Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Class Notes on Financial Mathematics. No-Arbitrage Pricing Model"

Transcription

1 Class Notes on No-Arbitrage Pricing Model April 18, 2016 Dr. Riyadh Al-Mosawi Department of Mathematics, College of Education for Pure Sciences, Thiqar University References: 1. Stochastic Calculus for Finance I: The binomial Asset Pricing Model by Steven E. Shreve, Spinger, Stochastic Calculus for Finance II: Continuous-Time Model by Steven E. Shreve, Spinger, Brownian Motion Calculus by Ubbo F Wiersema, John Wiley & Sons, Ltd

2 1 No-Arbitrage Pricing Model 1.1 Introduction An option is a tickets which gives its holder the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell a financial asset at or before a certain date (maturity) T at a predetermined price (strike price) K. The financial asset include, but are not limited to stocks, currencies, commodities (gold, copper, oil,...) and options. An option to buy the financial asset is referred to as a Call Option while an option to sell is called at Put Option. If you can exercise the option only at time of expiration T, this is called a European Option. If you can exercise at the time T or any time before the time T, it is called an American Option. The holder of a call option is not obliged to exercise it. The writer (seller) of European call option needs to pay the buyer of the option an amount of (value of the option) { (S T K) + ST K, if S T > K; = max(0, S T K) = 0, if S T K. where S T is stock price ate time T. Similarly, the value of European put option is given by { K (K S T ) + ST, if S T < K; = max(0, K S T ) = 0, if S T K. It is clear that the writer (seller) of the option bears an unlimited risk. The natural question, then, is how much the writer should charge as Pricing the Option at time t = 0. 1

3 The fundamental condition for establishing the price of an option is that it should not permit an Arbitrage. Arbitrage ( No free Lunch ) opportunity is a situation where an investor can make a granted profit without incurring any risk (riskless profit). Hedging the Option. The procedure to find the no-arbitrage price of the option is to determine how much money should be invested in the bond (riskless investment like bank account) and stock market to meet payment obligations (with respect to the seller of the option) at maturity time T. The main reason of using the options is that the option is more sensitive to price changes than the underlying asset itself. Consider for example a European call with strike price K = 0. At a time t let S t = 60 then the value of the option is (S t K) + = (60 0) + = 10. If S t increases by 10% to 66 then the value of the option will be (66 0) + = 16, an increase of 60%. Similarly if S t decreases by 10% to 4 then the value of the option decreases from 10 to (4 0) + = 4, a loss of 60%. A portfolio means a collection of financial assets such as stocks and bonds and cash equivalents. Self-financing portfolio means that the change in the portfolio value over time should only come from the change in the value of the stock and the change in borrowing i.e. no many is withdrawn or added freely. Compound Interest Rate. Consider a simple savings account with initial investment D$ invested at an annual interest rate of r compound monthly. After T years the account will be () T D$ After n months (or T = n/12 years ), the account will be ( ) nd$ ( = ) 12T D$ Suppose we compound m times a year at an annual rate of r Then after T years ( the account will be 1 + m) r mt D$. 2

4 Then the account is compound continuously if m which yields ( lim ) mt ( ( D = lim m ) T D = e m m m m) rt D$. Forward Contract. The buyer of a forward contract with maturity T and delivery price K is obliged to buy the underlying asset at price K on date T. The payments at time T will be S T K. 1.2 One Period Binomial Model Let t 0 =Begin time of the period t 1 =End time of the period S 0 =Price of a one stock at t 0 S 1 =Price of a one stock at t 1, where { S(H), if the result of a coin is Head; S 1 = S(T ), if the result of a coin is Tail. We assume that P(H) = p > 0, P(T ) = q = 1 p > 0 and p q. S 1 is known at time t 1 but not at time t 0 so it is random quantity. Suppose u = S 1(H) and d = S 1(T ), where S 0 S 0 3

5 d < u, u is called the up-factor and d is called the down-factor. S 1 (H) = us 0 S 0 S 1 (T ) = ds 0 Suppose r be the interest rate of the money market so 1$ invested (or borrowed) in the money market at time t 0 will yield (or indebt of) ()$ at time t 1. Arbitrage as a trading strategy that begins with no money at time t 0, has zero probability of losing money and has a positive probability of making money at time t 1. Let us consider the following two cases: Case(I): Suppose d. At time t 0 one could begin with zero money borrow m$ dollars from the money market in order to buy a share of stock. At time t 1 his profit from the stock market is at least dm$ his dept of the money market is ()m$ since d then dm ()m the net profit is (d 1 r)m 0. This is an arbitrage. Case(II):If u. At time t 0 one could sell a stock by m$ dollars in the stock market invest the money m dollars in the money market. At time t 1 4

6 his loss from the stock market is at most um$ his profit from the money market is ()m$ since u then um ()m the net profit is ( u)m 0. This is an arbitrage. Thus to roll out (remove) the arbitrage from the market, we should assume d < < u Let us consider a European Call Option. The owner of the call option has the right but not obligation to buy one share of the stock at time t 1 for strike price K. Assume S 1 (T ) < K < S 1 (H). Case-I: If at time t 1, we get a Head on the coin then the option can be exercised and yields the profit S 1 (H) K. Case-II: If at time t 1, we get a Tail on the coin then no need to exercise the option since S 1 (T ) < K. Hence, at time t 1, the owner of the option will get max{s 1 K, 0} = (S 1 K) +. The fundamental question of option pricing is what is the price of the option at time t 0 the coin toss results head or tail. before we know whether This question is called the Option Valuation. Example 1.1 Hedging (Replicating) the Option. Let S 0 = 4, u = 2, d = 1 and r = 1. Then, the price of stock will be 2 4 { S1 (H) = us 0 = 2 4 = 8, if Head; S 0 = 4 S 1 (T ) = ds 0 = = 2, if Tail. Consider a European Call Option with strike price be K = and maturity at t 1. Assume the initial money is X 0 = 1.20$ and we want to buy, at time t 0, 0 = 1 2 shares of stock.

7 At time t 0. The cost of 0 = 1 2 shares of stock is 0 S 0 = = 2$ then have to borrow X 0 0 S 0 = = 0.8$. So we have indebt of 0.8 to the money market. At time t 1. We will be in dept of 1$ to the money market because We will also have stock value at either or ()(X 0 0 S 0 ) = (1 + 1 )( 0.8) = 1$ S 1(H) = = S 1(T ) = = 1. The portfolio of stock and money market account at time t 1 will be or X 1 (H) = 1 2 S 1(H) + ()(X 0 0 S 0 ) = 4 1 = 3 X 1 (T ) = 1 2 S 1(T ) + ()(X 0 0 S 0 ) = 1 1 = 0. The value of the option at time t 1 is either or (S 1 (H) K) + = max(8, 0) = max(3, 0) = 3 = X 1 (H) (S 1 (T ) K) + = max(2, 0) = max( 3, 0) = 0 = X 1 (T ). Hence the no-arbitrage price of the option is 1.2$. Example 1.2 Consider Example 1.1. Suppose the price of the option is 1.21$. At time t 0 : 6

8 the seller of the option could invest 1.21 X 0 = = 0.01$ in the money market the seller of the option will invest X 0 = 1.2 to replicate the option as in Example 1.1. At time t 1 : the seller of the option will get a granted profit 0.01 () = 0.01 (1.2) = 0.012$ from the money market This is an arbitrage because the seller of the option needs no money initially and without risks of loss has profit 0.012$ at time t 1. Example 1.3 Consider Example 1.1. Suppose the price of the option is 1.19$. At time t 0 : the buyer of the option could sell 0 = 1 shares of stock from his stocks in the stock 2 market with price 0 S 0 = = 2$. the buyer of the option uses 1.19$ to buy the option, put 0.80$ in the many market and in a separate account puts the remaining 0.01$. At time t 1. If there a Head in the coin, the buyer of the option will need 4 dollars to get (restore) 1 2 share of stocks get (S 1 (H) K) + = (8, 0) + = (3, 0) + = 3$ from the option get 0.80 () = 0.80 (1.2) = 1$ from the money market 7

9 get a granted profit from the money market () = 0.80 (1.2) = 0.012$ If there a Tail in the coin, the buyer of the option will need 1$ to get (restore) 1 2 share of stocks get (S 1 (T ) K) + = (2, 0) + = ( 3, 0) + = 0$ from the option get 0.80 () = 0.80 (1.2) = 1$ from the money market get a granted profit 0.01 () = 0.80 (1.2) = 0.012$ from the money market. This is an arbitrage. Example 1.4 Consider a European call option with strike price K = 98 and maturity t 1. Suppose at time t 0, the stock price is S 0 = 100 and the price at time t 1 is either S 1 (H) = 112 or S 1 (T ) = 84. Suppose the interest rate is r = %. We want to obtain a no-arbitrage price for the call option. t 0 t 1 t 1 Money Stock 100 S 1 (T )= 84 S 1 (H)=112 Option? (S 1 (T ) 98) + = (84 98) + = 0 (S 1 (H) 98) + = (112 98) + = 14 Solution : To find the no-arbitrage pricing for this option we should construct a portfolio that satisfies the equation Value of portfolio at time t 1 =Value of option at time t 1. 8

10 Let a denote money invested in the money market and b is money invested in the stock market. Then the no-arbitrage price satisfies the equations 1.0a + 84b = 0 1.0a + 112b = 14. Hence a = 40 and b = 0.. This means that we borrow 40$ from bank and buy a half share of stocks stock. At time t 0, this portfolio has a value of = 10$. Hence the no-arbitrage price of the option is 10$. Any other price will be arbitrage price. Case-1 Suppose the price is $. At time t 0. sell 0. share of stock by = 0$. buy the option by $ put 4$ in the money market. At time t 1. If there a Head in the coin, the buyer of the option will need 6$ to get (restore) 0. share of stocks get 14$ from the option get = 47.2$ from the money market get a granted profit =.2$. If there a Tail in the coin, the buyer of the option will need 42$ to get (restore) 0. share of stocks get 0$ from the option get = 47.2$ from the money market get a granted profit =.2$ rom the money market. 9

11 This is an arbitrage. Case-2 Suppose the price is 1$. This is an arbitrage At time t 0. sell the option by 1$ borrow 3$ from the money market buy 0. of stock by 0$. At time t 1. If there a Head in the coin, the seller of the option will sell 0. of stock by 6$ give = 36.7$ to the bank give 14$ to the buyer of the option get a granted profit =.2$. If there a Tail in the coin, the seller of the option will sell 0. of stock by 42$ give = 36.7$ to the bank give 0$ to the buyer of the option get a granted profit =.2$ This is an arbitrage Value of the Derivative Security The derivative is a form of an agreement to buy or sell an financial asset at a fixed price on or before a certain date. The value derivative securities varies with the value of the financial assets. Forward contracts, call and put options are some common types of derivatives. Suppose a derivative security V of amounts at time t 1 are given as V 1 (H) and V 1 (T ). Now we want to determine the value for a derivative security at time t 0 10

12 by replicating it. Let X 0 =initial wealth (money at time zero) 0 =share of stocks to be purchased at time zero. The value of portfolio of stock and money market at time one is X 1 = 0 S 1 + ()(X 0 0 S 0 ) =()X (S 1 ()S 0 ). that is mean X 1 (H) =()X (S 1 (H) ()S 0 ) X 1 (T ) =()X (S 1 (T ) ()S 0 ). Note that V 1, S 1, S 0, r are known and X 0, 0, V 0 are unknown We want to choose X 0 and 0 so that Now X 1 (H) = V 1 (H) and X 1 (T ) = V 1 (T ). Also X 1 (H) = V 1 (H) ()X (S 1 (H) ()S 0 ) = V 1 (H) ( ) S1 (H) X S 0 = V 1(H). (1.1) X 1 (T ) = V 1 (T ) ()X (S 1 (T ) ()S 0 ) = V 1 (T ) ( ) S1 (T ) X S 0 = V 1(T ). (1.2) Multiplying (1.1) by p and (1.2) by q = 1 p i.e. p + q = 1 gives us ( ) S1 (H) px 0 + p 0 S 0 = pv 1(H) and (1.3) ( ) S1 (T ) qx 0 + q 0 S 0 = qv 1(T ). (1.4) 11

13 and by adding (1.3) to (1.4) we get ( p + q)x ( ps1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) Since p + q = 1 then Take Then (1.) becomes X ( ps1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) ( p + q)s 0 ) S 0 ) = pv 1(H) + qv 1 (T ). = pv 1(H) + qv 1 (T ). (1.) S 0 = ps 1(H) + qs 1 (T ). (1.6) X 0 = pv 1(H) + qv 1 (T ). (1.7) By subtracting (1.2) from (1.1) we get ( ) S1 (H) X S 0 ( ) S1 (T ) X 0 0 S 0 0 S 1 (H) 0 0 = V 1(H) V 1 (T ) S 1 (H) S 1 (T ) = V 1(H) = V 1(T ) S 1 (T ) = V 1(H) V 1(T ) (1.8) From (1.17), we have which implies ( ) 1 pu + qd S 0 = pus 0 + qds 0 = S 0 ( pu + qd ) = 1 = 1 ( ( ) u d = p = p = d u d ) pu + (1 p)d + d = 1 = 1 (1.9) (1.10) 12

14 and q = 1 p = 1 d u d = u 1 r u d. Then p = d u d and q = u 1 r u d. (1.11) Equation (1.8) is called Delta-Hedging formula. Let P = ( p, q) and P = (p, q). Hence the no-arbitrage price of the derivative security at time zero is X 0 = V 0 V 0 = p V 1(H) + q V 1(T ) and any other price would introduce an arbitrage. Remark 1.1 (1.12) We call ( p, q) risk-neutral probabilities while we call (p, q) the actual probabilities. Since d < < u, then ()S 0 < ps 1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) = pus 0 + qds 0 < p u + q d and from Equation (1.17) we get ()S 0 = ps 1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) = pus 0 + qds 0 = p u + q d. Equation (1.12) is called the risk-neutral pricing formula for the one period binomial model. Note that the value of the derivative security at time zero (Eq. 1.12) does not depend upon the probability of up (p) and down factor (q) but it depends of the size of the two possible moves (u and d). The quantities V 1 /() is called the discounted derivative security at time t 1, and S 1 /() is called the discounted stock price at time t 1, where r is the interest rate of money market. 13

15 1.3 Multiperiod Binomial Model Consider the initial stock price S 0 > 0 and two-period (T = t 2 ) binomial model. At time t 1 (after the first toss): The stock price S 1 will be { S1 (H) = us 0, if there is a Head in the coin; S 1 = S 1 (T ) = ds 0, if there is a Tail in the coin. At time t 2 (after the second toss): The stock price S 2 will be S 2 (HH) = u 2 S 0, S 2 = S 2 (HT ) = S 2 (T H) = dus 0, S 2 (T T ) = d 2 S 0, if there are two Heads in the two coins; if there is one Head in the two coins. if there is no Head in the two coins. S 2 (HH) = u 2 S 0 S 1 (H) = us 0 S 0 S 2 (HT ) = uds 0 = S 2 (T H) S 1 (T ) = ds 0 S 2 (T T ) = d 2 S 0 Note that V 2, S 0, S 1, S 2, r are known and X 0, 0, V 0 are unknown The portfolio X 2 at time t 2 is X 2 = 1 S 2 + ()(X 1 1 S 1 ) From the equation V 2 = X 2 we have V 2 (HH) = 1 (H)S 2 (HH) + ()(X 1 (H) 1 (H)S 1 (H)), (1.13) V 2 (HT ) = 1 (H)S 2 (HT ) + ()(X 1 (H) 1 (H)S 1 (H)), (1.14) V 2 (T H) = 1 (T )S 2 (T H) + ()(X 1 (T ) 1 (T )S 1 (T )), (1.1) V 2 (T T ) = 1 (T )S 2 (T T ) + ()(X 1 (T ) 1 (T )S 1 (T )). (1.16) 14

16 Take S 1 (H) = ps 2(HH) + qs 1 (HT ), and S 1 (T ) = ps 2(T H) + qs 1 (T T ) (1.17) Now, multiplying (1.13) by p and (1.14) by q and adding them gives us pv 2 (HH) + qv 2 (HT ) = 1 (H)( ps 2 (HH) + qs 2 (HT )) + ()(X 1 (H) 1 (H)S 1 (H)) = 1 (H)()S 1 (H) + ()X 1 (H) 1 (H)()S 1 (H) =()X 1 (H) X 1 (H) = p V 2(HH) + q V 2(HT ) (1.18) where p = d u d and q = d 1 u u d. Similarly, by multiplying (1.1) by p and (1.16) by q and adding them gives us X 1 (T ) = p V 2(T H) + q V 2(T T ) (1.19) So be considering X 1 = V 1 we get V 1 = p V 2 + q V 2 (1.20) or V 1 (H) = p V 2(HH) V 1 (T ) = p V 2(T H) + q V 2(HT ) + q V 2(T T ) (1.21) (1.22) Equations (1.21) and (1.22) are called risk-neutral pricing formula. Subtracting (1.14) from (1.13) and (1.16) from (1.1), gives us 1 (H) = V 2(HH) V 2 (HT ) S 2 (HH) S 2 (HT ) and 1(T ) = V 2(T H) V 2 (T T ) S 2 (T H) S 2 (T T ) (1.23) The Equation (1.23) is called the delta-hedging formula. For one-period binomial model, we have V 0 = p V 1(H) + q V 1(T ) and 0 = V 1(H) V 1 (T ) S 1 (H) S 1 (T ) 1

17 Using Eq. (1.20) in the above equation for V 1, we obtain V 0 = p V 1(H) + q V 1(T ) = p [ p V 2(HH) + q V 2(HT ) ] + q [ p V 2(T H) + q ] = 1 () 2 [ p 2 V 2 (HH) + p qv 2 (HT ) + p qv 2 (T H) + q 2 V 2 (T T ) Remark 1.2 Note that we have three stochastic process { 0, 1 } share of stocks stochastic process {X 0, X 1, X 2 } portfolio stochastic process {V 0, V 1, V 2 } price of derivative security stochastic process ] V 2(T T ) (1.24) Notation: For simplicity, let w n = w 1 w 2 w n and w c n = w n+1 w n+2 w N where w i = H or w i = T. So w N = w 1 w 2 w N, w n H = w 1 w 2 w n H and w n T = w 1 w 2 w n T. Remark 1.3 Generally, for N-period binomial model, we have the following equations for n = 0, 1,, N 1 The delta-hedging formulas is given by V n (w n ) = 1 [ p Vn+1 (w n H) + q V n+1 (w n T ) ] (1.2) n (w n ) = V n+1(w n H) V n+1 (w n T ) S n+1 (w n H) S n+1 (w n T ) (1.26) Example 1. (2-Period Binomial Model) Suppose S 0 = 4, u = 2, d = 1 2, r = 1 4. Then p = d u d = = 1 2 and q = u 1 r u d = =

18 S 2 (HH) = 16 S 0 = 4 S 1 (H) = 8 S 1 (T ) = 2 S 2 (HT ) = 4 = S 2 (T H) S 2 (T T ) = 1 Consider the derivative security is a European call option call option with maturity at time t 2 and strike price 3 i.e. V 2 = [S 2 3] +. At time t 2 we have V 2 (HH) =[S 2 (HH) 3] + = [16 3] + = 13 V 2 (HT ) =[S 2 (HT ) 3] + = [4 3] + = 1 V 2 (T H) =[S 2 (T H) 3] + = [4 3] + = 1 V 2 (T T ) =[S 2 (T T ) 3] + = [1 3] + = 0. At time t 1 we have At time t 0 we have V 1 (H) = 1 ( pv 2(HH) + qv 2 (HT )) = 4 ( ) =.6 V 1 (T ) = 1 ( pv 2(T H) + qv 2 (T T )) = 4 ( ) = 0.4. V 0 = 1 [ pv1 (H) + qv 1 (T ) ] = 4 ( ) = 2.4 Thus the no-arbitrage price of the option at time t 0 is 2.4$ and using the delta-hedging formula we get 0 = V 1(H) V 1 (T ) S 1 (H) S 1 (T ) So that the replication process is as follows: At time t 0 = = shares of stock 17

19 - sell option by V 0 = X 0 = 2.4$ - buy 0 = shares of stock by 0 S 0 = = 3.467$ - borrow X 0 0 S 0 = = 1.067$ from the money market. At time t 1 - from money market we indept ()(X 0 0 S 0 ) = = 1.334$ - if there is Head in the coin, then from stock market we have 0 S 1 (H) = = 6.936$ so the portfolio is X 1 (H) = V 1 (H) = =.6$ - if there is Tail in the coin, then from stock market 0 S 1 (T ) = = 1.734$ so the portfolio is X 1 (T ) = V 1 (T ) = = 0.4$ Example 1.6 (Three-Period Binomial Model) Suppose S 0 = 4, u = 2, d = 1 2, r = 1 4. Then p = d u d = 1 2 and q = u 1 r u d = 1 2. Consider the derivative security is a lookback call option which entitled to a payment at time t 3 as V 3 = max 0 n 3 (S n) S 3 18

20 S 3 (HHH) = 32 S 0 S 1 (H) = 8 S 1 (T ) = 2 S 2 (HH) = 16 S 2 (HT ) = 4 = S 2 (T H) S 2 (T T ) = 1 S 3 (T HH) = 8 = S 3 (HT H) = S 3 (T HH) S 3 (T T H) = 2 = S 3 (T HT ) = S 3 (HT T ) S 3 (T T T ) = 0. Now, at time t 3 we have V 3 (HHH) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HH), S 3 (HHH)} S 3 (HHH) =S 3 (HHH) S 3 (HHH) = = 0 V 3 (HHT ) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HH), S 3 (HHT )} S 3 (HHT ) =S 2 (HH) S 3 (HHT ) = 16 8 = 8 V 3 (HT H) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HT ), S 3 (HT H)} S 3 (HT H) =S 1 (H) S 3 (HT H) = 8 8 = 0 V 3 (T HH) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T H), S 3 (T HH)} S 3 (T HH) =S 3 (T HH) S 3 (T HH) = 8 8 = 0 V 3 (HT T ) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HT ), S 3 (HT T )} S 3 (HT T ) =S 1 (H) S 3 (HT T ) = 8 2 = 6 V 3 (T HT ) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T H), S 3 (T HT )} S 3 (T HT ) =S 2 (T H) S 3 (T HT ) = 4 2 = 2 V 3 (T T H) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T T ), S 3 (T T H)} S 3 (T T H) =S 0 S 3 (T T H) = 4 2 = 2 V 3 (T T T ) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T T ), S 3 (T T T )} S 3 (T T T ) =S 0 S 3 (T T T ) = 4 0. =

21 At time t 2 we have V 2 (HH) = 1 ( pv 3(HHH) + qv 3 (HHT )) = 4 ( ) = 3.2 V 2 (HT ) = 1 ( pv 3(HT H) + qv 3 (HT T )) = 4 ( ) = 2.4 V 2 (T H) = 1 ( pv 3(T HH) + qv 3 (T HT )) = 4 ( ) = 0.8 V 2 (T T ) = 1 ( pv 3(T T H) + qv 3 (T T T )) = 4 ( ) = 2.2. At time t 1 we have At t 0 is given by V 1 (H) = 1 ( pv 2(HH) + qv 2 (HT )) = 4 ( ) = 2.24 V 1 (T ) = 1 ( pv 2(T H) + qv 2 (T T )) = 4 ( ) = 1.2. V 0 = 1 ( pv1 (H) + qv 1 (T ) ) = 4 ( ) = Now using the delta-hedging formula we get 0 = V 1(H) V 1 (T ) S 1 (H) S 1 (T ) = So that the replication process is as follows: At time t 0 = shares of stock. - sell option by V 0 = X 0 = 1.376$ - buy 0 = shares of stock by 0 S 0 = = $ - invest X 0 0 S 0 = = $ in the money market. At time t 1 20

22 - from money market we get ()(X 0 0 S 0 ) = = 0.833$ - if there is Head in the coin, then from stock market 0 S 1 (H) = = $ so the portfolio is X 1 (H) = V 1 (H) = = 2.24$ - if there is Tail in the coin, then from stock market 0 S 1 (T ) = = $ so the portfolio is X 1 (T ) = V 1 (T ) = = 1.2$ and so on. 21

23 2 Finite Probability Space Definition 2.1 (Finite Probability space) A finite probability space consists of a sample space Ω and a probability measure P. The sample space Ω is a non-empty finite set i.e. Ω = {w 1, w 2, w n } and the probability measure P is a function that assigns to each element w of Ω a number in [0, 1] so that P(w) = 1. An event is a subset of Ω, and we define the probability of an event A to be P(A) = P(w). w A w Ω Example 2.1 Suppose a coin is tossed three times. The sample space is Ω = {w : w = HHH, HHT, HT H, T HH, HT T, T HT, T T H, T T T }. Suppose that on each toss the probability of a head P(H) = p and the probability of tail P(T ) = q = 1 p. We assume the tosses are independent. Then the probability measure P is p 3, if w = HHH; p 2 q, if w = HHT, HT H, T HH; P(w) = pq 2, if w = HT T, T HT, T HH; q 3, if w = T T T. Then the space (Ω, P) is a finite probability space. Let A be an event for the first toss is a head, then P(A) =P{w : w = HHH, HT H, HHT, HT T } =p 3 + p 2 q + p 2 q + pq 2 =p 2 (p + q) + pq(p + q) =p 2 + pq =p(p + q) = p. 22

24 Definition 2.2 (Random Variable) Let (Ω, P) be a finite probability space. A random variable X is a real-valued function defined on Ω. The distribution of the r.v. X is the probability of the X at each value X = x. Remark 2.1 A random variable is not a distribution and a distribution is not a random variable. Example 2.2 Consider Example 2.1. Let p = q = 1. Define the random variables 2 X = Total number of heads and Y = Total number of tails. Note that X Y because Y = 2 X. The probability distribution of X is P X (X = 0) = P{w : w = T T T } = 1 8 P X (X = 1) = P{w : w = T T H, T HT, HT T } = 3 8 The probability distribution of Y is P X (X = 2) = P{w : w = T HH, HT H, HHT } = 3 8 P X (X = 3) = P{w : w = HHH} = 1 8. P Y (Y = 0) = P{w : w = HHH} = 1 8 P Y (Y = 1) = P{w : w = T HH, HT H, HHT } = 3 8 P Y (Y = 2) = P{w : w = T T H, T HT, T T H} = 3 8 P Y (Y = 3) = P{w : w = T T T } = 1 8. Then P X P Y. So that P X P Y X Y. Example 2.3 Consider Example 2.2. Let p = 2 and q = 1. Define the random variables 3 3 X = Total number of heads. 23

25 The probability distribution of X is P X (X = 0) = P{w : w = T T T } = 1 27 P X (X = 1) = P{w : w = T T H, T HT, HT T } = 6 27 P X (X = 2) = P{w : w = T HH, HT H, HHT } = P X (X = 3) = P{w : w = HHH} = Note that the distribution of X under the probability measure (p, q) = ( 1, 1 ) is different 2 2 from the probability distribution under the probability measure (p, q) = ( 2, 1 ). So that 3 3 Definition 2.3 (Expectation) X Y P X P Y. Let X be a random variable defined on a finite probability space (Ω, P). The expected value of X is given by The variance of X is E P (X) = w Ω X(w)P(w). V P (X) = E P (X E P (X)) 2 = E P (X 2 ) (E P (X)) 2. Remark 2.2 Suppose P be another probability measure defined on Ω. Then the expected value of X is E P(X) = w Ω X(w) P(w). Note that P X P X = E P(X) E P (X). Homework : Find the mean and variance of X of the examples 2.2 and 2.3. Definition 2.4 (Convex Function) 1. A function g(x) is said to be convex over an interval (a, b) if for every x 1 and x 2 we have g(λx 1 + (1 λ)x 2 ) λg(x 1 ) + (1 λ)g(x 2 ), where 0 λ 1. 24

26 2. A function is said to be strictly convex if g(λx 1 + (1 λ)x 2 ) < λg(x 1 ) + (1 λ)g(x 2 ), where 0 < λ < A function g(x) is concave if g(x) is convex. Remark 2.3 The following are graphes of some convex and concave functions. Example 2.4 Let g(x) = x. g(λx + (1 λ)y) = λx + (1 λ)y λ x + 1 λ y =λ x + (1 λ) y λg(x) + (1 λ)g(y). Then g(x) is a convex function. 2

27 Example Convex functions: x log x for x > 0, x 2, e x. 2. Concave functions: log x for x > 0, x for x > Both convex and concave: ax + b. Theorem 2.1 A function is convex (or strictly convex) if and only if its second derivative is non-negative (positive) everywhere. Example Let g(x) = x 2. Since d2 g dx 2 = 2 > 0 then g(x) is convex function. 2. Let g(x) = 1. Since d2 g = 2 < 0 for x > 0 and d2 g = 2 x dx 2 x 3 dx 2 x 3 concave for x > 0 and convex function for x < 0 function. > 0 for x < 0 then g(x) is 3. Let g(x) = x 3. Since d2 g = 6x > 0 for x > 0 and d2 g = 6x < 0 for x < 0 then g(x) is dx 2 dx 2 convex function for x > 0 and concave function x < 0. Theorem 2.2 (Jensen s Inequality) Let X be a random variable on a finite probability space (Ω, P). Let ϕ(x) be a convex function of x. Then E P (ϕ(x)) ϕ(e P (X)). Remark 2.4 Since g(x) = x 2 is convex function, then using Jensen s inequality, we get E P (X 2 ) (E P (X)) 2 = V P (X) = E P (X 2 ) (E P (X)) 2 0. Remark 2. If g(x) is a linear function then E P (g(x)) = g(e P (X)). For example, if g(x) = ax + b then Example 2.7 E P (g(x)) = E P (ax + b) = ae P (X) + b = g(e P (X)). 1. Since e x is convex then E P (e X ) e E P(X). 2. Since log(x) is concave then E P (log(x)) log(e P (X)). 26

28 3. Since x 3 is convex for x > 0 and concave for x < 0 then Notation: For simplicity, let E P (X 3 ) (E P (X)) 3 for x > 0 and E P (X 3 ) (E P (X)) 3 for x < 0. w n = w 1 w 2 w n, and w c n = w n+1 w n+2 w N where w i = H or w i = T. So w N = w 1 w 2 w N, w n H = w 1 w 2 w n H and w n T = w 1 w 2 w n T. 2.1 Conditional Expectation Definition 2. (Conditional Expectation) Define #H(w n ) = Number of heads in the sequance w n, and #T (w n ) = Number of tails in the sequance w n. Suppose probability distribution is P = (p, q) where p = P(H) and q = 1 p = P(T ). Let X(w N ) be a random variable. For 1 n N, and for a given w n the conditional expectation of X given w n is given by E P [X w n ] = w c n p # H(wc n) q # T (wc n) X(w N ), where =. w c n w N =H or T w n+2 =H or T w n+1 =H or T Special Cases: (i) The conditional expectation given no information is given by E P [X w 0 ] = wn p # H(w N ) q # T (w N ) X(w N ) = E P [X] 27

29 (ii) The conditional expectation given all information is given by E P [X w N ] = X. (iii) If X depends on the first w n+1 i.e. X(w n+1 ) we get the following special case E P [X w n ] = w n+1 =H or T =px(w n H) + qx(w n T ). p # H(w n+1) q # T (w n+1) X(w n+1 ) Remark 2.6 Note that the unconditional expectation E P [X] is a numeric quantity while the conditional expectation E P [X w n ] is a random variable. Remark 2.7 Note that w 1 p # H(w1) q # T (w1) = p + q = 1. w 1 w 2 p # H(w1w2) q # T (w1w2) = p 2 + 2pq + q 2 = (p + q) 2 = 1 for 1 n 1 n 2 N. w n1 w n2 p # H(wn1 wn2 ) q # T (wn1 wn2 ) = (p + q) n2 n1 = 1, Remark 2.8 If Z(w m ) for 0 n < m N then E P [Z(w m ) w n ] = w c n p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) Z(w m ) = { }}{ p # H(wn+1 wm) q # T (wn+1 wm) Z(w m ) p # H(wc m) q # T (wc m) w n+1 w m = E P [Z(w m ) w n ] = Example 2.8 Consider the following diagram w c m w n+1 w m p # H(wn+1 wm) q # T (wn+1 wm) Z(w m ). =1 28

30 S 3 (HHH) = 32 S 0 = 4 S 1 (H) = 8 S 1 (T ) = 2 S 2 (HH) = 16 S 2 (HT ) = 4 = S 2 (T H) S 2 (T T ) = 1 S 3 (T HH) = 8 = S 3 (HT H) = S 3 (T HH) S 3 (T T H) = 2 = S 3 (T HT ) = S 3 (HT T ) S 3 (T T T ) = 0. Suppose the probability distribution is given by P = (p, q) = (0., 0.). E P [S 2 H] =ps 2 (HH) + qs 2 (HT ) = = 10 E P [S 2 T ] =ps 2 (T H) + qs 2 (T T ) = = 2. E P [S 3 HH] =ps 3 (HHH) + qs 3 (HHT ) = = 20 E P [S 3 HT ] =ps 3 (HT H) + qs 3 (HT T ) = = E P [S 3 T H] =ps 3 (T HH) + qs 3 (T HT ) = = E P [S 3 T T ] =ps 3 (T T H) + qs 3 (T T T ) = = E P [S 3 H] =p 2 S 3 (HHH) + pqs 2 (HHT ) + pqs 3 (HT H) + q 2 S 3 (HT T ) = = E P [S 3 T ] =p 2 S 3 (T HH) + pqs 2 (T HT ) + pqs 3 (T T H) + q 2 S 3 (T T T ) = =

31 Note that the unconditional expectations are E P [S 1 ] =ps 1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) = =. E P [S 2 ] =p 2 S 2 (HH) + pqs 2 (HT ) + pqs 2 (T H) + q 2 S 3 (T T ) = = 6.2. E P [S 3 ] =p 3 S 3 (HHH) + p 2 qs 2 (HHT ) + p 2 qs 3 (HT H) + pq 2 S 3 (HT T ) + p 2 qs 3 (T HH) + pq 2 S 2 (T HT ) + pq 2 S 3 (T T H) + q 3 S 3 (T T T ) = = Properties of Conditional Expectation Let N be a given integer, and let X(w N ) and Y (w N ) be random variables. Let 0 n N be given. Property-1: Linearity where c 1 and c 2 are constants. Proof : E P [c 1 X + c 2 Y w n ] = c 1 E P [X w n ] + c 2 E P [Y w n ], Recall the definition of the conditional expectation as E P [X w n ] = w c n p # H(wc n) q # T (wc n) X(w N ) Now, since X and Y be random variables depending on the first N coin tosses then c 1 X+c 2 Y is also a random variable depending on the first N coin tosses. Hence E P [c 1 X + c 2 Y w n ] = E P [c 1 X + c 2 Y w n ] = p # H(wc n) q # T (wc n) [c 1 X(w N ) + c 2 Y (w N )] wn c =c 1 p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) X(w N ) + c 2 p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) Y (w N ) w c n w c n =c 1 E P [X w n ] + c 2 E P [Y w n ]. 30

32 Property-2: Taking out what is known If X depends only on the first n coin tosses, then Proof : Homework E P [XY w n ] = XE P [Y w n ]. Property-3: Iterated Conditioning If 0 n < m N, then In particular E P [E P [X w n ]] = E P [X]. Proof : E P [E P [X w m ] w n ] = E P [X w n ] = E P [E P [X w n ] w m ] Denote Z = E P [X w m ]. Then Z actually depends on w m only and E P [E P [X w m ] w n ] =E P [Z w n ] = = w n+1 w N p # H(wc = n ) q # T (wc n ) Z(w m ) w n+1 w m p # H(wn+1 wm) q # T (wn+1 wm) Z(w m ) =1 {}}{ w m+1 w N p # H(wm+1 wn ) q # T (wm+1 wn ) p # H(wn+1 wm) q # T (wn+1 wm) Z(w m ) w n+1 w m = p # H(wn+1 wm) q # T (wn+1 wm) E P [X w m ] w n+1 w m = p # H(wn+1 wm) q # T (wn+1 wm) w n+1 w m m) q # T (wc m) X(w N ) = w m+1 w N p # H(wc w n+1 w N p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) X(w N ) = E P [X w n ]. Property-4: Independence If X depends only on tosses n + 1, n + 2,, N, then E P [X w n ] = E P [X]. 31

33 Proof : Since X does not depend on the first n coin tosses then E P [X w n ] = w c n = w c n p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) X(w N ) p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) X(w c n) =1 { }}{ = p # H(wn) q # T (wn) p p # H(wc n ) q # T (wc n ) X(wn) c w n = wn w c n p # H(w N ) q # T (w N ) X(w c n) =E P [X]. Property-: Conditional Jensen s Inequality If g(x) is a convex function of x, then E P [g(x) w n ] g (E P [X w n ]). Example 2.9 Consider Example 2.8 with p = 2 and q = Linearity. Since E P [S 2 H] = = 12, E P [S 3 H] = = 18, then E P [S 2 H] + E P [S 3 H] = = 30. But also E P [S 2 + S 3 H] = 4 9 ( ) + 2 (16 + 8) (4 + 8) + 1 (4 + 2) 9 =30. Then E P [S 2 + S 3 H] = E P [S 2 H] + E P [S 3 H]. 32

34 Similarly, we can prove (Homework!!!) E P [S 2 + S 3 T ] = E P [S 2 T ] + E P [S 3 T ]. Hence E P [S 2 + S 3 w 1 ] = E P [S 2 w 1 ] + E P [S 3 w 1 ]. 2. Taking out what is known. Note that S 1 depends only on the first coin toss w 1. Since E P [S 2 H] = 12 then Also Then S 1 (H)E P [S 2 H] = 8 12 = 96. E P [S 1 S 2 H] = = E P [S 1 S 2 H] = S 1 (H)E P [S 2 H]. Similarly, we can prove (Homework!!!) E P [S 1 S 2 T ] = 6 = S 1 (T )E P [S 2 T ]. Hence E P [S 1 S 2 w 1 ] = S 1 E P [S 2 w 1 ]. 3. Iterated Conditioning. E P [S 3 HH] = = 24, E P [S 3 HT ] = = 6, E P [S 3 T H] = = 6, E P [S 3 T T ] = =

35 Now E P [E 2 [S 3 w 1 w 2 ] H] = 2 3 E P[S 3 HH] E P[S 3 HT ] = = 18, E P [E P [S 3 w 1 w 2 ] T ] = 2 3 E P[S 3 T H] E P[S 3 T T ] = = 4.. Also E P [S 3 H] = = 18, E P [S 3 T ] = = 4.. Hence E P [E P [S 3 w 1 w 2 ] w 1 ] = E P [S 3 w 1 ]. 4. Independence. Note that and S 2 (HH) S 1 (H) = 16 8 = 2 = S 2(T H) S 1 (T ) S 2 (HT ) S 1 (H) = 4 8 = 1 2 = S 2(T T ) S 1 (T ) that means S 2 S 1 depends only on the result of the second toss, w 2. [ ] S2 E P S 1 H = 2 S 2 (HH) + 1 S 2 (HT ) 3 S 1 (H) 3 S 1 (H) = = 3 [ ] 2 S2 E P T = 2 S 2 (T H) + 1 S 2 (T T ) 3 S 1 (T ) 3 S 1 (T ) S 1 = = 3 2. So that [ ] [ ] S2 E P H S2 = E P T = 3 2. S 1 S 1 34

36 Now Hence [ ] S2 E P =p 2 S 2(HH) + pq S 2(HT ) S 1 S 1 (H) S 1 (H) + pq S 2(T H) + q 2 S 2(T T ) S 1 (T ) S 1 (T ) = = 3 2. [ S2 ] [ ] w1 S2 E P = E P = 3 S 1 S Jensen s Inequality. Let g(x) = x 2 which is convex. E P (S 2 2 H) =ps 2 2(HH) + qs 2 2(HT ) = 2 3 (16) (4)2 = 176 E P (S 2 2 T ) =ps 2 2(T H) + qs 2 2(T T ) = 2 3 (4) (1)2 = 11 (E P (S 2 H)) 2 =(ps 2 (HH) + qs 2 (HT )) 2 = (E P (S 2 T )) 2 =(ps 2 (T H) + qs 2 (T T )) 2 = ( 2 ) 2 (16) + 1(4) 3 3 = 144 ( ) 2 2 (4) + 1(1) 3 3 = 9. Hence E P (S 2 2 H) > (E P (S 2 H)) 2 and E P (S 2 2 T ) > (E P (S 2 T )) 2 = E P (S 2 2 w 1 ) > (E P (S 2 w 1 )) 2. 3

37 3 Martingales Definition 3.1 (Adapted Stochastic Process) A stochastic process {M n } N n=1 is called an adapted stochastic process if M n depends only the first n coin tosses w n i.e is independent of n + 1, n + 2, N coin tosses w c n. Hence {M n } N n=1 is adapted iff = M 1 depends only on w 1 M 2 depends only on w 1, w 2. M n depends only on w 1, w 2,..., w n. Remark 3.1 If {M n } N n=1 is an adapted stochastic process then E[M n w n ] = M n. Definition 3.2 (Martingale) Let {M n } N n=0 be an adapted stochastic process and M 0 is constant. 1. If M n =E P [M n+1 w n ], n = 0, 1,, N 1 (3.1) we say this process is martingale (no tendency to rise or fall). 2. If M n E P [M n+1 w n ], n = 0, 1,, N 1 we say this process is submartingale (tendency to rise). 3. If M n E P [M n+1 w n ], n = 0, 1,, N 1 we say this process is supermartingale (tendency to fall). 36

38 Remark 3.2 Note that if {M n } is a martingale process then M n+1 = E P [M n+2 w n+1 ] = E P [M n+1 w n ] = E P [E P [M n+2 w n+1 ] w n ] = E P [M n+1 w n ] = E P [M n+2 w n ] = M n = E P [M n+2 w n ]. Then, the stochastic process {M n } is martingale if and only if M n = E P [M m w n ], 0 n < m N. Remark 3.3 The expectation of a martingale is constant over time i.e. if {M n } is martingale, then M 0 =E P (M n ), n = 0, 1,, N. (3.2) Observe that M 0 =E P (M 1 w 0 ) = E P (M 1 ) M 1 =E P (M 2 w 1 ) = E P (M 1 ) = E P (E P (M 2 w 1 )) = E P (M 2 ). M n =E P (M n+1 w n ) = E P (M n ) = E P (E P (M n+1 w n )) = E P (M n+1 ). Since M 0 is constant then M 0 = E P M 0 = E P M 1 = = E P M N. Theorem 3.1 Let Z be a random variable. Define Z n = E P (Z w n ), n = 0, 1,, N. Then {Z n } N n=0 is a martingale under P. Proof : For n = 0, 1,, N 1, we have E P [Z n+1 w n ] = E P [E P [Z w n+1 ] w n ] = E P [Z w n ] = Z n. This shows that {Z n } N n=0 is a martingale. 37

39 Remark 3.4 It is shown that S n (w n ) = 1 ( ps n+1(w n H) + qs n+1 (w n T )) = 1 E P[S n+1 (w n+1 ) w n ] Divide both sides of the above equation by () n, we get [ S n (w n ) () = Sn+1 (w n+1 ) ] wn n E P. (3.3) () n+1 We call S n the stock price at time n and S n we call the discounted stock price at time n, where r is the interest rate of () n money market. Theorem 3.2 Consider the general binomial model with 0 < d < < u. Let the risk neutral probabilities P = ( p, q), where p = d u d, q = u 1 r u d. Then, under the risk-neutral probabilities, the discounted stock price is a martingale i.e. [ S ] [ n+1 wn S ] n+1 Sn S n E P = () n+1 E P = () n+1 (). n Proof : Let n and w n be given. Then [ S ] n+1 wn 1 = () n+1 () 1 n [ ps n+1(w n H) + qs n+1 (w n T )] E P = = 1 () 1 n [ pus n(w n ) + qds n (w n )] S n pu + qd () n = S n pu + qd, since () n = 1. Example 3.1 Consider the following three period binomial model 38

40 S 3 (HHH) = 32 S 0 = 4 S 1 (H) = 8 S 1 (T ) = 2 S 2 (HH) = 16 S 2 (HT ) = 4 = S 2 (T H) S 2 (T T ) = 1 S 3 (T HH) = 8 = S 3 (HT H) = S 3 (T HH) S 3 (T T H) = 2 = S 3 (T HT ) = S 3 (HT T ) S 3 (T T T ) = 0. Suppose up and down probabilities are P 1 = (1/3, 2/3), P 2 = (2/3, 1/3) and P = (1/2, 1/2). For the probability distribution P 1 E P1 [S 1 S 0 ] = ps 1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) = = 4 = S 0 E P1 [S 2 H] = ps 2 (HH) + qs 2 (HT ) = = 8 = S 1(H) E P1 [S 2 T ] = ps 2 (T H) + qs 2 (T T ) = = 2 = S 1(T ) = E P1 [S 2 w 1 ] = S 1 E P1 [S 3 HH] = ps 3 (HHH) + qs 3 (HHT ) = = 16 = S 2(HH) E P1 [S 3 HT ] = ps 3 (HT H) + qs 3 (HT T ) = = 4 = S 2(HT ) E P1 [S 3 T H] = ps 3 (T HH) + qs 3 (T HT ) = = 4 = S 2(T H) E P1 [S 3 T T ] = ps 3 (T T H) + qs 3 (T T T ) = = 1 = S 2(T T ) 39

41 = E P1 [S 3 w 1 w 2 ] = S 2 E P1 [S 3 H] = p 2 S 3 (HHH) + pqs 2 (HHT ) + pqs 3 (HT H) + q 2 S 3 (HT T ) = = 8 = S 1(H) E P1 [S 3 T ] = p 2 S 3 (T HH) + pqs 2 (T HT ) + pqs 3 (T T H) + q 2 S 3 (T T T ) = = 2 = S 1(T ) = E P1 [S 3 w 1 ] = S 1. Thus E P1 [S m w n ] = S n, 0 n < m 3, and hence the process {S 0, S 1, S 2, S 3 } is martingale under the probability measure P 1. For the probability distribution P 2 E P2 [S 1 S 0 ] = ps 1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) = = 6 = 3 2 S 0 E P2 [S 2 H] = ps 2 (HH) + qs 2 (HT ) = = 12 = 3 2 S 1(H) E P2 [S 2 T ] = ps 2 (T H) + qs 2 (T T ) = = 3 = 3 2 S 1(T ) = E P2 [S 2 w 1 ] = 3 2 S 1 E P2 [S 3 HH] = ps 3 (HHH) + qs 3 (HHT ) = = 24 = 3 2 S 2(HH) E P2 [S 3 HT ] = ps 3 (HT H) + qs 3 (HT T ) = = 6 = 3 2 S 2(HT ) E P2 [S 3 T H] = ps 3 (T HH) + qs 3 (T HT ) = = 6 = 3 2 S 2(T H) E P2 [S 3 T T ] = ps 3 (T T H) + qs 3 (T T T ) = = 3 2 = 3 2 S 2(T T ) 40

42 Thus = E P2 [S 3 w 1 w 2 ] = 3 2 S 2 E P2 [S 3 H] = p 2 S 3 (HHH) + pqs 2 (HHT ) + pqs 3 (HT H) + q 2 S 3 (HT T ) = = 18 = [ 3 2] 2 S 1 (H) E P2 [S 3 T ] = p 2 S 3 (T HH) + pqs 2 (T HT ) + pqs 3 (T T H) + q 2 S 3 (T T T ) = = 9 2 = [ 3 2] 2 S 1 (T ) = E P2 [S 3 w 1 ] = S 1. E P2 [S m w n ] = ( ) m n 3 S n S n, 0 n < m 3, 2 and hence the process {S 0, S 1, S 2, S 3 } is submartingale under the probability measure P 2. Assume the interest rate r = 1/4. The discounted stock price at time n is ( ) n S n 4 () = S n n. Then [ (4 ] n+1 ( ) n+1 4 E P2 S n+1 w ) n = E P2 [S n+1 w n ] ( ) n = 2 S n ( ) n 4 = S n ( ) n 4 S n. Thus the discounted stock price is submartingale under the probability measure P 2. This is typically the case in the real markets. 41

43 For the risk neutral probability distribution P E P[S 1 S 0 ] = ps 1 (H) + qs 1 (T ) = = = 4 S 0 E P[S 2 H] = ps 2 (HH) + qs 2 (HT ) = = 10 = 4 S 1(H) E P[S 2 T ] = ps 2 (T H) + qs 2 (T T ) = = 2 = 4 S 1(T ) = E P[S 2 w 1 ] = 4 S 1 E P[S 3 HH] = ps 3 (HHH) + qs 3 (HHT ) = = 20 = 4 S 2(HH) E P[S 3 HT ] = ps 3 (HT H) + qs 3 (HT T ) = = = 4 S 2(HT ) E P[S 3 T H] = ps 3 (T HH) + qs 3 (T HT ) = = = 4 S 2(T H) E P[S 3 T T ] = ps 3 (T T H) + qs 3 (T T T ) = = 3 4 = 4 S 2(T T ) = E P[S 3 w 1 w 2 ] = 4 S 2 E P[S 3 H] = p 2 S 3 (HHH) + p qs 2 (HHT ) + p qs 3 (HT H) + q 2 S 3 (HT T ) = = 2 [ ] 2 2 = S 1 (H) 4 Thus E P[S 3 T ] = p 2 S 3 (T HH) + p qs 2 (T HT ) + p qs 3 (T T H) + q 2 S 3 (T T T ) = = 2 [ ] 2 8 = S 1 (T ) 4 = E P[S 3 w 1 ] = S 1. E P[S m w n ] = ( ) m n S n S n, 0 n < m 3, 4 and hence the process {S 0, S 1, S 2, S 3 } is submartingale under the risk neutral probabilities P = { p = 1/2, q = 1/2}. Assume the interest rate r = 1/4. The discounted stock price at time n is Now since S n () n = ( ) n 4 S n. E P[S n+1 w n ] = 4 S n, 42

44 then ( ) n+1 ( ) n Ẽn [S n+1] = = Ẽn [ (4 ) n+1 S n+1] = ) n S n. ( 4 4 S n Thus the discounted stock price is a martingale under the risk neutral probabilities P. Remark 3. The portfolio equation of N-period binomial model is X n+1 = n S n+1 + ()(X n n S n ), n = 0, 1, 2,, N 1. (3.4) Since n, the share of stock at time n, depends only on first n coin tosses and also S n, the stock price at time n, depends only on first n coin tosses then, the stochastic processes { n } and {S n } are adapted stochastic processes. Thus the portfolio process {X n } is also adapted stochastic process. Theorem 3.3 Consider N-binomial period model. Let the share of stocks { n } N 1 n=0 be an adapted stochastic process. Let the portfolio process {X n } N n=1 where X n+1 = n S n+1 + ()(X n n S n ), n = 0, 1, 2,, N 1 { Xn and X 0 be a constant. The discounted portfolio stochastic process is a () n n=0 martingale under the risk-neutral probabilities P i.e. [ X n () = X ] n+1 wn n E P, n = 0, 1, 2,, N 1. (3.) () n+1 } N 43

45 Proof : E P We compute [ X ] n+1 wn () n+1 =E P =E P = n E P [ n S n+1 () + X n n S ] n wn n+1 () [ n n S ] [ n+1 wn Xn n S ] n wn + () n+1 E P () [ n S ] n+1 wn + X n n S n () n+1 () n (Taking out what is known) (linearity) = ns n () n + X n n S n () n (Theorem 3.2) = X n () n. Corollary 3.1 Under the conditions of Theorem 3.3, we have [ X ] n wn E P = X () n 0, n = 0, 1, 2,, N. (3.6) Theorem 3.4 (First Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing) If we can find a risk-neutral probabilities P in a model then there is no arbitrage in the model. 44

46 3.1 Random Walk Process Definition 3.3 (Random Walk) Toss a coin repeatedly. Assume P(H) = p and P(T ) = q = 1 p. Let { 1, if the j-th toss is H; X j = 1, if the j-th toss is T. Consider the stochastic process M n, n = 0, 1, defined by M 0 = 0 and n M n = X j, n 1. This stochastic process is called a Random Walk Process. Example 3.2 Suppose we have w 1 = H, w 2 = T, w 3 = T, w 4 = T, w = H. j=1 Then X 1 = 1, X 2 = 1, X 3 = 1, X 4 = 1, X = 1 which implies that M 0 =0 M 1 =X 1 = 1 M 2 =X 1 + X 2 = 1 1 = 0 M 3 =X 1 + X 2 + X 3 = = 1 M 4 =X 1 + X 2 + X 3 + X 4 = = 2 M =X 1 + X 2 + X 3 + X 4 + X = = 1 4

47 1 M 1 M 0 1 M M 1 3 1M 1 M 4 46

48 Remark With each toss, the process either steps up one unite with probability p or steps down one unite with probability q. 2. If p = 1, the process M 2 n is called a symmetric random walk. 3. If p 1 the process M 2 n is called asymmetric random walk. 4. The symmetric random walk is a martingale process. Proof : Now Note that n+1 M n+1 = X i = i=1 n X i + X n+1 = M n + X n+1. i=1 E(M n+1 w n ) =E(M n + X n+1 w n ) =E(M n w n ) + E(X n+1 w n ) (linearity) =M n + E(X n+1 ) (adaptivity and independence) =M n (1) ( 1) =M n. Remark 3.7 For a symmetric random walk {M n }, the mean is E(M n ) = 0 and the variance is V(M n ) = n. (Prove.) 4 Markov Process Definition 4.1 (Markov Process) Let X 0, X 1,, X N, be an adapted process. If for every n between 0 and N 1 and for every function f(x), there is another function g(x) (depending on n and f) such that E P [f(x n+1 ) w n )] = g(x n ) (4.1) we say that X 0, X 1,, X N, is a Markov Process. 47

49 Example 4.1 Random walk process {M n } N n=0 is an example of Markov process. Note that M n+1 = X n+1 + M n. E P [f(m n+1 (w n+1 )) w n )] = E P [f(x n+1 (w n+1 ) + M n (w n )) w n ] [due to independent of X 1,, X n+1 ] = p #H(wn+1) q #T (wn+1) f(x n+1 (w n+1 ) + M n (w n )) w n+1 = pf(x n+1 (H) + M n (w n )) + qf(x n+1 (T ) + M n (w n )) = pf(m n + 1) + qf(m n 1) = g(m n ), where g(y) = pf(y + 1) + qf(y 1). Remark 4.1 (i) By definition, E P [f(x n+1 ) w n )] is random; it depends on the first n coin tosses. The Markov property says that this dependence on the coin tosses occurs through X n and does not depend on X 0, X 1,..., X n 1 i.e., the information about X n is sufficient to evaluate E P [f(x n+1 ) w n ]. (ii) The Markov process reduces to a martingale process when f(x) = g(x) = x. (iii) Not every martingale is Markov. For example, E(X n+1 w n ) = X n is martingale does not imply that we can find a function g such that E(Xn+1 w 2 n ) = g(x n ). (iv) Not every Markov process is a martingale. When considering the function f(x) = x, the Markov property requires finding a function g such that E[X n+1 w n ] = g(x n ) it does not require that the function g be given by g(x) = x. Lemma 4.1 (Independence) Suppose the random variables X 1...,, X K depend only on coin tosses w 1,..., w n and the random variables Y 1,..., Y L depend only on coin tosses w n+1,..., w N. Let f(x 1,, x K, y 1,, y L ) be a function of variables x l,, x K and y l,, y L. Then E P f(x 1,, X K, Y 1, Y L w n ) = E P f(x 1,, x K, Y 1, Y L ). Example 4.2 Consider a random walk process M n. Let X = M n which depends on w n and 48

50 let Y = M n+1 M n which depends on w n+1. Then E P [f(m n+1 ) w n ] =E P [f ( ) M wn ] n+1 M n M n =E P [f(xy ) w n ] =E P [f(xy )] =pf(x) + qf( x) =pf(m n ) + qf( M n ) =g(m n ). Definition 4.2 (2 dimensional Markov process) Let {(X n, Y n ); n = 0, 1,, N} be a 2 dimensional adapted process; i.e., X n and Y n are adapted processes. If, for every n between 0 and N 1 and for every function f(x, y), there is another function g(x, y) (depending on n and f) such that E P [f(x n+1, Y n+1 ) w n ] = g(x n, Y n ) (4.2) we say that {(X n, Y n ); n = 0, 1,, N} is a 2 dimensional Markov process. Remark 4.2 In the binomial model, the stock price at time n + 1 given the stock price at time n by { usn (w S n+1 (w n+1 ) = n ), if w n+1 = H; ds n (w n ), if w n+1 = T. Therefore, E P [f(s n+1 ) w n ] = pf(us n (w n )) + qf(ds n (w n )), and we can rewrite the above equation as E P [f(s n+1 ) w n ] = g(s n ), where the function g is defined by g(x) = pf(ux) + qf(dx). This shows that the stock price process is Markov. Remark 4.3 The stock price process is Markov under either the actual or the risk-neutral probability measure. To determine the price V n at time n of a derivative security whose 49

51 payoff at time N is a function v N of the stock price S N i.e., V N = v N (S N ), we use the risk-neutral pricing formula V n = 1 E P[V n+1 w n ], n = 0, 1,..., N 1. But V N = v N (S N ) and the stock price process is Markov, so for some function v N 1. Similarly, V N 1 = 1 E P[V N w N 1 ] = 1 E P[v N (S N ) w N 1 ] = p v N(uS N 1 ) =v N 1 (S N 1 ) + q v N(dS N 1 ) V N 2 = 1 E P[v N 1 (S N 1 )] = p v N 1(uS N 2 ) + q v N 1(dS N 2 ) for some function v N 2. = v N 2 (S N 2 ) In general, V n = v n (S n ) for some function v n. Moreover, we can compute the functions v N, v N 1,..., v 0 by v n (s) = 1 [ pv n+1(us) + qv n+1 (ds)], n = N 1, N 2,, 0 (4.3) Example 4.3 Consider the three-period model Suppose S 0 = 4, u = 2, d = 1 2, r = 1 4. Assume a European put option with strike price K = and maturity time T = t 3 V 3 = ( S 3 ) +. It can be seen that the price of option depends on the current stock prince so it is a function of the current stock price i.e. V n = v n (S n ). Then Note that p = d u d = 1 2 and q = u 1 r u d V 3 (HHH) =( S 3 (HHH)) + = ( 32) + = 0 = 1 2. V 3 (HHT ) =( S 3 (HHT )) + = ( 8) + = 0 = V 3 (HT H) = V 3 (T HH) V 3 (HT T ) =( S 3 (HT T )) + = ( 2) + = 3 = V 3 (T HT ) = V 3 (T T H) V 3 (T T T ) =( S 3 (T T T )) + = ( 0.) + = 4.. i.e 0

52 Let v 3 (S) be the value of the option at time t 3 when the stock price at time t 3 is S. Then 0, if S = 32, 8; V 3 =v 3 (S) = 3, if S = 2; 4., if S = 0.. So at time t 2 we have v 2 (S) = 1 ( p v 3(uS) + q v 3 (ds)) = 4 (0. v 3(2S) + 0. v 3 (0.S)) = 2 (v 3(2S) + v 3 (0.S)) Hence Similarly, at time t 1 we have Finally, at time t 0 we have v 2 (16) = 2 (v 3(32) + v 3 (8)) = 0 v 2 (4) = 2 (v 3(8) + v 3 (2)) = 2 (0 + 3) = 1.2 v 2 (1) = 2 (v 3(2) + v 3 (0.)) = 2 (3 + 4.) = 3. v 1 (S) = 2 (v 2(2S) + v 2 (0.S)) = v 1 (8) = 2 (v 2(16) + v 2 (4)) = 2 ( ) = 0.48 = v 1 (2) = 2 (v 2(4) + v 2 (1)) = 2 ( ) = v 0 (S) = 2 (v 1(2S) + v 1 (0.S)) = v 0 (4) = 2 (v 1(8) + v 1 (2)) = 2 ( ) = Therefor, the no-arbitrage price of the option at time t 0 is The delta-hedging formula for this method is n (S) = v n+1(us) v n+1 (ds) us ds = v n+1(2s) v n+1 (0.S). 1.S 1

53 Remark 4.4 To calculate V 0 of Example 4.3 using the alternative procedure, we can use the formula v 0 (s) = 1 () N N i=0 [ ( ) N ] p N i q i v N (u N i d i s) i For N = 3, u = 2, d = 1, s = S 2 0 = 4, r = 1, we get 4 [ [ v 0 (s) = ] ( ) 3 (1 3 i ( 1 ) i ( v3 2 i 2) 3 i 1 ] 2 2 s) i i=0 [ 2 3 [ ] = v 3 (8s) + 3v 3 (2s) + 3v 3 (s/2) + +v 3 (s/8) ] [ 2 3 [ ] v 0 (4) = v 3 (32) + 3v 3 (8) + 3v 3 (2) + v 3 (1/2) ] [ 2 3 [ ] = ] =0.864 Example 4.4 (Non-Markov process) Case I: Consider three binomial model with the random process M n = max 0 k n S k, n = 0, 1, 2, 3. S 3 (HHH) = 32 (4.4) S 0 = 4 S 1 (H) = 8 S 1 (T ) = 2 S 2 (HH) = 16 S 2 (HT ) = 4 = S 2 (T H) S 2 (T T ) = 1 S 3 (T HH) = 8 = S 3 (HT H) = S 3 (T HH) S 3 (T T H) = 2 = S 3 (T HT ) = S 3 (HT T ) S 3 (T T T ) = 0. 2

54 Note that M 0 = S 0 = 4 M 1 (H) = max{s 0, S 1 (H)} = {4, 8} = 8 M 1 (T ) = max{s 0, S 1 (T )} = {4, 2} = 4 M 2 (HH) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HH)} = {4, 8, 16} = 16 M 2 (HT ) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HT )} = {4, 8, 4} = 8 M 2 (T H) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T H)} = {4, 2, 4} = 4 M 2 (T T ) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T T )} = {4, 2, 1} = 4 M 3 (HHH) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HH), S 3 (HHH)} = {4, 8, 16, 32} = 32 M 3 (HHT ) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HH), S 3 (HHT )} = {4, 8, 16, 8} = 16 M 3 (HT H) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HT ), S 3 (HT H)} = {4, 8, 4, 8} = 8 M 3 (T HH) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T H), S 3 (T HH)} = {4, 2, 4, 8} = 8 M 3 (HT T ) = max{s 0, S 1 (H), S 2 (HT ), S 3 (HT T )} = {4, 8, 4, 2} = 8 M 3 (T HT ) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T H), S 3 (T HT )} = {4, 2, 4, 2} = 4 M 3 (T T H) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T T ), S 3 (T T H)} = {4, 2, 1, 2} = 4 M 3 (T T T ) = max{s 0, S 1 (T ), S 2 (T T ), S 3 (T T T )} = {4, 2, 1, 0.} = 4 3

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure

3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Stock under the risk-neutral measure 3 Adapted processes We have seen that the sampling space Ω = {H, T } N underlies the N-period binomial model for the stock-price process Elementary event ω = ω ω

More information

2 The binomial pricing model

2 The binomial pricing model 2 The binomial pricing model 2. Options and other derivatives A derivative security is a financial contract whose value depends on some underlying asset like stock, commodity (gold, oil) or currency. The

More information

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut

Financial Mathematics. Spring Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut Financial Mathematics Spring 22 Richard F. Bass Department of Mathematics University of Connecticut These notes are c 22 by Richard Bass. They may be used for personal use or class use, but not for commercial

More information

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting. Binomial Models Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October 14, 2016 Christopher Ting QF 101 Week 9 October

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Stochastic Calculus for Finance

Stochastic Calculus for Finance Stochastic Calculus for Finance Albert Cohen Actuarial Sciences Program Department of Mathematics Department of Statistics and Probability A336 Wells Hall Michigan State University East Lansing MI 48823

More information

MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I

MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I MATH 361: Financial Mathematics for Actuaries I Albert Cohen Actuarial Sciences Program Department of Mathematics Department of Statistics and Probability C336 Wells Hall Michigan State University East

More information

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time 4 Martingales in Discrete-Time Suppose that (Ω, F, P is a probability space. Definition 4.1. A sequence F = {F n, n = 0, 1,...} is called a filtration if each F n is a sub-σ-algebra of F, and F n F n+1

More information

Finance 651: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 2012

Finance 651: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 2012 Finance 65: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 0 Instructor: Bjørn Kjos-anssen Student name Disclaimer: It is essential to write legibly and show your work. If your work is absent

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

MORE REALISTIC FOR STOCKS, FOR EXAMPLE

MORE REALISTIC FOR STOCKS, FOR EXAMPLE MARTINGALES BASED ON IID: ADDITIVE MG Y 1,..., Y t,... : IID EY = 0 X t = Y 1 +... + Y t is MG MULTIPLICATIVE MG Y 1,..., Y t,... : IID EY = 1 X t = Y 1... Y t : X t+1 = X t Y t+1 E(X t+1 F t ) = E(X t

More information

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19 To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should 1. know how to do the homework problems. 2. be able to provide (correct and complete!) definitions

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Finance 651: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 2012

Finance 651: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 2012 Finance 651: PDEs and Stochastic Calculus Midterm Examination November 9, 2012 Instructor: Bjørn Kjos-anssen Student name Disclaimer: It is essential to write legibly and show your work. If your work is

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/27 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/27 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser Part 1: Introduction Chapter 1: Review of discrete time finance Part 2: Stochastic analysis Chapter 2: Stochastic processes

More information

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model International Journal of Basic & Applied Sciences IJBAS-IJNS Vol:3 No:05 47 Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model Sheik Ahmed Ullah

More information

Lecture 23: April 10

Lecture 23: April 10 CS271 Randomness & Computation Spring 2018 Instructor: Alistair Sinclair Lecture 23: April 10 Disclaimer: These notes have not been subjected to the usual scrutiny accorded to formal publications. They

More information

Keeping Your Options Open: An Introduction to Pricing Options

Keeping Your Options Open: An Introduction to Pricing Options The College of Wooster Libraries Open Works Senior Independent Study Theses 2014 Keeping Your Options Open: An Introduction to Pricing Options Ryan F. Snyder The College of Wooster, rsnyder14@wooster.edu

More information

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES THE SOURCE OF A PRICE IS ALWAYS A TRADING STRATEGY SPECIAL CASES WHERE TRADING STRATEGY IS INDEPENDENT OF PROBABILITY MEASURE COMPLETENESS,

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims Beatrice Acciaio Gregor Svindland December 2011 Abstract We prove that in a discrete-time market model the lower arbitrage bound of an American

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58-6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15-19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9-31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36-37)

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation. Stochastic Differential Equation Consider. Moreover partition the interval into and define, where. Now by Rieman Integral we know that, where. Moreover. Using the fundamentals mentioned above we can easily

More information

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing 1/33 The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing Professor Karl Sigman Columbia University Dept. IEOR New York City USA 2/33 Outline The Binomial Lattice Model (BLM) as a Model

More information

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus

Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Derivatives Pricing and Stochastic Calculus Romuald Elie LAMA, CNRS UMR 85 Université Paris-Est Marne-La-Vallée elie @ ensae.fr Idris Kharroubi CEREMADE, CNRS UMR 7534, Université Paris Dauphine kharroubi

More information

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing presented by Yue Kuen KWOK Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology 1 Parable of the bookmaker Taking

More information

How Much Should You Pay For a Financial Derivative?

How Much Should You Pay For a Financial Derivative? City University of New York (CUNY) CUNY Academic Works Publications and Research New York City College of Technology Winter 2-26-2016 How Much Should You Pay For a Financial Derivative? Boyan Kostadinov

More information

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models Eni Musta Università degli studi di Pisa San Miniato - 16 September 2016 Overview 1 Self-financing portfolio 2 Complete

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Kyle Hambrook

Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Kyle Hambrook Introduction to Financial Mathematics Kyle Hambrook August 7, 2017 Contents 1 Probability Theory: Basics 3 1.1 Sample Space, Events, Random Variables.................. 3 1.2 Probability Measure..............................

More information

Optimizing Portfolios

Optimizing Portfolios Optimizing Portfolios An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2010 Introduction Investors may wish to adjust the allocation of financial resources including a mixture

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 14 Lecture 14 November 15, 2017 Derivation of the

More information

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Binomial model: numerical algorithm Binomial model: numerical algorithm S / 0 C \ 0 S0 u / C \ 1,1 S0 d / S u 0 /, S u 3 0 / 3,3 C \ S0 u d /,1 S u 5 0 4 0 / C 5 5,5 max X S0 u,0 S u C \ 4 4,4 C \ 3 S u d / 0 3, C \ S u d 0 S u d 0 / C 4

More information

FE 5204 Stochastic Differential Equations

FE 5204 Stochastic Differential Equations Instructor: Jim Zhu e-mail:zhu@wmich.edu http://homepages.wmich.edu/ zhu/ January 13, 2009 Stochastic differential equations deal with continuous random processes. They are idealization of discrete stochastic

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar BROWNIAN MOTION II D.Majumdar DEFINITION Let (Ω, F, P) be a probability space. For each ω Ω, suppose there is a continuous function W(t) of t 0 that satisfies W(0) = 0 and that depends on ω. Then W(t),

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Lecture 3 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures Several important concepts were illustrated in the example in Lecture 2: arbitrage; risk neutral probability

More information

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS 1 2 FAIR PRICING There is a market for an object called S. The prevailing price today is S 0 = 100. At this price the object S can be bought or sold by anyone for any

More information

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher) Advanced Corporate Finance 5. Options (a refresher) Objectives of the session 1. Define options (calls and puts) 2. Analyze terminal payoff 3. Define basic strategies 4. Binomial option pricing model 5.

More information

Expected Value and Variance

Expected Value and Variance Expected Value and Variance MATH 472 Financial Mathematics J Robert Buchanan 2018 Objectives In this lesson we will learn: the definition of expected value, how to calculate the expected value of a random

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance - - Introduction to Mathematical Finance - Lecture Notes by Ulrich Horst The objective of this course is to give an introduction to the probabilistic techniques required to understand the most widely used

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Convergence. Any submartingale or supermartingale (Y, F) converges almost surely if it satisfies E Y n <. STAT2004 Martingale Convergence

Convergence. Any submartingale or supermartingale (Y, F) converges almost surely if it satisfies E Y n <. STAT2004 Martingale Convergence Convergence Martingale convergence theorem Let (Y, F) be a submartingale and suppose that for all n there exist a real value M such that E(Y + n ) M. Then there exist a random variable Y such that Y n

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Steven E. Shreve Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 USA shreve@andrew.cmu.edu A Talk in the Series Probability in Science and Industry

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 217 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 217 13 Lecture 13 November 15, 217 Derivation of the Black-Scholes-Merton

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing CHAPTR 2. CONTINUUM MODL 8 2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing Options are some of the commonest examples of derivative securities (also termed financial derivatives or simply derivatives). A uropean

More information

Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part one) Dr Nic Freeman

Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part one) Dr Nic Freeman Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part one) Dr Nic Freeman December 15, 2017 Contents 0 Introduction 3 0.1 Syllabus......................................... 4 0.2 Problem sheets.....................................

More information

Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering. A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim. Julienne LaChance

Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering. A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim. Julienne LaChance Introduction to Financial Mathematics and Engineering A guide, based on lecture notes by Professor Chjan Lim Julienne LaChance Lecture 1. The Basics risk- involves an unknown outcome, but a known probability

More information

Fixed-Income Options

Fixed-Income Options Fixed-Income Options Consider a two-year 99 European call on the three-year, 5% Treasury. Assume the Treasury pays annual interest. From p. 852 the three-year Treasury s price minus the $5 interest could

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October

More information

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis Jim Zhu Western Michigan University Kalamazoo, Michigan, USA March 3, 2011 A tale of two financial economists Edward O. Thorp and Myron Scholes Influential works: Beat the Dealer(1962) and Beat the Market(1967)

More information

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS May/June 2006 Time allowed: 2 HOURS. Examiner: Dr N.P. Byott This is a CLOSED

More information

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model Peter Carr Bloomberg LP and Courant Institute, NYU Continuous Time Finance Lecture 2 Wednesday, January 26th, 2005 One Period Model Initial Setup: 0 risk-free

More information

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees Pricing Options with Binomial Trees MATH 472 Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2018 Objectives In this lesson we will learn: a simple discrete framework for pricing options, how to calculate risk-neutral

More information

The Multistep Binomial Model

The Multistep Binomial Model Lecture 10 The Multistep Binomial Model Reminder: Mid Term Test Friday 9th March - 12pm Examples Sheet 1 4 (not qu 3 or qu 5 on sheet 4) Lectures 1-9 10.1 A Discrete Model for Stock Price Reminder: The

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13. FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Asset Price Dynamics Introduction These notes give assumptions of asset price returns that are derived from the efficient markets hypothesis. Although a hypothesis,

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO 1. Definitions and basic properties of options and other derivatives 1.1. Summary. Definition of European call and put options, American call and put option, forward (futures)

More information

Options Markets: Introduction

Options Markets: Introduction 17-2 Options Options Markets: Introduction Derivatives are securities that get their value from the price of other securities. Derivatives are contingent claims because their payoffs depend on the value

More information

Multiple Optimal Stopping Problems and Lookback Options

Multiple Optimal Stopping Problems and Lookback Options Multiple Optimal Stopping Problems and Lookback Options Yue Kuen KWOK Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science & Technology Hong Kong, China web page: http://www.math.ust.hk/ maykwok/

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Robert Almgren University of Chicago Program on Financial Mathematics MAA Short Course San Antonio, Texas January 11-12, 1999 1 Robert Almgren 1/99 Mathematics in Finance 2 1. Pricing

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

MATH20180: Foundations of Financial Mathematics

MATH20180: Foundations of Financial Mathematics MATH20180: Foundations of Financial Mathematics Vincent Astier email: vincent.astier@ucd.ie office: room S1.72 (Science South) Lecture 1 Vincent Astier MATH20180 1 / 35 Our goal: the Black-Scholes Formula

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +... No-Arbitrage Pricing Theory Single-Period odel There are N securities denoted ( S,S,...,S N ), they can be stocks, bonds, or any securities, we assume they are all traded, and have prices available. Ω

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Generating Random Variables and Stochastic Processes Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018 S p VT u = f(su ) S T = S u V t =? S t S t e r(t t) 1 p VT d = f(sd ) S T = S d t T time Figure 1: Underlying asset price in a one-step binomial model B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018 The simplesodel for a random

More information

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA School of Mathematics Main Series UG Examination 2016 17 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A Time allowed: 3 Hours Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other

More information

Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory

Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory Topics 1. Principle of Expected Return 2. St. Petersburg Paradox 3. Utility Theory 4. Principle of Expected Utility 5. The Certainty Equivalent 6. Utility

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 10: Options pricing in binomial lattices

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 10: Options pricing in binomial lattices MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 10: Options pricing in binomial lattices A. Salo, T. Seeve Systems Analysis Laboratory Department of System Analysis and Mathematics Aalto University, School of Science

More information

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance Lecture 1 s from finance Financial market instruments can be divided into two types. There are the underlying stocks shares, bonds, commodities, foreign currencies; and their derivatives, claims that promise

More information

Stats243 Introduction to Mathematical Finance

Stats243 Introduction to Mathematical Finance Stats243 Introduction to Mathematical Finance Haipeng Xing Department of Statistics Stanford University Summer 2006 Stats243, Xing, Summer 2007 1 Agenda Administrative, course description & reference,

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Aspects of Financial Mathematics: Aspects of Financial Mathematics: Options, Derivatives, Arbitrage, and the Black-Scholes Pricing Formula J. Robert Buchanan Millersville University of Pennsylvania email: Bob.Buchanan@millersville.edu

More information

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING 1. Introduction One of the consequences of incompleteness is that the price of derivatives is no longer unique. Various strategies for dealing with this exist, but a useful

More information

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee orean J. Math. 3 015, No. 1, pp. 81 91 http://dx.doi.org/10.11568/kjm.015.3.1.81 LOCAL VOLATILITY FOR QUANTO OPTION PRICES WITH STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee Abstract. This paper

More information

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options These notes 1 introduce forwards, swaps, futures and options as well as the basic mechanics

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Central Limit Theorem (cont d) 7/28/2006

Central Limit Theorem (cont d) 7/28/2006 Central Limit Theorem (cont d) 7/28/2006 Central Limit Theorem for Binomial Distributions Theorem. For the binomial distribution b(n, p, j) we have lim npq b(n, p, np + x npq ) = φ(x), n where φ(x) is

More information