Endogenous Counter-Cyclical Risk Aversion and the Cross Section

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Endogenous Counter-Cyclical Risk Aversion and the Cross Section"

Transcription

1 Endogenous Counter-Cyclical Risk Aversion and the Cross Section Anastasiya Ostrovnaya Carnegie Mellon University Bryan R. Routledge Carnegie Mellon University Stanley E. Zin Carnegie Mellon University and NBER December 25 Abstract Asset-pricing models that allow risk aversion to increase in recessions and decrease in expansions are capable of generating equilibrium asset returns that resolve the equity premium puzzle. Routledge and Zin (24) demonstrate that a tightly parametrized stationary recursive utility model with risk preferences that exhibit an aversion to outcomes that are sufficiently disappointing, has precisely this countercyclical risk aversion property in equilibrium. In this paper, we extend their Generalized Disappointment Aversion (GDA) model to a broader cross-section of assets. We show that the GDA model leads to a new cross-sectional risk factor in addition to the more traditional consumption-growth and market-return betas. By assuming that asset returns and consumption growth are jointly lognormally distributed, we provide a closed-form expression for this new factor, and show that it is a highly nonlinear function of the other two factors. In particular, this new factor introduces a new and independent role for the consumption-growth factor beyond the traditional consumption-capm. We estimate the parameters of the model and test its over-identifying restrictions with GMM applied to the model s Euler-equation forecast errors. The GDA model provides a significant improvement over the standard CAPM for both size and book-to-market sorted portfolios, as well as for industry portfolios. Correspondence: Tepper School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, <

2 1 Introduction Preference models in which risk aversion increases in recessions and decreases in expansions are able to reconcile dynamic general equilibrium asset-pricing theories with the properties of observed asset prices that are puzzling from the perspective of time-additive expected utility models (see, for example, Campbell and Cochrane (1999), Gordon and St-Amour (2), Barberis, Huang, and Santos (21), and Melino and Yang (23)). Routledge and Zin (24) show that a generalized version of disappointment aversion preferences (GDA), when imbedded in a stationary recursive utility framework, exhibits endogenous counter-cyclical risk aversion and, hence, a quantitative equilibrium asset-pricing model that matches the conditional and unconditional moments of equity and bond returns. This structural approach provides a tight link between the basic axioms of choice and the parameters of their quantitative model and, hence, establishes clear theoretical foundations for the counter-cyclical risk aversion that is apparent in the data. In this paper we consider the implications of the counter-cyclical risk aversion property of the GDA model for a broader cross-section of asset returns. It is well documented that firm characteristics like market capitalization and the accounting ratio of book to market equity provide a better characterization of the cross-sectional pattern of equity returns than the theoretically motivated consumption-growth and market-return betas (for example, Fama and French (1992)). Here, we will explore how much of this apparent pattern can be attributed to a risk premium that is an artifact of an aversion to particular types of risk, namely, disappointment aversion. In particular we document how a down market beta factor arises quite naturally in equilibrium and, as in Ang, Chen, and Xing (25), we show that such a factor significantly improves the empirical performance of standard CAPM regressions. Our structural model places additional restrictions on the functional form of this factor and provides a natural framework for testing this extension against alternative CAPM-like specifications. Our analysis is strictly preference-based and we do not explore potential interactions of preferences with more general cash-flow processes. As with an expected utility model, there is certainly scope for endogenous firm-level cash-flow decisions to produce additional risk and time-variation in risk factors (as in Gourio (25), 1

3 Tuzel (25)). Likewise, we do not explore the consequences of durable consumption decisions as in Pakos (25) and Yogo (25). Rather our approach is closer in spirit to Petkova and Zhang (25) who document the effect of time-variation in risk on the cross-section patterns and Santos and Veronesi (25) who investigate time-variation in the equity premium from a habits-based model. We proceed in this structural and preference-based fashion for a number of very practical, rather than purely theoretical, reasons. It serves to eliminate the potential for postulating behavior that would be generally viewed as irrational. That is, we avoid violating the basic properties of transitivity, monotonicity, and continuity as we consider departures from expected utility. In addition, starting with basic axioms governing choice over risky outcomes leads to a better understanding of the behavioral roles played by the parameters in our model. This is helpful for assessing both the reasonableness of parameter values and the likelihood of parameter stability across different economic and government policy environments We build on Routledge and Zin (24) that provides an axiomatic generalization of the disappointment aversion preferences of Gul (1991) which allow for a more flexible definition of a disappointing outcome. This one-parameter extension of Gul s utility function allows outcomes to be treated as disappointing not when they lie below the certainty equivalent, but only when they lie sufficiently far below the certainty equivalent. This focus on more extreme tail behavior echos real-world approaches such as Value at Risk calculations in finance (see Basak and Shapiro (21)), and with much of the behavioral/experimental evidence, such as Kahneman and Tversky (1979). In addition, by imposing standard regularity conditions (i.e., transitivity, monotonicity (first-order stochastic dominance), risk aversion (second-order stochastic dominance), and time stationarity, GDA preferences do not admit irrational behavior. Moreover, since they maintain many of the properties of expected utility models, GDA produces a tractable quantitative framework for studying departures from expected utility. Our paper is organized as follows. After reviewing the details of Generalized Disappointment preferences in an asset-pricing model in Section 2, we present a lognormal version of the model in Section 3 and discuss the empirical properties of the new downmarket factor implied by the model. Section 4 presents the results from estimating the model s parameters by applying GMM to Euler equation forecast 2

4 errors, and for tests of the model against the standard CAPM. Section 5 summarizes and concludes the paper. 2 Generalized Disappointment Aversion Expected utility preferences are useful in many applied settings such as asset pricing since they are tractable and involve a small number of parameters. However, in experiments choices rarely conform to expected utility. In particular, the independence axiom is typically violated. For example, the Allais (1979) ratio paradox and the Kahneman and Tversky (1979) common consequences effect both reveal preferences that violate independence (see also Machina (1987)) and Conlisk (1989)). 1 In this paper, we will focus on Generalized Disappointment Aversion preference introduced in Routledge and Zin (24). GDA preferences define the certainty equivalent, µ, implicitly, as µ α = i p i x α i θ i p i (δ α µ α x α i ) I(x i δµ(x)) (1) where x i is an outcome with probability p i and I( ) is an indicator function. Preference parameters are α, θ, and δ. The preferences specified here are linearly homogeneous (like CRRA preferences in expected utility). The preferences are similar to expected utility with constant relative risk aversion parameter α, except they impose a penalty, proportional to θ, on outcomes that lie below the disappointment threshold of δµ(p). This preference specification nests expected utility since with θ =, the preferences are expected utility. The specification also nests the disappointment aversion preferences of Gul (1991) when δ = 1. Preferences with δ < 1 capture non-central disappointment aversion by moving the disappointment cutoff. Outcomes are disappointing only if they lie sufficiently far below the certainty 1 The Allais ratio paradox is that people express a preference for a certain $2 over a.8 chance at $3 and they also express a preference for a.4 chance at $3 over a.5 chance at $2. These choices violate the independence axiom. To see why, let p 1 be the certain $2 lottery and p 2 be the.8 chance at $3. A.5 chance at $2 is the lottery.5p 1+.5() while a.4 chance at $3 is the lottery.5p 1 +.5(). The preference p 1 p 2 and.5p 1 +.5().5p 1 +.5() is inconsistent with independence. 3

5 equivalent. Equivalently, preferences in equation (1) can be expressed as N µ α = ˆp i x α i (2) i=1 where ˆp i are decision weights that overweight items, relative to expected utility, that are disappointing. [ ] 1 + θi(x i δµ) ˆp = p i 1 + θδ α (3) E[I(x δµ)] GDA preferences belong to the Chew-Dekel class of preferences (Chew (1983), (1989) and Dekel (1986)). This class of preferences generalize expected utility but maintain much of the parsimony and tractability of expected utility by satisfying the standard axioms of completeness, transitivity, and continuity. However, in place of the empirically troubling independence axiom, these preferences satisfy a weaker betweenness axiom. An important feature of these preferences that we rely on in our empirical analysis is that the preferences, hence, first-order and Euler conditions, are are linear in probabilities. Weighted Utility (Chew (1983)), Disappointment Aversion (Gul (1991)), and the Generalized Disappointment Aversion (Routledge and Zin (24)) that we focus on here are all examples of this class of preferences. See Backus, Routledge, and Zin (25) for an overview of these preferences. The focus or overweighting of lower-tail outcomes implied by GDA preferences is consistent with risk-management approaches such as value at risk calculations (see Basak and Shapiro (21)), and with much of the behavioral/experimental evidence, such as Allais (1979) and Kahneman and Tversky (1979). However, GDA preferences have an axiomatic foundations similar to expected utility. This eliminates the potential for postulating behavior that would be generally viewed as irrational. That is, GDA preferences maintain basic properties of transitivity, continuity, monotonicity (first-order stochastic dominance), and risk aversion (second-order stochastic dominance). GDA preferences are also based solely on the outcomes and probabilities. They do not include any external reference points or rely on any past action or outcome such as a habit. To see how these preferences differ from the more familiar expected utility preferences, Figure 1 plot indifference curves in a two-outcome setting where probabilities of the two states are fixed at p(x 1 ) = p(x 2 ) =.5. Figure 1(a) shows the familiar 4

6 smooth trade-off between state 1 and state 2 payoffs implied by expected utility. Figure 1(b) shows the indifference curve for disappointment aversion (Gul (1991)). Since disappointment is defined relative to the certainty equivalent, the indifference curve has a kink at certainty. This is the first-order-risk-aversion feature of disappointment aversion. Below the forty-five degree line, it is the state two outcome that is disappointing. Above the forty-five degree line, the state one outcome is disappointing. The parameter θ controls how much extra weight the disappointing outcome receives and, hence, the severity of the kink. Figure 1(c) shows an indifference curve for GDA in state space. Here, disappointment occurs for outcomes less than 8% of the certainty equivalence (δ =.8). For gambles close to certainty (shown as the center cone in Figure 1(c)), preferences are identical to expected utility since neither outcome is disappointing. This is analogous to the lower right hand portion of Figure 1(c). Lotteries where the state-two payoff is sufficiently low (below the cone) are disappointing (similarly for low state 1 payoffs). The kink in the indifference curves is not at certainty. The GDA preferences specified in equation (1) are also homothetic. For different utility levels, all kinks lie along the rays that define the cone in Figure 1(c). Figure 1(d) shows the indifference curve for GDA with δ = 1.25 > 1. The preferences are similar to Figure 1(c). In the center cone in Figure 1(d) both outcomes are disappointing, whereas in Figure 1(c) neither outcome is disappointing in this region. However, both cases preferences in the center cone are expected-utility-like. Figure 1 shows the effect of preference parameters θ and δ on effective risk aversion. In Disappointment Aversion, Figure 1(b), an increase in θ increases the severity of the kink and makes the preferences exhibit more risk aversion. This is also true in GDA in Figure 1(c) and (d). However, as δ moves away from one, the disappointment threshold is moved further away from certainty, the kink and effective risk aversion decreases. Monotonicity of preferences limits the kink since preferences can, at most, be a vertical (horizontal) line. 5

7 2.1 GDA and Asset Pricing Embedding GDA preferences into a standard representative agent asset-pricing economy is straightforward. 2 A representative agent consumes a single perishable consumption good in each period. In period t, current consumption, c t, is known with certainty, but future consumption levels are generally uncertain. Following Epstein and Zin (1989) and (199), the intertemporal utility functional is recursive. The Bellman equation defined by optimal consumption and portfolio choice has the form [( ) ρ U(a t,ω t ) = max c γ c t t,ω t 1 + ρ + 1 ] 1/γ 1 + ρ µγ t, γ 1, ρ >, (4) subject to a wealth constraint: a t+1 = (a t c t )R ω t+1 where R ω t+1 = N ωtr i t+1 i i=1 is the portfolio return and N i=1 ωi t = 1. (See Backus, Routledge, and Zin (25) for an overview.) GDA preferences are incorporated in µ t = µ(u (a t+1,ω t+1 ) Ω t ) which is defined by equation (1). It is the certainty equivalent of random future utility using the period-t conditional probability distribution. The preference parameters in equation µ t in equation (1) are α, a measure of risk aversion, θ, a degree of disappointment aversion, and δ, the threshold for disappointment. The other preference parameters are standard: γ determines the elasticity of intertemporal substitution and ρ is the marginal rate of time preference. This problem divides into separate portfolio and consumption decisions. Given a portfolio that maximizes µ t with stochastic return Rt+1 ω, the consumption decision is given by the Euler condition µ t (z t+1 ) = 1 (5) 2 Note that since GDA preferences are homothetic and depend solely on consumption, they share all the same aggregation properties of CRRA expected utility. Namely, if consumers have identical GDA preferences the cross sectional properties of wealth do not matter. 6

8 where [ 1 z t+1 = 1 + ρ ( ct+1 c t ) γ 1 R ω t+1] 1/γ (6) The Euler condition in (5) is a generalization of a familiar tangency condition for an optimum. Note that if the portfolio return is certain, the optimum involves setting the marginal rate of substitution, governed by the parameter γ, equal to the price ratio (the portfolio return). The optimum involves setting certainty equivalent of the tangency condition to one. Of course in an economy with risk, the ex-post tangency will not hold since given the realized return savings will be too high or too low. With a GDA certainty equivalent, disappointment only relates to this ex-post savings error. Disappointment effects are not, for example, defined exogenously on a the market nor any single asset return. The pricing kernel can be derived from the first-order-condition to portfolio optimization portion of the Bellman equation in equation (4). An important consequence of the fact that GDA preferences belong to the Chew-Dekel class of preferences is that the portfolio first-order conditions are linear in probabilities. This linearity in preferences allows us to apply standard method-of-moment estimation techniques in [ Section 4. The equilibrium pricing kernel, M t+1, that satisfies E t Mt+1 Rt+1] i = 1 for all i for the GDA model is M t+1 = zα t+1 (Rm t+1 ) 1 [1 + θi(z t+1 < δ)] 1 + θδ α E t [I(z t+1 < δ)], (7) where x t+1 = c t+1 c t is the growth rate in aggregate consumption and the optimal portfolio return is that of the return on aggregate wealth, Rt+1 m. 3 Log-Normality and the disappointment factor To explore the cross-sectional implications of GDA, it is helpful to consider a lognormal example. This will illustrate how a disappointment factor effects the properties of cross section of returns. To begin, we start with the implications for the unconditional properties of returns. (The basic structure developed here is maintained in the dynamic version that we consider in the next section). 7

9 The pricing kernel in the Generalized Disappointment Aversion model in equation (7) implies ] ] E [z α Ri R m + θe [z α Ri RmI(z < δ) = 1 + θδ α E[I(z < δ)] (8) where equation (6) defines z. Note, we are suppressing the time subscripts for the moment since we initially focus on the unconditional implications of or model. Assume that consumption growth, x, and all asset returns are jointly log-normally distributed: 3 ln x x σx 2 σ xm σ x1 σ xn ln R m r m σ mx σm 2 σ m1 σ mn ln R 1 N r 1, σ 1x σ 1m σ1 2 σ 1N. (9) ln R N r N σ Nx σ Nm σ N1 σn 2 Hence, using standard properties (see Appendix), the expectations in equation (8) can solved using the result in equations (A3) and (A4): r i + σi 2 /2 = λ + (1 α γ ) r m + α (1 γ) x γ ( + λ m β im + λ x β ix + log 1 + θδ α Φ( ) 1 + θφ( m β im + x β ix ) ), (1) 3 This assumption is, of course, an approximation since individual assets and portfolios cannot both be log-normally distributed. 8

10 where Φ is the standard normal density and β im β ix = σ im /σ 2 m = σ ix /σ 2 x λ = α γ log(1 + ρ) [α γ (1 γ)]2 σ 2 x/2 (1 α γ )2 σ 2 m/2 α γ (1 γ)(1 α γ )σ xm λ m = (1 α γ )σ2 m λ x = α γ (1 γ)σ2 x = [γ log(δ) + log(1 + ρ) + (1 γ) x r m ]/σ z m = + [σ 2 m (1 γ)σ xm]/σ z α γ σ z = σ 2 m/σ z x = (1 γ)σ 2 x /σ z σ z = [(1 γ) 2 σ 2 x + σ2 m 2(1 γ)σ xm] 1/2. Given a riskless log return, r f, expected excess log returns have the form: ( r i + σ 2 i /2) r f = λ m β im + λ x β ix ( + log 1 + θφ( ) 1 + θφ( m β im + x β ix ) ). (11) 3.1 The CAPM and a down-market factor As a starting point, consider a CAPM version of the model by choosing preference parameters α = (which implies log risk aversion in an expected utility version of the model) and γ = 1 (perfect substitutability of intertemporal consumption). In this case (11) is ( ) ( r i + σi 2 /2) r f = σm 2 β 1 + θφ ( ) im + log 1 + θφ ( σ m β im )) where = (log δ +log(1+ρ) r m +σ 2 m )/σ m). Returns in this parameterization of the model depend two factors. The first is the familiar linear CAPM market beta. The second term is down-market factor that depends on disappointment preference parameters δ and θ. While both factors depend only on the market beta, the second factor is not linear in market beta. 9 (12)

11 With θ = (or δ = ), this is the well-known expected utility model where all returns are proportional to the single factor, the market return. This, of course, is not a good model of the equity premium since it is not large enough and does not permit time variation in the equity premium. 4 However, our goal here is to investigate the cross-section relationship. Setting θ = and evaluating equation (11) for the Fama-French s size-and-book-to-market portfolios and industry portfolios reproduces the well-known empirical problem of the CAPM: the Market beta does not explain the cross section of returns. Figure 2 plots the market beta against excess return for the six size and book-to-market portfolios. Figure 3 shows the same information for ten industry portfolios. Even adjusting the equity premium to its historical level, the expected utility model cannot explain the cross section. With GDA preferences, θ >, the downmarket factor is the ratio of 1+θΦ ( ) to 1 + θφ ( σ m β im )). For β im >, this ratio is positive (recall Φ is cumulative Normal distribution and is increasing). Thus GDA parameters can increase the excess returns (and the equity premium) in this model. However, this version of the model will not help explain the cross section of returns. The cross-sectional variation in the down-market depends only on β im. However, the down-market factor is monotonically increasing in β im. Since the market betas do not align with the expected returns, this model does not explain the cross-section variation in the Fama-French portfolios. 3.2 The CAPM, CCAPM, and a down-market factor A natural extension to the simple CAPM is to include consumption risk and the consumption-growth beta as in Giovannini and Weil (1989). 5 In an expected utility context (θ = ), this is captured in equation (11) with α. Recall from equation (5), optimality sets the certainty equivalent of the ex post saving error, z t+1, to one. The savings error, z t+1, is the ratio of the slope of the budget constraint, R m t+1, to the slope of the indifference curve, (1 + ρ)(c t/c t+1 ) γ 1, all raised to the power 1/γ. Hence, what is considered a bad (risky) outcome depends on the sign 4 The parameterization α =, γ = 1, and θ =, from (5), implies that exp(e t[log(r t+1)]) = 1+ρ. Hence, expected returns are constant and there can be no time variation in the equity premium. 5 More recently, Campbell and Vuolteenaho (23), Campbell, Polk, and Vuolteenaho (25), Santos and Veronesi (25) have looked at multiple beta approaches. 1

12 of γ. For this reason, an expected-utility model (with θ = ) can have market and consumption risk premia that are positive or negative; i.e, the signs of λ m and λ x depend on the preference parameters α and γ. Despite this flexibility, however, the CAPM and CCAPM have little success in explaining the cross-section of asset returns. Since consumption and market betas are highly correlated, explaining the cross-section pattern shown in Figures 2 and 3 requires λ m and λ x to be of opposite signs. While one can choose parameters to achieve this, the already small equity premium of the CAPM model becomes even smaller. Moreover, as we will explain in more detail below, such a model cannot capture the salient dynamic properties of equity premiums. Consumption-growth risk in the GDA model (θ > ) is more interesting. To explore this feature, we maintain the logarithmic risk aversion, α =, assumption but allow for inter-temporal consumption smoothing γ < 1. With these parameters, excess returns from equation (11) are given by ( ) ( r i + σ i /2) r f = σm 2 β 1 + θφ ( ) im + log 1 + θφ ( m β im + x β ix )) Consumption-growth risk enters only in the downmarket factor. That is, λ x = but x >. Interestingly, in the downmarket factor, consumption-growth risk and market risk affect the equity premium differently. The downmarket factor is increasing in market beta but decreasing in consumption-growth beta: (13) ( r i r f ) φ( m β im + x β ix ) = θ x <, (14) β ix (1 + θφ( m β im + x β ix )) where φ is the standard normal density. To see why the consumption and market betas enter with different signs, look at the source of the downmarket factor in equation (8). With α =, the downmarket factor comes from the term E[(R m ) 1 R i z < δ]. The market beta, β im, arises from the usual interaction or R i with R m and from the relationship between R i and z through R m. However, the consumption-growth beta, β ix, enters only due to the fact the expectation is conditional on z which is a function of consumption-growth, x. To understand the downmarket factor and aid with our empirical calibration, Figure 4 plots the Normal cumulative density function. The downmarket factor depends on the distance between Φ ( ) and Φ ( σ m β im + x β ix )). If lies 11

13 in the tail of the distribution, from say a small value of the disappointment threshold δ, then for any values of β im and β ix, Φ ( ) Φ ( σ m β im + x β ix )) and the downmarket factor is zero. Therefore, for the disappointment factor to matter and for consumption-growth beta to play a role, the model must be calibrated so that lies close to the center of the distribution. To get a feel for how the downmarket factor works with the data, Figure 5 plots the downmarket factor for the Fama-French size and book-to-market portfolios. The consumption-growth and market betas are shown in Table 1. 6 For concreteness, set the disappointment aversion parameter at θ = 1 and plot the downmarket factor for a range of disappointment thresholds, δ. As noted above, for small levels of δ, log δ and hence lies in the left tail of the normal distribution and the disappointment factor is zero. The horizontal lines plotted are the average pricing errors from the expected utility CAPM (θ = ) (also in Table 1). From the figure, you can see which level of the disappointment threshold, δ, will exactly fit each of the six portfolios. For example, δ =.819 will exactly fit the S/L portfolio (small firms with low bookto-market). However, to fit the S/H portfolio, a threshold of δ =.91 is needed. Figure 6 plots the same information for ten industry portfolios. Here the range of δ that exactly fit each portfolio is smaller. To fit the Manufacturing portfolio a δ =.838 is needed and to fit the Energy portfolio a δ =.882 is needed. Is a range of threshold parameters from.8 to.9 reasonable? Is the range large? First the range of parameters is slightly smaller than Routledge and Zin (24) use to fit the dynamics of the equity premium. In their calibration a threshold of.97 was needed. However, of more concern is the wide range of δ implied by the individual portfolios. To fit the equity premium, and generate time-variation in the equity premium in Routledge and Zin (24), δ had to be carefully chosen. Perhaps another way to indicate that this range for δ is troubling is to choose a single value for the preference parameter δ and calculate the consumption-growth beta, β ix, that is needed to reconcile the realized returns data with the GDA model. Figures 7 and 8 show the results for the Fama-French and industry portfolios. The plot shows the β ix needed to fit each of the portfolios for the value of δ shown (again, other parameters are held fixed in this exercise). At any fixed level of δ, the consumption-growth betas for most of the portfolios are counter-factually large 6 The data sources are standard. See Appendix B for a description. 12

14 (or small) by an order of magnitude. Perhaps, one could argue that this reflects some more complicated dynamics in consumption growth as in Bansal and Yaron (25) and Kiku (25) that makes measured unconditional consumption-growth betas misleading. Alternatively, the unconditional normality assumption may be misleading. To explore this possibility, we now turn to a dynamic version of the model. 3.3 Time varying risk aversion From Backus and Zin (1994), Campbell and Cochrane (1999), Melino and Yang (23), Routledge and Zin (24), we know that understanding the time-series property of equity returns requires a model that incorporates time-variation in the equity premium. Presumably, the time variation in equity premium has significant implications for the conditional cross sectional behavior of asset returns. The basic structure of the unconditional log-normal model maintains in a dynamic setting. Assume that the lognormality assumption in equation (9) is a statement about conditional probabilities. Assume that the conditional variancecovariance matrix is constant. That is, interpret the constant σ parameters as conditional variances and covariances, and attach a time subscript to the conditional means to denote their dependence on the state of the economy. The dynamic analog to equation (1) r i,t + σi 2 /2 = λ + (1 α γ ) r m,t + α γ (1 γ) x t + [ + λ m β im + λ x β ix + log 1 + θδ α Φ( t ) 1 + θφ(,t m β im + x β ix ) The analogue to equation (11) for excess returns is given by: ]. (15) ( r i,t + σ 2 i /2) rf t = λ m β im + λ x β ix ( ) 1 + θφ(,t ) + log 1 + θφ(,t m β im + x β ix ) (16) Note that in this model, the the dynamics enter only through the parameter t (and t, ). Therefore, the only source of dynamics is the GDA downmarket factor. This is, perhaps, not surprising since it is difficult for an expected utility preference 13

15 specification to yield time variation in the equity premium (see Routledge and Zin (24)). However, even an expected utility-like model with time-variation in the equity premium is not sufficient to explain the cross-section of asset returns. 7 In addition to maximum likelihood estimation, imposing the cross-equation restrictions of equation (16), we can estimate and test this model using restrictions on Euler equation forecast errors and GMM. 4 GMM Estimation The pricing kernel in equation (7), for any assets i and j, implies ( )] E t [z t+1 α (Rm t+1 ) 1 [1 + θi(z t+1 < δ)] Rt+1 i Rj t+1 =, (17) where, recall from equation (6), z t+1 = [ ] 1 1/γ 1 + ρ (x t+1) γ 1 Rt+1 m (18) Note that this equation is linear in probabilities (a feature of the fact GDA belongs to the Chew-Dekel class of preferences). Therefore we can use a method of moments estimator. Define the ex-post Euler equation error for portfolio i as ( ) ǫ i t = zα t+1 (Rm t+1 ) 1 [1 + θi(z t+1 < δ)] Rt+1 i Rf t+1 (19) We obtain initial consistent estimates of the GDA parameters θ and δ by minimizing the equally weighted sample analogs of the population moment E[ǫ i t] =. Since we are primarily interested in the GDA parameters, here we hold fixed the other preference parameters ρ =.4/12 and α = and γ =.5. We discuss this issue further below. In our estimation on a sample of excess returns, δ is only estimated up to an interval over which the number of disappointing outcomes in the sample increments by one. We arbitrarily use the mid-point for this interval as the 7 For example, through exogenous time variation in the risk-aversion parameter as in Melino and Yang (23) or Gordon and St-Amour (2). 14

16 point estimate for δ. 8 Given these consistent parameter estimates, we then estimate the efficient weighting matrix and obtain efficient parameter estimates, as well as asymptotic standard errors and test statistics, using standard methods. 4.1 Estimates To begin, Table 2 shows GMM estimates for the notoriously hard-to-price Fama- French size and book-to-market portfolios. In general, the GDA model has both lower average Euler equation errors than the CAPM and the errors are also more volatile. Both attributes contribute to making the GDA model harder to reject. The estimate for disappointment aversion parameter θ is which is significantly different from the expected utility level of zero. More interesting is the parameter for δ of.76. This choice of disappointment threshold implies that, in this sample, there are 4 ex-post disappointing events. To see the effect of disappointment on the pricing kernel and the ex post Euler errors, Figures 9 and 1 plot the ex-post Euler errors in both the CAPM model and the GDA model. For most of the sample, the ex-post errors in the CAPM and GDA model are identical since for most of the period, z t > δ and events are not disappointing. The top panel plots the realized z t and the threshold δ. The four disappointing outcomes for z t are denoted. On the four disappointing months, the ex-post error in the GDA model is significantly larger (multiplied by 1 + θ). Effectively, risk aversion is higher in these months. On the plot the CAPM (θ = ) Euler errors are indicated by a o. The GDA Euler error is indicated with a. The reason the GDA model is able to improve the fit, over the CAPM, is that the four disappointing months happen to correspond to bad outcomes of the portfolio return. It is important to note that disappointment is not judged stock-by-stock (or portfolio-by-portfolio). Disappointment effect enters the pricing decision through the aggregate consumption-savings/portfolio decision. The high average returns seen in some of the Fama-French size/book-to-market portfolios is because, in the GDA model, they are risky; their returns are low when the pricing kernel is amplified with the disappointment effect. The disappointment effect is present (or not) for all stocks simultaneously. As emphasized in the previous section, correlation is still 8 Since the population moments are continuous in δ, we can still estimate a standard error for this parameter using standard methods. 15

17 the source of risk. However, when the implied risk aversion in the pricing kernel is state-dependent, the correlation is amplified during disappointing periods. Note that for the GDA model, the endogenous time variation in the risk aversion is important. To fit the data, disappointment effects appear infrequently. It is crucial to our model that the risk aversion be not constant. For example, the Gul (1991) version of DA with δ = 1, will not work. Setting δ = 1 implies that roughly half of the dates have disappointing z t outcomes. This means that these dates will have the 1 + θ amplification. This will amplify the ex post pricing errors to a much greater degree. However, recall the correlation between z t and the size-book-tomarket portfolios is weak (e.g., the CAPM and CCAPM models do not work very well). Therefore, the GDA model with δ = 1 will amplify both the good and bad returns. The extra volatility in the pricing kernel reflects the higher effective risk aversion but cannot explain the cross section. The key to the GDA model is the disappointment effect that comes from the risky consumption/savings decision as seen in the Euler equation in (5). Recall that the z t represents the ex-post savings error. This is the degree to which the consumptionsavings decision missed setting the marginal rate of intertemporal substitution equal to the budget constraint slope. It is determined by consumption growth and the market return (and the the preference parameter of patience, ρ, and intertemporal substitution, γ). Low outcomes of z t < δ are disappointing and trigger the magnification by 1 + θ. The GMM estimate of δ for the size/book-to-market portfolios implies that there are four disappointing outcomes in the realized z t series. These are the four months represent the four lowest realizations of z t in the sample. Since consumption growth in the data is so smooth, the key disappointment dates, not surprisingly, are driven by low market returns. They are November, 1973, March, 198, October 1987, and August Turning to the Industry portfolios, we repeat the GMM exercise. Table 3 reports the results. The estimate of θ is similar to the FF portfolios at However, in this sample the estimate disappointment threshold δ, is higher at With this value of δ there are 7 disappointing events in the realized series z t. Figures 11, 12, and 13 show the realized z t and the ex-post Euler errors for the industry portfolios. 9 This indicates that the results are sensitive to the measurement of the data. In quarterly data, for example, the October 1987 event is far less prominent. 16

18 Since other preference parameters of ρ and γ are constant across these estimations, the series z t is identical to that used in the size/book-to-market portfolios. We have more to say on this below. Here the seven disappointing outcomes include the same four dates mentioned above: November 1973, March 198, October 1987, and August However, now fitting the industry data is improved by including April 197, September 1974, and October Lastly, Table 4 estimates the preference parameters on sample of six size/book to market and ten industry portfolios jointly. The results are broadly similar to Tables 2 and 3. The estimate for disappointment aversion, θ, is The estimate of disappointment threshold, δ, is.7927 indicating there are six disappointing realizations for the consumption/savings error, z t. 4.2 Discussion Estimating the disappointment threshold parameter δ in our model is somewhat non-standard. In our sample of portfolio returns for the six size/book-to-market portfolios, for example, we estimate that there are four key dates that are disappointing. A value for δ anywhere in the range.753 to.7758 will yield the same four disappointing outcomes in our sample of realized ex-post saving errors, z t. In any finite sample, excess returns can only estimate a range for δ. More precise point estimates could be obtained by using level for returns rather than excess returns we focus on here. That is, since the denominator in equation (7) is continuous in δ, estimating E t [M t+1 Rt+1 i ] = 1 can uniquely identify δ. However, even in our excess-return exercise, we seem to generate fairly precise information about δ since both the estimated range is small, and since the model s performance would worsen dramatically for the size/book-to-market portfolios if we were to lower δ to imply only 3 (or fewer) disappointing dates, or raise δ to imply 5 (or more) disappointing dates. Our GMM strategy here, is to estimate the key GDA parameters δ and θ. To do this, we fixed ρ =.4/12, α =, and γ =.5 across all the estimations. Given these parameters, we can calculate the z t ex post savings errors. Holding ρ and γ constant across our estimation implies that z t are the same in each of our estimations. Fixing the parameter ρ is of little importance (it is mostly a scaling parameter). The effects 17

19 of altering the expected utility risk aversion parameter α are also straightforward. However, setting γ > is important. This implies that intertemporal consumption at different dates (along certain paths) are substitutes. Besides the usual importance this has in an expected utility model, the sign of γ determines what type of savings errors are disappointing. Recall, in the consumption-savings problem that underlies our asset pricing model, the definition of disappointment depends on the intertemporal substitution parameter γ. Recall from equation (5), optimality sets the certainty equivalent of the ex post saving error, z t+1, to one. z t+1 is the the ratio of the slope of the constraint, Rt+1 ω, to the slope of the indifference curve, (1 + ρ)(c t /c t+1 ) γ 1, raised to the power 1/γ. So with γ >, z t+1 < δ implies that the realization that period-t savings was larger than would have been optimal ex post, is the disappointing outcome. Conversely, if intertemporal consumption is complementary, γ <, the realization that period-t savings was smaller than would have been optimal ex post, is the disappointing outcome. Therefore, the nature of disappointment depends on the sign of the substitution parameter γ. The fact that the cross-sectional evidence suggests γ > is interesting and is worth considering in future research. 5 Conclusion [TO BE ADDED] 18

20 References Allais, M. (1979): The Foundations of a Positive Theory of Choice Involving Risk and a Criticism of the Postulates and Axioms of the American Schhol, in Expected Utility Hypothesis and the Allais Paradox, ed. by M. Allais, and O. Hagen. D. Reidel Publishing Co., Dordrecht, Holland. Ang, A., J. Chen, and Y. Xing (25): Downside Risk, NBER Working Papers Backus, D. K., B. R. Routledge, and S. E. Zin (25): Exotic Preferences for Macroeconomists, in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 24, ed. by M. Gertler, and K. Rogoff, vol. 19, pp MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Backus, D. K., and S. E. Zin (1994): Reverse Engineering the Yield Curve, NBER Working Paper # W4676. Bansal, R., and A. Yaron (25): Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, Journal of Finance (forthcoming), Wahrton Working Paper. Barberis, N., M. Huang, and T. Santos (21): Prospect Theory and Asset Prices, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXVI(1). Basak, S., and A. Shapiro (21): Value-at-Risk Based Risk Management: Optimal Policies and Asset Prices, Review of Financial Studies, 14, (2), Campbell, J. Y., and J. H. Cochrane (1999): By Force of Habit: A Consumption- Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior, Journal of Political Economy, 17, Campbell, J. Y., C. Polk, and T. Vuolteenaho (25): Growth or Glamour? Fundamentals and Systematic Risk in Stock Returns, NBER Working Paper No Campbell, J. Y., and T. Vuolteenaho (23): Bad Beta, Good Beta, NBER Working Paper No Chew, S. H. (1983): A Generalization of the Quasilinear Mean with Applications to the Measurement of Income Inequality and Decision Theory Resolving the Allais Paradox, Econometrica,, 51(4), (1989): Axiomatic Utility Theories with the Betweeness Property, Annals of Operations Research, 19, Conlisk, J. (1989): Three Variants on the Allais Paradox, The American Economic Review, 79(3), Dekel, E. (1986): An Axiomatic Characterization of Preferences under Uncertainty, Journal of Economic Theory, 4, Epstein, L. G., and S. E. Zin (1989): Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework, Econometrica, 57(4), (199): First-Order Risk Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle, Journal of Monetary Economics, 26(3), Fama, E. F., and K. R. French (1992): The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance, 47,

21 Giovannini, A., and P. Weil (1989): Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in the Capital Asset Pricing Model, NBER Working Paper No Gordon, S., and P. St-Amour (2): A Preference Regiem Model of Null and Bear Markets, American Economic Review, 9(4), Gourio, F. (25): Operating Leverage, Stock Market Cyclicality, and the Cross-Section of Returns, Working Paper, Boston University. Gul, F. (1991): A Theory of Disappointment Aversion, Econometrica, 59(3), Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky (1979): Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk, Econometrica, 47(2), Kiku, D. (25): Is the Value Premium a Puzzle?, Duke University Working Paper. Machina, M. J. (1987): Choince Under Uncertainty: Problems Solved and Unsolved, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1(1), Melino, A., and A. X. Yang (23): State Dependent Preferences Can Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle, Review of Economic Dynamics, 6(2), Pakos, M. (25): Asset Pricing with Durable Goods and Non-Homothetic Preferences, Working Paper, Carnegie Mellon University. Petkova, R., and L. Zhang (25): Is Value Riskier than Growth?, Journal of Financial Economics, pp Routledge, B. R., and S. E. Zin (24): Generalized Disappointment Aversion and Asset Prices, NBER Working Paper No. w117. Santos, T., and P. Veronesi (25): Cash-Flow Risk, Discount Risk, and the Value Premium, NBER Working Papers Number Tuzel, S. (25): Corporate Real Estate Holdings and the Cross Section of Stock Returns, University of Souther California Working Paper. Yogo, M. (25): A Consumption-Based Explanation of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance, 61 forthcoming(2), April 26. 2

22 Appendix A Consider the expectation where» y1 y 2 E[exp {αy 1 + y 2} y 1 < a],»ȳ1 N, ȳ 2» σ 2 1 σ 12 σ 21 σ 2 2 (A1) «, (A2) and α and a are arbitrary real numbers. Using standard results, this expectation can be written as «a ȳ1 σ 12 E[exp {αy 1 + y 2}]Φ ασ 1, (A3) σ 1 where and Φ( ) is the standard normal cdf. E[exp {αy 1 + y 2}] = exp {αȳ 1 + ȳ 2 + α 2 σ 2 1/2 + σ 2 2/2 + ασ 12}, (A4) The assumption of log-normality of consumption growth and returns in equation (9), implies that ln z and ln R i lnr m are jointly normally distributed. Thus we can apply (A3) and (A4) to (8) to get equation (1). Appendix B - Data The data we use is standard. We use monthly data for the period February 1956 to April 25 (556 months). Consumption growth is calculated as per-capita monthly growth in real consumer non-durable and service chain-weighted expenditures (Source: Datastream). For asset returns, we use the data provided from Ken French on the nominal monthly returns for the one-month Treasury bill rate, the value-weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks. In addition, we use the nominal monthly returns on the ten industry portfolios as well as six portfolios constructed by sorting on size (market capitalization) and book-to-market ratio (the ratio shareholders equity to the market capitalization). Additional details are available at: < library.html> These nominal returns are converted to real returns using the the price level change calculated from the ratio of nominal to real consumer expenditures on non-durable and services chain-weighted expenditures (Source: Datastream). 21

23 Table 1: Data Mean St. Dev. Log Consumption Growth Log Equity Returns Log Risk-Free Rate Portfolio Return Moments Market Consumption CAPM Mean St. Dev. Beta Beta Error Ê[r i r f ] + ˆσ i 2/2 ˆσ i ˆβ im ˆβix Ê[ǫ i ] Market S/L S/M S/H B/L B/M B/H NoDur Durbl Manuf Enrgy HiTec Telcm Shops Hlth Utils Other The data consists of 256 monthly real rates of return for the period February 1959 to April 25. The portfolios are the Fama-French six size and book-to-market portfolios and ten industry portfolios. Consumption Growth and price-level data are from Datastream. ˆβim is the market beta and ˆβ ix is the consumption-growth beta calculated from the data. Ê[r i r f ] + ˆσ 2 i /2 is the estimated average excess return on the portfolios. Ê[ǫ i] is the average CAPM pricing error relative to the unconditional expected utility CAPM in equation (12). That is ǫ i,t = (r i,t r f,t + σ 2 i /2) σ 2 mβ im 22

24 Table 2: GMM Size and Book-to-Market Portfolios - Unconditional CAPM GDA Parameter Fixed Estimate st. error θ δ n.a.7644 n.a. freq. of z t < δ n.a 4 Euler Equation Errors mean st. dev. mean st. dev. S/L S/M S/H B/L B/M B/H J-statistic d.f 6 4 P-value GMM estimation of Euler equation restriction on cross section of returns. The CAPM column fixes θ = and δ is arbitrary. The GDA model estimates δ and θ. The standard error for the θ estimate is calculated. The standard error for δ is not provided. The frequency of z t < δ is implied by the choice of δ and is the number of occurrences in the 256 month sample. The data is monthly real excess returns in six Fama-French size and book-to-market portfolios for the period February 1959 to April 25. Other model parameters are fixed at α =, γ =.5, and ρ =.4/12. 23

25 Table 3: GMM Industry Portfolios - Unconditional CAPM GDA Parameter Fixed Estimate st. error θ δ n.a.7929 n.a. freq. of z t < δ n.a 7 Euler Equation Errors mean st. dev. mean st. dev. NoDur Durbl Manuf Enrgy HiTec Telcm Shops Hlth Utils Other J-statistic d.f 1 8 P-value GMM estimation of Euler equation restriction on cross section of returns. The CAPM column fixes θ = and δ is arbitrary. The GDA model estimates δ and θ. The standard error for the θ estimate is calculated. The standard error for δ is not provided. The frequency of z t < δ is implied by the choice of δ and is the number of occurrences in the 256 month sample. The data is monthly real excess returns in ten industry portfolios for the period February 1959 to April 25. Other model parameters are fixed at α =, γ =.5, and ρ =.4/12. 24

26 Table 4: GMM FF Size and Book-to-Market and Industry Portfolios - Unconditional CAPM GDA Parameter Fixed Estimate st. error θ δ n.a.7927 n.a. freq. of z t < δ n.a 6 Euler Equation Errors mean st. dev. mean st. dev. S/L S/M S/H B/L B/M B/H NoDur Durbl Manuf Enrgy HiTec Telcm Shops Hlth Utils Other J-statistic d.f 1 14 P-value GMM estimation of Euler equation restriction on cross section of returns. The CAPM table fixes θ = and δ is arbitrary. The GDA model estimates δ and θ. The standard error for the θ estimate is calculated. The standard error for δ is not provided. The frequency of z t < δ is implied by the choice of δ and is the number of occurrences in the 256 month sample. The data is monthly real excess returns on six size/book-to-market portfolios and ten industry portfolios for the period February 1959 to April 25. Other model parameters are fixed at α =, γ =.5, and ρ =.4/12. 25

27 Figure 1: Indifference Curves 3 (a): θ= (Expected Utility) 3 (b): θ=2. δ=1 (Gul) x x x x (c): θ=2. δ=.8, (GDA) x < δ µ(p) (d): θ=2. δ=1.25, (GDA) x < δ µ(p) 1 x x 1, x 2 > δ µ(p) x x 1, x 2 < δ µ(p) 1 x 2 < δ µ(p) 1 x 2 < δ µ(p) x x 1 Indifference Curve over two outcomes x 1 and x 2 with prob(x 1) =.5. Shown are: (a) Expected Utility (θ = ), (b) Gul Disappointment Aversion θ = 2. (δ = 1), (c) Generalized Disappointment Aversion θ = 2. and δ =.8 (d) Generalized Disappointment Aversion θ = 2. and δ = 1.2. The dashed lines are expected utility with distorted odds. The indifference curve is the upper envelope (solid line). The rays from the origin indicate the threshold where x 1 and/or x 2 are disappointing. 26

One-Factor Asset Pricing

One-Factor Asset Pricing One-Factor Asset Pricing with Stefanos Delikouras (University of Miami) Alex Kostakis Manchester June 2017, WFA (Whistler) Alex Kostakis (Manchester) One-Factor Asset Pricing June 2017, WFA (Whistler)

More information

One-Factor Asset Pricing

One-Factor Asset Pricing One-Factor Asset Pricing with Stefanos Delikouras (University of Miami) Alex Kostakis MBS 12 January 217, WBS Alex Kostakis (MBS) One-Factor Asset Pricing 12 January 217, WBS 1 / 32 Presentation Outline

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Nicola Pavoni October 21, 2016 The Lucas Tree Model This is a general equilibrium model where instead of deriving properties of

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Christian Julliard and Anisha Ghosh Working Paper 2008 P t d b J L i f NYU A t P i i Presented by Jason Levine for NYU Asset Pricing Seminar, Fall 2009

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Fall 2017 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Recursive Preferences

Recursive Preferences Recursive Preferences David K. Backus, Bryan R. Routledge, and Stanley E. Zin Revised: December 5, 2005 Abstract We summarize the class of recursive preferences. These preferences fit naturally with recursive

More information

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 15, 2013 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 15, 2013 1 / 56 Consumption-based Asset Pricing Even if we cannot easily solve

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in Durable Consumption Wei Yang 1 This draft: October 2009 1 William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester, Rochester,

More information

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) A stochastic discount factor is a stochastic process {M t,t+s } such that

More information

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle Resolution of a Financial Puzzle M.J. Brennan and Y. Xia September, 1998 revised November, 1998 Abstract The apparent inconsistency between the Tobin Separation Theorem and the advice of popular investment

More information

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods. Introduction In ECON 50, we discussed the structure of two-period dynamic general equilibrium models, some solution methods, and their

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri Basics of Asset Pricing Ali Nejadmalayeri January 2009 No-Arbitrage and Equilibrium Pricing in Complete Markets: Imagine a finite state space with s {1,..., S} where there exist n traded assets with a

More information

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective Ravi Bansal Dana Kiku Amir Yaron November 14, 2007 Abstract Asset return and cash flow predictability is of considerable

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Ian Dew-Becker and Stefano Giglio Duke Fuqua and Chicago Booth 11/27/13 Dew-Becker and Giglio (Duke and Chicago) Frequency-domain asset pricing

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Alberto Bisin Corporate Finance: Lecture Notes Class 1: Valuation updated November 17th, 2002 1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Consider an economy with two states of nature {s 1, s 2 } and with

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption Notes for Econ22A: Consumption Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas UC Berkeley Fall 215 c Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 215, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Disclaimer: These notes are riddled with inconsistencies, typos and

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Bryan Kelly NYU Stern and Chicago Booth Outline Introduction An Economic Framework Econometric Methodology Empirical Findings Conclusions Tail Risk

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Leads, Lags, and Logs: Asset Prices in Business Cycle Analysis

Leads, Lags, and Logs: Asset Prices in Business Cycle Analysis Leads, Lags, and Logs: Asset Prices in Business Cycle Analysis David Backus (NYU), Bryan Routledge (CMU), and Stanley Zin (CMU) Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College October 24, 2007 This version:

More information

Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Final Exam Suggested Solutions University of Washington Fall 003 Department of Economics Eric Zivot Economics 483 Final Exam Suggested Solutions This is a closed book and closed note exam. However, you are allowed one page of handwritten

More information

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Identifying : A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania CEPR and NBER Dongho Song University of Pennsylvania Amir Yaron University of Pennsylvania NBER February 12,

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule 1

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule 1 Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule 1 Michael Gallmeyer 2 Burton Hollifield 3 Francisco Palomino 4 Stanley Zin 5 September 2, 2008 1 Preliminary and incomplete. This paper was previously titled Bond

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University Volume 30, Issue Random risk aversion and the cost of eliminating the foreign exchange risk of the Euro Samih A Azar Haigazian University Abstract This paper answers the following questions. If the Euro

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

Salience and Asset Prices

Salience and Asset Prices Salience and Asset Prices Pedro Bordalo Nicola Gennaioli Andrei Shleifer December 2012 1 Introduction In Bordalo, Gennaioli and Shleifer (BGS 2012a), we described a new approach to choice under risk that

More information

SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, )

SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, ) Econometrica Supplementary Material SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, 55 111) BY IAN MARTIN FIGURE S.1 shows the functions F γ (z),scaledby2 γ so that they integrate

More information

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997 Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997 Seminar in Asset Pricing Theory Presented by Saki Bigio November 2007 1 /

More information

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M VIALE I Markowitz-Tobin Mean-Variance Portfolio Analysis Assumption Mean-Variance preferences Markowitz 95 Quadratic utility function E [ w b w ] { = E [ w] b V ar w + E [ w] }

More information

State Dependent Preferences and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A different Perspective

State Dependent Preferences and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A different Perspective State Dependent Preferences and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A different Perspective Sara Nada University of Rome Tor Vergata Sara_nada14@hotmail.com This draft: May 2014 Abstract This paper revisits state

More information

Risk Aversion and Wealth: Evidence from Person-to-Person Lending Portfolios On Line Appendix

Risk Aversion and Wealth: Evidence from Person-to-Person Lending Portfolios On Line Appendix Risk Aversion and Wealth: Evidence from Person-to-Person Lending Portfolios On Line Appendix Daniel Paravisini Veronica Rappoport Enrichetta Ravina LSE, BREAD LSE, CEP Columbia GSB April 7, 2015 A Alternative

More information

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility Harjoat S. Bhamra Sauder School of Business University of British Columbia Raman

More information

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility

More information

Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty

Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty We always need to make a decision (or select from among actions, options or moves) even when there exists

More information

Financial Economics: Capital Asset Pricing Model

Financial Economics: Capital Asset Pricing Model Financial Economics: Capital Asset Pricing Model Shuoxun Hellen Zhang WISE & SOE XIAMEN UNIVERSITY April, 2015 1 / 66 Outline Outline MPT and the CAPM Deriving the CAPM Application of CAPM Strengths and

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation I. Introduction Thus far, we have considered time-separable lifetime utility specifications such as E t Z T t U[C(s), s]

More information

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Persistent than You Think October 19th, 2009 Introduction: Habit Preferences Habit preferences: can generate a higher equity premium for a given curvature

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices Prospect Theory and Asset Prices Presenting Barberies - Huang - Santos s paper Attila Lindner January 2009 Attila Lindner (CEU) Prospect Theory and Asset Prices January 2009 1 / 17 Presentation Outline

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

More information

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis A. Buss B. Dumas R. Uppal G. Vilkov INSEAD INSEAD, CEPR, NBER Edhec, CEPR Goethe U. Frankfurt

More information

Lecture 11. Fixing the C-CAPM

Lecture 11. Fixing the C-CAPM Lecture 11 Dynamic Asset Pricing Models - II Fixing the C-CAPM The risk-premium puzzle is a big drag on structural models, like the C- CAPM, which are loved by economists. A lot of efforts to salvage them:

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 60 minutes Part B (Prof. Barro): 60

More information

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008)

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Backus, Routledge, & Zin Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Asset pricing with Kreps-Porteus preferences, starting with theoretical results from Epstein

More information

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 ortfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach Validity of the Mean-Variance Approach Constant absolute risk aversion (CARA): u(w ) = exp(

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets Andrey Ermolov Columbia Business School April 24, 2014 1 / 41 Stylized Facts about Bond Markets US Fact 1: Upward Sloping Real Yield Curve In US, real long

More information

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Tolga Cenesizoglu March 1, 2016 Cenesizoglu Return Decomposition & the Business Cycle March 1, 2016 1 / 54 Introduction Stock prices depend on investors expectations

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

Online Appendix: Extensions

Online Appendix: Extensions B Online Appendix: Extensions In this online appendix we demonstrate that many important variations of the exact cost-basis LUL framework remain tractable. In particular, dual problem instances corresponding

More information

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Ralph S.J. Koijen, Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh University of Chicago, UCLA & NBER, and NYU, NBER & CEPR UC Berkeley, September 10, 2009 Unified Stochastic

More information

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management Archana Khetan 05/09/2010 +91-9930812722 Archana090@hotmail.com MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management 1 Portfolio Management Portfolio is a collection of assets. By investing in a portfolio or combination

More information

A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails

A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails Florida International University FIU Digital Commons Economics Research Working Paper Series Department of Economics 11-26-2008 A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails Zhiguang (Gerald)

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

A Consumption CAPM with a Reference Level

A Consumption CAPM with a Reference Level A Consumption CAPM with a Reference Level René Garcia CIREQ, CIRANO and Université de Montréal Éric Renault CIREQ, CIRANO and University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Andrei Semenov York University

More information

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II Chao Wei Department of Economics George Washington University Washington, DC 20052 January 2007 1 1 Deterministic Dynamic Programming Below I describe a typical dynamic

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a 316-406 ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a Chris Edmond hcpedmond@unimelb.edu.aui Introduction to consumption-based asset pricing We will begin our brief look at asset pricing with a review of the

More information

Non-Monotonicity of the Tversky- Kahneman Probability-Weighting Function: A Cautionary Note

Non-Monotonicity of the Tversky- Kahneman Probability-Weighting Function: A Cautionary Note European Financial Management, Vol. 14, No. 3, 2008, 385 390 doi: 10.1111/j.1468-036X.2007.00439.x Non-Monotonicity of the Tversky- Kahneman Probability-Weighting Function: A Cautionary Note Jonathan Ingersoll

More information

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets René Garcia Edhec Business School, Université de Montréal, CIRANO and CIREQ Georges Tsafack Suffolk University Measuring

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule. Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income Markets

Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule. Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed Income Markets Term Premium Dynamics and the Taylor Rule Michael Gallmeyer (Texas A&M) Francisco Palomino (Michigan) Burton Hollifield (Carnegie Mellon) Stanley Zin (Carnegie Mellon) Bank of Canada Conference on Fixed

More information

Implications of Long-Run Risk for. Asset Allocation Decisions

Implications of Long-Run Risk for. Asset Allocation Decisions Implications of Long-Run Risk for Asset Allocation Decisions Doron Avramov and Scott Cederburg March 1, 2012 Abstract This paper proposes a structural approach to long-horizon asset allocation. In particular,

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings, State Pricing 1/ 40 Introduction We now consider a consumption-savings decision along with the previous portfolio choice decision. These

More information

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance Yale ICF Working Paper No. 08 11 First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, 1992 Safety First Portfolio Insurance William N. Goetzmann, International Center for Finance, Yale School of Management,

More information

Rational theories of finance tell us how people should behave and often do not reflect reality.

Rational theories of finance tell us how people should behave and often do not reflect reality. FINC3023 Behavioral Finance TOPIC 1: Expected Utility Rational theories of finance tell us how people should behave and often do not reflect reality. A normative theory based on rational utility maximizers

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

Outline. Simple, Compound, and Reduced Lotteries Independence Axiom Expected Utility Theory Money Lotteries Risk Aversion

Outline. Simple, Compound, and Reduced Lotteries Independence Axiom Expected Utility Theory Money Lotteries Risk Aversion Uncertainty Outline Simple, Compound, and Reduced Lotteries Independence Axiom Expected Utility Theory Money Lotteries Risk Aversion 2 Simple Lotteries 3 Simple Lotteries Advanced Microeconomic Theory

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information