e R T i2 T (r i1 u q u)du if K i1 > K i2 e R T i2 T (r i1 u q u)du and C i 1 > i, i 1, i 2 [1, m] s.t. i i 1 and i i 2, j [, n i ], [, n i1 ], [, n i2 ] s.t. e R T i 1 (r u q u)du K i1 < e R T i (r u q u)du K i j < e R T i 2 (r u q u)du K i2 e R T i q udu C i j er T i 1 q udu C i1 e R T i 1 (r u q u)du K i1 e R T i (r u q u)du K i j e R T i 2 q udu C i2 e R T i q udu Cj i e R T i (r u q u)du Kj i R T i 2 e (r u q u)du K i2 then there exists a process (S t ) t starting at the initial stock price, such that (S t e R t (ru qu)du ) t is a martingale and further i s.t. 1 i m, j s.t. j n i C i j = E[e R T i r udu (S Ti K i j )+ ] Proof. We will use the results we have proven in the case of a non-dividend paying stock where the interest rates are null. First let us define i s.t. 1 i m, j s.t. j n i K i j K i je R T i (r u q u)du C i j e R T i q udu C i j We can see that Kj i and Ci j satisfy the hypothesis of Theorem 4.2. Consequently, there exists a continuous time Markov martingale (M t ) such that: C i j = E[(M Ti K i j) + ] This can be written as: C i j = E[e R T i r udu (M Ti e R T i (r u q u)du K i j) + ] Let us define the process (S t ) t as follows: S t M t e R t (ru qu)du. The last property we have to verify is that this process starts at S. The two processes have the same starting value by definition and the process (M t ) t, which is a martingale, starts at C i = e R T i q udu C i = S. 12

13 The inequalities of Proposition 7.1 are again necessary for the absence of static arbitrage. Furthermore, the algorithm described in Section 6 to obtain a realistic Markov chain model can also be generalized easily. Indeed, it is possible to return to the no interest rate volatility and no dividend case by the following one-to-one transformation, K i j K i je R T i (r u q u)du C i j er T i q udu C i j Then we can apply the algorithm previously described, and finally return to the general case by the inverse of the above transformation. 8 Conclusion The elimination of the well-known static strategies involving European calls are in general not sufficient to prevent static arbitrage: the limitation to static strategies is not sufficient to make the notion of arbitrage independent of the underlying statistical measure. Nevertheless, we have proved that these necessary conditions are sufficient for the existence of an arbitrage free model consistent with the call quotes. We also focused on providing an algorithm explaining how to construct a realistic, arbitrage free, Markov chain model. We used the notion of entropy as well as the notion of Brownian copula to choose realistic marginal and joint distributions. An application of this model is for example the pricing of mildly path-dependent claims, (e.g. globally floored, locally capped, compounding cliquet options), as explained in Carr and Cousot (24). 13

14 References [1] Avellaneda, M., R. Buff, C. Friedman, N. Grandechamp, L. Krusk and J. Newman, 2, Weighted Monte Carlo: A new technique for calibrating asset pricing models International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 4, 1, [2] Carr, P., H. Geman, D. Madan, M. Yor, Stochastic Volatility for Lévy processes, Mathematical finance, Vol.13, No.3 (23), [3] Carr P., L. Cousot, Semi-Static Hedging of Path-Dependent Securities, Preprint, Courant Institute, New York University (24). [4] Carr, P., D. Madan, A Note on Sufficient Conditions for No Arbitrage, Preprint, Courant Institute, New York University (24). [5] Cover, T. and J. Thomas, 1991, Elements of Information Theory, Wiley, New York. [6] Darsow, W., B. Nguyen and E. Olsen, 1992, Copulas and Markov Processes, Illinois Journal of Mathematics, 36, 4, [7] Davis, M. The Range of Traded Option Prices, Preprint, Imperial College London (24). [8] Hardy, J., J. Littlewood, G. Polya, Inequalities, Cambridge University Press (1934). [9] Kellerer, H., Markov Komposition und eine Anwendung of Martingale, Math. Ann. 98, (1972) [1] Merton, R, Theory of rational option pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4 (1), (1973) [11] Sherman, S., On a theorem of Hardy, Littlewood Ploya and Blackwell, Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA 37 (1951) [12] Strassen, V., The existence of probability measures with given marginals, Ann. Math. Stat. 36 (1965)

15 Appendix 1: Construction of marginal distributions, a numerical example Let us consider the following situation: the current price of the non dividend paying stock is S = 1 and the available call quotes are detailed in Table 1. (We assume that there are no interest rates.) Maturity Strike Implied Volatility % % % 3m % % % % % % % 6m % % % % % % % 1y % % % % Table 4: Quotes, which satisfy the hypothesis of Proposition 4.2. Instead of setting the slope of the segment [A i n i, A i n i+1 ] to MaxSlope/2, we could have set it to α MaxSlope with < α < 1 without changing the validity of the proof of Proposition 4.2. Here we choose α =.999 to reduce the value of Kn i i+1. α =.999 MaxSlope = 1 5 n 1 = 7 n 2 = 8 n 3 = 6 K 1 n 1+1 = K 2 n 2+1 = K 3 n 3+1 = The (k i ) in this example are the minimal set of all the (Kj i) 1 i m,1 j n i+1. In the following tables, the approximations up to 1 8 of the distributions qc i and qi C,new are given. 15

16 k j q 1 C (k j) q 1 C,new (k j) Kn Kn Kn Table 5: the distributions q 1 C and q1 C,new Figure 3: Marginal distributions at 3 month maturity, q 1 C (left) and q1 C,new (right). 16

17 k j q 2 C (k j) q 2 C,new (k j) Kn Kn Kn Table 6: the distributions q 2 C and q2 C,new Figure 4: Marginal distributions at 6 month maturity, q 2 C (left), q2 C,new (right). 17

18 k j q 3 C (k j) q 3 C,new (k j) Kn Kn Kn Table 7: the distributions q 3 C and q3 C,new Figure 5: Marginal distributions at 1 year maturity, q 3 C (left), q3 C,new (right). 18

19 We also tried with a thiner grid. The next distributions have been obtained with: (k i ) = {, 3, 35, 4, 45, 5, 55, 6, 65,7, 75, 8, 85, 9, 95, 1, 15, 11, 115, 12, 13, 135,14, 145, 15, K 2 n 2+1, 18, K3 n 3+1, K2 n 2+1 } k j q 1 C (k j) q 1 C,new (k j) Table 8: the distributions q 1 C and q1 C,new. k j q 1 C (k j) q 1 C,new (k j) Kn Kn Kn Figure 6: Marginal distributions at 3 month maturity, q 1 C (left) and q1 C,new (right). 19

20 k j q 2 C (k j) q 2 C,new (k j) Table 9: the distributions q 2 C and q2 C,new. k j q 2 C (k j) q 2 C,new (k j) Kn Kn Kn Figure 7: Marginal distributions at 6 month maturity, q 2 C (left), q2 C,new (right). 2

21 k j q 3 C (k j) q 3 C,new (k j) k j q 3 C (k j) q 3 C,new (k j) Kn Kn Kn Table 1: the distributions q 3 C and q3 C,new Figure 8: Marginal distributions at 1 year maturity, q 3 C (left), q3 C,new (right). 21

22 Appendix 2: Construction of a joint distribution, a numerical example If the (k i ) are the minimal set of all the (K i j ) 1 i m,1 j n i+1, we obtain: Figure 9: Joint distribution of (S T1, S T2 ) Figure 1: The corresponding transition matrix. 22

23 The following joint distribution and the corresponding transition matrix have been obtained with: (k i ) = {, 3, 35, 4, 45, 5, 55, 6, 65,7, 75, 8, 85, 9, 95, 1, 15, 11, 115, 12, 13, 135,14, 145, 15, K 2 n 2+1, 18, K3 n 3+1, K2 n 2+1 } Figure 11: Joint distribution of (S T1, S T2 ) Figure 12: The corresponding transition matrix. 23

A note on sufficient conditions for no arbitrage

A note on sufficient conditions for no arbitrage Finance Research Letters 2 (2005) 125 130 www.elsevier.com/locate/frl A note on sufficient conditions for no arbitrage Peter Carr a, Dilip B. Madan b, a Bloomberg LP/Courant Institute, New York University,

More information

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Rama Cont Yu Gu Abstract When the underlying asset is a continuous martingale, call option prices solve the Dupire equation, a forward parabolic

More information

Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads

Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads Stefan Gerhold TU Wien Joint work with I. Cetin Gülüm MFO, Feb 2017 (TU Wien) MFO, Feb 2017 1 / 32 Introduction The consistency problem Overview Consistency

More information

No-Arbitrage Conditions for a Finite Options System

No-Arbitrage Conditions for a Finite Options System No-Arbitrage Conditions for a Finite Options System Fabio Mercurio Financial Models, Banca IMI Abstract In this document we derive necessary and sufficient conditions for a finite system of option prices

More information

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis 1/18 : estimation and model analysis, EDHEC Business School (joint work with Rama COT) Modeling and managing financial risks Paris, 10 13 January 2011 2/18 Outline 1 2 of multi-asset models Solution to

More information

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14 Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA March 1, 2012 1 Introduction Premia 14 Top-down" models for portfolio credit derivatives have been introduced as

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Pricing with a Smile. Bruno Dupire. Bloomberg

Pricing with a Smile. Bruno Dupire. Bloomberg CP-Bruno Dupire.qxd 10/08/04 6:38 PM Page 1 11 Pricing with a Smile Bruno Dupire Bloomberg The Black Scholes model (see Black and Scholes, 1973) gives options prices as a function of volatility. If an

More information

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information Rüdiger Frey Universität Leipzig Bressanone, July 2007 ruediger.frey@math.uni-leipzig.de www.math.uni-leipzig.de/~frey joint with Abdel Gabih and Thorsten

More information

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile? A Summary of Arbitrage Restrictions and Smile Asymptotics Vimal Raval Imperial College London & UBS Investment Bank www2.imperial.ac.uk/ vr402 Joint Work with Mark

More information

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015 Best-Reply Sets Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis This version: May 2015 Introduction The best-reply correspondence of a game the mapping from beliefs over one s opponents actions to

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1 Computational Finance Computational Finance p. 1 Outline Binomial model: option pricing and optimal investment Monte Carlo techniques for pricing of options pricing of non-standard options improving accuracy

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model Peter Carr Ali Hirsa Courant Institute Morgan Stanley New York University 750 Seventh Avenue 51 Mercer Street New York, NY 10036 1 60-3765 (1) 76-988

More information

Log-linear Dynamics and Local Potential

Log-linear Dynamics and Local Potential Log-linear Dynamics and Local Potential Daijiro Okada and Olivier Tercieux [This version: November 28, 2008] Abstract We show that local potential maximizer ([15]) with constant weights is stochastically

More information

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics Chapter 12 American Put Option Recall that the American option has strike K and maturity T and gives the holder the right to exercise at any time in [0, T ]. The American option is not straightforward

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

The Uncertain Volatility Model

The Uncertain Volatility Model The Uncertain Volatility Model Claude Martini, Antoine Jacquier July 14, 008 1 Black-Scholes and realised volatility What happens when a trader uses the Black-Scholes (BS in the sequel) formula to sell

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1. THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** Abstract The change of numeraire gives very important computational

More information

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples RolfPoulsen and Kourosh Marjani Rasmussen Abstract In the basic Markowitz and Merton models, a stock s weight in efficient portfolios goes up if its

More information

A utility maximization proof of Strassen s theorem

A utility maximization proof of Strassen s theorem Introduction CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique Paris Advances in Financial Mathematics, Paris January, 2014 Outline Introduction Notations Strassen s theorem 1 Introduction Notations Strassen s theorem 2 General

More information

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Market Risk Analysis Volume I Market Risk Analysis Volume I Quantitative Methods in Finance Carol Alexander John Wiley & Sons, Ltd List of Figures List of Tables List of Examples Foreword Preface to Volume I xiii xvi xvii xix xxiii

More information

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives John Crosby Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Presentation at Baruch College, in New York, 16th November 2010

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model American Journal of Theoretical and Applied Statistics 2018; 7(2): 80-84 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/ajtas doi: 10.11648/j.ajtas.20180702.14 ISSN: 2326-8999 (Print); ISSN: 2326-9006 (Online)

More information

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005 Valuation of Volatility Derivatives Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 005 Paris May 4, 005 he opinions expressed in this presentation are those of the author alone, and do not necessarily

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps Begoña Fernández Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México joint work with Laurent Denis and Ana Meda PASI, May 21 Begoña

More information

THE TRAVELING SALESMAN PROBLEM FOR MOVING POINTS ON A LINE

THE TRAVELING SALESMAN PROBLEM FOR MOVING POINTS ON A LINE THE TRAVELING SALESMAN PROBLEM FOR MOVING POINTS ON A LINE GÜNTER ROTE Abstract. A salesperson wants to visit each of n objects that move on a line at given constant speeds in the shortest possible time,

More information

Discrete-time Asset Pricing Models in Applied Stochastic Finance

Discrete-time Asset Pricing Models in Applied Stochastic Finance Discrete-time Asset Pricing Models in Applied Stochastic Finance P.C.G. Vassiliou ) WILEY Table of Contents Preface xi Chapter ^Probability and Random Variables 1 1.1. Introductory notes 1 1.2. Probability

More information

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1 A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model of Inequity Aversion 1 Kirsten I.M. Rohde 2 January 12, 2009 1 The author would like to thank Itzhak Gilboa, Ingrid M.T. Rohde, Klaus M. Schmidt, and

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO 1. Definitions and basic properties of options and other derivatives 1.1. Summary. Definition of European call and put options, American call and put option, forward (futures)

More information

Existence of Nash Networks and Partner Heterogeneity

Existence of Nash Networks and Partner Heterogeneity Existence of Nash Networks and Partner Heterogeneity pascal billand a, christophe bravard a, sudipta sarangi b a Université de Lyon, Lyon, F-69003, France ; Université Jean Monnet, Saint-Etienne, F-42000,

More information

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model Wai-Ki Ching Tak-Kuen Siu Li-min Li 26 Jan. 2007 Abstract In this paper, we consider the pricing of exotic options when the price dynamic

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model Peter Carr Bloomberg LP and Courant Institute, NYU Continuous Time Finance Lecture 2 Wednesday, January 26th, 2005 One Period Model Initial Setup: 0 risk-free

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

The Birth of Financial Bubbles The Birth of Financial Bubbles Philip Protter, Cornell University Finance and Related Mathematical Statistics Issues Kyoto Based on work with R. Jarrow and K. Shimbo September 3-6, 2008 Famous bubbles

More information

Casino gambling problem under probability weighting

Casino gambling problem under probability weighting Casino gambling problem under probability weighting Sang Hu National University of Singapore Mathematical Finance Colloquium University of Southern California Jan 25, 2016 Based on joint work with Xue

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL

sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL sample-bookchapter 2015/7/7 9:44 page 1 #1 1 THE BINOMIAL MODEL In this chapter we will study, in some detail, the simplest possible nontrivial model of a financial market the binomial model. This is a

More information

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES THE SOURCE OF A PRICE IS ALWAYS A TRADING STRATEGY SPECIAL CASES WHERE TRADING STRATEGY IS INDEPENDENT OF PROBABILITY MEASURE COMPLETENESS,

More information

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle Resolution of a Financial Puzzle M.J. Brennan and Y. Xia September, 1998 revised November, 1998 Abstract The apparent inconsistency between the Tobin Separation Theorem and the advice of popular investment

More information

Hierarchical Exchange Rules and the Core in. Indivisible Objects Allocation

Hierarchical Exchange Rules and the Core in. Indivisible Objects Allocation Hierarchical Exchange Rules and the Core in Indivisible Objects Allocation Qianfeng Tang and Yongchao Zhang January 8, 2016 Abstract We study the allocation of indivisible objects under the general endowment

More information

Bruno Dupire April Paribas Capital Markets Swaps and Options Research Team 33 Wigmore Street London W1H 0BN United Kingdom

Bruno Dupire April Paribas Capital Markets Swaps and Options Research Team 33 Wigmore Street London W1H 0BN United Kingdom Commento: PRICING AND HEDGING WITH SMILES Bruno Dupire April 1993 Paribas Capital Markets Swaps and Options Research Team 33 Wigmore Street London W1H 0BN United Kingdom Black-Scholes volatilities implied

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating strategies Xinliang Chen, Griselda Deelstra, Jan Dhaene, Daniël Linders, Michèle Vanmaele AFI_1491 On an optimization problem related to static

More information

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

Game Theory: Normal Form Games Game Theory: Normal Form Games Michael Levet June 23, 2016 1 Introduction Game Theory is a mathematical field that studies how rational agents make decisions in both competitive and cooperative situations.

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Approximating a multifactor di usion on a tree.

Approximating a multifactor di usion on a tree. Approximating a multifactor di usion on a tree. September 2004 Abstract A new method of approximating a multifactor Brownian di usion on a tree is presented. The method is based on local coupling of the

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 1. Default dynamics of a single obligor. 2. Model the dependence structure of defaults

More information

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach Matteo Burzoni Marco Frittelli Marco Maggis June 30, 2015 Abstract In a model independent discrete time financial

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting. Binomial Models Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October 14, 2016 Christopher Ting QF 101 Week 9 October

More information

Optimization Approaches Applied to Mathematical Finance

Optimization Approaches Applied to Mathematical Finance Optimization Approaches Applied to Mathematical Finance Tai-Ho Wang tai-ho.wang@baruch.cuny.edu Baruch-NSD Summer Camp Lecture 5 August 7, 2017 Outline Quick review of optimization problems and duality

More information

Local Variance Gamma Option Pricing Model

Local Variance Gamma Option Pricing Model Local Variance Gamma Option Pricing Model Peter Carr at Courant Institute/Morgan Stanley Joint work with Liuren Wu June 11, 2010 Carr (MS/NYU) Local Variance Gamma June 11, 2010 1 / 29 1 Automated Option

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

A Lower Bound for Calls on Quadratic Variation

A Lower Bound for Calls on Quadratic Variation A Lower Bound for Calls on Quadratic Variation PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Chicago,

More information

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation Entropic Derivative Security Valuation Michael Stutzer 1 Professor of Finance and Director Burridge Center for Securities Analysis and Valuation University of Colorado, Boulder, CO 80309 1 Mathematical

More information

Bilateral counterparty risk valuation with stochastic dynamical models and application to Credit Default Swaps

Bilateral counterparty risk valuation with stochastic dynamical models and application to Credit Default Swaps Bilateral counterparty risk valuation with stochastic dynamical models and application to Credit Default Swaps Agostino Capponi California Institute of Technology Division of Engineering and Applied Sciences

More information

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Paul J. Atzberger General comments or corrections should be sent to: paulatz@cims.nyu.edu 1 Introduction When using the Black-Scholes-Merton model to price derivative

More information

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure Yuri Kabanov 1,2 1 Laboratoire de Mathématiques, Université de Franche-Comté, 16 Route de Gray, 253 Besançon,

More information

Towards a Theory of Volatility Trading. by Peter Carr. Morgan Stanley. and Dilip Madan. University of Maryland

Towards a Theory of Volatility Trading. by Peter Carr. Morgan Stanley. and Dilip Madan. University of Maryland owards a heory of Volatility rading by Peter Carr Morgan Stanley and Dilip Madan University of Maryland Introduction hree methods have evolved for trading vol:. static positions in options eg. straddles.

More information

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives In these lecture notes we introduce the main approaches to credit modeling and we will largely

More information

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE DOI: 1.1214/ECP.v7-149 Elect. Comm. in Probab. 7 (22) 79 83 ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE FIMA KLEBANER Department of Mathematics & Statistics,

More information

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Leonardo P. Santiago & Pirooz Vakili November 2004 Abstract In this paper we consider the question of whether an increase in uncertainty increases

More information

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics John R. Birge Northwestern University www.iems.northwestern.edu/~jrbirge Illinois Section MAA, April 3, 2004 1 Introduction Trends in financial mathematics

More information

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE Proceedings of the 44th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, and the European Control Conference 005 Seville, Spain, December 1-15, 005 WeA11.6 OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives John Schoenmakers 9th Summer School in Mathematical Finance

More information

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Finance Stochast. 1, 251 257 1997 c Springer-Verlag 1997 A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Tina Hviid Rydberg University of Aarhus, Department of Theoretical

More information

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 13 Haijun Li Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Week 13 1 / 28 Outline 1 Simulation

More information

A New Tool For Correlation Risk Management: The Market Implied Comonotonicity Gap

A New Tool For Correlation Risk Management: The Market Implied Comonotonicity Gap A New Tool For Correlation Risk Management: The Market Implied Comonotonicity Gap Peter Michael Laurence Department of Mathematics and Facoltà di Statistica Universitá di Roma, La Sapienza A New Tool For

More information

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Spring 2016 c 2016 by Martin Haugh A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging In these notes we briefly describe the martingale approach to the pricing of

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products by David Epstein (LINK:www.maths.ox.ac.uk/users/epstein) Mathematical Institute (LINK:www.maths.ox.ac.uk) Oxford Paul Wilmott (LINK:www.oxfordfinancial.co.uk/pw)

More information

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Part I: Discrete-time finance Exercise 1 (20 points) a. Provide the definition of the pricing kernel k q. Relate this pricing kernel to the set of discount factors D

More information

Equilibrium payoffs in finite games

Equilibrium payoffs in finite games Equilibrium payoffs in finite games Ehud Lehrer, Eilon Solan, Yannick Viossat To cite this version: Ehud Lehrer, Eilon Solan, Yannick Viossat. Equilibrium payoffs in finite games. Journal of Mathematical

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Term Structure Lattice Models

Term Structure Lattice Models IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models These lecture notes introduce fixed income derivative securities and the modeling philosophy used to

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

University of Texas at Austin. HW Assignment 5. Exchange options. Bull/Bear spreads. Properties of European call/put prices.

University of Texas at Austin. HW Assignment 5. Exchange options. Bull/Bear spreads. Properties of European call/put prices. HW: 5 Course: M339D/M389D - Intro to Financial Math Page: 1 of 5 University of Texas at Austin HW Assignment 5 Exchange options. Bull/Bear spreads. Properties of European call/put prices. 5.1. Exchange

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Alfredo Garcia and Robert L. Smith Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering Universityof Michigan, Ann Arbor MI 48109 December

More information

A Harmonic Analysis Solution to the Basket Arbitrage Problem

A Harmonic Analysis Solution to the Basket Arbitrage Problem A Harmonic Analysis Solution to the Basket Arbitrage Problem Alexandre d Aspremont ORFE, Princeton University. A. d Aspremont, INFORMS, San Francisco, Nov. 14 2005. 1 Introduction Classic Black & Scholes

More information

Arbitrage-Free Pricing of XVA for American Options in Discrete Time

Arbitrage-Free Pricing of XVA for American Options in Discrete Time Arbitrage-Free Pricing of XVA for American Options in Discrete Time by Tingwen Zhou A Thesis Submitted to the Faculty of the WORCESTER POLYTECHNIC INSTITUTE In partial fulfillment of the requirements for

More information

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model James Dong School of Operations Research and Information Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853, USA jd748@cornell.edu A. Serdar Simsek

More information

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models José E. Figueroa-López 1 1 Department of Statistics Purdue University University of Missouri-Kansas City Department of Mathematics

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/33 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/33 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games University of Illinois Fall 2018 ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games Due: Tuesday, Sept. 11, at beginning of class Reading: Course notes, Sections 1.1-1.4 1. [A random

More information