Do forecasts of stock returns also forecast covariances? ABSTRACT

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Do forecasts of stock returns also forecast covariances? ABSTRACT"

Transcription

1 Do forecasts of stock returns also forecast covariances? Gregory R. Duffee Haas School of Business University of California Berkeley This Draft: February 12, 2002 ABSTRACT I construct forecasts of aggregate stock returns with standard variables, then use the forecasts to predict covariances between stock returns and real variables such as consumption and GDP growth. The results are strong and surprising. Return forecasts contain substantial information about covariances, but the sign of the relation is opposite that predicted in standard asset-pricing models. Higher expected returns correspond to substantially smaller covariances. Part of this pattern is driven by the fact that forecasts of stock returns also forecast business cycle dynamics. When expected returns are low, inflation and output growth are negatively correlated. When expected returns are high, this negative relation disappears. Voice , fax , duffee@haas.berkeley.edu. Address correspondence to 545 Student Services Building #1900, Berkeley, CA This is a much-revised version of Why does the slope of the term structure forecast excess returns? I thank seminar participants at many universities and the NBER 2001 Summer Institute, and in particular John Campbell, Doug Elmendorf, Blake LeBaron, and Sydney Ludvigson for helpful discussions and/or comments. The most recent version of this paper is at duffee.

2 1 Introduction Decades of research has tentatively concluded that there are predictable variations in aggregate stock returns. The uncertainty in this conclusion is partially driven by our inability to interpret comfortably these variations in an agreed-upon model of asset pricing. No-arbitrage implies that expected excess returns are determined by the covariance between returns and the state-price deflator. Thus we would like evidence that this covariance changes over time. However, there is little direct evidence of variation in the covariance of aggregate stock returns with any plausible proxy for the state-price deflator, except for stock returns themselves (i.e., stock returns are heteroskedastic). In particular, there is no evidence of time-varying covariances between stock returns and real variables such as aggregate consumption. One interpretation of this fact is that we are unable to observe the true time-variation in covariances because we are working with poorly and infrequently measured real variables. Researchers commonly use ARCH-type models to look for time-varying second moments, where the variables used to forecast second moments are lagged products of shocks. Even with perfectly measured data, it is hard to notice year-to-year swings in the volatility of aggregate consumption growth using four observations of quarterly shocks. Measurement error compounds the difficulty. Some higher-frequency data are available, such as monthly aggregate consumption or industrial production, but these are subject to greater measurement error than quarterly data. In this paper I rely on finance theory and use time-variation in expected stock returns to look for time-variation in covariances. In other words, can covariances between stock returns and real variables be predicted with expected stock returns? The basic approach is straightforward. I use variables identified in earlier research to form a time-t forecast of future excess aggregate stock returns. I then examine whether this return forecast also predicts covariances between these stock returns and, say, consumption growth. I document an economically strong and statistically robust link between expected excess stock returns and covariances involving aggregate consumption and GDP. This result is based on quarterly U.S. data from 1953 through Unfortunately, at least for those desiring a simple explanation for time-varying expected stock returns, the pattern goes the wrong way. When expected excess returns are lower than average, subsequent stock returns and macroeconomic growth are closely tied. For example, the correlation between innovations in annual stock returns and GDP growth is about 0.6. By contrast, when expected excess returns are higher than average, the relation between stock returns and macroeconomic growth is much weaker the correlation between innovations in annual stock returns and GDP growth is less than 0.3. In addition, both stock returns and macroeconomic growth 1

3 are less volatile when expected excess returns are high. Similar patterns are documented for different return horizons, across subsamples, and for alternative methods of forming forecasts of stock returns and covariances. This puzzling evidence raises a number of questions. First, what kinds of news moves stock prices in low-expected-return periods versus high-expected-return periods? Second, since expected excess returns are probably just proxying for fundamental forces driving timevarying covariances, what are these fundamental forces? Third, why do investors require higher expected excess returns in periods when stock returns are only weakly related to aggregate consumption growth? I shed some light on these questions, but I cannot offer a clearcut answer to any of them. I find that the kinds of shocks that hit the economy when expected returns are low are qualitatively different from those that hit when expected returns are high. When expected returns are low, inflation and output growth are inversely related. When expected returns are high, inflation and output growth have a greater tendency to move together. A superficial interpretation of this pattern is that aggregate demand shocks are relatively more important when expected returns are high, but there are doubtless other interpretations that are consistent with the evidence presented here. This inflation-output relation helps explain the link between expected returns and covariances between stock returns and macroeconomic growth. In low-expected-return periods, contemporaneous shocks to real dividends and inflation are negatively correlated. Because investors react positively to both news of higher dividends and news of lower inflation, this negative correlation magnifies the univariate relation between stock returns and real activity. In high-expected-return periods, shocks to dividends and inflation are positively correlated, dampening the univariate relation between stock returns and real activity. I have less success in identifying fundamental variables that drive conditional covariances. Since expected returns are countercylical, a natural hypothesis is that the state of the business cycle determines both expected returns and conditional covariances. I find mixed evidence for this conclusion. Covariances appear to be driven by turning points in business cycles. In other words, recent output growth and forecasts of near-term output growth help predict covariances between stock returns and the macroeconomy; higher growth (or higher forecasts) corresponds to lower covariances. But expected excess returns contain substantial incremental predictive power for covariances. I am also unsuccessful at explaining why investors appear to require high returns when the conditional covariance between stock returns and aggregate consumption growth is low. One potential explanation is that stockholders consumption may be decoupled from aggregate consumption in recessions. In recessions, a larger share of aggregate consumption may 2

4 be driven by liquidity-constrained agents. The consumption of stockholders, who are not constrained, may still be closely linked to stock returns even though aggregate consumption is not. In the absence of consumption data for stockholders, I can test this story only indirectly by extending the instrumental variables approach in Campbell and Mankiw (1990). The results are not supportive of the potential explanation. If the results are taken literally, they suggest a larger proportion of liquidity-constrained agents in low-expected-return periods. The next section presents the theoretical motivation behind the empirical analysis in the paper. Section 3 presents the main empirical evidence. It describes the construction of expected stock returns, measures of the covariance between stock returns and real variables, and then reports regression evidence. Section 4 is devoted to convincing the reader that these results are robust. Section 5 considers the questions that are raised by the first set of results. Concluding comments are offered in Section 6. The Appendix contains a description of the data. 2 The theoretical motivation 2.1 Expected returns and covariances The stochastic discount factor is at the center of standard asset-pricing theory. Denote this strictly positive random variable by exp(m(t)). In a discrete-time framework, the excess return to any asset i during period t + 1 satisfies [ ] E t exp(m(t +1))=E t exp(r i (t + 1))) exp(m(t +1)). (1) R i (t + 1) denotes the log excess return (log real return less log riskfree rate) to the asset. Equation (1) is a requirement of no arbitrage. In a utility-based framework, we can think of exp(m(t + 1)) as the ratio of the marginal utility of real wealth at time t + 1 to the marginal utility of real wealth at time t. If we assume conditional joint normality of R t (t) andm(t), (1) implies E t R i (t +1)+ 1 2 Var t(r i (t +1))= Cov t (R i (t +1),M(t + 1)) (2) Equation (2) says that excess returns are linear in covariances with the stochastic discount factor. The variance term adjusts for Jensen s inequality created by using log returns instead of returns. Asset-pricing models restrict M(t+1). The intuition used in this paper is that of recursive 3

5 utility, developed by Epstein and Zin (1989) and Weil (1989). In recursive utility M(t +1) can be expressed as M(t +1)=θ[log δ (1/Λ) C(t +1)] (1 θ)r w (t +1). (3) In (3), C(t + 1) is the change in log real consumption from t to t +1,R w (t +1)isthelog return to total real wealth, including human capital, and the parameters are determined by investors rate of time preference, elasticity of intertemporal substitution, and relative risk aversion. Substituting (3) into (2) yields E t R i (t +1)+ 1 2 Var t(r i (t +1))= (4) ( ) ( ) θ Λ Cov t R i (t +1), C(t +1) +(1 θ)cov t R i (t +1),R w (t +1) In principle we can test (4) by looking for variables that capture time-variation in the conditional covariances on the right-hand-side, and then checking whether this time-variation is accompanied by time-variation in expected excess returns. The history of such tests is not encouraging. The standard approach is to use information in the residuals of asset returns and consumption growth to detect changes in variances and covariances. These methods detect strong evidence of time-variation in the volatility of returns to financial assets (which is a component of R w (t + 1)), but this variation appears unrelated to variation in expected excess returns. 1 There is no evidence of substantial timevariation in either the volatility of aggregate consumption growth or in covariances of asset returns with aggregate consumption growth. 2 It is not clear what to make of this evidence. An important limitation on our ability to test (4) is poor data. Aggregate consumption is measured infrequently and with noise. Thus ARCH or GARCH methods have low power for detecting changes in volatility over time. Similarly, a two-dimensional ARCH has low power for detecting changes in the covariance between an asset s return and consumption. In addition, total wealth is poorly measured. Financial wealth is measured reasonably well, but human wealth is unobserved. In this paper I reverse the logic of previous tests of (4). If there is some variation in the investors conditional covariances over time, (4) tells us that expected excess returns will also vary. Thus we can use expected excess returns to predict covariances. In this recursive utility framework the only reason for variations in expected excess returns is variations in 1 See Campbell (1999) and Whitelaw (2000) for discussions and references. 2 See, e.g., Boudoukh (1993). 4

6 conditional covariances with consumption or wealth. In alternative models for the stochastic discount factor, such as the habit formation framework used by Campbell and Cochrane (1999), expected excess returns can vary independently of these covariances. Nonetheless, it is difficult to write down a consumption-based asset-pricing model where conditional covariances with consumption or wealth do not affect expected excess returns. The power of this approach depends on the magnitude of the variation in expected excess returns. Thus to implement it, we want to focus on assets for which there is evidence of substantial time-variation in expected excess returns. The most obvious choice is the aggregate stock market, owing to the large literature documenting time-variation in expected excess returns. Denote the excess log return to the stock market during time t as R(t). (This return has no subscript, for consistency with the empirical work that follows.) Then (4) suggests the following hypothetical regressions. ( R(t +1) Et R(t +1) )( C(t +1) E t C(t +1) ) = b 0,c + b 1,c E t R(t +1)+e c (t +1) (5) ( R(t +1) Et R(t +1) )( R w (t +1) E t R w (t +1) ) = b 0,w + b 1,w E t R(t +1)+e w (t +1) (6) The time-t expectations of the left-hand-sides of (5) and (6) are Cov t (R, C)andCov t (R, R w ) respectively. The coefficients b 1,c and b 1,w will be nonzero if expected excess returns are correlated with these conditional covariances. Risk aversion in a recursive utility model implies that either b 1,c or b 1,w will be positive if expected excess returns vary over time. 3 These regressions might appear similar to tests for constant correlations conditional on the sizes of the shocks. Boyer, Gibson, and Loretan (1999) note that when one-period-ahead correlations are constant, correlations conditioned on the size of either shock will be nonconstant. But here, the right-hand-side variable is not a shock; it is known at time t. Thus (5) and (6) are not subject to the effect described in Boyer et al. 2.2 The testing framework Two barriers prevent us as econometricians from estimating (5) and (6) directly. First, we do not perfectly observe C or R w. Second, we do not know investors time-t expectations. I overcome these barriers in the usual fashion. I use the log of aggregate per capita real consumption on nondurables and services to proxy for C. We do not observe the return to total wealth but we do observe dividends to wealth. Campbell (1996) and others 3 They need not both be positive, or even nonnegative. For example, if σ t (R, C) andσ t (R, W )are negatively correlated, an increase in σ t (R, C) could correspond to both a large increase in expected excess returns and a decrease in σ t (R, W ). In this (admittedly unlikely) situation, b 1 < 0 is possible. 5

7 interpret labor income as the dividend to the human wealth component of total wealth. More broadly, we could think of GDP as the dividend to total wealth. Shocks to dividends should correspond to shocks to returns, both because current dividends are a component of the current return and because a shock to current dividends conveys information about future dividends. Thus I use innovations in log changes in (real, per capita) aggregate labor income and GDP as proxies for the innovation in the return to total wealth. Estimation follows a two-step procedure. First, investor expectations are proxied by forecasts from OLS regressions on a set of variables known to investors at time t. Denote these predetermined variables by Z t. The regressions are R t+1 = a 0,r + a 1,rZ t + R t+1, (7) y t+1 = a 0,y + a 1,yZ t +ỹ t+1. (8) Regression (7) is used to produce the forecasted return R t+1. R t+1 a 0,r + a 1,rZ t (9) Second, regress the product of residuals from this first step onto the OLS forecast of excess returns. R t+1 ỹ t+1 = b 0 + b 1 Rt+1 + e t+1 (10) The econometric properties of this two-step process are nonstandard. issues, assume the true model is To clarify the R t+1 = E t (R t+1 )+q t+1, (11) y t+1 = E t (y t+1 )+v t+1, (12) E t (R t+1 ) = α 0,r + α 1,rZ t, (13) E t (y t+1 ) = α 0,y + α 1,yZ t, (14) Cov t (q t+1,v t+1 ) = β 0 + β 1 E t (R t+1 ), (15) q t+1 v t+1 = Cov t (q t+1,v t+1 )+ɛ t+1. (16) We can plug the true model into (10) to reveal (after some substitutions) R t+1 ỹ t+1 = β 0 + β 1 Rt+1 + [ β 1 ( R t+1 q t+1 )+q t+1 (ỹ t+1 v t+1 )+ v t+1 ( R t+1 q t+1 )+(ỹ t+1 v t+1 )( R t+1 q t+1 )+ɛ t+1 ]. The term in square brackets is the true residual for the OLS regression of R t+1 ỹ t+1 on R t+1. 6

8 The first term in this residual arises because R t+1 is a generated regressor, as discussed in Pagan (1984). The hypothesis we are interested in testing is β 1 = 0. Under this null, the presence of a generated regressor has no effect on either the parameter estimates or their standard errors. The next three terms in square brackets cause inference problems even under the null. They all depend, in part, on fitted values from the first step. OLS standard errors from the second step will not capture the uncertainty in these fitted values, thus under the null we expect the second-step standard errors to be biased downward. Under alternative hypotheses these terms are also likely to be correlated with the explanatory variable R t+1. Note that these terms are all related to the joint behavior of innovations in R and y. Under an alternative hypothesis that the covariance between R and y varies with E t (R t+1 ), these terms are likely to be correlated with R t+1. To get a sense of the importance of these features of the econometric approach, I use Monte Carlo simulations. 2.3 Monte Carlo evidence The variables that exhibit the greatest forecasting power for stock returns are typically correlated with lagged stock returns. Forecasts produced with these variables (such as D/P ratios) are subject to the predictive regressions bias of Stambaugh (1999). Because the implications of this bias on the second-stage regressions used here are unclear, the simulated model should include lagged dependent variables among the forecasting instruments. I therefore assume the vector Z t is given by Z t =(R t y t h t ) where h t is an independent variable distributed as N(0, 1). The conditional means of R t+1 and y t+1 are γ r h t and γ y h t, respectively. Thus α 0,r = α 0,y =0,α 1,r =(00γ r ),andα 1,y =(00γ y ). The zero coefficients on R t and y t imply that the explanatory power of these lagged values is an artifact of finite sample sizes. Only h t truly forecasts R t+1 and y t+1. In order to model the relation between Cov t (q t+1,v t+1 )ande t (R t+1 ), we need to specify how the variance of R, the variance of y, and their correlation depend on E t (R t+1 ). In the empirical results we will see later in the paper, much of the action is in time-varying correlations. This fact motivates the following specification choice. The vector of shocks (q t v t ) is distributed as a bivariate normal with unit variances. The correlation coefficient is 1 if β 0 + β 1 E t (R t+1 ) < 1; ρ = 1 if β 0 + β 1 E t (R t+1 ) > 1; β 0 + β 1 E t (R t+1 ) otherwise. Thus the correlation is linear in E t (R t+1 ) unless this linear relation produces a value outside 7

9 of [ 1, 1]. Under the null hypothesis, 1 β 0 1andβ 1 = 0. The alternative values of β 0 and β 1 that we will consider imply that the boundary is exceeded only in extremely rare events. Thus under the alternative hypotheses, the covariance is almost exactly linear in E t (R t+1 ). An econometrician observes a sample of length N and follows the two-step procedure described above to estimate the model. Two methods of implementing step one are considered. The first method uses a single regression. This produces in-sample forecasts of R t+1 and corresponding in-sample residuals. Because lagged values of R and y are used in forecasting, these regressions are subject to the predictive regressions bias. It seems plausible that the second-step estimates may be improved by using forecast errors that are not subject to this bias. This motivates the second method. It uses step-ahead forecasts from expanding regressions. The forecasts of R τ+1 and y τ+1 are constructed from OLS regressions estimated with observations one through τ. The out-of-sample forecast errors are the differences between the realized values at τ + 1 and the forecasts. The expanding regressions use a minimum of 30 observations, so the first forecast is made for observation 31. Table 1 reports the mean results across 1000 simulations. The baseline uses N = 160 (the number of quarters in 40 years), δ r =0.2 andδ y =0.4 (which produce R 2 s roughly in line with the observed predictability of stock returns and consumption growth), β 0 =0.3 (roughly the unconditional correlation between residuals of quarterly stock returns and consumption growth), and β 1 = 0 (the null hypothesis). The simulations indicate that this estimation procedure is well-behaved when in-sample residuals are used. The estimate of β 1 is unbiased and five percent of the absolute t-statistics exceed When out-of-sample residuals are used, the estimate of β 1 has a minimal bias, but the standard errors are too small. The five percent critical value for the absolute t-statistics is The first alternative hypothesis we consider is β 1 = 1. The magnitude of this coefficient is motivated by the empirical evidence presented in the next section, although the sign is reversed. Under this alternative, the relation between Cov(q t+1,v t+1 )ande t (R t+1 ) is linear for h t [ 6.5, 3.5]. Since h t is distributed as a standard normal, the likelihood of values outside of this range is vanishingly small. The simulation results indicate substantial bias towards zero in the estimate of β 1. The mean estimate using in-sample residuals is 0.76 and the mean estimate using out-of-sample residuals is only The power of the test is much larger when in-sample residuals are used than when out-of-sample residuals are used. When the five percent critical value is used to reject the null hypothesis (1.96 for the in-sample residuals and 2.15 for the out-of-sample residuals), the hypothesis is rejected in half of the simulations using in-sample residuals but in only a quarter of the simulations using out-ofsample residuals. When the alternative hypothesis is changed to β 1 = 1, the results are 8

10 similar (aside from the sign change in the estimate of β 1 ). Table 1 also reports simulation results under the null hypothesis for various changes to the baseline assumptions. First, the (constant) correlation between q t+1 and v t+1 is increased from 0.3 to 0.5. The main effect of this change is to increase the critical value for the t-test. Second, mean of R t is made time-invariant. This is designed to capture the idea that any forecastability of stock returns is spurious. This change increases the critical value for the t-test with out-of-sample residuals, but has little effect on the in-sample results. Third, the number of observations is cut in half. The effect of this change is similar to the effect of the second change. There are three main points to take from this Monte Carlo evidence. First, residuals should be constructed in-sample rather than with expanding regressions. Second, given reasonable parameter values under the null, this two-stage regression procedure using insample residuals produces unbiased point estimates and reasonably accurate rejection rates at a five percent critical value. Third, under plausible alternative hypotheses, inference is somewhat problematic. Point estimates are biased toward zero and the likelihood of failing to reject the null hypothesis is fairly high. 3 The evidence for predictable covariances 3.1 Some timing issues Asset prices are measured at points in time while real variables are time-averaged. Thus we need a timing convention to align asset returns with growth in real variables. I follow Campbell (1999) by defining an asset return from quarter t to quarter t + k as the return from the beginning of quarter t (the end of t 1) to the beginning of quarter t + k (the end of quarter t + k 1). The growth in a real variable over the same period is defined as the log change from quarter t to quarter t + k. Covariances between observed asset returns and real variables are determined largely by economic fundamentals. But they are also affected by time-averaging, measurement error, and the frequency at which individuals and firms adjust their behavior. Lynch (1996) notes that when decision costs lead to infrequent adjustments by agents, covariances between stock returns and real variables such as consumption growth will be lower than if agents reacted instantaneously. There is no reason to believe that the influences of time-averaging or measurement error on covariances will vary systematically over time. But a case can be made for a systematic relation between decision costs and the business cycle. For example, it wouldn t be hard to construct a model in which the utility cost of slow adjustment is larger 9

11 in recessions. Although the relation between decision costs and the macroeconomy is interesting, it is not the focus of this paper. Therefore I want to minimize the potential influence of decision costs on the results here. Lynch s model implies that as the measurement horizon for returns and growth in real variables is increased, the influence of infrequent decisionmaking declines. The econometric cost of longer horizons is fewer independent observations. I consider both quarterly and annual horizons because there is no clear way to evaluate this tradeoff. 3.2 The data All of the data are quarterly beginning in 1953:4, the first quarter after the end of the Korean War. The real variables I consider are those discussed in Section 2: log real per capita GDP, denoted Y (t), log consumption on nondurables and services, denoted C(t), and log labor income L(t). Changes from quarter t to quarter t + k are denoted C(t, t + k), Y (t, t + k), and L(t, t + k). My measure of aggregate excess stock returns in quarter t is the log return to the CRSP value-weighted index during quarter t less the continuously-compounded threemonth Treasury bill yield at the end of quarter t 1. The excess return from the beginning of quarter t to the beginning of quarter t + k is denoted R(t, t + k). This notation uses twotimeindexesinsteadofthesingletimeindexusedinsection2becausewewillconsider different return horizons. In the remainder of this paper, we will use only excess returns, not raw returns. Thus when the paper refers to stock returns, it should be read as excess returns. The number of variables used in the literature to forecast stock returns is impressively large. To limit the potential for data-mining, I focus on variables that are plausibly linked to the macroeconomy. My motivation is that the business cycle is the most likely source of variability in covariances between returns and real variables. 4 Fama and French (1989) identify three variables that forecast returns and are linked to the business cycle: The slope of the term structure TERM, the aggregate dividend/price ratio D/P, and the default premium (i.e., the credit spread) DEF. More recently, Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) find that the trend deviation in the log consumption-wealth ratio is a strong forecaster of expected stock returns. This deviation, denoted CAY, is a natural candidate for my purposes. The variables TERM, D/P, DEF, andcay are chosen because of their ability to forecast stock returns. I also need to forecast C(t, t+k), Y (t, t+k), and L(t, t+k) for the purpose of constructing innovations to real variables. Because there is some evidence of serial correlation in log changes in these variables, I use lagged changes of GDP and consumption 4 There is, however, somewhat sparse evidence connecting the business cycle to volatilities. See Schwert (1989). 10

12 as additional forecasting variables. I also include lagged aggregate stock returns, which tend to lead consumption and output. Thus I use a total of seven forecasting variables. 5 This set of variables is used to construct expectations of both stock returns and macroeconomic growth. 3.3 Constructing forecasts, shocks, and covariance estimates The variables used at the end of quarter t to form forecasts of future stock returns and macroeconomic growth are TERM(t) D/P(t) DEF(t) Z(t) = CAY (t 1). C(t 2,t 1) Y (t 2,t 1) R(t, t +1) The second lags of CAY and the growth rates of consumption and output are used because the macro variables are announced with a lag. The stock return R(t, t + 1) is known at the end of t. Stock returns from the beginning of quarter t + 1 to the beginning of quarter t + k are forecast with the regression R(t +1,t+ k) =a r,k,0 + a r,k,1z(t)+ R(t +1,t+ k). This regression is estimated for both quarterly (k = 2) and annual (k = 5) stock returns. Both regressions are estimated with quarterly data, which produces overlapping residuals for annual stock returns. The regression-produced forecast of R(t + 1,t + k) is denoted R(t + 1,t + k). Forecasts and residuals for changes in log consumption, GDP, and labor income are produced in the same way. The residuals for these series are denoted C(t +1,t+ k), Ỹ (t +1,t+ k), and L(t +1,t+ k). The sample period for the quarterly regressions is 1954Q2 through 2000Q1. Because of the additional three quarters needed for annual horizons, the sample period for the annual regressions ends in 1999Q2. The top panel of Figure 1 displays the forecasts of annual returns. The remaining panels in the figure display the corresponding annual stock return 5 I examined no other forecasting variables in this study. 11

13 residuals and annual GDP growth residuals. All variables are expressed in percent. The stock return forecast made at time t, the error in this forecast, and the contemporaneous error in forecasted GDP growth are all plotted at time t on the horizontal axis. It is hard to believe that these expected returns really correspond to the expectations of typical investors. For example, the return forecast produced for mid-1999 is about negative ten percent. It strains the imagination to come up with reasons why investors would buy stocks if they truly believed this forecast. A more plausible view is that these regression-based forecasts are noisy measures of investors true expectations. If our forecasting regression is correctly specified, then asymptotically the product of the OLS residual to stock returns and the OLS residual to, say, log consumption growth is drawn from a distribution with mean zero and covariance σ t (R, C). (For notational convenience, the dependence of this covariance on the horizon k is suppressed.) This product is therefore used as an ex-post estimate of the covariance. The notation I use is σ t ex (R, C) R(t +1,t+ k) C(t +1,t+ k). The superscript ex refers to an ex-post estimate. Ex-post covariances between returns and either GDP or labor income are similarly defined. Table 2 reports summary statistics for these covariance estimates, as well as for stock return forecasts. All of the variables are measured in percent. Note that the annual covariances are approximately eight times the corresponding quarterly covariances. This is the standard result (see, e.g., Campbell (1999)) that stock returns and macroeconomic growth are more closely tied at the annual frequency than at the quarterly frequency. 3.4 Explaining conditional covariances We now examine whether stock return forecasts also forecast covariances. The basic regression is σ ex t (R, X) =b 0 + b 1 R(t +1,t+ k)+e(t +1,t+ k), X {C, Y, L}. (17) The results for quarterly and annual horizons are displayed in Table 3. The table reports results for the full sample and for two subsamples created by splitting the full sample period in half. The significance level of a test that the coefficients are constant across the two subsamples is also reported. The test statistics use a Newey-West adjustment with one MA lag for quarterly horizons and four MA lags for annual horizons. There are four broad conclusions to take from this table. First, covariances between returns and both consumption and GDP growth are sensitive to forecasted stock returns. 12

14 But in stark contrast to the predictions of the model in Section 2, in the data covariances are higher when expected returns are lower. For both quarterly and annual horizons, in the full sample we can statistically reject the null hypothesis of no relation. The covariance between labor income and stock returns does not appear to be related to expected stock returns. The second conclusion is that the economic significance of this predictability is large. To put these results into perspective, consider what the point estimates from the consumption regressions imply at two different levels of expected returns: the 25th and 75th percentiles of the distribution of R(t, t + k). The values reported in Table 2 in combination with the parameter estimates in Table 3 imply the following. At the quarterly horizon, the covariance between stock returns and consumption growth conditional on the 75th percentile of expected returns is The quarterly covariance conditioned on the 75th percentile is 1.39, almost three times as large. Put differently, the ratio expected excess return RRA = 100 conditional covariance is 8.5 at the 25th percentile and 162 at the 75th percentile. This ratio is approximately the coefficient of relative risk aversion in a power utility model. 6 At the annual horizon, the corresponding conditional covariances are 3.74 and 10.70, with implied RRA coefficients of 8.4 and 299 respectively. These results are very surprising on two counts. First, research prior to this paper found no evidence not even weak evidence for time-varying covariances between stock returns and real variables. Second, the sign of this time-variation is at odds with the intuition of consumption-based asset-pricing models. It is hard to understand why investors demand high risk premia during periods when stock returns are largely decoupled from the real economic growth. One interpretation of these results is that they are spurious. Although there is no way to completely rule out this explanation, the third conclusion drawn from Table 3 is that there is no evidence that these results are an artifact of a particular subsample. The subperiod results indicate that the negative relation is somewhat stronger in the period than in the period, but the only statistical evidence of instability is for labor income for which there is no clear evidence in any period between conditional covariances and expected stock returns. In Section 4 I consider other tests of robustness. The fourth conclusion is that the negative relation is stronger at the annual horizon than at the quarterly horizon. This suggests that expected returns contain information about covariances between quarterly stock returns and subsequent macroeconomic growth, as 6 The ratio is missing the Jensen s inequality term in (4). 13

15 well as information about covariances between returns and contemporaneous macroeconomic growth. I take a closer look at this issue later. For now, I focus on the annual horizon. Although these linear regressions were motivated by the asset-pricing logic in Section 2, the signs of the estimated coefficients cannot be explained by this logic. Therefore we have no reason to continue to assume that the true relation between expected returns and covariances is linear. A more robust way to examine the data is to simply split the sample in half based on the level of the stock return forecast at time t. Let the dummy variable DUM A (t) be defined as { 1 if DUM A (t) = R(t +1,t+5)> median( R(t +1,t+ 5)); 0 otherwise. The subscript A refers to forecasts of annual returns. (In Section 4 a similar dummy is introduced based on quarterly return forecasts.) The split-sample results are determined by estimating σ t ex (R, X) =b 0 (1 DUM A (t)) + b 1 DUM A (t)+e(t), X {C, Y, L}. (18) In (18), b 0 represents the covariance conditional on low expected returns and b 1 represents the covariance conditional on high expected returns. The results of estimating (18) are displayed in Table 4. For completeness, I also report the split-sample covariances between the real variables. Where three numbers appear as a group in the table, the first is the estimated coefficient, the second (in parentheses) is the p-value of the asymptotic χ 2 (1) test that the coefficient equals zero, and the third (in brackets) is the split-sample correlation. The final set of numbers are the p-values of the asymptotic χ 2 (1) test that the covariances are equal across the two samples. The test statistics use a Newey-West adjustment (four MA lags). Table 4 confirms that covariances between returns and both consumption and output are higher when expected returns are lower. We can reject at the 5% level the hypothesis that the covariance with consumption growth is constant across the two samples, and at the 1% level the corresponding hypothesis for output growth. The covariances in the low-expectedreturn sample are about three times the covariances in the high-expected return sample. The table also confirms that the covariance with labor income is insensitive to expected returns. Changes in covariances can be decomposed into changes in standard deviations and changes in correlations. Table 4 indicates that the standard deviations of both stock returns and the real variables in the low expected return sample are about 1.2 to 1.3 times the corresponding standard deviations in the high expected return sample. This pattern in stock 14

16 return variances is consistent with earlier evidence that stock return volatilities and expected returns exhibit a modest negative relation. 7 This pattern for real variables is documented here for the first time, but it is not particularly dramatic, and the statistical significance is marginal. Correlations between stock returns and real variables are more sensitive to expected returns. They are about twice as large in the low expected return sample than in the high expected return sample. (Again, labor income is an exception.) The correlations are so low in the high-expected-return period that we cannot reject at the 1% level the hypothesis that stock returns have a zero covariance with either consumption growth or GDP growth. Visual evidence is helpful here. Figure 2 displays four scatter plots. The left column contains scatter plots of stock return shocks and either consumption (top) or GDP (bottom) shocks in high-expected-return periods. The right column corresponds to low-expectedreturn periods. It is clear from this figure that the correlation patterns documented with regression evidence are not artifacts of a few data points. The results in this section document a strong, stable negative relation between the covariances and the regression-produced forecasts of expected returns. In the next section we take a closer look at various aspects of this relation. 4 Additional evidence 4.1 Out-of-sample results The use of in-sample regressions means that we are using information that investors do not have in forming forecasts of conditional variances. This is innocuous as long as investors forecasts are time-invariant linear functions of the state vector Z(t). Then the econometrician is simply inferring what investors already know. Since this assumption of investors forecasts is likely overly strong, here I adopt a procedure that could be implemented in real time. For each quarter-end τ, I replicate the first-step regressions described in Section 3.3 using data available through τ. (For example, I assume the most recent available observation of aggregate consumption is that for τ 1.) 8 Predicted returns and residuals of returns, consumption growth, GDP growth, and labor income growth from these first-step regressions are then used to estimate (17) at the annual horizon. The first-step regressions are also used to form out-of-sample, time-τ forecasts of R(τ +1,τ +5), C(τ +1,τ +5), Y (τ +1,τ +5), and L(τ +1,τ +5). The forecast of R(τ +1,τ +5) is combined with the parameters from the quarter-τ estimate 7 See, e.g., Whitelaw (2000). 8 Data revisions are ignored. 15

17 of (17) to forecast out-of-sample covariances σ τ(r, X),X {C, Y, L}. The asterisk refers to forecasts made using this out-of-sample approach. The process is repeated for each τ {1965Q1, 1999Q2}. (I choose the first date so that each regression equation has at least 30 degrees of freedom.) To evaluate the accuracy of these forecasted covariances, I compare them to the product of realized forecast errors. Realizations of R(τ + 1,τ + 5) and the contemporaneous growth rates in real variables are used to construct forecast errors. Products of the forecast errors correspond to ex-post estimates of the covariances, denoted στ ex, (R, X),X {C, Y, L}. I then estimate the regression σ t ex, (R, X) =c 0 + c 1 σ t (R, X)+η(t), X {C, Y, L}. If the forecasts are unbiased, we should find c 0 =0andc 1 = 1. Results from this regression are displayed in Table 5. Of course, this methodology is not truly out of sample; the choice of variables included in the forecasting vector Z(t) is determined by our knowledge of the entire sample path. In addition, the forecasting variable CAY defined by Lettau and Ludvigson uses an in-sample cointegrating regression. I do not attempt to address the first of these two problems, but to address the second I reproduce the entire exercise dropping CAY as a forecasting variable. These results are also displayed in Table 5. The main message of Table 5 is that the out-of-sample forecasts for covariances between stock returns and either consumption or GDP contain substantial information about actual covariances. I focus on the results using CAY ; those excluding CAY are similar. The first column of numbers reports the mean estimates of the regression coefficient b 1 in (17). The means for consumption and GDP are about half their in-sample counterparts reported in Table 3. This is not surprising; the errors-in-variables problem in (17) is more pronounced with smaller sample sizes. Excluding the results for labor income, the estimates of c 0 are statistically indistinguishable from zero and the estimates of c 1 are statistically indistinguishable from one. (The standard errors use a Newey-West adjustment (four MA lags)). We can reject at the 5% level the hypothesis that c 1 = When do stock returns forecast the macroeconomy? As we saw in Section 3.4, contemporaneous covariances at the annual horizon are more sensitive to expected returns than are covariances at the quarterly horizon. This suggests that non-contemporaneous covariances at the quarterly horizon are also sensitive to expected returns. I take a look at this issue here. The approach I take is a little different from that used earlier. Instead of constructing shocks to returns and economic growth, I use the 16

18 stock return R(t + 1,t + 2) to predict contemporaneous and three future quarters of changes in consumption and output. The coefficient on the stock return is allowed to depend on DUM Q (t), an indicator variable for the magnitude of the quarter-t forecast R(t +1,t+2). If this forecast is greater than the median forecast, the dummy equals one. The regression for consumption is C(t +1+k, t +2+k) = b 0 + b 1 DUM Q (t)+ (b 2 + b 3 DUM Q (t))r(t +1,t+2), k =0,...,3. I also estimate this regression using GDP. The sample period is 1954Q2 through 2000Q1. Because the residuals are correlated, I use a Newey-West adjustment for the test statistics (three MA lags). Table 6 contains the results, which can be summarized with two observations. First, the relation between stock returns and both contemporaneous and future macroeconomic growth is strong when expected returns are low. All of the estimates of b 2 exceed zero and six of the eight are statistically significant at the 5% level. This evidence is consistent with earlier work, which found that (unconditionally) increases in stock prices correspond to contemporaneous and future increases in aggregate consumption and output. 9 However, the second observation is that when expected returns are high, the relation between stock returns and macroeconomic growth disappears. The column labeled p-val of sum reports the significance level of the test that b 2 +b 3 =0. Thishypothesisisnotrejected at the 10% level in any of the regressions. Thus when expected returns are high, quarterly stock returns are largely decoupled from both contemporaneous and future macroeconomic growth. The well-documented link between stock returns and macroeconomic growth holds only in periods of low expected returns. As an aside, this result implies that the forecasting equation used to produce residuals of consumption and GDP growth in Section 3.3 is misspecified. In that regression, a linear relation is assumed to hold between stock returns and future macroeconomic growth, which is inconsistent with the evidence here. 4.3 Other assets The theory motivating the empirical tests in this paper does not imply anything special about stocks. Any risky asset will work, as long as it has predictable variations in returns. An earlier version of this paper looked at both stocks and long-term bonds. The detailed results are not included in this paper because they can be summarized easily. There is 9 See, e.g., Fischer and Merton (1984) or Barro (1989). 17

19 no significant relation between forecasts of excess bond returns and conditional covariances between bond returns and real variables. Given the other results presented here, this insignificance does not tell us much. If I had documented a positive relation between expected stock returns and conditional covariances with stock returns, the insignificance of the bond results would be more worrisome. We would be tempted to interpret a positive relation in the stock market as evidence that risk premia varied because investors were reacting to conditional covariances. Since risk premia vary in the bond market without corresponding variations in conditional covariances, this would be a more difficult story to tell. However, since expected stock returns and covariances move inversely, we cannot tell this story anyway. The next section considers some alternative explanations for these empirical patterns. 5 Interpretations This paper documents a strong relation between forecasted stock returns and conditional covariances between stock returns and economic growth. This evidence begs a number of questions that I examine in this section. 5.1 What moves stock prices? We saw in Section 4.2 that the relation between stock returns and macroeconomic growth is predictably strong or weak, depending on expected returns to stocks. This suggests that the kinds of shocks that hit the economy in periods of high expected stock returns are qualitatively different from the kinds of shocks that hit in periods of low expected stock returns. Can we say anything more about the nature of these shocks? Put differently, can we say what stock prices are reacting to across these regimes? Stock prices should respond to news about cash flows and discount rates. Realizations of cash flows, discount rates, and future interest rates are noisy measures of these expectations. Thus a standard test of models of asset-price determination is to regress asset returns on current and future realizations of relevant variables. 10 I follow the same approach here. A natural starting point is dividends. I also use inflation, based on earlier research that documents a strong inverse relation between inflation and stock prices. 11 In addition, long-term bond yields should contain information about future discount rates. Denote by DIV (t + 4) the log of one year of trailing dividends (sum of dividends during quarters t See Fama (1990) for an implementation of this approach and references to earlier research. 11 See, e.g., Fama (1981). 18

20 through t + 4). This variable is known at the beginning of quarter t + 5. The appendix describes the construction of the series. The one-year trailing inflation rate in quarter t + 4 (log change in the CPI from t to t+4) is denoted π(t+4). I assume this variable is known at the beginning of quarter t + 5. The ten-year Treasury bond yield observed at the beginning of quarter t + 5 is denoted 10YR(t +5). I want to use these three variables to explain the innovation R(t+1,t+5). Therefore I construct innovations in the explanatory variables by regressing them on information available at the end of quarter t. The explanatory variables DIV (t),div(t 4), π(t),π(t 4), 10YR(t), and 10Y R(t 4). Denote the in-sample residuals as DIV (t+4), π(t+4), and 10YR(t+5). I performed some extensive data-mining to end up with this short list of explanatory variables. Below I briefly mention results using other variables of interest. The main regression is R(t +1,t+5)=b 0 + b 1 DIV (t +4)+b 2 π(t +4)+b 3 10YR(t +5)+e(t +5). Following the methodology adopted earlier, I estimate this regression on two samples, based on whether the expectation of R(t +1,t+ 5) formed at the end of quarter t isgreaterorless than its median value. 12 The results are displayed in Table 7. When dividend innovations are used to explain innovations in stock returns, we see a dramatic difference across the two samples. When expected stock returns are low, dividend shocks and stock returns are closely linked. The adjusted R 2 using this single variable is By contrast, when expected stock returns are high, there is, at best, a weak relation between shocks to dividends and stock returns. The estimated coefficient is statistically indistinguishable from zero at the 5% level, and the adjusted R 2 is only (The standard error of the estimated residuals (SEE) is higher in the latter sample. The reason is that, as documented in Table 4, the variance of stock returns is larger when expected returns are high than when they are low.) This dichotomy is consistent with the evidence presented elsewhere in this paper. There is an apparent disconnect between real activity and the stock market in high-expected-return periods. What explains this? Part of the answer lies with the dynamics of dividends and inflation. When the inflation innovation is included in the high-expected-return regression, the adjusted R 2 in the highexpected-return sample jumps from 0.07 to In addition, the coefficient on the dividend innovation is larger than when inflation is not included, and is strongly significant. Adding inflation to the regression in the low-expected-return sample also raises the adjusted R 2, but 12 The regressions used to construct innovations in dividends, inflation, and ten-year bond yields are also estimated separately on these samples, to allow for the possibility that their dynamics depend systematically on expected returns. 19

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Properties of the estimated five-factor model Informationin(andnotin)thetermstructure Appendix. Additional results Greg Duffee Johns Hopkins This draft: October 8, Properties of the estimated five-factor model No stationary term structure model is

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective

A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective A Note on the Economics and Statistics of Predictability: A Long Run Risks Perspective Ravi Bansal Dana Kiku Amir Yaron November 14, 2007 Abstract Asset return and cash flow predictability is of considerable

More information

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics Appendix 1 A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics This section provides a simple illustrative example to show how the level and slope factors incorporate expectations regarding

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2013 GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 1 / 37 Squared log returns for CRSP daily GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 2 / 37 Absolute value

More information

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Estimation of dynamic term structure models Estimation of dynamic term structure models Greg Duffee Haas School of Business, UC-Berkeley Joint with Richard Stanton, Haas School Presentation at IMA Workshop, May 2004 (full paper at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/duffee)

More information

Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates

Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates Prof. Massimo Guidolin Advanced Financial Econometrics III Winter/Spring 2017 Overview The key point One open puzzle Cointegration approaches to forecasting interest

More information

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Christian Julliard and Anisha Ghosh Working Paper 2008 P t d b J L i f NYU A t P i i Presented by Jason Levine for NYU Asset Pricing Seminar, Fall 2009

More information

Global Currency Hedging

Global Currency Hedging Global Currency Hedging JOHN Y. CAMPBELL, KARINE SERFATY-DE MEDEIROS, and LUIS M. VICEIRA ABSTRACT Over the period 1975 to 2005, the U.S. dollar (particularly in relation to the Canadian dollar), the euro,

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Department of Finance Working Paper Series

Department of Finance Working Paper Series NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LEONARD N. STERN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Department of Finance Working Paper Series FIN-03-005 Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch, Jessica Wachter

More information

Predicting Dividends in Log-Linear Present Value Models

Predicting Dividends in Log-Linear Present Value Models Predicting Dividends in Log-Linear Present Value Models Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER This Version: 8 August, 2011 JEL Classification: C12, C15, C32, G12 Keywords: predictability, dividend yield,

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Predictable Stock Returns in the United States and Japan: A Study of Long-Term Capital Market Integration. John Y. Campbell Yasushi Hamao

Predictable Stock Returns in the United States and Japan: A Study of Long-Term Capital Market Integration. John Y. Campbell Yasushi Hamao Predictable Stock Returns in the United States and Japan: A Study of Long-Term Capital Market Integration John Y. Campbell Yasushi Hamao Working Paper No. 57 John Y. Campbell Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Ian Dew-Becker and Stefano Giglio Duke Fuqua and Chicago Booth 11/27/13 Dew-Becker and Giglio (Duke and Chicago) Frequency-domain asset pricing

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules

Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules Ray C. Fair May 2000 Abstract Estimated, calibrated, and optimal interest rate rules are examined for their ability to dampen economic fluctuations

More information

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults March, 2018 Contents 1 1 Robustness Tests The results presented in the main text are robust to the definition of debt repayments, and the

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University Volume 30, Issue Random risk aversion and the cost of eliminating the foreign exchange risk of the Euro Samih A Azar Haigazian University Abstract This paper answers the following questions. If the Euro

More information

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers Final Exam Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, 2004 Answers This exam consists of two parts. The first part is a long analytical question. The second part is a set of short discussion questions.

More information

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance Panel Data, Fixed Effects, and Standard Errors The use of panel datasets Source: Bowen, Fresard, and Taillard (2014) 4/20/2015 2 The use of panel datasets Source:

More information

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Addendum Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara This version: February 01 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. Nova School of Business

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Temporary movements in stock prices

Temporary movements in stock prices Temporary movements in stock prices Jonathan Lewellen MIT Sloan School of Management 50 Memorial Drive E52-436, Cambridge, MA 02142 (617) 258-8408 lewellen@mit.edu First draft: August 2000 Current version:

More information

Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions

Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions and their Uses in GARCH Modelling Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring 2015 Overview Non-normalities in (standardized) residuals from asset return

More information

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Time-Series Time-series is a sequence fx 1, x 2,..., x T g or fx t g, t = 1,..., T, where t is an index denoting

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes CFA Level II - LOS Changes 2017-2018 Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Ethics Topic LOS Level II - 2017 (464 LOS) LOS Level II - 2018 (465 LOS) Compared 1.1.a 1.1.b 1.2.a 1.2.b 1.3.a

More information

where T = number of time series observations on returns; 4; (2,,~?~.

where T = number of time series observations on returns; 4; (2,,~?~. Given the normality assumption, the null hypothesis in (3) can be tested using "Hotelling's T2 test," a multivariate generalization of the univariate t-test (e.g., see alinvaud (1980, page 230)). A brief

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix Denote by Λ t the Lagrange multiplier attached to the capital accumulation equation. The optimal policy is characterized by the first order conditions: (1 α)a t K t α

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Understanding Stock Return Predictability Hui Guo and Robert Savickas Working Paper 2006-019B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-019.pdf

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998

Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998 economics letters Intertemporal substitution and durable goods: long-run data Masao Ogaki a,*, Carmen M. Reinhart b "Ohio State University, Department of Economics 1945 N. High St., Columbus OH 43210,

More information

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM Campbell R. Harvey and Akhtar Siddique ABSTRACT Single factor asset pricing models face two major hurdles: the problematic time-series properties

More information

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford Financial Econometrics Notes Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford Monday 15 th January, 2018 2 This version: 22:52, Monday 15 th January, 2018 2018 Kevin Sheppard ii Contents 1 Probability, Random Variables

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes CFA Level II - LOS Changes 2018-2019 Topic LOS Level II - 2018 (465 LOS) LOS Level II - 2019 (471 LOS) Compared Ethics 1.1.a describe the six components of the Code of Ethics and the seven Standards of

More information

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract This version: July 16, 2 A Moving Window Analysis of the Granger Causal Relationship Between Money and Stock Returns Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper Abstract

More information

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Yin-Wong Cheung University of California, U.S.A. Frank Westermann University of Munich, Germany Daily data from the German and

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime Lecture 8: Markov and Regime Switching Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring 2016 Overview Motivation Deterministic vs. Endogeneous, Stochastic Switching Dummy Regressiom Switching

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Syed M. Hussain Samreen Malik May 9,. Online Appendix.. Anticipated versus Unanticipated Tax changes Comparing our estimates with the estimates

More information

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession Roger E.A. Farmer Department of Economics, UCLA 23 Bunche Hall Box 91 Los Angeles CA 9009-1 rfarmer@econ.ucla.edu Phone: +1 3 2 Fax: +1 3 2 92

More information

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Carlo Favero July 2012 Favero, Xiamen University () Demographics & Stock Market July 2012 1 / 37 Outline Return Predictability and the dynamic dividend growth

More information

Asymmetric cross-sectional dispersion in stock returns: Evidence and implications ABSTRACT

Asymmetric cross-sectional dispersion in stock returns: Evidence and implications ABSTRACT Asymmetric cross-sectional dispersion in stock returns: Evidence and implications Gregory R Duffee Haas School of Business UC Berkeley Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco This Draft:

More information

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility Current Account Balances and Output Volatility Ceyhun Elgin Bogazici University Tolga Umut Kuzubas Bogazici University Abstract: Using annual data from 185 countries over the period from 1950 to 2009,

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime Lecture 9: Markov and Regime Switching Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring 2017 Overview Motivation Deterministic vs. Endogeneous, Stochastic Switching Dummy Regressiom Switching

More information

A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes

A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes Preliminary and Incomplete Not for circulation A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes Marcio G. P. Garcia Depto. de Economica PUC RIO Rua Marques de Sao Vicente, 225 Gavea Rio

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques

Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Recent Advances in Fixed Income Securities Modeling Techniques Day 1: Equilibrium Models and the Dynamics of Bond Returns Pietro Veronesi Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago CEPR, NBER Bank

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements Table of List of figures List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements page xii xv xvii xix xxi xxv 1 Introduction 1 1.1 What is econometrics? 2 1.2 Is

More information

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011 Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011 Kurt G. Lunsford University of Wisconsin Madison January 2013 Abstract I propose an augmented version of Okun s law that regresses

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Hui Guo a, Christopher J. Neely b * a College of Business, University of Cincinnati, 48

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops

More information

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, NBER, PIER March 2018 Pushing the Frontier of Central Bank s Macro Modeling Preliminaries This paper

More information

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA?

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA? C. Barry Pfitzner, Department of Economics/Business, Randolph-Macon College, Ashland, VA, bpfitzne@rmc.edu ABSTRACT This paper investigates the

More information

The Impacts of State Tax Structure: A Panel Analysis

The Impacts of State Tax Structure: A Panel Analysis The Impacts of State Tax Structure: A Panel Analysis Jacob Goss and Chang Liu0F* University of Wisconsin-Madison August 29, 2018 Abstract From a panel study of states across the U.S., we find that the

More information

Spurious Regression and Data Mining in Conditional Asset Pricing Models*

Spurious Regression and Data Mining in Conditional Asset Pricing Models* Spurious Regression and Data Mining in Conditional Asset Pricing Models* for the Handbook of Quantitative Finance, C.F. Lee, Editor, Springer Publishing by: Wayne Ferson, University of Southern California

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT Long Chen Lu Zhang Working Paper 15219 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15219 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Critical Finance Review, 2012, 1: 141 182 The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Jason Beeler 1 and John Y. Campbell 2 1 Department of Economics, Littauer Center,

More information

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets Andrey Ermolov Columbia Business School April 24, 2014 1 / 41 Stylized Facts about Bond Markets US Fact 1: Upward Sloping Real Yield Curve In US, real long

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? Massimiliano Marzo and Paolo Zagaglia This version: January 6, 29 Preliminary: comments

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Volume 35, Issue 1 Exchange rate determination in Vietnam Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Abstract This study investigates the determinants of the exchange rate in Vietnam and suggests policy

More information

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Jason Beeler and John Y. Campbell October 0 Beeler: Department of Economics, Littauer Center, Harvard University,

More information

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis WenShwo Fang Department of Economics Feng Chia University 100 WenHwa Road, Taichung, TAIWAN Stephen M. Miller* College of Business University

More information

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol., No., Fall 998, pp. 3 Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research David E. Runkle Research Officer Research Department

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNCOVERING THE RISK-RETURN RELATION IN THE STOCK MARKET. Hui Guo Robert F. Whitelaw

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNCOVERING THE RISK-RETURN RELATION IN THE STOCK MARKET. Hui Guo Robert F. Whitelaw NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNCOVERING THE RISK-RETURN RELATION IN THE STOCK MARKET Hui Guo Robert F. Whitelaw Working Paper 9927 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9927 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

Momentum and Downside Risk

Momentum and Downside Risk Momentum and Downside Risk Abstract We examine whether time-variation in the profitability of momentum strategies is related to variation in macroeconomic conditions. We find reliable evidence that the

More information

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs John L. Glascock 1 University of Connecticut Ran Lu-Andrews 2 California Lutheran University (This version: August 2016) Abstract The traditional

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction

Chapter 1. Introduction Chapter 1 Introduction 2 Oil Price Uncertainty As noted in the Preface, the relationship between the price of oil and the level of economic activity is a fundamental empirical issue in macroeconomics.

More information

Hedging inflation by selecting stock industries

Hedging inflation by selecting stock industries Hedging inflation by selecting stock industries Author: D. van Antwerpen Student number: 288660 Supervisor: Dr. L.A.P. Swinkels Finish date: May 2010 I. Introduction With the recession at it s end last

More information

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen Outline Introduction Equity premium puzzle Recent contribution Contribution of this paper Long-Run Risk Model

More information

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018 Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018 Contents Ray C. Fair 2018 1 Macroeconomic Methodology 4 1.1 The Cowles Commission Approach................. 4 1.2 Macroeconomic Methodology.................... 5 1.3 The

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information