Infrastructure and the Optimal Level of Public Debt

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Infrastructure and the Optimal Level of Public Debt"

Transcription

1 Infrastructure and the Optimal Level of Public Debt Santanu Chatterjee University of Georgia Felix Rioja Georgia State University February 29, 2016 John Gibson Georgia State University Abstract We examine the role played by government investment in infrastructure in determining the optimal quantity of public debt in a heterogeneous agent economy with incomplete markets. Calibrating our model to the key aggregate and distributional moments of the U.S. economy, we show that the inclusion of public investment in this framework significantly alters the level of optimal public debt. In fact, this optimal level is now negative, underscoring a previously ignored channel through which government spending can affect the precautionary savings motive at the individual level. We also show how changes in the composition of government spending generate trade-offs for the household: while public investment tends to reduce the precautionary savings motive, other types of public spending may work in the opposite direction. Our results also indicate that previous work in this area, by ignoring public investment, may have significantly over-estimated the optimal level of public debt for the United States. Finally, we show that an increase in public investment in infrastructure is associated with a reduction in wealth inequality. Keywords: Infrastructure, public investment, heterogenous agents, public debt, welfare. JEL Classification: E2, E6, H3, H4, H6 Department of Economics, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602, USA. Telephone: schatt@uga.edu Department of Economics, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA 30303, USA. Telephone: jgibson25@gsu.edu Department of Economics, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA 30303, USA. Telephone: frioja@gsu.edu 1

2 1 Introduction What is the optimal amount of public debt? This is an important question that has received a lot of attention recently, especially after the global financial crisis of In a traditional representative agent macro model, the quantity of public debt is irrelevant for private decision making, as long as the intertemporal budget constraint of the government satisfies the transversality condition, thereby ensuring that the government does not run a ponzi scheme against the private sector. However, in a context where households receive idiosyncratic shocks that cannot be perfectly insured, public debt can have important consequences for private investment and labor supply and, therefore, it can affect their precautionary savings motive. The seminal paper by Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) started a literature studying this question finding that the optimal quantity of debt in the US was about two-thirds of GDP, which was very close to the actual share of US public debt in They also found that there were only small welfare gains to moving from the existing level of debt at the time to the optimum. Subsequent refinements to that framework by Floden (2001), Desbonnet and Weitzenblum (2011), and Rohrs and Winter (2015) have found that the optimum quantity of debt may actually be negative; or in other words, that positive public savings may be optimal. However, an important issue in this context is the role played by the government in influencing economic activity at the individual level. While the existing literature has only considered unproductive public expenditures like government consumption and transfers, little attention has been paid to another potential channel through which the government can influence resource allocation decisions, namely public investment. Public investment, by generating a stock of infrastructure such as roads, transportation and telecommunications networks, power, ports airports, etc., can have important consequences for the productivity of private factors like labor and capital, and also for a households precautionary motive for savings. A large body of literature has documented its importance, not only for an economy s productive capacity and long-run growth (Aschauer, 1989; Barro, 1990; Glomm 2

3 and Ravikumar, 1994), but also for the distribution of wealth (Chatterjee and Turnovsky, 2012; Gibson and Rioja, 2015a, 2015b; Klenert et al., 2016). The total public infrastructure stock in the US is sizable, at about 60% of GDP and, given the recent concerns about its maintenance and upgrading, its inclusion is essential in a model of optimal debt. This is the central objective of this paper. We study how the optimal quantity of public debt is affected by the presence of government spending on public infrastructure in a heterogeneous agent economy with incomplete markets. As in the previous literature, individuals in our model are subject to idiosyncratic shocks to their productivity that cannot be fully insured. Thus, they undertake precautionary saving in order to self-insure, with government debt reinforcing this motive by relaxing their borrowing constraint. In this scenario, we introduce a stock of public infrastructure that is complementary to private capital and labor supply in the production function. In incorporating public investment into the model, we take into account the distinction between investment in the provision of new public capital and maintenance expenditures on its existing stock. In addition, we also consider other types of government spending such as transfers and government consumption. In essence, we have a more careful description of the composition of government spending than the previous literature on this issue. We calibrate our baseline model with infrastructure investment and maintenance to be consistent with the key aggregate and distributional characteristics of the U.S. economy. We also consider a model specification where infrastructure has been removed. This allows us to compare our baseline model s results with a model more aligned with the current literature. Our results indicate that the inclusion of public infrastructure can fundamentally alter the optimal quantity of public debt for the United States. As mentioned above, the benchmark result from the work of Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) is that the optimal share of public debt is about 67 percent of US GDP, with very little welfare gains from reducing debt from this level. However, in a model with public infrastructure, we find that the optimal level is actually a large surplus for the government, around 140 percent of GDP. In other words, 3

4 the inclusion of infrastructure implies that it is optimal for the government to have positive savings and be a net creditor to the private sector. Further, to address issues related to the underlying income shock process assumed by Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), we adopt the more recent strategy of Castaneda et al. (2003) and Rohrs and Winter (2015) and use the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances to calibrate the income process. The basic insight from this exercise is that the inclusion of public capital, and its associated benefits for the return on capital and labor, tend to reduce the precautionary savings motive for households, causing them to sell their claims on the government. We also consider changes in the composition of government spending in favor of more public investment, which can come about by either reducing public consumption or government transfers. Here, we show that the effects of the composition of government spending on the optimal quantity of public debt depends critically on two opposing effects: on the one hand, public capital, by reducing the precautionary savings motive, tends to reduce the optimal level of public debt, while on the other the resource withdrawal effects of a reduction in other categories of public expenditures tend to increase the precautionary motive. The net effect on the optimum depends on the relative strength of these opposing influences. Finally, we show that increasing infrastructure investment leads to a reduction in wealth inequality. This paper is related to a growing body of work that attempts to quantify the optimal level of public debt for the United States. For example, Floden (2001) finds that the positive optimal debt found in Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) depends on whether government transfers are below their optimal level. Further, while Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) and Floden (2001) find that deviations from the optimal level do not lead to significant changes in the level of welfare, Desbonnet and Weitzenblum (2012) study the transitional dynamics of the welfare effects of getting to the optimal debt level, and find sizable effects. More recently, Rohrs and Winters (2015) use a more careful calibration to the wealth and earnings distribution data for the U.S. and find that the optimal level of public debt is negative, at about 80 percent of GDP. While our results are qualitatively consistent with theirs, we 4

5 show that the inclusion of public investment implies a much larger quantity of public savings at the optimum, at about 140 percent of GDP and a much larger change in welfare from moving away from this optimum. This suggests that previous studies, by neglecting the role of infrastructure investment, may have significantly over-estimated the optimal quantity of public debt and under-estimated the welfare effects associated with deviating from this optimum for the United States. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the analytical framework. Section 3 describes the calibration and computational procedure. Section 4 discusses the quantification of the optimal level of debt, while Section 5 considers some policy experiments related to the composition of government spending. Finally, Section 6 concludes. 2 Analytical Framework We consider an economy populated by a continuum of infinitely-lived households. The key feature of these households is that they face incomplete markets, as in Aiyagari (1994), i.e., they are unable to purchase perfect insurance against the realization of an idiosyncratic labor productivity shock. Therefore, though all households are identical ex-ante, their inability to insure against the labor productivity shock makes them heterogeneous ex-post. There is a government in the economy which spends tax revenues on two types of public goods-a public consumption good and the economy s stock of public infrastructure which, in turn, generates productivity spillovers for private production. The government can also sell or purchase bonds, resulting in a government debt or credit balance. 5

6 2.1 Households Households in this economy choose their rate of consumption, c, and time allocation between labor and leisure to maximize a per-period utility function given by: U(c, l) = [ c η (1 l) 1 η] 1 σ 1 σ (1) where l denotes the allocation of the household s unit time endowment to labor supply. Households are identical ex-ante, but receive idiosyncratic shocks to their labor productivity, ε, at the beginning of each period. While agents cannot perfectly insure against these fluctuations, they can partially insure against them by accumulating a stock of assets, a, that pay out a market-determined interest rate, r. These assets are comprise of private capital, which the households rent to the representative firm in the economy, and holdings of the government bond, b, such that a household s portfolio is given by a = k + b. Therefore, the presence of incomplete markets generate a precautionary motive for savings, causing households to accumulate wealth during periods of high productivity, in order to compensate for periods where adverse productivity shocks are realized. Over time, this mechanism leads to an endogenous distribution of wealth across households. In maximizing their per-period utility (1), households are constrained by an intertemporal budget constraint c + a [1 + (1 τ) r] a + (1 τ) wlε + T (2) where a denotes the household s stock of wealth in the next period, τ represents the income tax rate, w is the real wage rate, and T represents a lumpsum transfer, received from the government. We assume that the household-specific productivity shock, ε, follows a Markov process with a transition matrix given by π (ε ε). The household s maximization problem 6

7 can then be written as: V (a, ε) = max c,l,a U (c, l) + β π (ε ε) V (a, ε ) (3) ε subject to the intertemporal budget constraint (2), along with the restriction that a Firms A representative firm in this economy produces a flow of final output using a standard neoclassical technology and three inputs, namely private capital, K, rented from all households, labor purchased from households, L, and the stock of public infrastructure, K G, provided by the government: Y = (ΩK G ) φ K α L 1 α, φ (0, 1), α (0, 1) (4) In the production function (4), Ω represents the efficiency of the economy s existing stock of public infrastructure, and the term ΩK G is the efficiency-adjusted stock of public capital. As we discuss below, the level of efficiency of the stock of public capital is determined by government spending on maintenance. The representative firm is competitive and, in maximizing its flow of profits, takes all market prices and the stock of public capital as exogenously given. The firm s problem can be written as: max K,L (ΩK G) φ K α L 1 α wl (r + δ K ) K (5) where δ K is the rate of depreciation of private capital. The optimality conditions for the firm s problem pins down the equilibrium real wage and return on capital: w = (1 α) (ΩK G ) φ ( K L ) α (5a) r = α (ΩK G ) φ ( K L ) α 1 δ K (5b) 7

8 2.3 Government The government raises revenues by levying a tax on household income, and spends on transfer payments, a public consumption good and investment in the economy s stock of public capital. The government can also issue or purchase instantaneous one-period bonds (which are held by households). The government s flow budget constraint can be written as: b = (1 + r) b + G C + G I + T (τwlε + ra) (6) where b is the stock of public debt, G C is spending on the public consumption good, and G I is spending on public investment. Total spending on public investment is composed of two parts: G I = G N + G M (7) where G N denotes investment in new public capital, and G M represents expenditures to maintain the existing stock of public capital. We assume that the government spends a fraction g I of the economy s final output on new public investment, such that G N = g I Y, g I (0, 1) (7a) In addition, the government spends a proportion g M of the economy s output on the maintenance of the existing stock of public capital. These maintenance expenditures serve a dual purpose: they enhance the efficiency of the public capital stock and also reduce its depreciation rate over time: Ω = f(g M ) = f(g M Y ), g M (0, 1) (7b) δ G = 1 g ς M, ς > 0 (7c) 8

9 where the parameter ς captures the sensitivity of the depreciation rate for public capital to public maintenance expenditures. In other words, as ς 0, public capital would depreciate fully each period. The stock of public capital evolves according to K G = g I Y + (1 δ G (g M ))K G (8) Combining (2) with (7), we can derive the economy s aggregate market-clearing condition: k = (1 + r) k + wlε c G C G I (9) 2.4 Equilibrium A stationary equilibrium in this economy is characterized by a value function v (a, ε), agentspecific decision rules a (a, ε), l (a, ε) and c (a, ε), a time-invariant joint distribution of individual states F (a, ε), factor prices w and r, government policy variables g I, g M, τ, G C, and T, and the following market clearing conditions Labor market: L = ɛl(a, ɛ)f(a, ɛ)da ɛ a Asset market: A = a (a, ɛ)f(a, ɛ)da = K + B ɛ a Goods market: Y = c(a, ɛ)f(a, ɛ)da + I + G C + G I ɛ a (10a) (10b) (10c) where f(a, ɛ) is the density function associated with the distribution of individual states F (a, ɛ), K and B denote the economy-wide aggregate stocks of private capital and public debt, respectively, and I is aggregate private investment, given by I = K (1 δ K )K (11) 9

10 An important aspect of our analysis is the measurement of economic welfare from an underlying menu of government policies. We follow Floden (2001) and Rohrs and Winter (2015) in defining aggregate welfare as Γ = ɛ a V (a, ε) df (a, ε) (12) The intertemporal welfare measure in (12) can be interpreted as the welfare level of the average individual in the economy. In reporting welfare changes in subsequent sections, we use a compensating variation measure, which quantifies the units of consumption that need to be transferred between two steady-states (say, generated by two different policies or shocks), such that the average individual is indifferent between these steady states. This leads to the following compensating variation measure for welfare changes: [ ɛ a Γ = V ] 1 (ã, ε) df 1 (ã, ε) 1 η(1 σ) ɛ V 1 (13) a 0 (ã, ε) df 0 (ã, ε) where the subscripts 0 and 1 refer to the baseline (pre-shock) and new (post-shock) steady states. As in Rohrs and Winter (2015), if Γ > 0, the average agent would prefer being at the new equilibrium without compensation for the change. On the other hand, if Γ < 0, then Γ units of consumption is required to make the agent indifferent between the two steady states. This then becomes a measure of welfare loss across the two steady states. 3 Calibration The model is calibrated to be consistent with the long-run moments for the U.S. economy. To understand better the role played by public infrastructure, we compare our benchmark specification with infrastructure to a specification where infrastructure has been removed. 10

11 For the specification without infrastructure, the production function is given by: Y = ΦK α L 1 α, Φ > 0, α (0, 1) (14) where Φ denotes an exogenously specified aggregate level of productivity for the production sector. In this specification, government spending entails only the public consumption good G C and transfers, T. Table 1 describes the calibration of the benchmark model specification with public infrastructure. We set the parameter σ in the utility function (1) to 1.5, which yields an intertemporal elasticity of substitution of about 0.67, within the range of estimated values reviewed by Guvenen (2006). The relative share of consumption in the utility function, η, is set to 0.33 to match the aggregate share of time allocated to work, which is about 30 percent. The rate of time preference, β, is set at 0.95 in order to match a steady-state interest rate (or return on capital) of 3.5 percent. In the production function (4), we set the share of capital, α, to its standard value of 0.3, while the efficiency of public infrastructure, Ω, is set to 1 in the baseline case, indicating that the U.S. is at the global growth frontier. In other words, any deviation of Ω below 1 would denote an efficiency level for public infrastructure that is below the frontier. The depreciation rate for private capital and infrastructure are set at 8.9 and 4.4 percent, respectively, to target an aggregate capital-output ratio of The output elasticity of public infrastructure is set at 0.14, consistent with the findings of Bom and Ligthart (2014). With respect to the government policy parameters, we set the public investment parameters g I and g M to 1.2 percent each, such that total public investment (including new investment and maintenance) equal 2.4 percent of GDP, which is consistent with corresponding estimates from the Congressional Budget Office. Government transfers, T, are set to 8.2 percent of GDP, following Trabandt and Uhlig (2011). Finally, government consumption expenditures are set to 19.3 percent of GDP, so that total government spending equals about 30 percent of GDP in the steady state, consistent with the corresponding 1 We define the aggregate capital-output ratio as: (K + K G )/Y 11

12 long-run average for the U.S. economy. We set the public debt-to-gdp ratio, B/Y, to equal 0.67, which is the optimal level computed by Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), in their study of public debt in the United States. Following Rohrs and Winter (2015), we assume that households can borrow up to 30 percent of output produced in the steady state equilibrium. As Rohrs and Winter (2015) report, this borrowing limit matches the share of households with zero or negative financial assets in the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances in the U.S. Finally, we allow the income tax rate, τ, to adjust to satisfy the government budget constraint (6). In the alternative model specification without public capital, as characterized by the production function (14), we set the TFP parameter, Φ, to ensure that this specification yields a productivity index that matches (ΩK G ) φ in the baseline specification with public capital; See eq. (4). We also set the public debt-gdp ratio to 0.67, as in our baseline specification. This enables us to isolate the role played by public infrastructure in influencing the optimal quantity of public debt. Since there is no government spending on infrastructure in this alternative specification, we increase the share of transfers to 10.6 percent of GDP, in order to target the aggregate share of government spending of 30 percent in our baseline model. In other words, while total government spending is identical across the two specifications, its internal composition is quite different. The question we ask here is: what are the optimum shares of public debt in these two specifications? 3.1 Income Shock Process The vector of productivity shocks (ε) and the corresponding transition matrix π are calibrated to ensure that the distribution of net financial assets (wealth) in our model is consistent with its counterpart in the 2007 Survey of Consumer Finances. Our approach follows previous work by Castaneda et al. (2003), Abraham and Carceles-Poverda (2010), and Rohrs and Winter (2015). Given that households in our model have a precautionary savings motive due to the realization of idiosyncratic shocks, we calculate net financial assets for households 12

13 by excluding longer term investments such as property, vehicles, business ownership, residential mortgages, and automobile loans. Table 2 shows the distribution of net financial assets from the 2007 SCF: the top 20 percent of households hold more than 90 percent of net financial assets, while the bottom 40 percent s share is about 10 percent. The wealth Gini coefficient for this distribution is 0.9, indicating a highly unequal distribution of wealth in the U.S. economy. We assume that the vector of productivity realizations is given by four productivity states: s = [ɛ 1, ɛ 2, ɛ 3, ɛ 4 ] Following Heer and Trede (2003), we normalize the average productivity across all four quartiles to one. Using the 2007 SCF data, we find the following for the vector of productivity shocks and the corresponding transition matrix: 2 s = [0.055, 0.551, 1.195, 7.351] π = Table 2 illustrates the distribution of wealth (net financial assets) implied by our model s calibration, for both the specifications with and without public capital. As can be seen, both model specifications do a good job in matching the wealth distribution in the data, especially for the top two and bottom quintiles. The implied wealth Gini for both specifications is around 0.81, consistent with the high level of inequality seen in the data. 2 In the current draft we simply set s and π based on Rohrs and Winter (2015) and find a strong match between the empirical wealth distribution and our model generated wealth distribution. We are currently in the process of updating our calibration to include income and wealth data from the 2013 SCF. 13

14 4 The Optimal Level of Public Debt In this section, we ask the following question: what is the optimal quantity of public debt for the U.S. economy? More specifically, how does the presence of government investment in public capital affect the optimal quantity of public debt? To examine this issue, Figure 1 compares the stationary steady-state equilibria for our two model specifications, namely with public capital (red line) and without (black line), as a function of the underlying share of public debt in GDP. As can be seen from Figure 1, the optimum quantity of public debt differs dramatically depending on the inclusion or exclusion of public capital in the model specification. The model without public capital is essentially similar to the one considered by Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), modified by the income shock process as in Castaneda et al. (2003). Consistent with Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), we find that the optimal level of public debt is about two-thirds of GDP which, in turn, is the historical long-run average for the U.S. economy. In sharp contrast, the model specification with public capital implies a very different level for the welfare-maximizing level of public debt: in this case, the optimal share of public debt is actually a surplus of about 140 percent of GDP. In other words, the provision of a productive public good like infrastructure leads to the government accumulating assets to maximize aggregate welfare, in sharp contrast to the case without public capital, where welfare maximization requires a stock of net liabilities (debt). This is an important result, suggesting that by not including infrastructure in the model specification, previous studies on this issue may have over-estimated the optimal level of public debt by a significant amount. Further, we also note that the welfare function implied by the model without public capital is very flat around the optimum, indicating that reducing public debt from this level does not lead to significant welfare gains for the economy. On the other hand, the welfare function for the model with public capital is much steeper around the optimum, indicating that the welfare loss from reducing the net public surplus from the optimum level is non-trivial. To understand better the contrast between the implications of the two model specifica- 14

15 tions, we focus on the steady-state comparison between the economy s key macroeconomic aggregates, such as output, hours worked, and private capital. As shown in Figure 1, the presence of public capital leads to a higher stock of private capital and aggregate hours worked relative to the model without public capital. As such, aggregate output is also higher. This happens because of the productivity-enhancing role of public capital: it raises both the marginal product of labor and capital, enabling the agent to increase the flow of final output. The higher output increases tax revenues for the government, thus enabling it to reduce its debt liabilities to the private sector. As the government reduces the level of public debt, it further crowds in private capital which, in turn, feeds back into higher output. This can be easily seen in Figure 1: the lower is public debt, the larger is the gap between the flow of aggregate output between the two model specifications. The higher output enables the agent to increase consumption, thereby increasing welfare. In other words, in the presence of public capital, the government can raise aggregate welfare by reducing the quantity of public debt. As Figure 1 shows, this leads the government to accumulate assets and run a surplus, until diminishing returns to public capital set in, leading to the optimum. The intuition behind the dramatically different levels of optimal public debt across the two specifications can be explained as follows. In the specification without public capital, the interpretation of the Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998) result holds: increasing public debt relaxes the borrowing constraint for households around the borrowing limit, allowing them to respond to their precautionary savings motive and accumulate assets (claims against the government). Further, positive levels of public debt, by crowding out private savings, skews the composition of aggregate savings towards claims against the government. Consequently, the optimal level of public debt is positive. By contrast, when the government provides a productive public good like infrastructure, it acts as a complement to private factors in the production function, thereby raising the return to private capital and labor. Consequently, this reduces the precautionary savings motive for households, allowing them to sell their claims on the government. This causes households to be net debtors and the government to 15

16 be a net creditor to the private sector at the optimum. From a distributional standpoint, the inclusion of public capital leads to a larger increase in hours worked than in private investment relative to the specification without public capital. As such, the gap in labor income (the real wage rate) between the two model specifications also tends to be larger the lower is the level of public debt. Facing idiosyncratic shocks, households in the model specification with public capital therefore tend to have more insurance from wage earnings and savings. This leads to a more equal distribution of wealth relative to that implied by the model without public capital. 5 Policy Experiments In this section we consider two counterfactual policy experiments, and then compare the steady-state outcomes as a function of the share of public debt. Specifically, we increase new investment in public capital, g I, from its baseline value by 1 percentage point. To satisfy the government budget constraint, we examine two financing scenarios, where the increase in g I is financed by (i) reducing government consumption, G C, and (ii) reducing transfers, T. In other words, we are interested in analyzing the consequences of a change in the composition of government spending in favor of public investment. Note that in doing so, we keep total government spending at its baseline level of approximately 30 percent of GDP. Figures 2 and 3 illustrate the steady-state changes from these two policies, respectively, with the black line representing the case of an increase in public investment and the red line denoting the baseline steady state equilibrium, corresponding to Table 1 and Figure Increase in Public Investment by Reducing Public Consumption Figure 2 illustrates the steady-state consequences of increasing government investment in public capital by diverting resources away from public consumption. At the outset, given 16

17 that government consumption enters the government budget constraint as a lump-sum expenditure, its reduction in favor of more public investment has a level effect on the economy. Aggregate output, capital stock, and the real wage rate are higher, as the higher public capital stock increases the productivity of the private factors. Aggregate hours do not change much from this policy, mainly because the lower government consumption tends to crowd in private investment, reducing the marginal utility of wealth, and causing the agent to reduce labor supply. On the other hand, the higher level of government investment tends to raise labor supply by raising the marginal product of labor. In equilibrium, these two effects tend to offset each other. Further, the lower is the share of public debt, the more equal is the distribution of wealth from an increase in public investment. In terms of the welfare consequences of this policy as a function of public debt, we see that the optimum share of debt is still a surplus as in our baseline case, and remains more or less unaffected by this change in the composition of government spending. The intuition here is that the reduction in government consumption is an aggregate withdrawal of resources, and therefore does not affect the individual household s precautionary savings motive. As a result, the household has no incentive to change its net asset position, relative to the government. However, the fact that the lower level of government consumption leads to a higher level of government investment and its associated productivity benefits, leads to a larger welfare gain at the optimum. 5.2 Increase in Public Investment by Reducing Transfers Figure 3 plots the steady-state responses for an increase in public investment that is financed by a reduction in government transfers to households. The aggregate effects are similar to those in Figure 2, with output, capital, and the real wage being higher with the increase in government investment. Aggregate hours worked now increases, in contrast to the previous case. This is because a reduction of transfers to households represents a resource withdrawal effect at the individual level, which increases the marginal utility of wealth, leading the 17

18 household to increase labor supply. This is further reinforced by the higher return on labor generated by the increase in public investment. Interestingly, the increase in public investment financed by a reduction in transfers implies a welfare-maximizing level of public debt that is higher than that obtained in our baseline scenario. In other words, increasing public investment from the baseline case requires the government to lower its net surplus in order to maximize aggregate welfare. This happens because of two offsetting effects on the household s precautionary savings motive: on the one hand, the higher level of public investment reduces the precautionary savings motive for households, causing them to sell their claims on the government. On the other, the reduction in transfers is a resource withdrawal from households, and this increases their precautionary savings motive, causing them to accumulate more claims on the government. Over all, the second effect dominates the first, leading to a decline in the public surplus at the welfare-maximizing point. For the distribution of wealth, we find that the higher level of public investment tends to lower wealth inequality, with this effect becoming stronger the lower the share of public debt. 6 Conclusions In this paper, we have revisited an important policy issue that has recently received a lot of attention, namely the optimal share of public debt in an economy populated by heterogeneous agents. Previous studies, starting with the seminal work of Aiyagari and McGrattan (1998), have shown that this optimal share is positive, at least for the United States, possibly around two-thirds of GDP. More recent work has focused on the underlying income process that is used to calibrate these models to the data, showing that the Aiyagari-McGrattan result is indeed sensitive to the income process. One important issue this literature has neglected is the role of public investment in the context of heterogeneous agent models. Arguably, public investment, by generating productivity benefits for private capital and labor, can help reduce the precautionary savings motive in these models where households face idiosyncratic shocks 18

19 and incomplete insurance markets. On the other hand, how this investment is financed by the government can work in the opposite direction. This trade-off can have important consequences for the optimal quantity of public debt in the economy. By embedding public investment (and the stock of public capital it generates) into a standard heterogeneous agent economy with imperfect markets, we attempt to bridge an important gap in this literature. We calibrate the model to match the key aggregate and distributional moments of the United States, while also modeling carefully the composition of government spending. Here, we consider two types of public investment, on new public goods as well as maintenance of the existing stock of public capital. In addition, our model also incorporates government consumption and transfers. To understand better how our model relates to the previous literature, we compare our baseline specification to one without public capital. Further, we also adopt an income shock process used in the recent literature to avoid issues of robustness. Our results indicate that the inclusion of public capital fundamentally changes the optimal quantity of public debt for the U.S. economy. In fact, the optimal debt is now a surplus, indicating that aggregate welfare maximization requires the government to be a net lender to the private sector. We further investigate this result by examining changes in the composition of government spending. Specifically, we consider two cases where public investment increases, but via appropriate reductions in (i) government consumption and (ii) transfers. We find that an increase in public investment financed by a reduction in government consumption does not alter much the optimum quantity of public debt. On the other hand, diverting resources away from transfers into new public investment lowers the welfaremaximizing public surplus. These results are mainly driven by the trade-offs generated by a change in the composition of government spending for the household s precautionary savings motive. In summary, our paper contributes to the existing literature on the optimal quantity of public debt in two important ways. First, we show that previous studies, by neglecting the role of public investment and infrastructure, may have significantly over-estimated the 19

20 optimum quantity of debt. In fact, in the presence of public capital, this optimum quantity is a surplus. Second, we show how changes in the composition of government spending affects this optimal quantity, by generating trade-offs for the precautionary savings motive for households who face idiosyncratic shocks. Needless to say, there are several related issues that we do not yet consider, such as the internal composition of public spending between new investment and maintenance, transitional dynamics, and a richer tax structure that differentiates the tax rates on capital and labor income. These are important issues that we hope to address in future research. 20

21 Table 1: Model Parameters Parameter Value Target α Capital s Income Share β Rental Rate of Approximately 3.5% δ K Private Plus Public Capital-Output Ratio δ G Private Plus Public Capital-Output Ratio σ Std. Arrow-Pratt CRRA η Average Labor Supply in Steady State φ Elasticity of Y w.r.t Infrastructure g I Infrastructure Investment-GDP Ratio g M Infrastructure Maintenance-GDP Ratio Ω Efficiency of U.S. Infrastructure Table 2: Baseline Model vs. Data Aggregate Variables Wealth Distribution Data a Baseline Without KG Data b Baseline Without KG Interest Rate Q G C /Y Ratio Q T /Y Ratio Q C/Y Ratio Q K/Y Ratio Q a While we calibrate our model to target G C /Y, T /Y, and K/Y, we do not target C/Y. model s fit to the data in this dimension is an additional demonstration of its quality. Therefore, our b Wealth distribution data for the U.S. at the quintile level was taken from Rohrs and Winters (2015). 21

22 Table 3: Compare Model Specifications Baseline Without K G Add 1% to K G (T) Add 1% to K G (G) Government Budget Allocation g M g I G C T τ Aggregate Effects K G K N Y w r Distributional Effects Q Q Q Q Q

23 Figure 1: Model With K G Versus Model Without K G 23

24 Figure 2: Increase K G Investment and Reduce G by 1% of Output 24

25 Figure 3: Increase K G Investment and Reduce T by 1% of Output 25

26 References Abraham, A. & Carceles-Poverda, E., 2010, Endogenous Trading Constraints with Incomplete Asset Markets, Journal of Economic Theory, 145(3): Aiyagari, R. & McGrattan, E., 1998, The Optimum Quantity of Debt, Journal of Monetary Economics, 42: Aschauer D., 1989, Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private Capital? Journal of Monetary Economics, 24(2): Barro R., 1990, Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth, Journal of Political Economy, 98(5): S Bom P. R. & Ligthart J. E., 2014, What Have we Learned from Three Decades of Research on the Productivity of Public Capital? Journal of Economic Surveys, 28(5): Castaneda, A., Diaz-Giminenez, J., & Rios-Rull, J, 2003, Accounting for the U.S. Earnings and Wealth Inequality, Journal of Political Economy, 111(4): Chatterjee, S. & Turnovsky, S., 2012, Infrastructure and Inequality, European Economic Review, 56(8): Desbonnet, A., & Weitzenblum, T., 2012), Why Do Governments End Up with Debt? Short?Run Effects Matter. Economic inquiry, 50(4), Floden, M., 2001, The Effectiveness of Government Debt and Transfers as Insurance, Journal of Monetary Economics, 48: Gibson J., & Rioja, F., Public Infrastructure Maintenance and the Distribution of Wealth, Working paper.. Gibson J., & Rioja, F., A Bridge to Equality?: Aggregate and Distributional Effects of Investing in Infrastructure, Working paper. Glomm, G., & Ravikumar, B., Public Investment in Infrastructure in a Simply Growth Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 18(6): Guvenen, F., 2006, Reconciling conflicting evidence on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: A macroeconomic perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(7), Heer, B. & Trede, M., 2003, Efficiency and Distribution Effects of a Revenue-Neutral Income Tax Reform, Journal of Macroeconomics, 25: Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Edenhofer, O., & Lessmann, K. 2014, Infrastructure and Inequality: Insights from Incorporating Key Economic Facts about Household Heterogeneity, CESifo Working Paper Series 4714, CESifo Group Munich. 26

27 Rohrs, S., & Winter, C., 2016, Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality, Working Paper. Trabandt, M., & Uhlig, H., 2011, The Laffer curve revisited. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(4),

Optimal Public Debt Redux

Optimal Public Debt Redux Optimal Public Debt Redux Santanu Chatterjee University of Georgia Felix Rioja Georgia State University October 6, 2016 John Gibson Georgia State University Abstract We examine the role played by government

More information

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis Santanu Chatterjee University of Georgia Felix Rioja Georgia State University October 31, 2017 John Gibson Georgia State University Abstract

More information

The Welfare Effects of Infrastructure Investment in a Heterogenous Agents Economy

The Welfare Effects of Infrastructure Investment in a Heterogenous Agents Economy The Welfare Effects of Infrastructure Investment in a Heterogenous Agents Economy John Gibson Georgia State University Felix Rioja Georgia State University April 26, 2017 Abstract Public infrastructure

More information

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Ctirad Slavík, CERGE-EI, Prague (with Hakki Yazici, Sabanci University and Özlem Kina, EUI) January 4, 2019 ASSA in Atlanta 1 / 31 Motivation Optimal

More information

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis University of Western Ontario February 2013 Question Main Question: what is the welfare cost/gain of US social safety

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 April Last week two benchmarks: autarky and complete markets non-state contingent bonds:

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University November 17, 2008 Abstract We extend a standard overlapping-generations

More information

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls Lucas (1990), Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review, Oxford Economic Papers When I left graduate school, in 1963, I believed that the single most desirable change in the U.S. structure would be the

More information

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011 Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation Gabriele Camera Purdue University YiLi Chien Purdue University August 2011 BROAD VIEW Study impact of macroeconomic policy in heterogeneous-agent

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role of Fiscal Policy Revisited Santanu Chatterjee y Department of Economics University of Georgia Sugata Ghosh z Department of Economics and Finance

More information

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Constantine Angyridis Ryerson University Dept. of Economics Toronto, Canada December 7, 2012 Abstract This paper considers an endogenous growth

More information

Final Exam Solutions

Final Exam Solutions 14.06 Macroeconomics Spring 2003 Final Exam Solutions Part A (True, false or uncertain) 1. Because more capital allows more output to be produced, it is always better for a country to have more capital

More information

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap (R&R Quarterly Journal of nomics) October 31, 2016 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

The Macroeconomics of Universal Health Insurance Vouchers

The Macroeconomics of Universal Health Insurance Vouchers The Macroeconomics of Universal Health Insurance Vouchers Juergen Jung Towson University Chung Tran University of New South Wales Jul-Aug 2009 Jung and Tran (TU and UNSW) Health Vouchers 2009 1 / 29 Dysfunctional

More information

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Department of Economics, Trinity College, Dublin Policy Institute, Trinity College, Dublin Open Republic

More information

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES Kanat S. Isakov, Sergey E. Pekarski FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES BASIC RESEARCH PROGRAM WORKING PAPERS SERIES: ECONOMICS WP BRP 113/EC/2015 This Working Paper is an output of a research project

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh Discussion by Gaston Navarro March 3, 2015 1 / 25 Motivation

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Tiago V. de V. Cavalcanti Anne P. Villamil July 14, 2005 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Antnio Antunes Tiago Cavalcanti Anne Villamil November 2, 2006 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Johannes Wieland University of California, San Diego and NBER 1. Introduction Markets are incomplete. In recent

More information

Balance Sheet Recessions

Balance Sheet Recessions Balance Sheet Recessions Zhen Huo and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis CAERP CEPR NBER Conference on Money Credit and Financial Frictions Huo & Ríos-Rull

More information

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016 Evolution of top wealth inequality

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

insights from incorporating key economic facts about household heterogeneity

insights from incorporating key economic facts about household heterogeneity David Klenert, Linus Mattauch, Ottmar Edenhofer, Kai Lessmann Infrastructure and inequality insights from incorporating key economic facts about household heterogeneity Article, Postprint This version

More information

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours?

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours? Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours? Josep Pijoan-Mas CEMFI and CEPR November 2005 Abstract This paper quantifies the macroeconomic implications of the lack of insurance against idiosyncratic

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives William B. Peterman Federal Reserve Board william.b.peterman@frb.gov Erick Sager Bureau of Labor Statistics sager.erick@bls.gov February 5, 206 Abstract In their

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Davide Porcellacchia 8 February 2017 Abstract The canonical New Keynesian model features a zero lower bound on the interest rate. In the simple setting

More information

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies Introduction In macroeconomics, we study the behavior of economy-wide aggregates e.g. GDP, savings, investment, employment and so on - and

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales, Sydney July 2009, CEF Conference Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics Models of the wealth distribution Gabriel Zucman zucman@berkeley.edu 1 Roadmap 1. The facts to explain 2. Precautionary saving models 3. Dynamic random shock models

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Dean Corbae Pablo D Erasmo 1 Univ. of Wisconsin FRB Philadelphia June 12, 2014 1 The views expressed here do not necessarily

More information

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital University of A Coruna From the SelectedWorks of Manuel A. Gómez April, 2000 Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital Manuel A. Gómez Available at: https://works.bepress.com/manuel_gomez/2/

More information

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation Fujisaki Seiya and Mino Kazuo Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University 20. October 2010

More information

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification by Lawrence Christiano Incorporating Financial Frictions into a Business Cycle Model General idea: Standard model

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives Macroeconomics Research Workshop 28 April 2017 Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives William B. Peterman Federal Reserve Board Erick Sager Bureau of Labor Statistics March 28, 2017 Abstract In a

More information

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G Chapter 6 Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G 195 6.1 The Simple AK Model Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 6.1.1 Pareto Allocations Total output in the economy is given by Y t = F (K t, L t ) = AK t, where

More information

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances Enrique G. Mendoza University of Maryland, IMF & NBER Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR & NBER José-Víctor Ríos-Rull

More information

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Selahattin İmrohoroğlu 1 Shinichi Nishiyama 2 1 University of Southern California (selo@marshall.usc.edu) 2

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Home Production and Social Security Reform

Home Production and Social Security Reform Home Production and Social Security Reform Michael Dotsey Wenli Li Fang Yang Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia SUNY-Albany October 17, 2012 Dotsey, Li, Yang () Home Production October 17, 2012 1 / 29

More information

Wealth Inequality and the Optimal Level of Government Debt

Wealth Inequality and the Optimal Level of Government Debt Working Paper Series National Centre of Competence in Research Financial Valuation and Risk Management Working Paper No. 769 Wealth Inequality and the Optimal Level of Government Debt Sigrid Röhrs Christoph

More information

Saving Europe? Some Unpleasant Supply-Side Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity

Saving Europe? Some Unpleasant Supply-Side Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity Saving Europe? Some Unpleasant Supply-Side Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity Enrique G. Mendoza University of Pennsylvania and NBER Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan and NBER Jing Zhang University of

More information

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives William Peterman Federal Reserve Board Erick Sager Bureau of Labor Statistics QSPS May 20, 2016 **The views herein are the authors and not necessarily those

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles RIETI Discussion Paper Series 07-E-062 Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI NUTAHARA Kengo the University of Tokyo / JSPS The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and

More information

Quantifying the Impact of Financial Development on Economic Development

Quantifying the Impact of Financial Development on Economic Development Quantifying the Impact of Financial Development on Economic Development Jeremy Greenwood, Juan M. Sanchez, Cheng Wang (RED 2013) Presented by Beatriz González Macroeconomics Reading Group - UC3M January

More information

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium Seiya Fujisaki Graduate School of Economics Kazuo Mino Graduate School of Economics Abstract This paper re-examines equilibrium determinacy

More information

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Introduction to economic growth (2) Introduction to economic growth (2) EKN 325 Manoel Bittencourt University of Pretoria M Bittencourt (University of Pretoria) EKN 325 1 / 49 Introduction Solow (1956), "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic

More information

Endogenous Growth, Inequality and the Composition of Government Expenditures

Endogenous Growth, Inequality and the Composition of Government Expenditures Endogenous Growth, Inequality and the Composition of Government Expenditures Constantine Angyridis Ryerson University Dept. of Economics Toronto, Canada February 5, 2016 Abstract This paper considers an

More information

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities 14.452. Topic 7. Nominal rigidities Olivier Blanchard April 2007 Nr. 1 1. Motivation, and organization Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? In monetary models, the price level (the

More information

Capital Income Taxation with Household and Firm Heterogeneity

Capital Income Taxation with Household and Firm Heterogeneity Capital Income Taxation with Household and Firm Heterogeneity Alexis Anagnostopoulos, Orhan Erem Atesagaoglu, Eva Cárceles-Poveda Stony Brook University November, 203 Abstract The US tax code stipulates

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 5 - Money Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 February A brief history of money in macro 1. 1. Hume: money has a wealth effect more money increase in aggregate demand Y 2. Friedman

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6 Contents 1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) 2 1.1 Question (a).................................................... 2 1.2 Question (b).................................................... 6 2 Countercyclical

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1 Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1 Chun Chang a Zheng Liu b Mark Spiegel b a Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance b Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco International Monetary Fund

More information

Transitional Housing Market and the Macroeconomy

Transitional Housing Market and the Macroeconomy Transitional Housing Market and the Macroeconomy Lini Zhang October 5, 3 Abstract This paper studies the U.S. housing market in the Great Recession. To achieve this goal, I build a quantitative general

More information

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University March 22, 2010 Abstract We extend a

More information

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET* Articles Winter 9 MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET* Caterina Mendicino**. INTRODUCTION Boom-bust cycles in asset prices and economic activity have been a central

More information

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default Satyajit Chatterjee Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Makoto Nakajima University of Pennsylvania Dean Corbae University of Pittsburgh

More information

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare Shutao Cao Bank of Canada Césaire A. Meh Bank of Canada José Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Yaz Terajima

More information

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013 .. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective Gary Hansen (UCLA) and Selo İmrohoroğlu (USC) May 10, 2013 Table of Contents.1 Introduction.2 Model Economy.3 Calibration.4 Quantitative

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 March 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors

More information

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] 1. A tax is to be levied on a commodity bought and sold in a competitive market. Two possible forms of tax may be used: In one case, a per unit tax

More information

Slides III - Complete Markets

Slides III - Complete Markets Slides III - Complete Markets Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides III - Complete Markets Spring 2017 1 / 33 Outline 1. Risk, Uncertainty,

More information

Tax reform with endogenous borrowing limits and incomplete asset markets

Tax reform with endogenous borrowing limits and incomplete asset markets ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES Tax reform with endogenous borrowing limits and incomplete asset markets Árpád Abrahám Eva Carceles Poveda June 2016 WP 2016/013 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Analysis and Application Max Gillman UMSL 27 August 2014 Gillman (UMSL) Modern Macro 27 August 2014 1 / 23 Overview of Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 1: Overview of the

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka Working Paper 9211 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9211 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks Greg Kaplan University of Chicago Gianluca Violante Princeton University BdF/ECB Conference on HFC In preparation for the Special Issue of JEP on The

More information

1 No capital mobility

1 No capital mobility University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #7 1 1 No capital mobility In the previous lecture we studied the frictionless environment

More information

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia? Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia? Fiscal Limits and Default Risk Premia for Slovakia Moderné nástroje pre finančnú analýzu a modelovanie Zuzana Múčka June 15, 2015 Introduction Aims

More information