( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather"

Transcription

1 Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT ) P( KT ) PV 0T ( F 0T K ) e rt ( F 0T K ) where C( KT )- the price of European call with strike price K and time to expiration T; P KT - the price of European put with strike price K and time to expiration T; F 0T - the forward price for the underlying asset; K the strike price; T the time to expiration of the options; PV 0T - the present value over the life of the options. The intuition is that buying a call and selling a put with the strike equal to the forward price ( F 0T K ) creates a synthetic forward contract and hence must have a zero price. If we create a synthetic long forward position at a price lower than the forward we have to since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather pay PV 0T F 0T K than the forward price. Put-call parity implies that C( KT ) P( KT ) S PV ( K ) so that PV ( K ) S C( KT ) + P( KT ). The creation of a synthetic risk-free bond by buying the stock writing a call and buying a put is called a conversion. Its reverse is called a reverse conversion. Generalized parity and exchange options In general options can be designed to exchange any asset for any other asset and relative put and call premiums are determined by prices of prepaid forwards on the underlying and strike assets. Assume we are exchanging an asset A with price S t for a strike asset B P with price Q t. Let F tt S denote the time t price of a prepaid forward on the underlying ( Q) denote the time t price of a prepaid forward P asset paying S T at time T and let F tt on the asset B paying Q T at time T. Then the parity equation at time t is: P C S t Q t T t ( S) F tt ( Q). P P( S t Q t T t) F tt The Black-Scholes Formula Let S t be a random variable describing the value of an asset (a stock or some other asset) whose price follows a process we will be describing at time t with S 0 S. Let f t be the risk-neutral PDF of S t. The value of a European call with exercise price K and exercise time T is

2 + C e rt ( x K ) f T ( x)dx. K Assume that S t is lognormally distributed so that the continuously compounded rate of S return on the underlying over t years has the normal distribution with mean tµ and variance tσ. Based on the properties of the lognormal distribution E S T S and f T ( x) e T µ + σ xσ πt e x S T µ σ Tσ. Assuming risk-neutral valuation S E( e rt S T ) e rt Se T µ + or e rt e T µ + σ. This means that µ r σ. Combining the above we get + x S T r σ x K C e rt xσ πt e Tσ dx K x y S T r σ K S T r σ x K y F dy x dx x y σ Integration by substitution Se y +T r + K e rt e Se y +T r y Ke + y dy e rt y dy F π F π T +rt S eyσ Tσ + y rt e + dy Ke rt y π π dy e ( y ) + e + S dy Ke rt y π π dy F z y y F z F S dz dy y z We define Integration by substitution in the first integral F F σ e + z + π dz e Ke rt F F F y π dy.

3 K S d ( F ) T r F + σ + S K + T r σ + σ T S K + T r + σ S K + T r d F σ d. This gives C S e + z π dz e + Ke rt y F F ( ) Ke rt N F S N F ( ) Ke rt N F π dy S N F SN ( d ) Ke rt N d. This is the Black-Scholes formula. Note also that the coefficient of Ke rt N ( d ) e + y F π dy Pr( Y > F) Pr( S T > K ) so that N d money. On the other hand the coefficient of S is is ( ) can be interpreted as the risk-neutral probability of the call expiring in the N ( d ) + e z π dz > F e + z π dz N ( d ). F The Black-Scholes formula is a limiting case (as number of steps in binomial tree goes to infinity) of the binomial formula for the price of European options. In general the Black- Scholes formula gives the price of a European call option on a stock that pays dividends at the continuous rate δ as: C( SKσrT δ ) Se δt N ( d ) Ke rt N ( d ) where Se δt Ke rt + σ T S K + ( r δ )T + σ T d Se δt Ke rt σ T d d. In the above S is the current price of the stock K is the strike price of the option σ is the volatility of the stock (standard deviation of the continuously compounded rate of return on the stock) r is the continuously compounded risk-free rate T is the time to

4 expiration; δ is the dividend yield on the stock; and N(x) is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution. Put option The Black-Scholes formula for European put option on a stock that pays dividends at the continuous rate d is: P( SKσrT δ ) Ke rt N ( d ) Se δt N ( d ) where as for call options Se δt Ke rt + σ T S K + ( r δ )T + σ T d Se δt Ke rt σ T d d. We can get the put option price from the put-call parity: P C + Ke rt Se δt using this property of the standard normal distribution: N ( x) N ( x). Assumptions of the Black-Scholes Formula Assumptions about the distribution of the stock: Continuously compounded returns on the stock are normally distributed and independent over time (no jumps). The volatility of continuously compounded returns is known and constant. Future dividends are known (a dollar amount or fixed dividend rate). Assumptions about economic environment: The risk-free rate is known and constant. There are no transaction costs or taxes. It is possible to sell short without any cost and to borrow at the risk-free rate. Option Greeks Option Greeks are formulas that express the change in the option price when one input to the formula changes taking all the other inputs as fixed. In other words a Greek is a partial derivative of the option price with respect to one particular input. These formulas are used in investment practice to assess risk exposure. We will talk about the Greeks for a purchased option (i.e. for a long position in an option). The Greek for a written option is opposite in sign to that for the same purchased option. Delta Δ If S is the price of the underlying and C is the price of the derivative then delta is defined as Δ C. Delta is also the value obtained in the process of replication of a S derivative with underlying and cash resulting in: Derivative price Δ S + B. Delta is positive for calls and negative for puts. In-the-money option is more sensitive to the stock price (larger delta) than an out-of-the-money option. As time to expiration increases

5 delta is less for high stock prices and greater at low stock prices. If Black-Scholes formula holds call price equals Se δt N ( d ) Ke rt N ( d ) and the call delta is e δt N ( d ). and N ( d ) are This might seem to be merely the first approximation because N d also functions of S. But let us consider this in some more detail. Let us write ϕ for the PDF of the standard normal distribution. Note that d S d S S Se δt Ke rt Ke rt Se e δt δt Ke rt S. We have C S ( S Se δt N ( d ) Ke rt N ( d )) S S e δt N d + Se δt N ( d ) S Ke rt N ( d ) S e δt N ( d ) + Se δt ϕ ( d ) d S Ke rt ϕ ( d ) d S e δt N d + Se δt ϕ ( d ) Ke rt ϕ ( d ) + Se δt e d Ke rt e d e δt N d S π Now consider d d d d This implies that d Se δt and therefore ( Se δt ) e d e S π and d + d d + d ( ) e δt N d ( d d ) S δt Se + e d e S π ( d ( d )) d d Se δt σ Ke rt T Se δt Ke rt + σ T σ T Ke rt rt ( Ke ) d d 0 + σ T Se δt Ke rt rt ( Ke ) d σ T ( Se δt ) ( Ke rt )..

6 C S e δt N ( d ) not approximately but exactly. Also based on put-call parity P S C Se δt + Ke rt e δt N ( d ) e δt e δt ( N ( d ) ) e δt N ( d ). S Note that since P Ke rt N ( d ) Se δt N ( d ) this is the same value we would get by taking the partial derivative with respect to S and ignoring the partial derivatives of N ( d ) and N ( d ). Gamma G Defined as Γ Δ S C S. Gamma is always positive for purchased call or put. When call-put parity holds C S P S ( C P) ( S PV ( K )) 0 S S gamma is the same for put and call with the same strike and time to expiration. Gamma is close to zero for deep in-the-money and deep out-of-the-money options. Vega Defined as C. Increase of volatility increases the price of call or put so Vega is σ positive. Vega is greater for at-the-money options. It is greater for options with moderate time to expiration than with short time to expiration. Under the assumptions of the putcall parity Vega is the same for put and call with the same strike and time to expiration. Theta Defined as θ C and it measures the rate of change in option price with respect to T decrease in the time to maturity. Options generally become less valuable as the time to expiration decreases. Time decay is greatest for the at-the-money short-term options. Time decay can be positive for deep in-the-money calls on stocks with high dividends and deep in-the-money puts. Rho Defined as ρ C. Positive for call negative for put (greater interest means smaller r present value of strike price). Psi

7 Defined as Ψ C. Negative for call positive for put (greater dividend yield means δ smaller present value of stock to be received). Greek Measures for Portfolios For a portfolio containing n options with a single underlying stock with ω i quantity of the i-th option: Δ portfolio n i ω i Δ i. Same for the other Greeks. Option Elasticity Computes the percentage change in the option price relative to the percentage change in the stock price (the percentage change in the option price for a % change in stock price). Let e be a change in stock price. Then ed is the change in option price. Ω % change in the value of C % change in the value of S εδ C ε SΔ C. S For a call W (call is replicated by a levered investment in the stock) for a put W 0 (involves shorting the stock). Volatility of the option σ option σ stock Ω. This makes sense since elasticity is a measure of leverage. Let a denote the expected rate of return on the stock g the expected rate of return on the option. Since the call price C Δ S + B γ Δ S C α + Δ S C r Ωα + ( Ω)r. Thus: γ r ( α r)ω. The risk premium on the option equals the risk premium on the stock times option elasticity. risk premium Sharpe ratio for an asset volatility Sharpe ratio for stock α r σ Sharpe ratio for call Ω α r α r Ωσ σ. For a portfolio containing n options with a single underlying stock with ω i fraction invested in the i-th option: Ω portfolio ω i Ω i. n i

8 Lognormal distribution Recall that a random variable W is lognormal if its natural logarithm is normal i.e. X W N ( µσ ). In this case also W e X and E ( W ) e µ+ σ. Note that e µ+ E e X σ > e E( X) e µ. This is a special case of the Jensen s Inequality which says the following: Let h be a twice differentiable real-valued function of a real variable and let X be a random variable such that d h E X h E X E h( X) E h( X) dx h x 0 at every x at which f x X > 0. Then ( ). Under the same assumptions if d ( ). dx h x 0 then If the stock price S t is lognormal for S t S 0 e X where X the continuously compounded return from 0 to t is normal. If returns over non-overlapping time intervals of the same length are IID the mean and variance of the continuously compounded returns are proportional to time. If we assume that S t ~ N α δ σ tσ t S 0 then S t S 0 e α δ σ t + ( σ t )Z where Z is standard normal. If current stock price is S0 the probability that a call option with exercise price K expiring at time t will expire in the money is Pr ( S t > K ) N ( ˆd ) where ˆd contains α the true expected return on the stock in place of r the risk-free rate continuously comnpounded. Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma Brownian Motion is a stochastic process that is a random walk occurring in continuous time with movements that are continuous rather than discrete. Its definition is as follows: Brownian Motion is a stochastic process Z(t) with the following characteristics: Z 0 0. Z ( t) is normally distributed with mean 0 and variance s. Z ( t) is independent of Z ( t) Z t s Z t + s Z t + s where s > 0 s > 0. In other words increments over non-overlapping time intervals are independent. Z(t) is continuous as a function of t. These properties imply that Z(t) is a martingale a stochastic process for which E Z ( t + s) Z ( t). Z t The process Z(t) is also called a diffusion process.

9 Arithmetic Brownian Motion We generalize Brownian Motion to allow an arbitrary variance and a nonzero mean: dx t αdt + σdz ( t) We say that α is an instantaneous mean per unit of time and σ is an instantaneous variance per unit of time. The term αdt introduces a nonrandom drift to the process. Since arithmetic Brownian Motion is a basically a scaled Brownian Motion we see that X ( T ) X ( 0) ~ N ( αt σ T ). In this model X may assume negative values so this is not a good model for stock prices. Ito Process This is a process where both the drift ˆα and volatility ˆσ are functions of the stock (or a capital asset in general) price X(t): dx ( t) ˆα ( X ( t) )dt + ˆσ ( X ( t) )dz ( t) Geometric Brownian Motion This is an Ito process where both the drift ˆα and volatility ˆσ are linear functions of stock price X(t); more precisely multiples: ˆα X t ( ) α X ( t) and ˆσ ( X ( t) ) σ X ( t). We can represent geometric Brownian motion as: dx ( t) α X ( t)dt + σ X ( t)dz ( t) or in this more popular form: dx ( t) αdt + σdz t X ( t). Thus the percentage change in the asset value is normally distributed with instantaneous mean α and instantaneous variance σ. This is the most popular model of stock returns. For the change over time period of length h we have: X ( t + h) X ( t) α X ( t)h + σ X ( t)y ( t) h. Thus over short period of time the character of Brownian motion is determined almost entirely by the random component. Over time interval longer than a year the mean becomes more important than standard deviation. Lognormality A variable that follows geometric Brownian motion is lognormally distributed. More precisely if X(t) satisfies dx t αdt + σdz ( t X t ) then the distribution of its logarithm is

10 ( X ( t) ) ~ N ( ( X ( 0) ) + ( α 0.5σ )tσ t) or equivalently the solution of the above differential equation is ( X ( t) X ( 0)e α 0.5σ )t+σ tz where Z ~ N ( 0). Note that if U ~ N ( µσ ) then E e U expected value of X(t) ( E X ( t) e α 0.5σ )te e σ ty ( e α 0.5σ )te 0.5σ t X ( 0)e αt. X 0 X 0 e µ + σ we can compute the Thus we can see that α is the expected continuously compounded rate of return on X. The Sharpe Ratio Recall that the Sharpe ratio for an asset is its risk premium α r per unit of volatility σ : Sharpe Ratio α r σ. We will show that two perfectly correlated assets must have the same Sharpe ratio or otherwise there is an arbitrage opportunity. Consider the following processes for nondividend-paying stocks which have the same source of randomness. ds ( t) α S ( t)dt + σ S ( t)dz ( t) ds ( t) α S ( t)dt + σ S ( t)dz ( t). Assume that Sharpe ratio for asset is greater than that for asset. We then buy σ S shares of asset and short shares of asset. These two positions will have σ S generally different costs so we invest (or borrow) the cost difference by σ σ buying (or borrowing) the risk-free bond which has the instantaneous rate of return rdt. The return on the two assets and the risk-free bond is ds ds + σ S σ S σ σ rdt α r σ α r σ dt. This demonstrates that if Sharpe ratio of asset is greater than that for asset we can construct a zero investment portfolio with a positive risk-free return. Ito s Lemma Suppose that a stock with an expected instantaneous return of ˆα dividend yield of ˆδ and instantaneous volatility ˆσ follows an Ito process: ds( t) ( ˆα ( S( t)t) ˆδ ( S( t)t) )dt + ˆσ ( S( t)t)dz ( t). If C( S( t)t) is a twice-differentiable function of S( t) then the change in C dc S( t)t is

11 dc( S( t)t) C S ds + C S ( ds ) + C t dt When working with Ito processes and Ito Lemma we could use the following multiplication rules : dt dz 0 0 dt. dt dz In the above Z(t) is the standard Brownian motion (i.e. not arithmetic or geometric Brownian motion). The reasoning behind these multiplication rules is that the multiplications resulting in powers of dt greater than vanish in the limit. In the case of geometric Brownian motion: ds( t) S( t) ( α δ )dt + σdz ( t ) Ito lemma becomes: dc( St) ( α δ )SC S + σ S C SS + C t dt + σ SC S dz since ( ds) σ S ( dz) σ S dt. The Black-Scholes Equation The process of valuation of securities in a continuous time model uses differential equations. Consider the basis equation relating the values of a stock at time t to the value of the same stock at time t + h: S ( t)( + r h ) D( t + h)h + S ( t + h). It can be rewritten as S( t)r D( t + h)h h + S ( t + h ) S( t). Return on stock Cash payment Change in stock price Dividing by h and letting h à 0 results in a differential equation: ds ( t) + D( t) rs ( t) dt with r being the continuously compounded rate of return as always. We obtain the differential equation that describes the evolution of the stock price over time to generate an appropriate rate of return. For dividend-paying stocks If the value of the stock at time T is S that is the terminal boundary condition: S(T ) S and the solution is

12 De S t T t ds r s t + Se. For bonds Let S(t) represent the price of a zero-coupon bond that pays $ at T. We have ds t + D( t ) rs ( t). dt 0 because no income is paid The general solution to this differential equation is S t Ae. With the terminal boundary condition S(T) $ the particular solution for the bond value is S t e Now consider the problem of creating a riskless hedge for an option position through trading in shares and bonds. Assume that the stock price follows geometric Brownian motion: ds S ( α δ )dt + σdz where α is the expected return in the stock σ is the stock s volatility and δ is the continuous dividend yield. If we invest W in riskless bonds the change in value of the bond is dw rwdt. Let I denote the total investment in the portfolio N stocks and W in the risk-free bonds so that the total investment is zero with V standing for the value of the derivative security I V (S t) + NS + W 0. Applying Itô s Lemma. di dv + N(dS + δsdt) + dw V t dt + V S ds + σ S V SS dt + N(dS + δsdt) + rwdt. Since the option delta is V S set N V S this will make W V S S V. Also di 0 because with zero investment the return should also be zero. Substituting all these and dividing by dt we obtain: V t + σ S V SS + ( r δ )SV S rv 0. This is the Black-Scholes stochastic partial differential equation (PDE) for any contingent claim assuming Underlying asset follows constant volatility geometric Brownian motion. Underlying asset pays a continuous proportional dividend at the rate δ. The contingent claim itself pays no dividend. The interest rate is fixed with equal borrowing and lending rates. There are no transaction costs. The call pricing formula Se δ (T t ) N(d ) Ke r(t t ) N(d ) satisfies the Black-Scholes PDE using the appropriate boundary condition. Similarly it can be shown that the put pricing formula and the formulas for asset-or-nothing options cash-or-nothing options and gap options satisfy the Black-Scholes PDE using the

13 appropriate boundary condition in each case. Black-Scholes PDE can be generalized to the case when one uses equilibrium expected return on the underlying asset instead of the risk-free return. Risk-neutral pricing The Black-Scholes partial differential equation does not contain the expected stock return α but only the risk-free rate and this implies that the equation must be consistent with any world in which no arbitrage is possible. The actual expected change in the option price is E dv dt dt E ( dv ) V t + σ S V SS + ( α δ )SV S. Let E* denote the risk-neutral expected value. Under the risk-neutral valuation the expected change in the stock price is E *( ds) ( r δ )dt. The drift of the option price can therefore be written as dt E *( dv ) V t + σ S V SS + ( r δ )SV S. If we compare this with the Black-Scholes equation V t + σ S V SS + ( r δ )SV S rv 0 we conclude that the equivalent form of the Black-Scholes equation is: dv dt E* rv indicating that the option appreciates on average at the risk-free rate. The solution of the equation is equivalent to computing the expected payoff of the derivative security and discounting it at the risk-free rate. For a simple European call option on a stock that pays dividends at a constant continuous rate δ that call s price is S T e K ( K ) f * s ds where s is a specific value of S(T). The integral form of the Black-Scholes equation is also called the Feynman-Kac equation. Option pricing Another approach to option pricing is to impose the condition that the actual expected return on the option must equal the equilibrium expected return. To avoid arbitrage two assets with returns generated by the same dz must have the same Sharpe ratio i.e. α r σ Ω Ω α option r σ option where σ option Ω σ and the option s elasticity is

14 % change in option price Ω % change in stock price εv S V εs SV S V S V V S. This produces the equilibrium condition that the option must obey: ( α r) α option r SV S V This means that the option must be priced so that its expected return is related to the expected return on the stock in a particular way. Under the Black-Scholes framework the price of an option V must satisfy Black-Scholes equation V t + σ S V SS + ( r δ )SV S rv 0 or else there is an arbitrage opportunity. Moreover the pricing formula must satisfy the appropriate boundary conditions which depend on the type of the option. Consider a European call option. Its Black-Scholes pricing formula is V S ( t)t N ( d ) Ke N ( d ) where d Se ( T t ) Se δ Ke + σ T t S K + r δ + σ T t d d. It satisfies the Black-Scholes equation and we will check for the boundary conditions: V ( S ( T )T ) max ( 0 S ( T ) K ). When t T e e. As t T we have: S > K S S K K > 0 + N ( d ) N ( d ) V S K. S < K S S K K < 0 N ( d ) N ( d ) 0 V 0. All or Nothing Options An asset-or-nothing call pays one share of stock if S T denote its value at time t by V 3 S( t)t > K and 0 otherwise. We will or just V 3. Note that V 3 ( S ( T )T ) S ( T ) if > K and 0 otherwise. There is also an asset-or-nothing put which pays one share < K and 0 otherwise. We will write V 4 ( S( t)t) or just V 4 for its value > K and 0 otherwise. We will denote ( S( t)t) or just V 5. Notice that V 5 ( S( T )T ) if S ( T ) > K S T of stock if S T at time t. A cash-or-nothing call pays $ if S T its value at time t by V 5 and 0 otherwise. There is also a cash-or-nothing put which pays $ if S T < K and 0

15 otherwise. We will write V 6 ( S( t)t) for its value at time t. These options: asset-or-nothing call asset-or-nothing put cash-or-nothing call and cashor-nothing put are also called binary options. The prices of them under Black-Scholes framework are: V 3 Se N ( d ) V 4 Se N ( d ) V 5 e N ( d ) V 6 e N ( d ) where d and d are calculated using the standard formulas in the Black-Scholes framework. Note also that the event S T { K} has zero probability so that V 3 + V 4 Se as well as V 5 + V 6 e. Note also that V 4 Se N ( d ) Se N ( d ) V 3 e V 6 e N d Se ( ) e N d V 5. Proof that V 3 V 4 V 5 and V 6 are solutions of the Black-Scholes equation Recall the Black-Scholes equation V t + σ S V S + r δ V S rv 0. S Consider V Se N ( d ) where ( Se) Ke + σ ( T t) d ( T t) σ S K + σ r δ + σ T t Note that d ( T t) t t σ S K + σ r δ + σ ( T t ) ( ) σ ( T t ) 3 S K + ( ) σ r δ + σ ( T t ) S T t K r δ + T t σ ( T t ) S T t K + r δ + σ ( T t ) r δ + T t σ ( T t ) d r δ + T t σ.

16 and d S S. Therefore δ V Se ( T t ) N d t t and ( ) δse N ( d ) + Se δse N ( d ) + Se ( ) V S Se δ ( T t) N d S V S e N ( d ) + Se e N ( d ) + e e Based on this N d e e d + e π Sσ d d d π d t d π d T t ( Se) e d π π d S d π d π S T t + ( e) σ π S e e d T t e d r δ + σ. π d S π S d

17 V t + σ S V S + r δ V S S rv δse N ( d ) + Se + σ S e + ( r δ )S e N ( d ) Se +Se d N d d π d T t Se π S e + e ( r) δ + r δ + 0 d π d r δ + π σ + d π S d + ( rse ) N d d π d r δ + T t σ + σ d T t + r δ 0. Now consider V 4 Se V 3. Because V 3 is a solution of the Black-Scholes Equation all we need to show is that Se is a solution of it. We have ( Se δ ( T t) ) ( Se δt e ) δt Se δt δe δt δ δse ( T t ) t t ( S Se) e Se δ ( T t) S and thus for V Se S e 0 V t + σ S V S + r δ V S S rv δse ( r δ )S e rse Now consider V e N d ( Se) d Note that Ke where σ T t T t 0 0 σ S K + σ r δ σ T t.

18 d t d r δ + T t d t d + r δ + σ + T t d T t + σ r δ + σ + d T t + σ r + δ σ + σ σ and d S d S S. Therefore V ( e N ( d )) t t and V S re N ( d ) + e ( ) r( T t) V e N d S S e T t σ σ σ σ re N ( d ) + e e d π S S d T t ( ) d r δ T t σ d π d t d π d T t ( e) e d π d π d S e e d e π d S S + e e Based on this d π d S σ T t e e d e d e d π S. r δ σ π S π S

19 V t + σ S V S + r δ V S S rv re N ( d ) + e + σ S e + ( r δ )S e e N d +e ( r r) + 0 d d π d T t e π d S σ T t d π S e d r δ π σ + d ( re ) N d π S + d π d r δ T t σ d T t σ + r δ 0. This proves that the formula for the value of the cash or nothing call is a solution of the Black-Scholes equation. Now consider V 6 e V 5. Because V 5 is a solution of the Black-Scholes Equation all we need to show is that e is a solution of it. We have ( e r( T t) ) ( e rt e ) rt e rt re rt r re ( T t ) t t 0 S e e r ( T t) 0 S and thus for V e V t + σ S V S + r δ V S S rv re 0. re Note that because derivative is a linear functional this implies that any linear combination of these two formulas is a solution of the Black-Scholes equation and one such linear combination is the Black-Scholes formula for the price a European call obtained as a linear combination of V 3 and V 5 while another one is the Black-Scholes formula for the price of a European put obtained as a linear combination of V 4 and V 6 : C Se r N d ( T t ) N d P Ke N d Ke Se 0 V 3 K V 5 K V 6 V 4. N d

20 In the process of proving the statements above we also obtained some values of Greeks for these binary options Delta of an asset-or-nothing call: V 3 S ( e) N ( d ) + e d π Delta of an asset-or-nothing put: e V 4 S ( S Se) V 3 Delta of a cash-or-nothing call: V 5 S ( e) e d π S Delta of a cash-or-nothing put: N d e d π V 6 S ( S e) V 5 V 5 S ( e) e d π S Gamma of an asset-or-nothing call: V 3 e δ ( T t) e d S π S ( e) e d π S d Gamma of an asset-or-nothing put: V 4 Se δ ( T t) V 3 V 3 S S S d e π S + e Gamma of a cash-or-nothing call: V 5 e r ( T t) e d S π d S σ T t Gamma of a cash-or-nothing put: V 6 e r ( T t) V 5 V 5 S S S e d π d S σ T t Theta of an asset-or-nothing call: e d e + e π S d e d e d π S π S

21 V 3 V t T t 3 δse N ( d ) Se Theta of an asset-or-nothing put: V 4 4 Se δ ( T t) V 3 T t t t V δse δse + δse N ( d ) + Se d π d T t + ( Se) e d π + V 3 t d π d T t ( Se) e d π δe N ( d ) + Se d π d T t ( Se) e d π Theta of a cash-or-nothing call: V 5 V t T t 5 re N ( d ) e and theta of a cash-or-nothing put: V 6 6 e T t t t V re + re N ( d ) + e re N ( d ) + e ( r( T t) V ) 5 re d π d T t e r δ + σ d π d T t + ( e) e d π + V 5 t d π d T t ( e) e d π e d r δ + σ r δ + σ σ T t r δ σ r δ σ σ r δ π σ. T t Interest Rate Models We model a zero-coupon bond by assuming that the price of a unit zero coupon bond P( tt ) follows an Ito process: dp( rtt ) P( rtt ) α ( rtt )dt + q ( rtt )dz. Here the coefficients cannot be constant. They have to be carefully modeled to reflect the bond boundary condition: has to be worth $ at maturity as well as the fact that the volatility of the bond should decrease as the bond approaches maturity. Equivalently we can assume that the short-term interest rate follows the Ito process:

22 where Z t dr a( r)dt + σ ( r)dz { } is a standard Brownian motion under the true probability measure. We call it the true stochastic process of the short rates. Now we can use Ito Lemma and get an expression for α ( rtt ) and q( rtt ) We have dp( rtt ) P r dr + a r P P ( dr) + P r t dt r + P r σ ( r ) + P t dt + P r σ r dz. + P( tt ) + W of one bond maturing at time T We analyze a portfolio I N P tt which we delta-hedge by buying N bonds maturing at T and we finance the difference by borrowing W. We use Ito Lemma and set di 0. This gives us two equivalent formulas. First we get that the Sharpe ratio for two bonds is equal (both bond prices are driven by the same random term dz they must have the same Sharpe ratio if they are fairly priced) α rtt r r q( rtt ) φ( rt) α rtt q( rtt ) Equivalently we obtain the partial differential equation that must be satisfied by any zero-coupon bond: ( σ ( r) P ) r + ( a( r) σ ( r )φ ( rt )) P r + P rp 0. t The risk-neutral process for the interest rate is obtained by subtracting risk premium from the drift: dr ( a( r) σ ( r)φ( rt) )dt + σ ( r)dz. Different specifications of a( r) σ ( r) and φ rt models. lead to different bond pricing The Rendelman-Bartter Model We assume here that the short-rate follows geometric Brownian motion: dr ardt + σrdz. Interest rates can never be negative in this model but they can be arbitrary high (while in reality they should exhibit mean reversion if rates are high we expect them on average to decrease). The Vasicek Model We assume here that the short-rate follows Brownian motion with mean reversion: dr a( b r)dt + σdz. Since the random term dz is multiplied only by σ the variability of rates is independent of the level of rates and the rates can become negative. In this model the Sharpe ratio is constant:

23 r q( rtt ) α rtt φ( rt) φ The price formula that solves the partial differential equation for zero-coupon bonds is: P( tt r( t) ) A( tt )e B( tt )r( t) where e r B tt ( +t T ) B σ e a T t 4a A tt B tt a r b + σφ a σ a where r is the yield to maturity of an infinitely lived bond a consol. Note that we can remember the formula e a T t B tt a in the Vasicek model P( tt r( t) ) A( tt )e B( tt as a T tδ a the present value of a continuous annuity-certain of rate payable for T t years and evaluated at force of interest a where a is the speed of mean reversion for the associated short-rate process. a T tδ a v ( T t) ( T t ) e δ ( T t ) e a. δ δ a The Cox-Ingersoll-Ross Model We assume here that the short-rate follows the following Ito process: dr a b r dt + σ rdz. Here the volatility of interest rates is proportional to r and thus the rates cannot become negative. They also exhibit mean reversion. In this model the Sharpe ratio is of the form: α rtt r q( rtt ) φ( rt) φ r σ. The price formula that solves the partial differential equation for zero-coupon bonds is similar to that of Vasicek model P tt r( t) e B( tt )r( t) A tt and B( tt ) are more complicated. Note that like in Vasicek but the formulas for A tt model both functions A and B depend on (T t) rather than on t and T separately.

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions Course MFE/3F Practice Exam Solutions The chapter references below refer to the chapters of the ActuarialBrew.com Study Manual. Solution 1 A Chapter 16, Black-Scholes Equation The expressions for the value

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu 4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs Math6911 S08, HM Zhu References 1. Chapter 13, J. Hull. Section.6, P. Brandimarte Outline Derivation of Black-Scholes equation Black-Scholes models for options Implied

More information

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions he chapter references below refer to the chapters of the ActuraialBrew.com Study Manual. Solution 1 C Chapter 16, Sharpe Ratio If we (incorrectly) assume that the

More information

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given: (1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given: (i) The current price of the stock is $60. (ii) The call option currently sells for $0.15 more

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Errata and updates for ASM Exam MFE/3F (Ninth Edition) sorted by page.

Errata and updates for ASM Exam MFE/3F (Ninth Edition) sorted by page. Errata for ASM Exam MFE/3F Study Manual (Ninth Edition) Sorted by Page 1 Errata and updates for ASM Exam MFE/3F (Ninth Edition) sorted by page. Note the corrections to Practice Exam 6:9 (page 613) and

More information

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes Bluff our Way Through Black-Scholes Saurav Sen December 000 Contents What is Black-Scholes?.............................. 1 The Classical Black-Scholes Model....................... 1 Some Useful Background

More information

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Greeks Introduction We have studied how to price an option using the Black-Scholes formula. Now we wish to consider how the option price changes, either

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 and Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 Prof. Dr. Erich Walter Farkas Lecture 06: March 26, 2015 1 / 47 Remember and Previous chapters: introduction to the theory of options put-call parity fundamentals

More information

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch chris bemis November 27, 2006 0-0 Goal: Derive the Black-Scholes PDE To do this, we will need to: Come up with some dynamics for the stock returns Discuss Brownian motion

More information

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 1/ 36 Introduction Asset prices are modeled as following di usion processes, permitting the possibility of continuous trading. This environment

More information

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Dr. Roman V Belavkin MSO4112 Contents 1 Geometric Brownian motion 1 2 The Black-Scholes pricing 2 3 The Black-Scholes equation 3 References 5 1 Geometric Brownian motion

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS May/June 2006 Time allowed: 2 HOURS. Examiner: Dr N.P. Byott This is a CLOSED

More information

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Financial Derivatives Section 5 Financial Derivatives Section 5 The Black and Scholes Model Michail Anthropelos anthropel@unipi.gr http://web.xrh.unipi.gr/faculty/anthropelos/ University of Piraeus Spring 2018 M. Anthropelos (Un. of

More information

Financial Stochastic Calculus E-Book Draft 2 Posted On Actuarial Outpost 10/25/08

Financial Stochastic Calculus E-Book Draft 2 Posted On Actuarial Outpost 10/25/08 Financial Stochastic Calculus E-Book Draft Posted On Actuarial Outpost 10/5/08 Written by Colby Schaeffer Dedicated to the students who are sitting for SOA Exam MFE in Nov. 008 SOA Exam MFE Fall 008 ebook

More information

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma 1 The Sharpe Ratio 2 The Risk-Neutral Process Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma 1 The Sharpe Ratio 2 The Risk-Neutral Process The Sharpe Ratio Consider a portfolio of assets

More information

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester Our exam is Wednesday, December 19, at the normal class place and time. You may bring two sheets of notes (8.5

More information

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key MFE/3F Questions Download free full solutions from www.actuarialbrew.com, or purchase a hard copy from www.actexmadriver.com, or www.actuarialbookstore.com. Chapter 1 Put-Call Parity and Replication 1.01

More information

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions Arfima Financial Solutions Contents Definition 1 Definition 2 3 4 Contenido Definition 1 Definition 2 3 4 Definition Definition: A barrier option is an option on the underlying asset that is activated

More information

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Aspects of Financial Mathematics: Aspects of Financial Mathematics: Options, Derivatives, Arbitrage, and the Black-Scholes Pricing Formula J. Robert Buchanan Millersville University of Pennsylvania email: Bob.Buchanan@millersville.edu

More information

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING Version date: June 3, 017 C:\CLASSES\TEACHING NOTES\TN98-04.WPD The exchange option, first developed by Margrabe (1978), has proven to be an extremely powerful

More information

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key MFE/3F Questions Download free full solutions from www.actuarialbrew.com, or purchase a hard copy from www.actexmadriver.com, or www.actuarialbookstore.com. Chapter 1 Put-Call Parity and Replication 1.01

More information

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets Types of options Option positions and profit/loss diagrams Underlying assets Specifications Trading options Margins Taxation Warrants, employee stock options, and

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t Economathematics Problem Sheet 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 1. Calculate Ee X where X is a gaussian random variable with mean µ and volatility σ >.. Verify that where W is a Wiener process. Ws dw s = 1 3 W t 3

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options Options An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2014 Definitions and Terminology Definition An option is the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell a security such

More information

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk IV Completeness and Hedging Tomas Björk 1 Problems around Standard Black-Scholes We assumed that the derivative was traded. How do we price OTC products? Why is the option price independent of the expected

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58-6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15-19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9-31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36-37)

More information

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions Course MFE/3F Practice Exam Solutions he chapter references below refer to the chapters of the ActuraialBrew.com Study Manual. Solution C Chapter 6, Sharpe Ratio If we (incorrectly) assume that the cost

More information

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull)

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull) Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull) One use of derivation is for investors or investment banks to manage the risk of their investments. If an investor buys a stock for price S 0,

More information

Financial Economics & Insurance

Financial Economics & Insurance Financial Economics & Insurance Albert Cohen Actuarial Sciences Program Department of Mathematics Department of Statistics and Probability A336 Wells Hall Michigan State University East Lansing MI 48823

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets (Hull chapter: 12, 13, 14) Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 17 The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model Black and Scholes

More information

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility Simple Arbitrage Relations Payoffs to Call and Put Options Black-Scholes Model Put-Call Parity Implied Volatility Option Pricing Options: Definitions A call option gives the buyer the right, but not the

More information

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS PRICING EMMS014S7 Tuesday, May 31 2011, 10:00am-13.15pm

More information

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13 1 The Black-Scholes-Merton Random Walk Assumption l Consider a stock whose price is S l In a short period of time of length t the return

More information

1 Interest Based Instruments

1 Interest Based Instruments 1 Interest Based Instruments e.g., Bonds, forward rate agreements (FRA), and swaps. Note that the higher the credit risk, the higher the interest rate. Zero Rates: n year zero rate (or simply n-year zero)

More information

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19 To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should 1. know how to do the homework problems. 2. be able to provide (correct and complete!) definitions

More information

European call option with inflation-linked strike

European call option with inflation-linked strike Mathematical Statistics Stockholm University European call option with inflation-linked strike Ola Hammarlid Research Report 2010:2 ISSN 1650-0377 Postal address: Mathematical Statistics Dept. of Mathematics

More information

P-1. Preface. Thank you for choosing ACTEX.

P-1. Preface. Thank you for choosing ACTEX. Preface P- Preface Thank you for choosing ACTEX ince Exam MFE was introduced in May 007, there have been quite a few changes to its syllabus and its learning objectives To cope with these changes, ACTEX

More information

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12 Lecture 11: Ito Calculus Continuous time models We start with the model from Chapter 3 log S j log S j 1 = µ t + p tz j Sum it over j: log S N log S 0 = NX µ t + NX p tzj j=1 j=1 Can we take the limit

More information

The Black-Scholes Equation

The Black-Scholes Equation The Black-Scholes Equation MATH 472 Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2018 Objectives In this lesson we will: derive the Black-Scholes partial differential equation using Itô s Lemma and no-arbitrage

More information

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1 Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1 1B, p. 72: (60%)(0.39) + (40%)(0.75) = 0.534. 1D, page 131, solution to the first Exercise: 2.5 2.5 λ(t) dt = 3t 2 dt 2 2 = t 3 ]

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Merton-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 18 The Black-Merton-Scholes-Merton (BMS) model Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton

More information

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation Peter Cassar May 0, 05 Assumptions of the Black-Scholes Model We have a risk free asset given by the price process, dbt = rbt The asset price follows a geometric

More information

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 Stochastic Financial Modelling Time allowed: 2 hours Candidates should attempt all questions. Marks for each question

More information

Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates. Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles

Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates. Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles Caps Floors Swaption Options on IR futures Options on Government bond futures

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

SOA Exam MFE Solutions: May 2007

SOA Exam MFE Solutions: May 2007 Exam MFE May 007 SOA Exam MFE Solutions: May 007 Solution 1 B Chapter 1, Put-Call Parity Let each dividend amount be D. The first dividend occurs at the end of months, and the second dividend occurs at

More information

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels 1/ 36 Introduction A contingent claim s price process can be transformed into a martingale process by 1 Adjusting

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU IFS, Chengdu, China, July 30, 2018 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 7/30/2018 1 / 35 Interest Rates and Volatility Practitioners and

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 217 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 217 13 Lecture 13 November 15, 217 Derivation of the Black-Scholes-Merton

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a variable depend only on the present, and not the history

More information

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends. 224 10 Arbitrage and SDEs last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends. 10.1 (Calculation of Delta First and Finest

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 14 Lecture 14 November 15, 2017 Derivation of the

More information

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan Hedging MATH 472 Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2018 Introduction Definition Hedging is the practice of making a portfolio of investments less sensitive to changes in market variables. There

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 9 Lecture 9 9.1 The Greeks November 15, 2017 Let

More information

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA EXAMINATIONS 23 rd March 2017 Subject CT8 Financial Economics Time allowed: Three Hours (10.30 13.30 Hours) Total Marks: 100 INSTRUCTIONS TO THE CANDIDATES 1. Please read

More information

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Dr. Maddah ENMG 65 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Chapter 11 Models of Asset Dynamics () Random Walk A random process, z, is an additive process defined over times t 0, t 1,, t k, t k+1,, such that z( t )

More information

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008 Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 008 Background Dynamic replication is a risk management technique used to mitigate market risk We hope to spend a certain

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher) Advanced Corporate Finance 5. Options (a refresher) Objectives of the session 1. Define options (calls and puts) 2. Analyze terminal payoff 3. Define basic strategies 4. Binomial option pricing model 5.

More information

Fixed-Income Options

Fixed-Income Options Fixed-Income Options Consider a two-year 99 European call on the three-year, 5% Treasury. Assume the Treasury pays annual interest. From p. 852 the three-year Treasury s price minus the $5 interest could

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly). 1 EG, Ch. 22; Options I. Overview. A. Definitions. 1. Option - contract in entitling holder to buy/sell a certain asset at or before a certain time at a specified price. Gives holder the right, but not

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Binomial model: numerical algorithm Binomial model: numerical algorithm S / 0 C \ 0 S0 u / C \ 1,1 S0 d / S u 0 /, S u 3 0 / 3,3 C \ S0 u d /,1 S u 5 0 4 0 / C 5 5,5 max X S0 u,0 S u C \ 4 4,4 C \ 3 S u d / 0 3, C \ S u d 0 S u d 0 / C 4

More information

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Black-Scholes-Merton Model Black-Scholes-Merton Model Weerachart Kilenthong University of the Thai Chamber of Commerce c Kilenthong 2017 Weerachart Kilenthong University of the Thai Chamber Black-Scholes-Merton of Commerce Model

More information

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing CHAPTR 2. CONTINUUM MODL 8 2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing Options are some of the commonest examples of derivative securities (also termed financial derivatives or simply derivatives). A uropean

More information

Probability in Options Pricing

Probability in Options Pricing Probability in Options Pricing Mark Cohen and Luke Skon Kenyon College cohenmj@kenyon.edu December 14, 2012 Mark Cohen and Luke Skon (Kenyon college) Probability Presentation December 14, 2012 1 / 16 What

More information

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T 1 Derivatives Pricing and Financial Modelling Andrew Cairns: room M3.08 E-mail: A.Cairns@ma.hw.ac.uk Tutorial 10 1. (Ho-Lee) Let X(T ) = T 0 W t dt. (a) What is the distribution of X(T )? (b) Find E[exp(

More information

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying Sensitivity analysis Simulating the Greeks Meet the Greeks he value of a derivative on a single underlying asset depends upon the current asset price S and its volatility Σ, the risk-free interest rate

More information

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 MSc Financial Engineering 2012-13 CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 Department EMS, Birkbeck Introduction The assignment consists of Reading

More information

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Black-Scholes Option Pricing Black-Scholes Option Pricing The pricing kernel furnishes an alternate derivation of the Black-Scholes formula for the price of a call option. Arbitrage is again the foundation for the theory. 1 Risk-Free

More information

ACTS 4302 FORMULA SUMMARY Lessons 1-3: Introduction to Financial Derivatives, Forward and Futures Contracts.

ACTS 4302 FORMULA SUMMARY Lessons 1-3: Introduction to Financial Derivatives, Forward and Futures Contracts. ACTS 4302 FORMULA SUMMARY Lessons 1-3: Introduction to Financial Derivatives, Forward and Futures Contracts. 1. If an asset pays no dividends, then the prepaid forward price is F0,T P = S 0. 2. If an asset

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems Steve Dunbar No Due Date: Practice Only. Find the mode (the value of the independent variable with the

More information

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13. FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Asset Price Dynamics Introduction These notes give assumptions of asset price returns that are derived from the efficient markets hypothesis. Although a hypothesis,

More information

Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution

Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution III. Black-Scholes model: Derivation and solution Beáta Stehlíková Financial derivatives Faculty of Mathematics, Physics and Informatics Comenius University, Bratislava III. Black-Scholes model: Derivation

More information

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12 Introduction to Binomial Trees Chapter 12 Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 8th Ed, Ch 12, Copyright John C. Hull 2013 1 A Simple Binomial Model A stock price is currently $20. In three months

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model Credit Risk : Firm Value Model Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev Institute for Statistics and Mathematical Economics University of Karlsruhe and Karlsruhe Institute of Technology (KIT) Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev

More information

www.coachingactuaries.com Raise Your Odds The Problem What is Adapt? How does Adapt work? Adapt statistics What are people saying about Adapt? So how will these flashcards help you? The Problem Your confidence

More information

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA School of Mathematics Main Series UG Examination 2016 17 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A Time allowed: 3 Hours Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other

More information

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA Доклади на Българската академия на науките Comptes rendus de l Académie bulgare des Sciences Tome 66, No 5, 2013 MATHEMATIQUES Mathématiques appliquées ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION

More information

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives M. Vidyasagar Cecil & Ida Green Chair The University of Texas at Dallas Email: M.Vidyasagar@utdallas.edu October

More information

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem) Change of Measure Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem Radon-Nikodym derivative: Taking again our intuition from the discrete world, we know that, in the context of option pricing, we need to price the claim

More information

Actuarial Models : Financial Economics

Actuarial Models : Financial Economics ` Actuarial Models : Financial Economics An Introductory Guide for Actuaries and other Business Professionals First Edition BPP Professional Education Phoenix, AZ Copyright 2010 by BPP Professional Education,

More information

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson Economics is extremely useful as a form of employment

More information

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns 1/ 38 Introduction We analyze the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Robert Merton (1973). The standard single-period CAPM holds when

More information

B.4 Solutions to Exam MFE/3F, Spring 2009

B.4 Solutions to Exam MFE/3F, Spring 2009 SOLUTIONS TO EXAM MFE/3F, SPRING 29, QUESTIONS 1 3 775 B.4 Solutions to Exam MFE/3F, Spring 29 The questions for this exam may be downloaded from http://www.soa.org/files/pdf/edu-29-5-mfe-exam.pdf 1. [Section

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 218 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 218 19 Lecture 19 May 12, 218 Exotic options The term

More information