Managerial Risk Incentives and a Firm s Financing Policy

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Managerial Risk Incentives and a Firm s Financing Policy"

Transcription

1 Managerial Risk Incentives and a Firm s Financing Policy Sigitas Karpavičius a and Fan Yu b a Accounting & Finance, Adelaide Business School, University of Adelaide. sigitas.karpavicius@adelaide.edu.au. b Department of Applied Finance and Actuarial Studies, Macquarie University. fan.yu@mq.edu.au. September 1, 2015 Abstract This paper provides a theoretical explanation for how risk preferences of a firm s manager impact a firm s optimal financing policy and shareholder value. The developed model implies that the increase in risk aversion of the firm s manager leads to higher (lower) debt level for firms with positive (negative) growth opportunities. Further, debt level increases when both growth opportunities and managerial risk aversion move in the same direction. The predicted impacts on shareholder value are just the opposite of those on leverage. The empirical analysis generally supports all the model s predictions except those related to firms with negative growth opportunities. Key words: Capital structure; Growth opportunities; Risk preferences. JEL classifications: D21; D22; D58; G32. The authors would like to thank Terry Walter and seminar participants at 2014 Annual Summer Meeting of Economists in Vilnius, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, and University of South Australia for their helpful comments and suggestions. Corresponding author.

2 1 Introduction Managerial risk and time preferences are believed to impact corporate policies (see, for example, Graham et al., 2013). However, our knowledge both empirical and theoretical on how managerial risk preferences impact a firm s optimal financing policy is quite limited. Moreover, the empirical results on the relation between leverage and a manager s risk preferences are mixed. For example, Coles et al. (2006) and Chava and Purnanandam (2010) find that book leverage decreases with CEO vega after controlling for industry fixed effects. 1 Coles et al. (2006) find that vega does not have significant impact on leverage, if firm fixed effects are included in the model. Cain and McKeon (2014) find that book leverage decreases with CEO vega after controlling for CEO-pilot dummy and firm fixed effects. The most relevant theoretical studies for this paper are Berk et al. (2010) and Bhagat et al. (2011). The dynamic model with risk-averse employees and risk-neutral investors in Berk et al. (2010) implies that optimal leverage for firms with more risk-averse employees is lower. A dynamic principal-agent model in Bhagat et al. (2011) predicts that short-term debt (i.e., negative cash reserve), as well as total debt, should decrease with the managerial risk aversion but long-term debt should increase with managerial risk aversion. Neither Berk et al. (2010) nor Bhagat et al. (2011) test these hypotheses empirically. Graham et al. (2013) show that risk-tolerant CEOs are more likely to be hired at high-growth companies and receive riskier compensation packages, that is, they are more likely to be paid with proportionally more restricted stock, options, and bonuses and with proportionally smaller salary. This suggests that firms strategically employ CEOs with certain risk preferences based on their growth opportunities. Thus, it is likely that managerial risk incentives have different impacts on firm value and corporate policies for low- and high-growth firms. The models in Berk et al. (2010) and Bhagat et al. (2011) do not include firms growth opportunities. Thus, it is not clear whether their results are applicable for both high- and low-growth firms. In this paper, we fill this gap in the 1 Less risk averse managers have lower vega. 1

3 literature. Specifically, we analyze how risk preferences of a firm s manager impact a firm s optimal financing policy and shareholder value and whether the effects differ for high- and low-growth firms. To develop testable hypotheses, we expand the dynamic partial equilibrium model developed in Karpavičius (2014b) to include external growth opportunities. The model assumes that a firm s manager maximizes a certain objective function that positively depends on shareholder value. In each time period, the firm s manager makes several simultaneous decisions, specifically, how much capital to raise in the external equity and debt markets, how much to produce, and how much to invest in productive capital stock. A firm uses a mix of equity and debt to finance its activities; however, there are no agency costs of debt. A firm produces a single tradable final good that is sold in a competitive market. The relation among all endogenous variables and their dynamics are jointly determined in equilibrium. We assume that a firm evolves along a stable growth path that proxies the firm s external growth opportunities. The model predicts that managerial risk preferences impact firm value and financing policy for high- and low-growth firms asymmetrically. The equilibrium relations imply that share price should decrease with managerial risk aversion for firms with positive growth opportunities and vice versa, share price should increase with managerial risk aversion for firms with negative growth opportunities. Further, the model implies that not only managerial risk aversion but also an interaction between it and external growth opportunities impacts shareholder value. Stock price is adversely affected when both growth opportunities and managerial risk aversion move in the same direction. The transmission mechanism between managerial risk preferences and firm value is as follows. The model suggests that the effective discount rate decreases with managerial risk aversion for firms with positive growth opportunities, and vice versa. The discount rate reflects the riskiness of the dividend stream and includes both the likelihood of generating free cash flows and the volatility of each cash flow. Risk-averse managers of firms operating in high-growth industries are likely to undertake less risky projects and are reluctant to 2

4 invest in profitable however riskier projects. The underinvestment would adversely impact free cash flows implying that dividend stream becomes riskier. Thus, dividends would be discounted using a higher discount rate. Similarly, if a high-growth firm is run by risk-seeking manager, a firm would exploit substantially more projects (including risky ones), ensuring that a firm would have enough financial resources to pay out dividends. Therefore, effective discount rate of dividends would be smaller. This implies that firms with positive (negative) growth opportunities run by risk-seeking (risk-averse) managers are more valuable. Similarly, for firms operating in the declining industries risk-seeking managers would overinvest in risky and value destroying projects jeopardizing dividend stream. Thus, the effective discount rate would be higher for such firms. The model predicts that the impact of managerial risk preferences on leverage are, in general, just the opposite to their impact on stock price. We find that a firm s external growth opportunities and managerial risk preferences have a limited and non-monotonic impact on optimal firm size or assets. Leverage is computed as the difference between firm s assets and equity over assets. If we assume that assets are constant then the predicted impacts on leverage are just the opposite of those on equity value. Thus, the increase in risk aversion of the firm s manager leads to higher (lower) debt level for firms with positive (negative) growth opportunities. Debt level increases when both growth opportunities and managerial risk aversion move in the same direction. Thus, according to the model, firm value is directly impacted by managerial risk aversion. However, the latter affects the firm s leverage indirectly. The unstable relation between leverage and managerial risk aversion across the spectrum of growth opportunities can help explain why the empirical evidence on the relation between leverage and a manager s risk preferences is mixed. 2 A dynamic principal-agent model in Bhagat et al. (2011) predicts that short-term debt as well as total debt should decrease with the managerial risk aversion but long-term debt should increase with managerial risk aversion. Our predictions are not consistent with the theoretical results in 2 See the discussion in the first paragraph of Section 1 (Introduction). 3

5 Bhagat et al. (2011) if we assume that the majority of firms are subject to positive growth opportunities. Further, John and John (1993) use a two-period model and show that there is a negative relation between pay-performance sensitivity and leverage. However, the recent studies argue that CEO vega rather than pay-performance sensitivity (which is equivalent to CEO delta) reflects managerial risk preferences (see, for example, Low, 2009). We test the model s implications using the sample of US industrial firms during the period According to the model, growth opportunities impact the demand of the firm s products; therefore, we measure firms growth opportunities using industry 3- year sales growth. Managers with higher vega are expected to be less risk averse and vice versa (Low, 2009). The panel data regressions generally support all model s predictions except those related to firms with negative external growth opportunities. We find that share price and capital structure of these firms are generally impacted neither by external growth opportunities nor managerial risk preferences. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces a non-stationary dynamic stochastic partial equilibrium model. We develop and test our hypotheses in Section 3. Finally, Section 4 concludes. 2 The model We use the non-stationary dynamic stochastic partial equilibrium (DSPE) model developed in Karpavičius (2014b). 3 The model replicates the performance of a representative firm in a dynamic world with a changing environment. We consider a firm with an infinite life span in discrete time. The firm s manager acts completely in the best interests of shareholders and has rational expectations about the future. In each time period, the firm s manager observes the changes in the environment that are defined by stock price and productivity shocks, and makes several decisions accordingly; namely, to choose how much capital to 3 In this section, the description of the model is broadly similar to one in Karpavičius (2014b). 4

6 raise in the external equity and debt markets, how much to produce, and how much to invest in capital stock (i.e., fixed assets used in production). The firm s manager does not know the timing of future shocks but knows their distributional properties. Thus, the decisions of the manager are made knowing that the future value of innovations is random but will have zero mean. The model is non-stationary; that is, a firm is subject to exogenous growth opportunities. A firm produces a single tradable final good that is sold in a competitive market. 2.1 A firm The firm s manager has the following intertemporal objective function: ( ) E 0 β t U t, (1) t=0 where β is the subjective discount factor and reflects the time preferences of the firm s manager. We assume that the firm s manager acts in the best interests of current shareholders and maximizes a certain objective function that increases with shareholder value. 4 Thus, the instantaneous objective function, U t, is given by: U t = (P t m N t ) 1 σ, 1 σ where P m t is market value of equity per share at time t and N t is the number of shares outstanding. σ is the coefficient of constant relative risk aversion (the inverse of elasticity of substitution). The firm s manager maximizes the objective function subject to the balance sheet 4 For more details, see the discussion on page 292 of Karpavičius (2014b). 5

7 equation and asset composition of the firm: Pt b N t = Pt 1N b t 1 + Pt 1N m t Pt 1N m t 1 +RE t (2) }{{} New share issue K t = κ(d t + P b t N t ). (3) P b t is book value of equity per share at time t. The left hand side of Equation (2) is the book value of equity. Therefore, ( P m t 1 N t P m t 1 N t 1) is the proceeds from issuance of common stock. 5 The relation between market value and book value of equity is given by: P m t = P b t e qt, (4) where q t is shock to market-to-book ratio and follows the AR(1) process: q t = ρ q q t 1 + η q t, (5) where η q t N(0, σ2 q), 0 ρ q < 1, and σq 2 > 0. q t measures the deviation of market value of equity per share from the book value and proxies the information asymmetry between the firm s manager and investors. Positive q t means that stock is overvalued, and vice versa. RE t denotes retained earnings: RE t = π t d t N t 1, (6) where d t is dividends at time t. They are paid to those who owned shares at time (t 1). Thus, investors who purchase shares at time t are not entitled to receive dividends in this period. π t represents net income. 5 This term controls for market timing activities. For example, a high stock price might trigger an equity issue. Similarly, if the share price falls below its fair value, a firm might decide to repurchase some shares, as it would be in line with the interests of shareholders. If N t < N t 1 then (P m t 1N t P m t 1N t 1) is equal to the funds spent to repurchase shares. 6

8 K t is capital stock at time t. D t is new borrowing; thus, D t 1 is debt a firm pays back in period t. For simplicity, it is assumed that debt consists of one-period securities. Equation (3) implies that a firm can invest only the κ fraction of its financial assets into capital stock. This assumption is introduced in order to make the model more realistic. For example, a mean of fixed assets-to-total assets ratio is equal to for the population of Compustat firms during The rest of the financial capital, (1 κ) (D t + Pt b N t ), can be seen as working capital. Thus, κ is the outcome of firm s working capital management. Stock of physical capital, K t, evolves according to: K t = (1 δ)k t 1 + I t, (7) where δ is the capital depreciation rate. I t stands for investment. The firm s net income is given by: π t = (S t C t δk t 1 D t 1 r t 1 ) (1 τ), (8) where S t is sales revenue. C t is the amount of production input (for example, labor and raw materials). It is assumed that the unit cost of C t is one. τ is corporate income tax. r t is the interest rate for a debt obtained in time t, D t. The interest rate at which a firm can borrow funds evolves according to the following equation: ( ) r t = r D t 1 + Φ r D t + Pt bn, (9) t where r is a constant and equal to the hypothetical interest rate on corporate bonds for firms with zero leverage. The last term in Equation (9) is the risk premium related to a firm s financial leverage. Φ r > 0 is the parameter of risk premium. The definition of interest rate implies that it is an increasing function of a firm s financial leverage. In the model, debt has advantages (such as tax deductibility of interest expenses and lower costs) 7

9 and disadvantages (increased bankruptcy risk). Sales revenue, S t, is the product of output volume, Y t, and the price per output unit, p t : S t = Y t p t. (10) The price per output unit depends on demand for a firm s products and is given by the following equation: ) η (Ỹt p t = p t, (11) Y t where Ỹt and p t are respectively the stable-growth path values of demand for a firm s products and their market price at time t. 6 Parameter η is price elasticity of demand. To produce a single tradable good, a firm uses the following Cobb-Douglas technology: Y t = Ae At K α t 1C 1 α t, (12) where A is the total factor of productivity. A t is the productivity shock that follows the AR(1) process: A t = ρ a A t 1 + η a t, (13) where ηt a N(0, σa), 2 0 ρ a < 1, and σa 2 > 0. α is capital share. Equation (12) implies that production output is the increasing function of capital stock and other production inputs. We assume that it takes one period for a firm to install the newly acquired productive capital stock before it can be used in production. Dividends per share evolve according to the following equation: d t = ψ d t + (1 ψ) π t N t 1, (14) where d t is the stable-growth path value of dividends per share. ψ is subjective dividend smoothness parameter that reflects the manager s perception on the dividend policy. Equa- 6 Throughout this paper, variables with tildes denote stable-growth path values. 8

10 tion (14) shows that dividends per share, d t, consist of constant and variable parts. The constant part is equal to the stable-growth path dividends per share, d t, multiplied by ψ. 7 It is equivalent to a certain amount of cash per share distributed to shareholders at the end of each period. The variable part is proportional to the firm s net income per share. 2.2 The equilibrium In each period, the firm s manager observes the values of the shocks and parameters and chooses strategy {C t, K t, N t, D t } t= t=0 to maximize her expected lifetime utility subject to constraints (Equations (2) and (3)), initial values of debt, capital stock, share price, the number of shares outstanding and a no-ponzi scheme constraint of the form: lim j E t D t+j j i=1 (1 + r i) 0. (15) To simplify the firm s manager s optimization problem, we assume that the firm s manager does not consider an option of strategic default while running a firm. We admit that, in some cases, it could be optimal from the shareholder perspective to liquidate a firm in order to avoid further losses. However, in reality, we do not observe (at least, we are not familiar with) cases where a manager liquidated a firm with positive net assets; that is, when a firm s assets exceeded its liabilities. Usually, managers try to run a firm as long as possible; thus, creditors initiate bankruptcy procedure. However, this occurs when a firm s net assets are negative. The potential explanations for why managers do not file for bankruptcy when firms net assets are still positive include agency-related reasons (managers do not want to lose their jobs and thus salaries important source of their income), information asymmetry (managers are more likely to have better information regarding the firm s prospects than other stakeholders), and behavioral reasons (managers might be overconfident about their firm s prospects and their abilities). Thus, without loss 7 The stable-growth path value of dividends per share, d t, can be seen as the long-term historical average dividends per share or the target dividends per share. In good times, actual dividends per share exceed the stable-growth path value but in bad times, actual dividends per share are lower than it. However, the average actual dividends per share are equal to the stable-growth path value. 9

11 of generality, we assume that the firm s manager does not foresee the possibility that a firm might default. Maximization of objective function (Equation (1)), subject to the evolution of shareholder value and asset composition of a firm (Equations (2) and (3)), yields the following first-order conditions: C t : C t = (1 α)(1 η)s t, (16) ( ) σ [ ( ) : (e qt ) 1 σ Kt K t κ D Nt+1 t λ t + βe t {λ t e qt 1 N t [ +κψ (1 τ) α(1 η) S ( ) ]]} 2 t+1 δ + Φ r r Dt κ = 0, (17) K t K t [ e q t 1 ( )] [ Kt 1 : λ t N t N t 1 κ D t 1 = βe t {λ t+1 e N ( ) ]} qt t+1 Kt (N t ) 2 κ D t + ψ d t, (18) [ ] σ : (e qt ) 1 σ Kt D t κ D t λ t { [ ( Nt+1 βe t λ t e qt 1 N t ) + ψe ψ t+1 (1 τ) r [ 1 + 2Φ r κ D ]]} t K t = 0, (19) where λ t is a Lagrange multiplier. Equation (16) defines the optimal level of production input, C t, and Equations (17)-(19) are Euler conditions. The equilibrium of the model is defined by the evolution of shareholder value, asset composition constraint, first-order conditions, several variable definitions (in total 15 equations), and two shocks. 8 The number of endogenous variables is equal to the number of equations; thus, the model can be solved. To understand long-term equilibrium relations among the model s variables, we analyze the properties of the model assuming a nonstochastic environment. We solve for the non-stochastic steady state of the model by using 8 Specifically, the equilibrium of the model is defined by Equations (2)-(4), (6)-(12), (14), (16)-(19) and two exogenous processes: Equations (5) and (13). 10

12 the following procedure: we detrend non-stationarly variables, then all shocks are set to zero, the time subscripts are dropped, and the steady-state values of each endogenous variable are expressed in terms of parameters. 2.3 Stable growth path and steady state We assume that the majority of variables feature the following law of motion: X t = X 0 e gt, (20) e g = Γ t Γ t g, (21) where X t is any variable, g is a quarterly growth rate, and Γ t is growth factor. d t, p t, r t, P b t, and P m t are stationary variables. Euler conditions imply that a Lagrange multiplier, λ t, decreases at a σg rate (i.e., a Lagrange multiplier s growth factor is e σg ). 9 To obtain steady-state relations, we detrend non-stationary variables by dividing them by their growth factor. 10 When all shocks are set to zero and the time subscripts are dropped, the model reduces to 13 equations: Equation (11) cancels out and the steady-state expressions of Equations (2) and (14) are identical. To express the steady-state values of each endogenous variable in terms of parameters and constants, the number of endogenous variables must be equal to the number of equations. Thus, we assume that steady-state values of the number of shares outstanding, N, and dividends, d, are known. We re-arrange steady-state expressions of Equations (3) and (18) and ascertain that market value of equity per share in the steady state is as follows: 11 P m = βe σg ψ d 1 βe σg e g. (22) 9 λ t grows at the same rate as the marginal utility. 10 The term steady state refers to the deterministic steady state. Throughout this paper, variables with bars denote steady-state values. 11 See Appendix A for more details. 11

13 If we assume that βe σg is the effective discount factor, then the effective discount rate is as follows: R = 1 βe σg βe σg = eσg β 1. (23) If g is a smal number, growth factor, e g, can be expressed as (1 + g). Then Equation (22) can be rewritten as follows: P m = ψ d R g. (24) Equation (24) is similar to the Gordon dividend growth model, except that the latter considers whole dividends (i.e., constant and variable parts) and implies that firms with greater growth opportunities are more valuable (see Williams (1938, p. 88) and Gordon (1959)). Previous studies usually assume that share price is equal to the present value of future dividend stream. The fact that our model is consistent with Gordon dividend growth model helps validate our model. 2.4 Calibration There is no consensus in the literature on the calibration of the coefficient of relative risk aversion. Some studies report or use the value of the coefficient equal to or less than one. Huddart (1994) sets the coefficient of relative risk aversion to 0.5 and Oyer and Schaefer (2005) use a coefficient of relative risk aversion value of one. Bhagat et al. (2011) set the coefficient of risk aversion to Lambert and Larcker (1987) use the Box-Cox estimation for the sample of 370 US firms from 1970 to 1984 and find that the mean (median) coefficient of relative risk aversion is (0.400). Brown and Kim (2014) find that 95 out of 101 (or 94%) experiment participants have the coefficient of relative risk aversion smaller than 0.97 in Epstein and Zin s (1989) framework. However, the value of the coefficient of relative risk aversion of the representative agent used in macroeconomic literature is normally between one and two. For example, Khan and Tsoukalas (2012) 12 The manager s utility function in Bhagat et al. (2011) is defined as U(x) = x 1 2 γx2. 12

14 estimate that it is 1.08, Smets and Wouters (2007) report a value of The recent survey by Graham et al. (2013) finds that CEOs are very different from the rest of the population. Graham et al. (2013) report that only 8.4% of CEOs have the coefficient of relative risk aversion greater than 3.76, in contrast to 64.6% of the general population of a similar age (Barsky et al., 1997). This suggests that CEOs are significantly less risk averse than ordinary individuals and could prompt their coefficient of relative risk aversion to be smaller than one, as assumed by the previous studies (for example, Huddart (1994)). We assume that the coefficient of manager s risk aversion, σ, is set to 0.97; that is, the value that is less than but close to one. The quarterly growth rate, g, is assumed to be 0.02 which is slightly lower than the average industry sales and assets growth rate. The quarterly discount factor, β, is set to It corresponds to an 8% annual discount rate, consistent with Bhagat et al. (2011). The values of β and g imply that the coefficient of relative risk aversion, σ, should be somewhat smaller than one, as only then do the exogenous growth opportunities lead to higher shareholder value (see Equation (22)). 14 This provides a further reason to set σ to The rest of the model is calibrated similarly as in Karpavičius (2014b) (see Table 1). 15 We assume that the variables are measured quarterly. The steady-state values for the number of shares outstanding, N, and dividends, d, are normalized to one. Following macroeconomic literature, quarterly capital depreciation rate, δ, is set to and capital share in the production function, α, is set to Further, we assume that a firm can invest 28% of its financial resources in productive capital; that is, κ = 0.28). The value is similar to average net property, plant, and equipment scaled by total book value of assets for US public firms over the last two decades. The steady-state quarterly interest rate on corporate bonds, r, is set equal to It implies that the hypothetical annual interest rate for unlevered firms is 6%. It is approximately equal to Moody s Seasoned Aaa 13 In addition, many studies (for example, Justiniano et al., 2010) use a log-utility function that assumes that the coefficient of relative risk aversion is equal to one. Others, for example, Gertler et al. (2012) set the coefficient of relative risk aversion as equal to two. 14 The exact relation among share price, σ, and g is derived in Section In this paper, we do not run any simulations; therefore, we do not calibrate the parameters of the stochastic processes. 13

15 Table 1: Calibration of the parameters and steady-state values of some variables This table presents the calibrated parameter values and steady-state values of some variables. Coefficient Description Value N Shares outstanding in the steady state 1 d Dividends in the steady state 1 g Quarterly growth rate 0.02 κ Fixed assets-to-capital ratio 0.28 τ Corporate income tax rate 0.3 r Interest rate for unlevered firm α Capital share 0.33 η Price elasticity of demand 0.15 β Subjective discount factor 0.98 ψ Weight of the constant part of dividends 0.7 Φ r Parameter of risk premium 1 δ Capital depreciation rate σ Coefficient of constant relative risk aversion 0.97 Corporate Bond Yield during the period. 16 The corporate income tax rate, τ, is 0.3, which is approximately equal to an average value of corporate marginal tax rate simulated in Graham and Mills (2008). To achieve reasonable leverage ratios, we calibrate the rest of the parameters respectively. We assume that ψ is 0.7. It implies that the weight of the constant part of the dividends is 0.7. We assume that price elasticity of demand, η, is It implies that if the production supply increases by 10%, the sale price decreases by 1.5%, and vice versa. The parameter of risk premium, Φ r, is set equal to one. It implies that if a firm s leverage increases by one percentage point, the quarterly interest rate will increase by 1.5 basis points if r is The calibrated parameter values imply quite reasonable firm characteristics in the steady state. Book (market) leverage, L = D P b, is N+ D Quarterly dividend yield is and implying that shareholders earn 11.5% per year on their investment. 17 Thus, equity financing is more expensive than debt financing. Net profit margin (net income, π, over sales, S) is equal to Source: 17 Share price, P m t, is a stationary variable; therefore, capital gains are zero. 18 Table B.1 in Appendix B presents the steady-state values of all variables. 14

16 3 Results In this subsection, we analyze the implications of the model, develop and test hypotheses concerning external growth opportunities and a firm s financing policy. 3.1 Implications of the model The expression of share price in the steady state (see Equation (22)) implies that a firm s stock price is impacted by the manager s time and risk preferences, growth opportunities, and dividend policy. To investigate the relation between share price, P m, and either managerial risk aversion, σ, or patience, β, we compute partial derivatives of share price, P m, with respect to the parameters: de σg P m β = ψ [ ] 1 βe g(1 σ) 2 > 0, (25) P m σ P m σ = βψ dge σg [ 1 βe g(1 σ) ] 2, (26) < 0 if g > 0, = 0 if g = 0, > 0 if g < 0. Equation (25) shows that share price is higher for more patient managers. The result is consistent with theoretical and empirical findings in Karpavičius (2014a) who uses a stationary model in the analysis. Equation (26) suggests that greater managerial risk aversion leads to higher stock prices only for firms with negative growth opportunities. If the growth opportunities are positive, shareholder value is higher if managers are less risk averse. If a firm has no growth opportunities (i.e., g = 0) then managerial risk aversion does not impact share price per equity. The implications are driven by the effective discount rate, R, which 15

17 is used to discount dividend stream (see Equation (23)). The model suggests that the effective discount rate decreases with managerial risk aversion for firms with positive growth opportunities, and vice versa. The discount rate reflects the riskiness of the dividend stream and includes both the likelihood of generating free cash flows and the volatility of each cash flow. Risk-averse managers of firms operating in high-growth industries are likely to undertake less risky projects and are reluctant to invest in profitable however riskier projects. The underinvestment would adversely impact free cash flows implying that dividend stream becomes riskier. Thus, dividends would be discounted using a higher discount rate. Similarly, if a high-growth firm is run by risk-seeking manager, a firm would exploit substantially more projects (including risky ones), ensuring that a firm would have enough financial resources to pay out dividends. Therefore, effective discount rate of dividends would be smaller. This implies that firms with positive (negative) growth opportunities run by risk-seeking (risk-averse) managers are more valuable. Similarly, for firms operating in the declining industries risk-seeking managers would overinvest in risky and value destroying projects jeopardizing dividend stream. Thus, the effective discount rate would be higher for such firms. This leads to the following hypotheses: Hypothesis 1a: For firms with positive growth opportunities, the decrease in managerial risk aversion leads to higher share price. Hypothesis 1b: For firms with negative growth opportunities, the decrease in managerial risk aversion leads to lower share price. Equation (26) shows that not only managerial risk aversion but also an interaction between it and external growth opportunities impacts shareholder value. Thus, we compute mixed second order partial derivative of stock price, P m, with respect to g and σ: 2 P m σ g = βψ de σg { [ [ ] 1 βe g(1 σ) 3 (σg 1) 1 βe g(1 σ)] 2g(1 σ)βe g(1 σ)}. (27) The left-hand side of Equation (27) is equal to 1,859.12, assuming that the model is calibrated as in Table 1. This implies that share price, P m, decreases if both growth 16

18 opportunities, g, and managerial risk aversion, σ, increase. Due to the complexity of Equation (27), it is difficult to infer the impact of different values of growth opportunities, g, and managerial risk aversion, σ, on a value of analysis of 2 P m σ g with respect to σ and g. 2 P m σ g. Thus, we perform sensitivity We calculate the values of the mixed second order partial derivative of share price, P m, with respect to growth opportunities, g, and managerial risk aversion, σ, for different values of the two parameters. The results are presented in Table 2 where cells with negative values are shaded. We find that the partial derivative is negative mostly for small values of growth opportunities and/or when the coefficient of relative risk aversion is close to one. For example, the mixed second order partial derivative is negative if 0.02 g 0.02 and 0 σ 1.75 or if g and 0.5 σ 1.5. Lambert and Larcker (1987) use the Box-Cox estimation for the sample of 370 US firms from 1970 to 1984 and find that the mean (median) coefficient of relative risk aversion is (0.400) and that 25 th (75 th ) percentile is (1.800). Thus, it is likely that for the majority of firms, the mixed second order partial derivative of share price, P m, with respect to growth opportunities, g, and managerial risk aversion, σ, is negative. Thus, our next hypothesis is: Hypothesis 2: Share price decreases when both growth opportunities and managerial risk aversion increase (or decrease). Using Equations (22) and (A.3), one can derive the following expression for the firm s financial leverage (debt-to-assets ratio), L: L = 1 e σg κβψ d N K (1 βe σg e g, where (28) ) K = Λ 2 Λ 2 ± 2 4Λ 1 Λ 3, (29) 2Λ 1 2Λ 1 ] Λ 1 = η [δ + r κ (1 + φ r), (30) [ ] 1 Λ 2 = α(1 η) 1 τ + (1 + 2φ r)r βe σg ψ d N 1 βe (1 σ)g, (31) ( βe Λ 3 = r σg ) 2 ψ d N φ r κ[η + 2α(1 η)] 1 βe (1 σ)g. (32) 17

19 in Table 2: Sensitivity analysis of mixed second order partial derivative of market value of equity per share with respect to g and σ ( ) This table presents the sensitivity analysis of mixed second order partial derivative of market value of equity per share with respect to g and σ 2 m P σ g the steady state. The model is calibrated ( as ) in Table 1. Cells with negative values are shaded. The highlighted numbers show the calibrated values for g and σ as well as the implied value of 2 m P in the steady state. σ g g σ , , ,715 1, , E+09 5, , E+06,7750 1, , E+06 11,840 1, , ,901 19,687 2, , ,978 37,069 2, ,715 87,935 85,207 4,568 1, ,715 49, ,048 7,723 1, ,715 30,486 2,442,278 15, ,715 19, E+09 36,920 5,359 1, ,715 13, E ,131 11,753 3, , ,982 2,430,750 36,772 7,669 1, ,715 6,765 49, E ,520 26,194 3, ,715 4,981 19, , E ,264 11, ,715 3,733 9,324 30, , E , ,1071 1,715 2,839 4,941 9,256 19,381 48, E ,083 1,358 1,715 2,185 2,814 3,670 4,862 6,561 12, ,503 1,559 1,588 1,618 1,650 1,682 1,715 1,749 1,785 1,821 1,859 1,898 1, ,838 1,802 1,785 1,767 1,750 1,732 1,715 1,698 1,681 1,664 1,647 1,631 1, ,166 7,082 5,184 3,861 2,916 2,227 1,715 1,329 1, E E ,102 2, , , E ,041 31,279 9,600 3,797 1, , , E , ,061 1, ,505 27, , E , ,540 7,942 37, E ,999 9,530 1, ,483 12, ,968 1,351,225 13,586 1, ,884 5,505 37, E+09 20,040 1, ,003 1, , ,

20 Leverage L= g σ Figure 1: Sensitivity analysis of leverage with respect to growth opportunities, g, and the coefficient of relative risk aversion, σ. The arrow indicates the value of leverage implied by current calibration (see Table 1). Due to the complexity of the formula for leverage, we do not compute its partial derivatives. Instead, we perform sensitivity analysis of leverage with respect to σ and g. We calculate the leverage values for different values of the two parameters. 19 The sensitivity analysis suggests that the impacts of σ and g on leverage are, in general, just the opposite to their impacts on stock price, P m (see Figure 1). 20 Figure 1 suggests that for firms with positive (negative) growth opportunities, leverage increases (decreases) with managerial risk aversion. If the firm has no growth opportunities, the coefficient of constant relative risk aversion does not impact leverage. The unstable relation between leverage and managerial risk aversion across the spectrum of growth opportunities can help explain why the empirical evidence on the relation between leverage and a manager s risk preferences is mixed. Coles et al. (2006) and Chava and Purnanandam 19 The unreported sensitivity analysis shows that leverage decreases with the subjective discount factor, β. This is consistent with Karpavičius (2014a) who finds that firms with more patient managers (i.e., managers with a higher subjective discount factor) have proportionally less debt. 20 One can notice that the evolution of leverage is not always continuous in Figure 1. For example, if g = 0.01 and if σ increases from 3 to 1.25, leverage increases from to However, if σ = 1, leverage is And if σ increases to 3, leverage gradually reaches the value of The non-continuous behavior of leverage is likely to be caused by its non-linear nature with respect to g and σ. 19

21 (2010) find that book leverage increases with CEO vega after controlling for industry fixed effects. Coles et al. (2006) find that vega does not have significant impact on leverage if firm fixed effects are included in the model. Cain and McKeon (2014) find that book leverage decreases with CEO vega after controlling for CEO-pilot dummy and firm fixed effects (the authors do not estimate regressions without the CEO-pilot dummy). Mehran (1992) reports that firms which grant their CEOs more stock options have greater long-term debtto-assets ratio. The most relevant theoretical study for this paper is Bhagat et al. (2011). A dynamic principal-agent model in Bhagat et al. (2011) predicts that short-term debt as well as total debt should decrease with the managerial risk aversion but long-term debt should increase with managerial risk aversion. Our predictions are not consistent with the theoretical results in Bhagat et al. (2011) if we assume that the majority of firms are subject to positive growth opportunities. Further, John and John (1993) use a two-period model and show that there is a negative relation between pay-performance sensitivity and leverage. However, the recent studies argue that CEO vega rather than pay-performance sensitivity (which is equivalent to CEO delta) reflects managerial risk preferences (see, for example, Low, 2009). This leads to the following hypotheses: Hypothesis 3a: For firms with positive growth opportunities, the decrease in managerial risk aversion leads to lower debt-to-assets ratio. Hypothesis 3b: For firms with negative growth opportunities, the decrease in managerial risk aversion leads to higher debt-to-assets ratio. Lastly, Figure 1 suggests that leverage increases when both growth opportunities and managerial risk aversion move in the same direction. Our last hypothesis is as follows: Hypothesis 4: Leverage increases when both growth opportunities and managerial risk aversion increase (or decrease). Unreported sensitivity analysis indicates that σ and g have a limited and not monotonic impacts on optimal firm size. Thus, for simplicity, one can assume that assets are constant when these parameters change. Therefore, the impacts of σ and g on leverage are, in 20

22 general, just the opposite to their impacts on stock price, P m ; that is, if the change in parameter value leads to higher stock price then leverage would decrease. 3.2 Empirical results In this subsection, we present our empirical results. First of all, we describe our sample. Then we test our hypotheses by estimating the least-squares dummy variable models (the fixed effects models). We include firm and year fixed effects in the models to control for unobserved firm-level heterogeneity, time period-related factors, and the fact that financing policy is highly firm specific. The standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level to accommodate heteroscekedasticity and within-firm autocorrelation Data Our initial sample is drawn from Compustat and ExecuComp. It covers the period 1992 to We eliminate financial firms (with Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes ) since they have different capital structure and might be subject to the regulatory authority. We also exclude public utility firms (with SIC codes ) because they operate in regulated industries and their financing and capital structure decisions might be impacted by the changes in the regulatory environment. To be included in our sample, firms must have positive values in book value of assets (Compustat item AT) and sales (Compustat item SALE) and non-missing SIC code (either Compustat item SIC or SICH). Further, all the firms must be incorporated in the United States. The final data set is comprised of more than 29 thousand firm-year observations. We measure the firms growth opportunities using industry (defined by the two-digit SIC code) 3-year sales growth, adjusted for inflation using the GDP deflator ( ISAL). 22 Industry-based growth proxy is superior to those based on firm level data, as it does not include idiosyncratic disturbances and thus better reflects the firms growth opportunities. 21 Our sample starts in 1992 when ExecuComp coverage begins. 22 See Table B.2 in Appendix B for variable definitions. 21

23 Coles et al. (2006) and Low (2009) argue that CEO vega rather than delta reflects CEO s risk preferences. Managers with higher vega are expected to be less risk averse. We compute CEO vega following the methodology of Guay (1999). We find that CEO vega is highly skewed. Its mean (median) is (33.98) and standard deviation is Thus, we use either the natural logarithm of CEO vega (VEGA1) or CEO vega scaled by the book value of firm assets (VEGA2) in the analysis. Table 3 provides descriptive statistics for the sample. 3-year industry sales growth is on average, implying that annual sales of the whole industry increase by approximately 8.4% per year. Market value of equity per share ( P m ) is proxied by market-to-book ratio (Q). The mean (median) value of Q is (1.632). For robustness, we use two leverage measures: market leverage (or market debt ratio (MDEBT)) and book leverage (or book debt ratio (BDEBT)). The mean (median) value of MDEBT is (0.112). The respective statistics for BDEBT are approximately twice higher. The last four columns in Table 3 show coefficients of Pearson correlation when ISAL > 0 and ISAL < 0. There is a positive correlation between Q and CEO vega for firms with positive and negative growth opportunities (i.e., when ISAL > 0 and ISAL < 0), supporting Hypothesis 1a but not Hypothesis 1b. 23 Table 3 shows that there is a negative correlation between market leverage and CEO vega for firms with positive and negative growth opportunities. However, book leverage is positively correlated with VEGA1 and negatively correlated with VEGA2 for firms with positive growth opportunities. For firms with negative growth opportunities, the correlation coefficient between book leverage and CEO vega is negative; however, it is insignificant for VEGA1. The results support Hypothesis 3a and but not Hypothesis 3b The impact of managerial risk preferences on share price To test Hypotheses 1a and 1b, that for firms with positive (negative) growth opportunities, the decrease in managerial risk aversion leads to higher (lower) share price, we regress market-to-book ratio (Q) on vega controlling for certain firm characteristics and firm and 23 The full correlation matrix is available upon request. 22

24 Table 3: Descriptive statistics This table presents the descriptive statistics. ISAL is industry (defined by the two-digit SIC code) 3-year sales growth, adjusted for inflation using the GDP deflator. VEGA1 is the natural logarithm of CEO vega (the dollar change in the CEO s wealth for a 0.01 change in standard deviation of stock returns; see Guay (1999) for more details). VEGA2 is the CEO vega scaled by book value of assets (Compustat item AT). AGE is the number of year the company has data on COMPUSTAT. MDEBT is debt (the sum of long-term debt (Compustat item DLTT) and debt in current liabilities (Compustat item DLC)) over market value of assets (book value of assets common equity (Compustat item CEQ) + common shares outstanding (Compustat item CSHO) closing share price at the end of the fiscal year (Compustat item PRCC_F)). BDEBT is debt over book value of assets. ASSETS is the natural logarithm of book value of assets (in millions of U.S. dollars (converted into 2009 constant dollars using the GDP deflator)). Q is market value of assets divided by book value of assets. ROA is net income (Compustat item NI) divided by book value of assets. CASH is cash and short-term investments (Compustat item CHE) over book value of assets. PPE is net property, plant, and equipment (Compustat item PPENT) divided by book value of assets. CAPEX is capital expenditures (Compustat item CAPX) to book value of assets ratio. RD is research and development expense (Compustat item XRD) divided by book value of assets. RDD is equal to one when research and development expense is reported in Compustat and zero otherwise. *** and ** indicates significance at 1% and 5% levels, respectively. Correlation matrix ISAL > 0 ISAL < 0 Variable Obs. Mean Median 25 th perc. 75 th perc. St. dev. VEGA1 VEGA2 VEGA1 VEGA2 ISAL 29, *** *** VEGA1 29, *** 0.348*** VEGA2 29, *** 0.348*** MDEBT 29, *** 0.203*** 0.042** 0.256*** BDEBT 29, *** 0.128*** *** AGE 29, *** 0.148*** 0.195*** 0.182*** ASSETS 29, *** 0.250*** 0.392*** 0.297*** Q 29, *** 0.296*** 0.070*** 0.431*** ROA 29, *** 0.022*** 0.099*** 0.106*** CASH 29, *** 0.258*** 0.034* 0.364*** PPE 29, *** 0.125*** 0.079*** 0.213*** CAPEX 29, *** *** 0.052*** RD 29, *** 0.068*** 0.370*** RDD 29, *** 0.099*** 0.130*** 0.147*** 23

25 year fixed effects. Specifically, we estimate the following model separately for firms with positive and negative growth opportunities: Q it =β 0 + β 1 VEGA it + β 2 ISAL it + β 3 ASSETS it + β 4 ROA it + β 5 PPE it + β 6 CAPEX it +β 7 RD it + β 8 RDD it + λ t + µ i + ɛ it, (33) where the indices i and t correspond to firm and year, respectively, ASSETS is the natural logarithm of market value of assets (in millions of U.S. dollars (converted into 2009 constant dollars using the GDP deflator)), ROA is returns on assets, PPE is net property, plant, and equipment (NPPE) divided by book value of assets. RDD is equal to one when R&D expense is unreported in Compustat and zero otherwise, λ and µ are year and firm fixed effects, respectively. The standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level to accommodate heteroscekedasticity and within-firm autocorrelation. 24 For robustness, we estimate models using both proxies of CEO vega (VEGA1 and VEGA2). Greater either proxy of vega reflects lower risk aversion. Thus, we expect that coefficient estimates for vega are positive for the subsample of firms with positive growth opportunities and negative for the subsample of firms with negative growth opportunities. Models 1 and 2 in Table 4 show that market-to-book ratio increases with either proxy of vega for firms with positive growth opportunities. The results are significant at 0.01 level and support our Hypothesis 1a. However, they are in contrast to those in Habib and Ljungqvist (2005) who report the negative relation between Q and vega of options. 25 The results are consistent with those in Mehran (1995) who finds that ROA and Q increase with the percentage of equity held by managers and with the percentage of their compensation that is equity-based. We repeat the same analysis for firms with negative growth opportunities. Models 3-4 in Table 4 show the results. We find that vega positively impact market-to-book ratio 24 This applies to all regressions estimated in this paper. 25 The conflicting results could be due to different sample time periods, different set of control variables included in the regressions as well as different methodology (e.g., Habib and Ljungqvist (2005) do not include any fixed effects in their models). 24

External Growth Opportunities and a Firm s Financing. Policy

External Growth Opportunities and a Firm s Financing. Policy External Growth Opportunities and a Firm s Financing Policy Sigitas Karpavičius a and Fan Yu b a Flinders Business School, Flinders University, GPO Box 2100, Adelaide, SA 5001, Australia. E-mail: sigitas.karpavicius@flinders.edu.au.

More information

Impact of Different Dividend Treatment of Restricted Stock. and Option Grants on Equity Value

Impact of Different Dividend Treatment of Restricted Stock. and Option Grants on Equity Value Impact of Different Dividend Treatment of Restricted Stock and Option Grants on Equity Value Sigitas Karpavičius a and Fan Yu b a Flinders Business School, Flinders University, GPO Box 2100, Adelaide,

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and US growth Michele Cavallo Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Anthony Landry Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas October 2008

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy Yusuf Soner Başkaya Timur Hülagü Hande Küçük 6 April 212 Oil price volatility is high and it varies over time... 15 1 5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (a) Mean.4.35.3.25.2.15.1.5 1985 199 1995 2 25 21 (b) Coefficient

More information

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California.

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California. Credit and hiring Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California November 14, 2013 CREDIT AND EMPLOYMENT LINKS When credit is tight, employers

More information

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix Denote by Λ t the Lagrange multiplier attached to the capital accumulation equation. The optimal policy is characterized by the first order conditions: (1 α)a t K t α

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy Iklaga, Fred Ogli University of Surrey f.iklaga@surrey.ac.uk Presented at the 33rd USAEE/IAEE North American Conference, October 25-28,

More information

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy This version: April 2004 Benoît Carmichæl Lucie Samson Département d économique Université Laval, Ste-Foy, Québec

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) Credit Frictions and

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

A Model with Costly-State Verification

A Model with Costly-State Verification A Model with Costly-State Verification Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 19, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 1 / 47 A Model with Costly-State

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Philippe Aghion Antonin Bergeaud Timo Boppart Peter J Klenow Huiyu Li January 17, 2017 A1 Heterogeneous elasticities and varying markups In

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Slides III - Complete Markets

Slides III - Complete Markets Slides III - Complete Markets Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides III - Complete Markets Spring 2017 1 / 33 Outline 1. Risk, Uncertainty,

More information

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop, Mendoza (AER) Sudden Stop facts 1. Large, abrupt reversals in capital flows 2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic production, absorption, asset prices, credit & leverage 3. Capital,

More information

Cash Flow Multipliers and Optimal Investment Decisions

Cash Flow Multipliers and Optimal Investment Decisions Cash Flow Multipliers and Optimal Investment Decisions Holger Kraft 1 Eduardo S. Schwartz 2 1 Goethe University Frankfurt 2 UCLA Anderson School Kraft, Schwartz Cash Flow Multipliers 1/51 Agenda 1 Contributions

More information

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.edu (617) 253-7974 John E. Core* jcore@mit.edu (617) 715-4819 Abstract We measure

More information

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Takashi Kano Hitotsubashi University @HIAS, IER, AJRC Joint Workshop Frontiers in Macroeconomics and Macroeconometrics November 3-4, 2017

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance (J.Gali et al., JME 2003) Miguel Angel Alcobendas, Laura Desplans, Dong Hee Joe March 5, 2010 M.A.Alcobendas, L. Desplans, D.H.Joe

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Selahattin İmrohoroğlu 1 Shinichi Nishiyama 2 1 University of Southern California (selo@marshall.usc.edu) 2

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno,

More information

Inflation & Welfare 1

Inflation & Welfare 1 1 INFLATION & WELFARE ROBERT E. LUCAS 2 Introduction In a monetary economy, private interest is to hold not non-interest bearing cash. Individual efforts due to this incentive must cancel out, because

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 1 / 52 Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 2 / 52 Policy Practice Motivation Standard policy practice: Fiscal expansions during recessions as a means of stimulating

More information

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe August 2 211 This document contains supplementary material to Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (211). 1 A Two Sector

More information

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model Burkhard Heer Alfred Maussner CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 3311 CATEGORY 12: EMPIRICAL AND THEORETICAL METHODS DECEMBER 2010 An electronic

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Jerry Tsai University of Oxford Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 12, 2014 and NBER A The iid model This section

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Leverage and Capital Utilization

Leverage and Capital Utilization Leverage and Capital Utilization HAMILTON GALINDO Arizona State University September, 18 ABSTRACT I document the cyclical relationship between capital structure and capital utilization of US firms. Capital

More information

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications Econ PhD, UC3M Lecture 9: Data and facts Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Spring, 2016 Today s lecture A look at the data Study what data says about open

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth The analysis of why some countries have achieved a high and rising standard of living, while others have

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through Gita Gopinath Harvard and NBER Oleg Itskhoki Harvard CEFIR/NES March 11, 2009 1 / 39 Motivation Micro-level studies document significant heterogeneity in

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring Introduction The recent Great Recession has highlighted the potential importance of financial market

More information

Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing *

Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing * Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing * Julio Garín Claremont McKenna College Robert Lester Colby College Jonathan Wolff Miami University Eric Sims University

More information

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s Julen Esteban-Pretel Ryo Nakajima Ryuichi Tanaka GRIPS Tokyo, June 27, 2008 Japan in the 1990s The performance of the Japanese economy in the 1990s was

More information

Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence

Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence Sebastian Gryglewicz (Erasmus) Barney Hartman-Glaser (UCLA Anderson) Geoffery Zheng (UCLA Anderson) June 17, 2016 How do growth

More information

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University November 17, 2008 Abstract We extend a standard overlapping-generations

More information

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Leonid Kogan 1 Dimitris Papanikolaou 2 1 MIT and NBER 2 Northwestern University Boston, June 5, 2009 Kogan,

More information

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model The representative household model is a dynamic general equilibrium model, based on the assumption that the

More information

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II ECON 815 A Basic New Keynesian Model II Winter 2015 Queen s University ECON 815 1 Unemployment vs. Inflation 12 10 Unemployment 8 6 4 2 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Core Inflation 14 12 10 Unemployment

More information

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b a Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK

More information

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government spending and firms dynamics Government spending and firms dynamics Pedro Brinca Nova SBE Miguel Homem Ferreira Nova SBE December 2nd, 2016 Francesco Franco Nova SBE Abstract Using firm level data and government demand by firm we

More information

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? Andrea Gamba Alexander J. Triantis Corporate Finance Symposium Cambridge Judge Business School September 20, 2014 What do we know

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 R. Schoenle 2 J. W. Sim 3 E. Zakrajšek 3 1 Boston University and NBER 2 Brandeis University 3 Federal Reserve Board Theory and Methods in Macroeconomics

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks. 2014 Booklet No. TEST CODE: QEB Afternoon Questions: 4 Time: 2 hours Write your Name, Registration Number, Test Code, Question Booklet Number etc. in the appropriate places of the answer booklet. The test

More information

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth In the models we have presented so far there is no role for money. Yet money performs very important

More information

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption Problem Set 3 Thomas Philippon April 19, 2002 1 Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption The goal of the question is to derive the formulas on p13 of Topic 2. This is a partial equilibrium analysis

More information

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel Daniel L. Greenwald MIT Sloan EFA Lunch, April 19 Daniel L. Greenwald Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy EFA Lunch, April 19 1 / 6 Introduction

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Michael Reiter 1 Leopold Zessner 2 1 Instiute for Advances Studies, Vienna 2 Vienna Graduate School of Economics Barcelona GSE Summer Forum ADEMU,

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S. Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S. Shuhei Aoki Makoto Nirei 15th Macroeconomics Conference at University of Tokyo 2013/12/15 1 / 27 We are the 99% 2 / 27 Top 1% share

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training J. Adda, C. Dustmann,C.Meghir, J.-M. Robin February 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper evaluates the return to formal

More information

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets M. Grasselli Mathematics and Statistics McMaster University IMPA - June 28, 2006 Strategic Decision Making Suppose we want to assign monetary values to

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44 TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Marija Vukotić Banque de France NBS, April 27, 2012 NBS, April 27, 2012 1 / 44 Motivation 1 Well Known Facts about the

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Consumption and Asset Pricing Consumption and Asset Pricing Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Williamson s lecture notes (2006) ch5 and ch 6 Further references: Stochastic dynamic programming:

More information