Stress Testing in a Structural Model of Bank Behavior

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Stress Testing in a Structural Model of Bank Behavior"

Transcription

1 Stress Testing in a Structural Model of Bank Behavior Dean Corbae *, Pablo D Erasmo, Sigurd Galaasen, Alfonso Irarrazabal, and Thomas Siemsen * Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Research Department Norges Bank, Research Department Department of Economics, Ludwig Maximilians University Munich May 18, 215 Preliminary and Incomplete! Do not distribute or cite! Abstract We present a structural model for microprudential stress testing. The bank has rational expectations and optimizes over portfolio allocation and dividend policy. It performs maturity transformation and is subject to regulatory and technological constraints. Facing these occasionally binding restrictions and uncertainty about future returns and funding opportunities, the bank has an incentive to hold a buffer stock of capital even in excess of regulatory requirements. We calibrate the model using Norwegian balance sheet data and compare it to reduced form stress testing setups. Performing a stylized stress test, we show that structural predictions for capital shortfalls deviate from their ad hoc counterparts. JEL classifications: C63, G11, G17, G21, G28 Key words: Stress testing, structural model, microprudential

2 1 Introduction State of the art models for micro and macroprudential stress testing rely on exogenous, behavioral assumptions and reduced form relationships to map macro scenarios to bank behavior. This approach may exogenously restrict behavior under stress and makes it prone to the Lucas critique. For example, the important recently developed CLASS model of the New York Fed imposes constant balance sheet growth and constant asset and liability composition. Cash flow dynamics are captured by reduced form dependencies between bank specific and macro variables (see Hirtle, Kovner, Vickery, and Bhanot, 214). In addition, stress test models often impose ad hoc dividend rules that dictate the allocation of profits between dividends and retained earnings (see for example Burrows, Learmonth, and McKeown, 212, among others). Based on the dynamic framework of Corbae and D Erasmo (214), we endogeneize portfolio allocation and dividend policy. The bank in this environment is subject to regulatory and technological constraints. We perform a stylized microprudential stress testing exercise and show that structural predictions for capital shortfalls can deviate from their ad-hoc counterparts. The approach used in recent stress testing models has an important purpose: it facilitates an otherwise daunting task the mapping of the macro scenario to the dynamics in bank variables such as allowances, interest income and losses. Modeling the idiosyncratic elasticities of bank variables to some aggregate macro variables is difficult as it requires extensive knowledge of each banks business model and operational strategies. By imposing either ad hoc restrictions or reduced form estimates of these relationships, regulators can take a stance on these dimensions of bank behavior. Moreover, these simplifying assumptions allow models a higher degree of granularity for banks balance sheets, which can generally not be found in structural (e.g. DSGE) models. Nevertheless, these behavioral rules may influence stress testing results in important ways. For example, by exogenously fixing banks balance sheet size and composition, deleveraging during stress are implicitly ruled out and capital shortfalls (capital ratio below regulatory requirements) may therefore be exaggerated. In addition, when portfolio or liability compositions are kept constant over the stress horizon, fire sales of certain asset classes are ruled out and the access to wholesale funding is guaranteed. Dividend rules, moreover, crucially affect the accumulation of bank capital, the core metric of stress tests. By basing bank behavior on ad hoc rules as well as reduced form correlations, and using this framework for policy design (e.g. capital regulation), the exercise is prone to the Lucas (1976) critique. In particular, relationships are derived from historical data and may break down under various stress scenarios. Our model provides important insights on banks intrinsic motives for portfolio and dividend choices, as well as for precautionary capital accumulation. First, a structural model makes a bank s incentives and tradeoffs for portfolio and dividend choices explicit. Second, it reflects optimal bank behavior thereby requiring less discretionary assumptions. Third, a non linear optimization problem introduces a precautionary capital motive for the bank. Facing potentially binding regulatory and technological constraints, together with uncertainty about future returns and funding opportunities, the bank has an incentive to hold a buffer stock of capital even in excess of any regulatory requirements. This precautionary motive has to be neglected in reduced form stress testing setups, as they do not provide a framework to model expectations. We therefore believe that our model is a valuable extension to state of the art stress testing literature. 1

3 Related literature The aim of this paper is to merge two strands of literature that until now coexisted: the literature on microprudential stress testing and on structural models of bank behavior. Summer (27) attributes the origins of models used today for microprudential stress testing to the quantitative risk management frameworks employed in financial institutions to assess portfolio risk exposures (see for example McNeil, Frey, and Embrechts, 25). These models fully explain exposures through a battery of exogenous, stochastic risk factors that determine idiosyncratic loss distribution of asset classes. Following this approach, state of the art micro and macroprudential stress test frameworks impose exogenous stress scenarios that drive risk characteristics of balance sheets. Two complementary approaches are used to map the exogenous macro scenario to bank specific variables: reduced form, backward looking relationships and ad hoc behavioral restrictions. 1 In the first approach, the correlations between bank specific variables and macro variables are estimated empirically, using historical dependencies. For macroprudential stress tests, Acharya, Engle, and Pierret (214) estimate a bivariate GARCH model that measures correlation between a bank s market capitalization and an equity price index to capture the bank s exposure to aggregate risk. Covas, Rump, and Zakrajcek (214) employ a dynamic panel quantile framework, which allows for non linear dynamics, to map macro variables to balance sheet and cash flow dynamics. For microprudential stress tests, the important, recently developed CLASS model (Hirtle, Kovner, Vickery, and Bhanot, 214) employs linear reduced form equations to map macro dynamics to banks cash flow (for a similar approach see Burrows, Learmonth, and McKeown, 212, among others). The second (and complementary) approach is to impose ad hoc restrictions on bank behavior. These restrictions have the advantage that they easily allow for non linear relationships. Behavioral restrictions are mostly imposed on banks dividend policy and balance sheet size and composition. For example, for Dodd-Frank act stress tests, dividends are assumed to remain constant at the pre stress scenario level (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 213). Hirtle, Kovner, Vickery, and Bhanot (214) allow for dynamic dividend adjustment during stress: dividend policy follows an exogenous error correction process with a constant divided target of 45 % of post tax income. For the 211 euro area wide stress test banks portfolio size was set to remain constant during the stress horizon (EBA, 211). Hirtle, Kovner, Vickery, and Bhanot (214) assume that banks balance sheet continue growing by 1.25 % per quarter and that portfolio shares remain constant under stress. These two approaches facilitates an otherwise daunting task the mapping of the macro scenario to dynamics of bank variables such as allowances, interest income and losses. Modeling the idiosyncratic elasticities of bank variables to aggregate macro variables is difficult as it requires extensive knowledge of banks business model and operational strategies. Imposing either ad hoc restrictions, or estimates of these relationships, allows to capture reduced form dependencies between any variables of interest. This enables richer models with a high degree of granularity on banks balance sheets and income statements, without requiring extensive information on bank specific structural parameters. However, these models are prone to misspecification and the Lucas (1976) critique. Using reduced form frameworks to derive out of sample counterfactuals requires historical relationships to be invariant to severe stress (Borio, Drehmann, and Tsatsaronis, 212) and policy shifts. This is especially a concern since correlations are not derived from past 1 For a survey on state of the art stress testing models see for example Foglia (29) or Borio, Drehmann, and Tsatsaronis (212). 2

4 stress episodes but rather from normal business cycles that can span various regulatory regimes. In addition, both ad hoc rules and reduced form estimates are silent on the role of expectations in banks behavior, thereby neglecting any anticipatory and precautionary motives. Related to that, banks structural incentives for portfolio allocation and dividend policy, the driving forces of observed data patterns, cannot be identified. Ad hoc behavioral restrictions also significantly affect stress test results. For example, by exogenously fixing banks balance sheet size and composition, frameworks implicitly rule out the possibility of deleveraging during stress, and may therefore exaggerate capital shortfalls (capital ratio below regulatory requirements). In addition, when portfolio or liability compositions are kept constant over the stress horizon, fire sales of assets are ruled out and the access to wholesale funding is guaranteed. Ad hoc dividend rules, moreover, crucially affect the accumulation of bank capital, the core metric of stress tests. There is evidence that during the recent financial crisis, US bank continued paying high dividends even though capital was running low and loan losses loomed high (Acharya, Gujral, Kulkarni, and Shin, 211). This points toward a more complex function of dividends (e.g. as a market signal) than can be captured by static or backward looking rules. We contribute to state of the are stress test literature by replacing ad hoc portfolio allocation and dividend policy by optimizing behavior derived from a structural model of banking. A growing strand of macro banking literature focuses on the effects of micro and macroprudential regulation in light of the soon to be implemented Basel III framework. However, these models mostly focus on specific regulatory requirements and policy tools and therefore restrict modeling of banks balance sheets, income statements and sources of risk to variables of interest. Thus, they do not feature the degree of granularity of balance sheet and income statement required for an informative stress test. The Basel III framework imposes liquidity requirements, prompt corrective actions and four layers of capital requirements: minimum, conservation, counter cyclical and systemic requirements (Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 211). The important contribution by De Nicolo, Gamba, and Lucchetta (214) analyzes the interaction of these three regulatory tools in a structural, partial equilibrium model of a representative bank with a parsimonious loan profit function that does, unlike the model we are using, not explicitly model credit default, a crucial concern in stress tests. They show that an optimal minimum capital requirement exists and that liquidity requirements always reduce lending, while both are efficiency dominated by prompt corrective actions. In a medium scale DSGE model with costly state verification and bank default Clerc, Derviz, Mendicino, Moyen, Nikolov, Stracca, Suarez, and Vardoulakis (214) also find that welfare benefits are concave with respect to minimum capital requirements. Due to the complexity of the model, it is solved by first order perturbation around a steady state in which the capital requirement is binding. It is therefore not suitable for stress testing as it cannot model capital shortfalls and since shocks are assumed small enough for the model to remain in the proximity of its steady state, thus neglecting non linear crisis dynamics. Corbae and D Erasmo (214) study the effects of changes in minimum capital requirements on industry wide loan supply and competition structure in a dynamic game between a big bank with market power and a price taking fringe sector. They find that higher requirements induce a reduction in aggregate lending and a more concentrated industry with higher loan rate. Our model is closely related to theirs, however, we allow for a more granular balance sheet and maturity transformation, while abstracting for industry equilibrium by considering the single bank s decision problem. Rios-Rull, Takamura, and Terajima (214) focus on the effects of capital requirements on bank s dividend policy. In their model the misalignment between 3

5 bank manager s and bank owner s objectives induces excess dividend payment and high equity costs. While minimum capital requirements are useful for reducing moral hazard due to limited liability, conservation requirements are targeted more directly at dividend policy and are thus more efficient in restricting high dividend payments in a crisis. Our paper is also related to the contribution of Bianchi and Bigio (214). There, the authors study the effects of banks portfolio choice on the conduct of monetary policy in a DSGE model with an interbank market. Looking through the lens of their model on the recent financial crisis, they conclude that the most likely scenario that induced the observed dynamics is a initial reduction in loans supply due to an increased precautionary motive in the face of higher interbank uncertainty, which induced adverse effects onto the real economy and led to a subsequent reduction in loan demand. The setup focuses, however, on the liquidity risk in banks balance sheets due to maturity mismatch and abstracts from any credit risk, i.e. loans are considered safe. Since credit risk is an important factor for banks equity losses, our model features both liquidity risk (through stochastic deposit supply) as well as credit risk. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 provides some facts on bank and crises heterogeneity. Section 3 lays out the model, Section 4 shows our preliminary calibration and Section 5 conducts simulation exercises. Finally, Section 6 concludes. 2 Facts about bank and crises heterogeneity Our framework aims at understanding bank behavior during stress episods. There are two important dimensions to banks survival probabilities. First, the equity position with which banks enter stress. Second, stress severity and duration. Heterogeneity along these two dimensions are therefore key determinants of stress outcomes. This section provides some empirical facts on these two sources of heterogeneity. 2.1 Equity heterogeneity We consider the Norwegian banking sector. Norges Bank s ORBOF database provides balance sheet, income statement and interest rate data for individual Norwegian financial intermediaries. These include a total 266 banks and 47 credit institutions available for different points in time. Since 27 Norwegian banks are allowed to issue covered bonds (OMFs) through credit companies (kredittforetaks). These companies have become an important funding source for banks as well as an important source of loans for the real economy (see Raknerud and Vatne, 213). To account for the fact that banks outsourced an important part of business to credit companies, we do not consider isolated banks but merge banks with their corresponding credit companies. We call this unit of observation banking group (BG). At this level of aggregation we have full data for four relevant BGs. As can be seen in Table 1 the Norwegian banking industry is highly concentrated. The six BGs account on average for 8 % of total industry assets, 71 % of retail loans and for 76 % of commercial loans. Asset shares drop rapidly from the largest to the second largest BG and again from the third to the fourth largest. Therefore, our sample of BGs covers big, dominant groups as well as smaller fringe groups. 4

6 Table 1: Shares in aggregate market Asset Share Loan market share retail C&I BG BG BG BG accumulated Note: Shares are computed as 1997Q1 214Q2 averages, source: ORBOF Capital ratios are key measures in a stress test. They determine banks abilities to cope with losses under counterfactual stress scenarios. Table 2 shows core capital ratios both at 211Q1 (Basel III framework was announced in December 21) as 211Q1-214Q2 averages with standard deviation and for the last observation available (214Q2). The two commercial banking groups, BG1 and BG3, now hold capital ratios close to the maximum Basel III requirement (13 %), which they started building up after its announcement. The savings and loans banking groups, BG2 and BG5, now hold capital ratios above the maximum Basel III requirement. Their capital equipments were already close to or above 13 % at Basel III announcement and experienced less volatility. The smallest banking group holds highest excess equity. The two bottom rows show cross sectional mean and standard deviation. Average core capital ratio increased over time, while dispersion decreased from 2.7 pps to 1.5 pps. Table 2: Core Capital Ratios 211Q1 211Q1-214Q2 (std.dev.) 214Q2 BG (1.7) 13.6 BG (.8) 14.4 BG (2.) 13.7 BG (.6) 17.2 mean std.dev Note: Basel III was announced in December 21. Source: ORBOF 2.2 Crises heterogeneity Economic crises have multiple dimensions. They have different duration and severity, they originate in different markets and are of different international extent. Consequently, their effects on banks equity are diverse. Barro and Ursua (28) provide an empirical analysis of macroeconomic crises since 187 for multiple countries. Figure 1 shows how GDP crises differ with respect to size of contraction, duration and recovery time back to HP-trend. The red line indicates the mean of the distributions. The mean GDP contraction is 21 % with a mean duration of 2.9 years and a mean recovery time of 1.7 years. The challenge for informative stress testing is, besides the choice of framework, the choice of macro scenario. It must be server enough to impose stress on banks balance sheets, while also capturing relevant sources of future stress. 5

7 Figure 1: Crises Heterogeneity Distribution of crises size 3 4 Duration of crises 5 Duration of recovery GDP drop (%) years (peak to trough) years (trough to trend) Notes: based on 36 countries since 187. A crisis is defined as GDP drop larger than 9.5 %. Recovery time defined as years from trough back to GDP trend (λ = 6.25). Red line indicates mean. Source: Barro and Ursua (28) and WDI to extend sample until 213. We will target moments of the average Barro and Ursua (28) crisis to calibrate our macro scenario. By using GDP crises across countries instead of special financial or banking crises, we account for the uncertainty in designing relevant macro scenarios for stress testing. One the one hand, purely backward looking design is prone to the false conclusion that the next crisis will be like the last crises. On the other hand, the identification of future trouble spots is difficult. By considering diverse GDP crises, our approach is agnostic to the exact nature of a crisis. Instead, we take GDP crises characteristics as reduced form reflections of the underlying source of crisis and allow these characteristics to affect banks differently through their impact on non performing loans. 3 A model of bank behavior Our model is a modified version of Corbae and D Erasmo (214) adopted to a single bank s decision problem. In period t the bank provides loans L ts to sector s S. We follow De Nicolo, Gamba, and Lucchetta (214) and assume that loans have an exogenous 1 maturity 1+χ s such that each period a constant fraction χ s of loans L ts matures. While sector specific maturity is exogenous, the fact that the bank endogenously chooses its loan exposure to the different sector induces an endogenous aggregate loan portfolio maturity. The bank s external funding D t has one period maturity. Therefore, the bank engages in maturity transformation by converting short term funding into long term loans. Each period t is divided into to sub periods: the beginning and the end of period. Beginning of period At the beginning of period t the bank is hit by two idiosyncratic shocks: (1) a shock δ t to maximum external funding capacity and (2) a shock ρ t to external funding costs. Both shocks follow a first-order Markov process in which δ t with transition matrix G(δ t, δ t+1 ) and ρ t Υ with H(ρ t, ρ t+1 ), respectively. 6

8 Constraint 1 (Capacity Constraint). The idiosyncratic shock to maximum funding capacity δ t induces an upper bound on external funding D t. D t δ t, (3.1) The bank is also exposed to aggregate uncertainty, captured by an exogenous GDP shock z t evolving according to a first-order Markov process with z t Z and transition matrix F(z t, z t+1 ). The GDP shock influences the share of non-performing loans on the bank s asset side. There are s + 1 endogenous state variables: the capital stock a t and the heritage loan stocks l ts. Therefore, the beginning of period state space is given by {z t, a t, {l ts } s, δ t, ρ t }. Given these states the bank makes beginning of period portfolio choices. On the liability side it decides on how many exogenous one period funding D t δ t at exogenous net costs ρ t to take on. D t has to be repaid at the beginning of period t + 1 when the new capacity shock δ t+1 materializes. External funding, together with bank capital a t, can either be invested into perpetual securities A t or into risky loans L ts. Consequently, balance sheet identity requires A t + s L ts = D t + a t (3.2) Since we assume a constant fraction χ s of loans L ts to come due at the beginning of every period, without further adjustment, the inherited loans stock l ts gradually decreases over time. The bank can decide, however, to reduce loan exposure faster than at rate χ s. In this case it must pay quadratic adjustment costs on disinvestment I ts = L ts l ts < Ψ s (I ts ) = I(I ts < )ψ s I 2 ts, s S, (3.3) where I( ) denotes the indicator function and ψ s is the cost coefficient. Marginal adjustment costs are increasing in I ts to reflect increasing reductions on loans face value if a large fraction of the loan stock has to be liquidated and sold off. These costs can capture both liquidation costs that arise when loans are sold off and fire sale costs due to sudden and large reductions in the loans stock. In contrast, increasing the loan exposure by choosing I ts does not require any additional adjustment costs. Any potential monitoring and screening costs are captured by proportional non interest expenses, c s, as shown below. Moreover, the bank is constrained in its investment choice by a regulatory capital requirement Constraint 2 (Capital Constraint). ( ) ϕ L ts + wa t a t, (3.4) s which requires to hold ϕ units of equity for each unit of risk weighted assets s L ts + wa t where w denotes the relative risk weight of securities to loans. Securities pay a safe interest of r a and bank loans generate an interest payment of r L ts. However, a fraction (1 P t+1s ) of bank loans are non performing. In that case it pays no interest and a fraction λ s has to be written down, reducing cash flow and tomorrows loan stock l t+1s. We assume that P t+1s = P(r L ts, z t, z t+1 ). 7

9 End of period End of period is initiated with the realization of the new aggregate shock z t+1. 2 This shock determines the fraction of non performing loans (1 P(rts, L z t, z t+1 )) in the bank s portfolio. At this stage, bank s cash flow is given by C t+1 = π t+1 (3.5) where π t+1 captures end of period cash profits. These are given by π t+1 = s [{ } Pt+1s rts L c s Lts Ψ s (I ts ) ] + r a A t ρ t D t κ, (3.6) where c s denotes proportional non interest expenses of loan providence such as screening and monitoring costs and κ are fixed costs. Note that there are no principal cash flows for L ts, A t and D t. Moreover, we assume that loan interest rates are floating. This is reflected in the fact that the contemporaneous interest rate r L ts applies to all loans L ts = l ts + I ts. This assumption reduces the state space, as we do not need to keep track of the whole history of loan providence. Note that Equations (3.5) and (3.6) imply that non performing loans neither pay interest nor principal. Banks now decide on their dividend policy, D t+1. They can distribute the cash flow to equityholder or retain earnings. Moreover, they have access to a short run liquidity market in which they can borrow liquidity at net costs r b. Let B t+1 < denote retained earnings and B t+1 > denote short run borrowing. Then, dividends are determined as The bank is also constrained in its dividend policy: Constraint 3 (Dividend Constraint). D t+1 = C t+1 + B t+1 (3.7) D t+1 [σd t, σd t ] (3.8) that is, we assume that contemporaneous dividend payments cannot deviate more than a factor σ (σ) above (below) previous period dividend. Constraint 3 can account for factors outside the model that induce sluggish dividend adjustment during crises (see Acharya, Gujral, Kulkarni, and Shin, 211, for the recent financial crisis). A reason for this can be asymmetric information between banks, such that dividends act as signaling device to peer institutions and the market. In this case we would have σ < 1 and σ = +. 3 If σ = and σ = +, the constraint is equivalent to ruling out seasoned equity offering, as dividends are constrained below at zero. Also, this constraint can capture the Basel III conservation requirement, which prohibits dividend payments if Tier 1 equity is below a threshold. In this case σ = σ =. Equations (3.7) and (3.8) together imply that if the bank wants to stay in the market despite negative cash flows, it has to tap the short term liquidity market (B t+1 > ) to not violate Constraint 3. If, however, the continuation value of operating in the market is low, the bank may prefer to exit the market. In contrast, if cash flow is high, the bank may not want to pay everything out as dividends but rather wants to retain some 2 We use the timing convention that all variables, which are determined after the realization of the aggregate shock z t+1 have time index t For now, we don t consider signally issues since we work in a model with perfect information. 8

10 earnings (B t+1 < ) to raise next periods initial capital a t+1. Short term borrowing requires collateral in form of securities. Constraint 4 (Collateral Constraint). The gross repayment of short term borrowing must not exceed contemporaneous security holdings: with r b = if B t+1. (1 + r b )B t+1 A t, (3.9) If banks do not have enough securities for covering a negative cash flow, they are forced to exit the market as Constraint 3 is violated. An alternative interpretation of Equation (3.9), on which we will drawn for the stress testing exercise, is that security holdings A t are not liquid and require liquidation costs 1 + r b if they are sold to cover negative cash flow. Following this interpretation r b is a measure for the fire sale price of securities upon stress. The higher r b, the higher is the discount, relative to face value, the bank has to accept when liquidating assets. Constraint 4 also reflects our assumption that loans on the balance sheet cannot be used as collateral for short term borrowing. Each period a fraction χ s of loans exogenously matures at the beginning of each period. Non performing loans neither generate interest nor principal repayment. Moreover, the bank writes down a fraction λ s on each dollar of non performing loan. Therefore, beginning of period t + 1 heritage loans are given by l t+1s = [1 χ s ]P t+1s L ts + [1 λ s ] (1 P t+1s ) L ts (3.1) Also, at the beginning of period t + 1, before any choice is made, the short term liquidity market is clears, i.e. B t+1 is repaid and principal repayment of performing loans occurs. Thus, beginning of next periods capital a t+1 is given by a t+1 = A t + s [l t+1s + χ s P t+1s L ts ] (1 + r b )B t+1 D t (3.11) As discussed above, retained earnings (B t+1 < ) raises a t+1. Figure 2 summarizes the timing. {z t, a t, {l ts } s, δ t, ρ t } Figure 2: Timing Assumption z t+1 {z t+1, a t+1, {l t+1s } s, δ t+1, ρ t+1 } z t+2 A t, {I ts } s, D t C t+1 A t+1, {I t+1s } s, D t+1 C t+2 stay exit B t+1, D t+1, a t+1, {l t+1s } s Due to the recursive nature of the bank s problem, we can drop time subscripts. Let 9

11 x t = x and x t+1 = x. Banks objective is to maximize expected franchise value, E t + k=t+1 β k D k, (3.12) where β is equityholders constant discount factor. The value of the bank at the beginning of the period is given by V (z, a, {l s } s, δ, ρ) = D δ A + L s a + D s ( ) ϕ L s + wa a s L s = L d s, s S max β E z zw (A, {I s } s, D, δ, ρ, z ) A,{I s} s,d s.t. The last constraint requires bank specific loan market clearing, where L d s is bank specific loan demand from sector s. In contrast to Corbae and D Erasmo (214) we assume exogenous loan demand L d s = L d s(rs L, z) with L d s/ rs L and L d s/ z. End of period value is given by { W (A, {I s } s, D, δ, ρ, z ) = max W x=1 (A, {I s } s, D, δ, ρ, z ), W x= (A, {I s } s, D, δ, ρ, z ) }, x {,1} with the exit value given by { [ ({ ) W x=1 (A, {I s } s, D, δ, ρ, z ) = max, ξ (r L s + χ s )P s + χ s [1 λ s ](1 P s) cs} Ls s ] } + (1 + r a )A (1 + ρ)d κ (3.13) where the lower bound zero implies limited liability upon exit and ξ is the salvage fraction the banks receive from liquidating assets. If limited liability kicks in, depositors are not entirely repaid. The continuation value is given by { W x= (A, {I s } s, D, δ, ρ, z ) = max D + E (δ,ρ ) (δ,ρ)v (z, a, {l s} s, δ, ρ ) } B A 1+r b D = C + B s.t. a = A + [l s + χ s P sl s ] (1 + r b )B D s l s = [1 χ s ]P sl s + [1 λ s ] (1 P s) L s, s S 1

12 4 Calibration Our calibration approach follows Corbae and D Erasmo (214) closely. One period corresponds to a quarter. The bank in the model corresponds to a banking group in the data. A banking group includes both the retail banking units as well as the credit companies which emerged in Norway in 27 and have since become an important funding source for banking groups (see Raknerud and Vatne, 213). We allow for two sectors s S = {retail, C&I}. The data is extracted from the Norges Bank ORBOF database, which provides information about individual Norwegian banks balance sheets, income statements and interest rates. All parameters are in real terms. We deflate using total CPI index. Let variables with superscript i denote variables calibrated to bank group i and variables without superscript aggregate variables. Exogenous shock processes The aggregate shock, z Z = [z H z L z C z R ], follows a four state Markov process. We need to calibrate the state vector Z and the transition matrix F(z, z) R 4 4. In our model, z is the only source of aggregate fluctuations. Therefore, it captures normal business cycle fluctuations, as well as the aggregate component of the stress scenario. We allow for two states to capture normal fluctuations: a high state, z H, and a low state, z L. These states and their transition probabilities are calibrated to capture the normal Norwegian business cycle. There is one crisis state, z C, and on recovery state, z R, which captures a smooth transition out of crises. Theses states can be calibrated to reflect any exogenous stress scenario. The calibration we provide here is to illustrate the mechanics of our model. Since crisis observations in Norway alone are limited, we rely on the Barro and Ursua (28) disaster dataset, which captures boom bust cycles for 36 countries between 187 and 28. We extend the data until 213 and identify GDP peaks and troughs using the method suggested in Barro (26). A crisis is defined as a GDP contraction of larger or equal 9.5 %. We derive the crisis calibration from the average of the 177 international crises observations (see Section 2). Figure 3 shows the log GDP series for Norway between 187 and 213 together with identified peaks and troughs. From the 144 Norwegian annual observations, 118 are normal business cycle years and 26 are crises years. The average contraction from a business cycle peak to a non crises trough is 2.58 % in Norway. We normalize z H to unity and set z L = z H.258 =.9742 to match the average contraction. Turning to the crisis state, we find that the average GDP contraction from peak to crisis trough is 2.56 %. Since the normal business cycle peak is identified by z H we set z C = z H.256 = To calibrate the recovery state z R, we measure the average recovery time from crisis trough back to GDP trend. We find that it takes on average years to recover back to trend. We identify z R as the average GDP level after half the recovery time: z R =

13 Figure 3: Norwegian GDP log Index (26=1) GDP Trend Peak Trough Crisis Notes: Peak and troughs identified by peak trough method of Barro (26). Data from Barro and Ursua (28) and extended using WDI database. Let P ij denote the probability of switching from state i to j. For the transition matrix F(z, z) we impose the following zero restrictions: P HH P HL F(z, z) = P LH P LL P LC P CC P CR, P RL P RR i.e. from z H only z L can be reached, the only way into a crisis is through z L, the recovery state z R can only be reached from the crisis state and from the recovery state only z L can be reached. To derive the switching probabilities between normal times state we follow Barro and Ursua (28) and estimate these probabilities as the ratio of normal times boom bust cycles (13) over normal time years (118). Then, P HL = P LH = 13/118 =.112 and P HH = = As in Barro and Ursua (28) we calibrate the probability of leaving normal times and entering a crisis as the ratio of crises observations over normal time years. In our dataset we have 544 yearly observations including 515 crises years over 177 crises and 4925 normal time years. Therefore P LC = 177/4925 =.359 and P LL = 1 P LH P LC = Along the same line, the probability of leaving a crisis and starting a recovery is estimated as the ratio of crises observations of crises year, i.e. P CR = 177/515 = Thus, P CC = 1 P CR = Finally, we calibrate the recovery persistence to match the average recovery duration (trough to trend) of years in the data. Since the expected recovery duration is given by 1 1 P RR, we have P RR =.66 and P RL =.34. We transform the annual probabilities to quarterly probabilities, P Q ij, through P ii = calibration. ( P Q ii) 4. Figure 4 summarizes our crisis 12

14 Figure 4: Crisis Calibration duration: 2.9 yrs recovery: 3. yrs z H z L recession: 2.6 % z R contraction: 21 % recovery growth: 19 % z C trough For the idiosyncratic deposit supply shock δ i = [δh i δi N δi H ], we proceed similar. First, we derive the quarterly volume of external funding, d i t, by summing up bank i s outstanding deposits, bonds and commercial papers. We estimate the following relationship for the period 1987Q4 214Q2: log(d i t) = (1 ρ d )k + ρ d log(d i t 1) + k 1 t + k 2 t 2 + k 3t + v d t, (4.1) where t denotes a time trend, k 3t are quarterly fixed effects and vt d N(, σd 2 ). We use the estimates ˆρ d and ˆσ d to discretize log(d i t) with Tauchen and Hussey (1991). Thereby, we set the middle state δn i equal to bank group i s average share of external funding in the aggregate Norwegian banking market. The discretization algorithm also provides us with G i (δ, δ). For the shock to bank i s external funding cost we calibrate the state vector ρ Υ i = [ρ i H ρi N ρi L ] and the corresponding transition matrix Hi (ρ, ρ) R 3 3 to match a rough cost measure. As shown in Section 2 a bank s stable external funding sources consist by a large part of deposits and bonds. The latter are mainly covered bonds issued by a banking group s credit companies. Therefore, we approximate total funding costs using a weighted average of deposit costs and interest expenses on bonds and commercial paper. We construct a quarterly series for interest expanses on bonds and commercial paper by dividing interest expenses on bonds and commercial paper in a given quarter by the total stock of bonds and commercial paper in this quarter. We weight costs on deposits and costs on external funding by their shares in the banking liability side. We then identify ρ i N with average funding costs between 21Q4 to 214Q2, ρi L with funding costs one standard deviation below mean and ρ i H with funding costs one standard deviation above mean. The maximum likelihood estimator for transition probability H i (ρ k, ρ l ), i.e. from state l to k, is the ratio of observations funding costs switched from state l to k to the number of state l observations. External calibration We calibrate net return on securities, ri a, to match the average ratio of interest income from bonds and certificates in a given quarter to the total stock 13

15 of bonds and certificates in the same quarter. We take the time average from 1997Q1 to 214Q2. To calibrate the proportional net non interest expanses, c i, to we use the ratio of wage and other staff costs minus net provision income over total gross lending. This choice of items reflects the assumption that to some degree staff costs and provision incomes are proportional to a banking group s share of loan providence and that these items should therefore not be allocated to fixed costs κ. Due to a lack of data, we cannot calibrate loss given default, λ i, by sector but instead assume that it is identical between retail and commercial sector. We therefore match total loss on lending. In the model total loss on lending is given by s (1 Pi st+1)l i stλ i s. To calibrate λ i consistently, we first derive a time series measure for (1 Pst+1) i as the ratio of new non performing loans by sector over gross lending by sector. 4 We then calibrate λ i as the ratio of total loss on lending over total non performing loans ( s (1 Pi s)l i s) taking the 1997Q1 to 214Q2 time average. In contrast to Corbae and D Erasmo (214) our model does not feature an entrepreneurial sector. Instead we calibrate the inverse demand equation ris(l L is, z) as well as the entrepreneurial risk reaction function in normal times P is (ris, L z ) directly from the data. To this end, we assume (1 P i st+1) = g(r L ist, z ) (4.2) r L ist = f(l i st, L i st, z), (4.3) where rist L denotes the loan rate of banking group i to sector s in quarter t, L ist is detrended loan supply of i to s in t and L ist is detrended loan supply of all other banking groups except i to s in t. z the continuous counterpart to the discretized shock z derived from HP-filtered GDP. (1 Pst+1) i is the fraction of non performing loans of i in s at end of t constructed as discussed in footnote 4. To account for stationarity of our model, we detrend loan supply from i to s by subtracting the aggregate linear market trend in sector s between 1987Q4 and 214Q2 from from time series L i st and L i st. By including L i st to Equation (4.3) we can, to some degree, capture the competitive environment with which banking group i interacts. Using least square regression we estimate Equation (4.2) as (1 P i st+1) = α + α 1 r L ist + α 2 z t+1 + u i st, (4.4) based on normal times observations. Therefore, this estimated equation is used in the model to describe the dynamics of non performing loans in states z H and z L. Non performing loans in crisis states z C and z R are calibrated based on banking crisis date in Laeven and Valencia (212). Over all documented crises, average peak non performing loans are 14.4% of total loans. For this simulation exercise, we assume that peak non performing loans occur on impact, when entering a crisis. Therefore 1 P i st+1(z = z L, z = z C ) = When staying in a crisis for multiple periods, non performing loans are assumed to be 5 % lower than on impact: 1 P i st+1(z = z C, z = z C ) = When leaving the crisis trough and entering a recovery non performing loans are calibrated as follows: we linearly regress log peak non performing loans from Laeven and Valencia (212) for each identified crisis on peak output loss, implied by HP-filtered real 4 ORBOF only provides data on new non performing loans from 21Q4 on. Therefore, we impute a time series going back until 1997 by computing the fraction of new non performing loans in the stock of non performing loans for the quarters available, take time average and then assume this fraction to be the same for the quarters where no data is available. 14

16 GDP (λ = 6.25). Using this exponential dependency, we derived the implied reduction in peak non performing loans when going from z C to z R. This gives us 1 P i st+1(z = z C, z = z R ) = To calibrate Equation (4.3) we use the estimates found in Akram (214). There, the author shows that the aggregate long run relationship between loan demand and real interest rate and GDP for Norway can be described by 5 r L t,c&i =.4726 z t.2141 log (L t,c&i ) (4.5) r L t,retail =.7368 z t.2632 log (L t,retail ) (4.6) From these equations we trace out the idiosyncratic demand curves, banking group i faces. To this end we adjust the semi elasticity of loan demand to target the average net interest margin, defined as r L is r D is, of banking group i. We adjust the constant to target i s loan market share in the aggregate market. We first adjust the sector specific aggregate demand curves from above to account for our normalization of the aggregate state, z t. Specifically, we adjust the constant to match the average aggregate real loan rate and the average aggregate loan to GDP ratio, Ls between 21Q4 and 214Q2. This determines sector specific aggregate loan demand L st (r L ts, z t ). We then derive the group specific constant by computing the average loan market share (over the same time period) of group i in sector s, m i s, and subtracting the implied loan demand that all other banks face, (1 m i s) [ Ls z ], from aggregate loan demand. Thus, idiosyncratic loan demand is given by L i st = L st (r L ts, z t ) (1 m i s) [ Ls z ], {i, s} (4.7) Adjustment costs are only paid if the bank liquidates the loan stock faster then the rate of maturity. This happens exclusively during crisis times, because in normal times the return on lending is positive. Therefore, the adjustment cost coefficient is set to target the relative variance of aggregate loans of bank i to GDP variance during the Norwegian banking crisis of We set fixed cost κ to target the average annual equity return of bank i. We calibrate to maturity parameters χ retail and χ C&I to an average maturity of 1 years and 4 years respectively. Since we consider a model with perfect information, we choose σ = and σ = +, such that Constraint 3 is equivalent to ruling out seasoned equity offerings as dividend is constrained below by zero. The two remaining parameters ξ and β are calibrated as in Corbae and D Erasmo (214): ξ =.7 and β =.987 (adjusting for quarterly instead of annual calibration). Table 3 shows the calibration for the a large Norwegian banking group. 5 see his equations (4) and (5) plus (6). 15

17 Table 3: Parameter Calibration large Norwegian banking group Parameter Calibration Target z G good state of the world 1 normalization z B bad state of the world.9742 Norwegian business cycle z C bad state of the world.7898 Barro and Ursua (28) z R bad state of the world.8729 Barro and Ursua (28) GDP data ρ H high cost state.58 funding cost measure ρ N high cost state.33 funding cost measure ρ L low cost state.8 funding cost measure δ H high funding state.1275 funding measure δ N medium funding state.85 funding measure δ L low funding state.425 funding measure β discount factor bank.987 Corbae and D Erasmo (214) r a net securities return.52 int. inc. bonds and sec. r b short term borrowing.52 r a (Corbae and D Erasmo, 214) c net non interest exp.14 net non-interest expanses ψ adjustment costs 2.1 Var(Loans)/Var(GDP) Crisis,Norway λ loss given default.1796 total loss to lending κ fixed cost of operation.1 return om equity ξ salvage value.7 Corbae and D Erasmo (214) χ retai maturity parameter 1/14 average maturity of 1 years χ C&I maturity parameter 1/5 average maturity of 4 years [σ, σ] dividend constraint [, + ] no SEO F(z, z) = H(ρ, ρ) = G(δ, δ) = The estimation results from equation (4.4) with p-values in parenthesis are (1 P retail,t ) =.4 (.72) (1 P C&I,t ) =.57 (.13) (.) (.) r L retail,t.635 (.) r L C&I,t.2545 (.) [z t+1 1] [z t+1 1] 16

18 5 Quantitative Analysis This section features preliminary stress testing results, derived from a one sector version of the model without C&I lending. Using the calibration discussed in Section 4, we derive quantitative results from our model s policy functions as follows: 1. Given the preliminary state of our calibration we currently target two moments in state z L : a RoE of 12 % and a net interest margin of 2.3 pps. 2. We seed the simulation at z L steady state values for bank i s equity and capital ratio. Given that there is no positive crisis probability in z H, seeding the simulation in z L allows for immediate crisis. 3. In exercises without idiosyncratic uncertainty, idiosyncratic shocks are assumed to remain in their normal states (ρ i N, δi N ). In exercises with idiosyncratic uncertainty, the shocks are initial seeded in their normal states. 4. We simulate 12 periods (3 years) of the aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks, 1, times. For the counterfactual stress scenario, we impose the following regulatory capital regime: { 13. %, if z {z h, z L } ϕ(z) = 4.5 %, if z {z C, z R } The 13 % requirement in normal times corresponds to the maximum requirement under Basel III, with a 4.5 % minimum requirement, a 2.5 % conservation requirement, a 3.5 % systemic requirement and a 2.5 % countercyclical requirement. 5.1 Normal Times Analysis Given our preliminary calibration, Table 4 shows currently targeted and non targeted moments for this BG. 5.2 Stress Test Table 4: Simulated Moments Moment Model Data s.s. z L 214Q2 targeted NIM RoE non targeted core capital ratio Notes: Source: ORBOF Only Aggregate Uncertainty As discussed in Section 2 two key dimensions affect stress outcomes: equity position upon stress entry and stress duration. In our macro scenario both dimensions are driven by the probabilistic crisis nature. 17

19 Facing the adverse macro scenario, the sufficiency of a bank s contemporaneous equity equipment is of ample importance for regulators to prevent bank default that imposes costs on deposit insurance and tax payers. Our framework provides two metrics of stress outcomes: first, the exit probability of a bank, i.e. E[W x=1 ( ) > W x= ( )], and second, conditional on survival, the equity depletion the bank experienced during stress. In contrast to reduced form stress tests, our framework identifies the bank s structural incentives for equity accumulation. The reasons for equity accumulation in our framework are twofold: (1) the bank is exogenously required through regulation to hold a fraction ϕ of RWA as equity, but (2) even in absence of any regulatory requirement the bank chooses to hold positive equity to protect and maximize its charter value both before and during stress. Table 5 shows stress test outcomes. Given an initial capital ratio of 13 % our model predicts a counterfactual survival probability facing an average Barro and Ursua (28) crisis of 96 % and a 4 % default probability. The bank will on average exit after 24.8 crisis periods (6.2 years) and will survive an average of 12.9 crisis periods (3.2 years). Table 5: Stress Test Outcomes exit survival Frequency.4.96 E(duration) E(equity loss) Note: baseline calibration for 13 % normal times capital requirement. The bank exits when equity is fully run down. Conditional on survival, the bank is expected to suffer a equity loss of 36 %, leaving the stress horizon with a strongly depleted capital position. Generally the bank can take two different exit routes: first, it can decide to exit immediately after observing end of period cash flow. In this case the bank pays no further dividend and receives the salvage value subject to limited liability (Equation 3.13). The alternative route is to stay in the market to liquidate as much assets as possible. To this end, the bank uses short term borrowing not only to cover the negative contemporaneous cash flow, but to liquidate securities (B = A/(1 + r b )). According to Equation (3.11) next period capital is only a = s [l s + χ s P s L s ] D. 6 Next period, capital is completely invested into securities and loans are liquidated. At the end of this period, the bank exits. This way, the bank is able to pay out dividends longer. On the other hand, for each additional period to enter, it has to pay fixed cost κ. If fixed costs are sufficiently low, the bank will choose to liquidate capital before leaving the market, resulting in a 1 % equity loss upon exit. Figure 5 shows an exit path. 6 Note that a must be positive, as otherwise staying in the loan market would not be in the choice set. 18

Stress Testing in a Structural Model of Bank Behavior

Stress Testing in a Structural Model of Bank Behavior Stress Testing in a Structural Model of Bank Behavior Dean Corbae, Pablo D Erasmo, Sigurd Galaasen, Alfonso Irarrazabal, Thomas Siemsen Preliminary Version. Do Not Distribute. January 29, 2016 Abstract

More information

Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics

Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics Jin Cao Lorán Chollete October 9, 2014 Abstract We present a framework for modelling optimum capital adequacy in a dynamic banking context. We combine

More information

Structural Stress Tests

Structural Stress Tests Structural Stress Tests Dean Corbae, Pablo D Erasmo, Sigurd Galaasen, Alfonso Irarrazabal, and Thomas Siemsen University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Norges Bank BI Norwegian

More information

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Dean Corbae Pablo D Erasmo 1 Univ. of Wisconsin FRB Philadelphia June 12, 2014 1 The views expressed here do not necessarily

More information

Booms and Banking Crises

Booms and Banking Crises Booms and Banking Crises F. Boissay, F. Collard and F. Smets Macro Financial Modeling Conference Boston, 12 October 2013 MFM October 2013 Conference 1 / Disclaimer The views expressed in this presentation

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Regulation, Competition, and Stability in the Banking Industry

Regulation, Competition, and Stability in the Banking Industry Regulation, Competition, and Stability in the Banking Industry Dean Corbae University of Wisconsin - Madison and NBER October 2017 How does policy affect competition and vice versa? Most macro (DSGE) models

More information

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Carlos de Resende, Ali Dib, and Nikita Perevalov International Economic Analysis Department

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 September 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 March 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors

More information

Bank Capital Buffers in a Dynamic Model 1

Bank Capital Buffers in a Dynamic Model 1 Bank Capital Buffers in a Dynamic Model 1 Jochen Mankart 1 Alex Michaelides 2 Spyros Pagratis 3 1 Deutsche Bundesbank 2 Imperial College London 3 Athens University of Economics and Business November 217

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada Motivation A large literature quantitatively studies the role of financial

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Bank Capital Buffers in a Dynamic Model 1

Bank Capital Buffers in a Dynamic Model 1 Bank Capital Buffers in a Dynamic Model 1 Jochen Mankart 1 Alex Michaelides 2 Spyros Pagratis 3 1 Deutsche Bundesbank 2 Imperial College London 3 Athens University of Economics and Business CRESSE 216,

More information

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Margarita Rubio 1 Fang Yao 2 1 University of Nottingham 2 Reserve Bank of New Zealand. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect

More information

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model Bundesbank and Goethe-University Frankfurt Department of Money and Macroeconomics January 24th, 212 Bank of England Motivation

More information

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Cristina Arellano Yan Bai Luigi Bocola FRB Minneapolis University of Rochester Northwestern University Economic Policy and Financial Frictions November 2015 1 / 37

More information

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop, Mendoza (AER) Sudden Stop facts 1. Large, abrupt reversals in capital flows 2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic production, absorption, asset prices, credit & leverage 3. Capital,

More information

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government spending and firms dynamics Government spending and firms dynamics Pedro Brinca Nova SBE Miguel Homem Ferreira Nova SBE December 2nd, 2016 Francesco Franco Nova SBE Abstract Using firm level data and government demand by firm we

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Reforms in a Debt Overhang Structural Javier Andrés, Óscar Arce and Carlos Thomas 3 National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4 Universidad de Valencia, Banco de España Banco de España 3 Banco de España National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4

More information

Capital regulation and macroeconomic activity

Capital regulation and macroeconomic activity 1/35 Capital regulation and macroeconomic activity Implications for macroprudential policy Roland Meeks Monetary Assessment & Strategy Division, Bank of England and Department of Economics, University

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Escaping the Great Recession 1

Escaping the Great Recession 1 Escaping the Great Recession 1 Francesco Bianchi Duke University Leonardo Melosi FRB Chicago ECB workshop on Non-Standard Monetary Policy Measures 1 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility

More information

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap (R&R Quarterly Journal of nomics) October 31, 2016 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Ricardo Reyes-Heroles Federal Reserve Board Gabriel Tenorio The Boston Consulting Group IEA World Congress 2017 Mexico City, Mexico June 20, 2017

More information

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability Hilde C. Bjørnland Vegard H. Larsen Centre for Applied Macro- and Petroleum Economics (CAMP) BI Norwegian Business School CFE-ERCIM December 07, 2014 Bjørnland and Larsen

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Credit Booms, Financial Crises and Macroprudential Policy

Credit Booms, Financial Crises and Macroprudential Policy Credit Booms, Financial Crises and Macroprudential Policy Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 March 219 1 The views expressed in this paper are those

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006 How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006 The Effects of Costly External Finance on Investment Still, after all of these years,

More information

Balance Sheet Recessions

Balance Sheet Recessions Balance Sheet Recessions Zhen Huo and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis CAERP CEPR NBER Conference on Money Credit and Financial Frictions Huo & Ríos-Rull

More information

TCH Research Note: 2016 Federal Reserve s Stress Testing Scenarios

TCH Research Note: 2016 Federal Reserve s Stress Testing Scenarios TCH Research Note: 2016 Federal Reserve s Stress Testing Scenarios March 2016 Francisco Covas +1.202.649.4605 francisco.covas@theclearinghouse.org I. Executive Summary On January 28, the Federal Reserve

More information

Efficient Bailouts? Javier Bianchi. Wisconsin & NYU

Efficient Bailouts? Javier Bianchi. Wisconsin & NYU Efficient Bailouts? Javier Bianchi Wisconsin & NYU Motivation Large interventions in credit markets during financial crises Fierce debate about desirability of bailouts Supporters: salvation from a deeper

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 1 / 52 Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 2 / 52 Policy Practice Motivation Standard policy practice: Fiscal expansions during recessions as a means of stimulating

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

On the Optimality of Financial Repression On the Optimality of Financial Repression V.V. Chari, Alessandro Dovis and Patrick Kehoe Conference in honor of Robert E. Lucas Jr, October 2016 Financial Repression Regulation forcing financial institutions

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending Michael Reiter 1 Leopold Zessner 2 1 Instiute for Advances Studies, Vienna 2 Vienna Graduate School of Economics Barcelona GSE Summer Forum ADEMU,

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011 Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation Gabriele Camera Purdue University YiLi Chien Purdue University August 2011 BROAD VIEW Study impact of macroeconomic policy in heterogeneous-agent

More information

Hotelling Under Pressure. Soren Anderson (Michigan State) Ryan Kellogg (Michigan) Stephen Salant (Maryland)

Hotelling Under Pressure. Soren Anderson (Michigan State) Ryan Kellogg (Michigan) Stephen Salant (Maryland) Hotelling Under Pressure Soren Anderson (Michigan State) Ryan Kellogg (Michigan) Stephen Salant (Maryland) October 2015 Hotelling has conceptually underpinned most of the resource extraction literature

More information

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis Thiên T. Nguyễn Introduction Motivation Motivation Key regulatory reform: Bank capital requirements 1 Introduction Motivation Motivation Key regulatory

More information

Banks Endogenous Systemic Risk Taking. David Martinez-Miera Universidad Carlos III. Javier Suarez CEMFI

Banks Endogenous Systemic Risk Taking. David Martinez-Miera Universidad Carlos III. Javier Suarez CEMFI Banks Endogenous Systemic Risk Taking David Martinez-Miera Universidad Carlos III Javier Suarez CEMFI Banking and Regulation: The Next Frontier A RTF-CEPR-JFI Workshop, Basel, 22-23 January 2015 1 Introduction

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money

More information

Discussion of Banks Equity Capital Frictions, Capital Ratios, and Interest Rates: Evidence from Spanish Banks

Discussion of Banks Equity Capital Frictions, Capital Ratios, and Interest Rates: Evidence from Spanish Banks Discussion of Banks Equity Capital Frictions, Capital Ratios, and Interest Rates: Evidence from Spanish Banks Gianni De Nicolò International Monetary Fund The assessment of the benefits and costs of the

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

A Structural Model of Continuous Workout Mortgages (Preliminary Do not cite)

A Structural Model of Continuous Workout Mortgages (Preliminary Do not cite) A Structural Model of Continuous Workout Mortgages (Preliminary Do not cite) Edward Kung UCLA March 1, 2013 OBJECTIVES The goal of this paper is to assess the potential impact of introducing alternative

More information

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity Aubhik Khan The Ohio State University Tatsuro Senga The Ohio State University and Bank of Japan Julia K. Thomas The Ohio

More information

Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS001) p approach

Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS001) p approach Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session CPS001) p.5901 What drives short rate dynamics? approach A functional gradient descent Audrino, Francesco University

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Eduardo Engel Cowles Lunch. March 3rd, 2010 Eduardo Engel 1 1. Motivation Micro adjustment is lumpy for many aggregates of interest: stock of durable good nominal

More information

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies Sami Alpanda Gino Cateau Cesaire Meh Bank of Canada November 2013 Alpanda, Cateau, Meh (Bank of Canada) ()Macroprudential - Monetary Policy

More information

Operationalizing the Selection and Application of Macroprudential Instruments

Operationalizing the Selection and Application of Macroprudential Instruments Operationalizing the Selection and Application of Macroprudential Instruments Presented by Tobias Adrian, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Based on Committee for Global Financial Stability Report 48 The

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia Diverse and Risk The Diverse and Time Variability of M. Kurz, Stanford University M. Motolese, Catholic University of Milan August 10, 2009 Individual State of SITE Summer 2009 Workshop, Stanford University

More information

Structural credit risk models and systemic capital

Structural credit risk models and systemic capital Structural credit risk models and systemic capital Somnath Chatterjee CCBS, Bank of England November 7, 2013 Structural credit risk model Structural credit risk models are based on the notion that both

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Liquidity Insurance in Macro. Heitor Almeida University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign

Liquidity Insurance in Macro. Heitor Almeida University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign Liquidity Insurance in Macro Heitor Almeida University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign Motivation Renewed attention to financial frictions in general and role of banks in particular Existing models model

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012 A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk Zhiguo He Arvind Krishnamurthy University of Chicago & NBER Northwestern University & NBER June 212 Systemic Risk Systemic risk: risk (probability)

More information

Explaining the Boom-Bust Cycle in the U.S. Housing Market: A Reverse-Engineering Approach

Explaining the Boom-Bust Cycle in the U.S. Housing Market: A Reverse-Engineering Approach Explaining the Boom-Bust Cycle in the U.S. Housing Market: A Reverse-Engineering Approach Paolo Gelain Norges Bank Kevin J. Lansing FRBSF Gisle J. Navik Norges Bank October 22, 2014 RBNZ Workshop The Interaction

More information

Macroeconomic Cycle and Economic Policy

Macroeconomic Cycle and Economic Policy Macroeconomic Cycle and Economic Policy Lecture 1 Nicola Viegi University of Pretoria 2016 Introduction Macroeconomics as the study of uctuations in economic aggregate Questions: What do economic uctuations

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Financial Institution Dynamics and Capital Regulations

Financial Institution Dynamics and Capital Regulations Financial Institution Dynamics and Capital Regulations José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Tamon Takamura Yaz Terajima University of Minnesota Bank of Canada Bank of Canada Mpls Fed, CAERP Preliminary Macroeconomic

More information

Impact of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) on the access to finance for business and long-term investments Executive Summary

Impact of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) on the access to finance for business and long-term investments Executive Summary Impact of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) on the access to finance for business and long-term investments Executive Summary Prepared by The information and views set out in this study are those

More information

Movements on the Price of Houses

Movements on the Price of Houses Movements on the Price of Houses José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Penn, CAERP Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria, Penn Tue Dec 14 13:00:57 2004 So Preliminary, There is Really Nothing Conference on

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Antnio Antunes Tiago Cavalcanti Anne Villamil November 2, 2006 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

Skewed Business Cycles

Skewed Business Cycles Skewed Business Cycles Sergio Salgado Fatih Guvenen Nicholas Bloom University of Minnesota University of Minnesota, FRB Mpls, NBER Stanford University and NBER SED, 2016 Salgado Guvenen Bloom Skewed Business

More information

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle: Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia May 31, 214 Midwest Macro Conference Raju Huidrom Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle Background

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK Stefania Villa a Jing Yang b a Birkbeck College b Bank of England Cambridge Conference - New Instruments of Monetary Policy: The Challenges

More information

Business cycle fluctuations Part II

Business cycle fluctuations Part II Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business Business cycle fluctuations Part II Lecture 7 Nicolas Coeurdacier nicolas.coeurdacier@sciencespo.fr Lecture 7: Business cycle fluctuations

More information

n n Economic Commentaries

n n Economic Commentaries n Economic Commentaries To ensure that the banking sector has enough capital to support the real sector, even during times of stress, it may be efficient to vary the capital requirements over time. With

More information

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Selahattin İmrohoroğlu 1 Shinichi Nishiyama 2 1 University of Southern California (selo@marshall.usc.edu) 2

More information

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, NBER, PIER March 2018 Pushing the Frontier of Central Bank s Macro Modeling Preliminaries This paper

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Greg Kaplan José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University of Minnesota, Mpls Fed, and CAERP EFACR Consumption

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER MFM Summer Camp June 12, 2016 DISCLAIMER: The views expressed are solely the responsibility of the authors and

More information

Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment

Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment Juan F. Jimeno and Carlos Thomas Banco de España ESSIM, May 25, 2012 Jimeno & Thomas (BdE) Collective bargaining ESSIM, May 25, 2012 1 / 39 Motivation

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Tiago V. de V. Cavalcanti Anne P. Villamil July 14, 2005 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez (Global Modeling & Long-term Analysis Unit) Madrid, December 5, 2017 Index 1. Introduction

More information

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand Susanto Basu Boston College NBER Brent Bundick Boston College Preliminary Can Higher Uncertainty Reduce Overall Economic Activity? Many think it is an

More information

Overborrowing, Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policy. Macro Financial Modelling Meeting, Chicago May 2-3, 2013

Overborrowing, Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policy. Macro Financial Modelling Meeting, Chicago May 2-3, 2013 Overborrowing, Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policy Javier Bianchi University of Wisconsin & NBER Enrique G. Mendoza Universtiy of Pennsylvania & NBER Macro Financial Modelling Meeting, Chicago

More information

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital University of Mannheim, University of Cologne, Munich Center for the Economics of Aging 13th Annual Joint Conference of the RRC

More information