Macroeconomic Sources of Equity Risk

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Macroeconomic Sources of Equity Risk"

Transcription

1 Macroeconomic Sources of Equity Risk P.N. Smith, S. Sorenson and M.R. Wickens University of York June 2003 Abstract Empirical studies of equity returns can be classified broadly into two types: those based on a theoretical model of the risk premium that satisfies the no-arbitrage condition, and statistical models constructed to best fit the data with no regard to the no-arbitrage condition. In this paper we show how the stochastic discount factor (SDF) model can be used to measure the equity risk premium for theoretical models. We provide new estimates of the equity risk premium for the US and the UK based on monthly data We show how most of the theoretical models of the equity risk premium that have been proposed in the literature are special cases the SDF model. These include CAPM, consumption CAPM, habit persistence models and the Epstein-Zin model. Several of these models were proposed especially to deal with the equity premium puzzle. We explain why some of them are unable to do this as formulated. Due to the difficulties of estimation, most of them have either been calibrated, or estimated using GMM, neither of which delivers an estimate of the risk premium. We use a new empirical approach that does produce estimates of the risk premium and allows tests ofthetheories. Asaresultweprovidethefirst estimates of the equity risk premium for some of these models. In addition to examining existing theories of the equity risk premium, we use the SDF model to generate new theories. We find that macroeconomic variables not previously considered and not consistent with standard general equilibrium theory, such as production, appear to be priced for the equity risk premium. This suggests that traditional general equilibrium considerations may not be the sole explanation for the equity risk premium; other short-term factors associated with pure price risk may also be involved. We then use our estimates to investigate the importance of different components of the equity risk premium including, amongst others, return volatility. A related, and rapidly growing, literature adopts a more statistical approach. It focusses on the empirical relation between the return on equity (or the Sharpe ratio) and return volatility. We use SDF theory to show that this relation is misconceived. 0

2 1 Introduction Empirical studies of equity returns can be classified broadly into two types: those based on a theoretical model of the risk premium that satisfies the no-arbitrage condition, and statistical models constructed to best fit the data with no regard to the no-arbitrage condition. The theory-based approach typically involves the use of a partial equilibrium model such as CAPM, or a general equilibrium model like consumption-capm (CCAPM). Due to the difficulty of directly estimating the risk premium given by CCAPM either its associated Euler equation is estimated by GMM (one of the first to this was Hansen and Singleton (1983), or the risk premium is calibrated (the best known example is Mehra, R. and E. C. Prescott (1985)). As a result, it has not proved possible to extract estimates of a time-varying equity risk premium for CCAPM. The main finding for CCAPM is that the coefficient of relative risk aversion must be implausibly large in order to match the observed (ex-post) risk premium. This is the equity premium puzzle. The response has been to try to modify the theory so that it possesses other means of capturing the risk premium, and doesn t have to rely solely the coefficient of relative risk aversion to do so. One route is to assume that the utility function is time non-separable. This permits the coefficient of relative risk aversion to be different from the elasticity of inter-temporal substitution, and so introduces additional variables into the expression for the equity risk premium. Again the resulting risk premia are not estimated directly; GMM estimates of the Euler equation (Epstein and Zin (1991)), or calibration of the risk premium is undertaken instead (Campbell, J.Y. (2002)). Another route, also based on time non-separable utility, is to allow the utility function used in general equilibrium models of risk to display habit persistence, (see Abel (1990), Constantinides (1990) and Campbell and Cochrane (1999)). This has the effect of causing the inter-temporal marginal rate of substution to become more variable and so be better able to match the observed volatility of equity returns. One of the main findings to emerge from the statistical approach is that average equity returns are positively related to their volatility. The usual interpretation, informally offered, is that higher volatility implies greater risk, and larger returns are required to compensate for this. In other words, the volatility is capturing a risk premium. This explanation cannot be correct, however, as risk should be should be expressed in terms of the covariance of returns with other factors, and not the volatility of returns. It would seem, therefore, that the empirical models are simply picking up the fact that one component of all of these covariances is in terms of the volatility of returns. A more general theoretical framework of asset pricing than either CCAPM or CAPM is the stochastic discount factor (SDF); CAPM and CCAPM are special cases of this. In this paper we 1

3 show how to obtain direct estimates of a time-varying risk premium derived from the SDF model. We apply the methodology to the following models: CAPM and CCAPM with power utility and with Epstein-Zin time non-separable preferences. We show that as formulated several of the habit persistence models do not admit a time-varying equity risk premium. This only becomes apparent when one attempts to derive the risk premium for the habit persistence model. The greater generality of SDF model compared with general equilibrium models allows us to consider whether there are other priced sources of equity risk. General equilibrium models imply that investors are concerned with future consumption, and in particular, consumption next period. The main holders of equity are financial institutions, especially pension funds. They act on behalf of investors consumption at a much more distant point in the future. In assessing risk, financial institutions focus largely on short-term performance, and on the value of the portfolio. This suggests that the market equity risk premium may be more influenced by short-term price risk than longer-term considerations of consumption. The factors that affect the price of equity in the short term are associated with the business cycle and inflation. We therefore examine whether output and inflation are priced sources of equity risk. In empirical implementations of the SDF model, the factors are latent variables. Equations for the latent factors must be specified. Since data only exist for the returns, estimates of the parameters of these equations must be obtained from the likelihood function for returns. Estimates of the factors and a time-varying risk premium can then be backed out of the returns data. This is the approach commonly followed for bond pricing. It is not, however, suitable for CAPM and CCAPM because the factors are observable macroeconomic variables, namely, the market interest rate in the case of CAPM, and consumption growth (among others) for CCAPM. To obtain direct estimates of a time-varying risk premium for the SDF model when the factors are observable we therefore need a new econometric approach. In the SDF model the risk premium is represented by the conditional covariances of excess equity returns with the factors. This implies that we must model the joint distribution of excess returns and the factors in such a way that the mean of the conditional distribution of excess returns is a linear function of selected conditional covariances of the joint distribution. A convenient model to use is the multi-variate GARCH model with in mean effects. It is important to stress that the in mean effect is not just the conditional variance of returns, but also includes conditional covariance terms. In order for the econometric model to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition, restrictions must be imposed on the conditional mean. A special case of this model that omits the conditional covariances in the mean relates equity returns solely to their volatility. This enables us to compare the statistical approach with the theory-based approach. We apply this new methodology to US 2

4 and UK monthly equity returns The paper is set out as follows. In Section 2 we consider various theoretical models of the equity risk premium. As they are all special cases of the SDF model of asset pricing, first we derive the equity risk premium for a general SDF model. We then show that a number of general equilibrium models that differ due to the specification of the investor s utility function are special cases of the SDF model. Three of these models are versions of CCAPM: with power utility, with habit persistence and with Epstein-Zin utility. The first has a time separable utility function and the other two have time non-separable utility functions. We then consider CAPM and our proposed alternative to general equilibrium models of equity risk. In Section 3 we examine the theoretical plausibility of models that relate equity returns to the volatility of returns. Our new econometric methodology is described in Section 4. Estimates of the various models are reported in Section 5 together with the implied estimates of the equity risk premium. 2 Theoretical models of the equity risk premium 2.1 The SDF model of asset pricing for equity returns TheSDFmodelisbasedonthesimpleideathatP t, the price of an asset at the beginning of period t, is determined by the expected discounted value of its pay-off at the start of period t +1, namely, X t+1 : P t = E t [M t+1 X t+1 ] where M t+1 is the stochastic discount factor, or pricing kernel (see Cochrane (2001) for a survey of SDF theory). For equity, the payoff is X t+1 = P t+1 + D t+1,whered t+1 are dividend payments assumed to be made at the start of period t +1. The pricing equation can also be written X t+1 1=E t [M t+1 ]=E t [M t+1 R t+1 ], P t where R t+1 =1+r t+1 = X t+1 /P t =(P t+1 + D t+1 )/P t is the gross return and r t+1 is the return. Taking logarithms and assuming log-normality (and noting that if ln x is N(µ, σ 2 ) then ln E(x) = µ + σ2 2 )weobtain 0 = lne t [M t+1 R t+1 ] = E t [ln(m t+1 R t+1 )] + V t [ln(m t+1 R t+1 )]/2 = E t (m t+1 )+E t (r t+1 )+V t (m t+1 )/2+V t (r t+1 )/2+cov t (m t+1,r t+1 ) where m t+1 =lnm t+1. Hence the pricing equation can be written E t (r t+1 )+E t (m t+1 )+V t (m t+1 )/2+V t (r t+1 )/2 = cov t (m t+1,r t+1 ) 3

5 If the asset is risk-free then its return is known at the start of period t implying r t+1 r f t, E t (r t+1 )=r f t and V t (r t+1 )=0. The pricing equation for the risk-free asset can therefore be written E t (m t+1 )+r f t V t(m t+1 )=0. Subtracting the two pricing equations gives the expected excess return on the risky asset E t (r t+1 r f t )+ 1 2 V t(r t+1 )= Cov t (m t+1,r t+1 ). This is the key no-arbitrage condition that all correctly priced assets must satisfy when their returns are lognormally distributed. The right-hand side is the risk premium and 1 2 V t(r t+1 ) is the Jensen effect Real versus nominal returns This no-arbitrage condition holds whether we measure returns in nominal or real terms. If real returns are measured ex-ante, i.e. as nominal returns less expected future inflation and the discount factor is defined in real ex-ante terms, then we can use either real or nominal returns in formula as expected future inflation is known at time t. In general equilibrium models it is usual to express the discount factor implicitly in real ex-ante terms. However, most empirical studies use ex-post and not ex-ante returns and discount factors. In this case the real ex-ante discount factor will different from the real ex-post. If we adopt this convention and define M t+1 as the real ex-post discount factor and r t+1 and r f t as real ex-post rates of return, then the no-arbitrage condition for nominal returns will require re-stating. Since only a nominal risk-free rate exists in practice (assuming no default risk this is the Treasury bill rate), it makes more sense to conduct the analysis of equity returns using nominal variables. Let Mt+1 N denote the nominal discount factor, let i t+1 and i f t be the respective nominal rates of return and let P t be the consumer price index at the start of period t. It follows that for ex-post real returns 1+i t+1 =(1+r t+1 ) P t+1 =(1+r t+1 )(1 + π t+1 ) P t where π t+1 is the inflation rate. Hence 1 = E t [M t+1.(1 + r t+1 )] = E t [M t+1. 1+i t+1 1+π t+1 ] M t+1 = E t [.(1 + i t+1 )] 1+π t+1 4

6 and so Mt+1 N = Mt+1 1+π t+1. It can be shown that the no-arbitrage condition for nominal returns and a real discount factor is E t (i t+1 i f t )+ 1 2 V t(i t+1 )= Cov t (m t+1,i t+1 )+Cov t (π t+1,i t+1 ). We now consider a number of models of the discount factor. 2.2 Consumption-based models C-CAPM with power utility The canonical model of the discount factor is the consumption-based CAPM for real asset returns. Asset prices derive their value from the expected consumption streams of investors who choose to subject to the budget constraint max C t {U t = U(C t )+βe t (U t+1 )} C t + W t+1 = Y t + W t R t where C t is real consumption, Y t is real non-asset income and W t is real financial wealth at the start of period t. The solution is the Euler equation E t [ βu 0 (C t+1 ) U 0 R t+1 ]=1. (C t ) This implies that the CCAPM has implicitly defined the real SDF as M t+1 = βu 0 (C t+1 ) U 0 (C t ) 1 For the power utility function U = C1 σ t 1 σ with constant coefficient of relative risk aversion σ, the real discount factor is: µ σ Ct+1 M t+1 = β Since real consumption is usually defined in ex-post terms, the discount factor will also be in real ex-post terms. Taking logarithms, and ignoring all constants, we obtain C t m t+1 = σ ln C t+1 where c t =lnc t. The no-arbitrage condition in real terms becomes E t (r t+1 r f t )+ 1 2 V t(r t+1 )=σcov t (r t+1 c t+1 ) 5

7 The interpretation of the real equity risk premium is that investors lose utility today by not consuming. To compensate investors who defer the utility from an extra unit of consumption today they need additional marginal utility from future consumption. Because marginal utility declines as consumption increases, a higher level of consumption is needed in the future. The return on the investment must be large enough to generate the required consumption in the future. The greater the consumption needed, the larger the return must be, hence the risk premium is larger the greater the predicted covariance between consumption and returns. Another way to think about the equity risk premium is to note that over the business cycle equity returns tend to be positively correlated with consumption growth. In the downturn when consumption growth tends to be low, equity returns are also low, hence risk is associated with the predicted covariance of returns with consumption. In nominal terms the no-arbitrage condition can be written E t (i t+1 i f t )+ 1 2 V t(i t+1 )=σcov t (i t+1 c t+1 )+Cov t (i t+1 π t+1 ) Thus the nominal risk premium involves the nominal return and has a second covariance term associated with consumer price inflation. The greater the covariance between nominal returns and inflation, the larger the risk premium. We have argued that the larger the future consumption needed, the higher real returns must be. This is also true for nominal returns. The extra risk is that nominal returns will be larger solely due to inflation C-CAPM with Epstein-Zin preferences CCAPM with power utility restricts the coefficient of relative risk aversion to be equal to the elasticity of inter-temporal substitution. This restriction can be relaxed using a time non-separable utility function. A general formulation of time non-separable utility proposed by Kreps and Porteus (1978) is U t = U[C t,e t (U t+1 )] Epstein and Zin (1989), Epstein and Zin (1991) have implemented a special case of this based on the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function: U t = (1 β)c 1 γ 1 t + β[e t (U 1 1 σ 1 1 γ 1 t+1 )]1 1 γ where β is the discount rate, σ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion and γ is the elasticity of inter-temporal substitution. In the separable, power utility case σ =1/γ. Epstein and Zin show that maximising U t subject to a slightly different budget constraint W t+1 = R m t+1(w t C t ) 6

8 where Rt+1 m is the return on the market portfolio of all invested wealth. The asset pricing equation for the portfolio return derived by Epstein and Zin is ( E t β( C 1 σ ) t+1 ) 1 1 γ R m γ 1 C t+1 =1 t and for the return on an individual asset with gross real return R t+1 is ( E t β( C t+1 C t ) 1 γ 1 σ 1 1 γ The real stochastic discount factor is therefore M t+1 = In logarithms it is β( C t+1 ) 1 γ C t ) 1 σ (Rt+1) m 1 γ 1 1 Rt+1 1 σ 1 1 γ 1 σ (Rt+1) m 1 γ 1 1 m t+1 = 1 σ 1 γ ln C t+1 1 γσ 1 γ rm t+1 The resulting no-arbitrage condition first derived by Campbell and MacKinlay (1997) is E t (r t+1 r f t )+ 1 2 V t(r t+1 )= 1 σ 1 γ Cov t(r t+1 c t+1 )+ 1 γσ 1 γ Cov t(r t+1 r m t+1) =1 Using nominal gross market returns R N t+1, the Euler equation becomes ( E t β( C t+1 C t ) 1 γ 1 σ 1 1 γ and the log nominal stochastic discount factor is ) Rt+1 N 1 σ 1 ( ) 1 1 R γ t+1 ( ) =1 P t+1 /P t P t+1 /P t m t+1 = 1 σ 1 γ ln C t+1 1 γσ γ(1 σ) 1 γ im t γ π t+1 where i m t+1 is the nominal market return. The no-arbitrage condition for the nominal return on an individual asset with Epstein-Zin preferences is E t (i t+1 i f t )+ 1 2 V t(i t+1 ) = 1 σ 1 γ Cov t(i t+1 c t+1 ) + 1 γσ 1 γ Cov t(i t+1 i m t+1) γ(1 σ) 1 γ Cov t(i t+1 π t+1 ) Adifficulty in implementing this in practice is choosing a market rate of return. A convenient alternative is to assume that the market portfolio consists of equity and a risk-free asset. The market return is then a weighted average of the two. i m t+1 = θ t i t+1 +(1 θ t )i f t 7

9 Iftheweassumethattheweightsθ t = θ, a constant, the Epstein-Zin no-arbitrage condition then becomes the fixed parameter model E t (i t+1 i f t )+( 1 2 θ 1 γσ 1 γ )V t(i t+1 ) = 1 σ 1 γ Cov t(i t+1 c t+1 ) γ(1 σ) 1 γ Cov t(i t+1 π t+1 ) Comparing the no-arbitrage condition for power utility with this condition, we note that the interpretation of all of the coefficients is changed. The coefficient on Cov t (i t+1 c t+1 ) is no longer the coefficient of relative risk aversion, and the coefficients on V t (i t+1 ) and Cov t (i t+1 π t+1 ) are no longer restricted Habit persistence An alternative example of time non-separable utility is the habit persistence model which assumes that U t = U(C t,x t ) where X t is the habitual level of consumption. Again the aim of this approach is to introduce additional terms in the risk premium. Various specific functional forms for the utility function have been suggested. Constantinides (1990) proposed the form U t = (C t λx t ) 1 σ 1 1 σ The stochastic discount factor implied by this is µ Ct+1 λx t+1 M t+1 = β C t λx t By a suitable choice of λ and X t it is possible to produce a discount factor that displays greater volatility and hence a larger risk premium. Campbell and Cochrane (1999) implemented this with the restriction that λ = 1. They introduced the concept of surplus consumption, defined as S t = C t X t C t. The discount factor can then be written µ σ Ct S t+1 M t+1 = β C t+1 S t Assuming log normality, the discount factor is σ no-arbitrage condition is m t+1 = σ c t+1 σ s t+1 E t (r t+1 r f t )+ 1 2 V t(r t+1 )= σcov t (r t+1, c t+1 )+σcov t (r t+1,s t+1 ) 8

10 where s t+1 =lns t+1. The attraction of this approach is the inclusion of the extra term to account for the risk premium. The problem lies in the way it has been implemented. Campbell and Cochrane assume that s t+1 is generated by an AR(1) process with a disturbance term whose variance depends on s t. They do not estimate the resulting model but, like Constantinides, use calibration methods. By calibrating the unconditional variance of the error term of the AR process suitably, it is possible to force the covariance between r t+1 and s t+1 to be of the necessary size. By this means success is virtually guaranteed. Unfortunately, by making s t+1 an AR(1) process, Cov t (r t+1,s t+1 )=0. As a result, this version of the habit persistence hypothesis is incapable of providing any additional explanation of the risk premium as the implied conditional covariance r t+1 and s t+1 is necessarily zero. A similar analysis applies to the habit persistence utility function proposed by Abel (1990) U t = ³ Ct X t 1 σ 1 1 σ where X t is a function of past consumption, for example X t = Ct 1. δ The stochastic discount à Ct+1! σ factor becomes M t+1 = β and so X t+1 C t X t m t+1 = σ c t+1 + σ x t+1 where x t =lnx t. Assuming log normality, the no-arbitrage condition is now E t (r t+1 r f t )+ 1 2 V t(r t+1 )=σcov t ( c t+1,r t+1 ) σcov t (r t+1, x t+1 ) If, however, it is assumed that x t+1 = δc t then Cov t (r t+1, x t+1 )=δcov t (r t+1, c t )=0 and so once again the habit persistence model is of no help in providing additional terms in the risk premium. Thus, the problem is that if habit is solely related to past consumption - which is its natural meaning - then the conditional covariance of returns with the discount factor are unaffected. As unconditional moments are used in GMM estimation of the Euler equation, measuring habit by past consumption does not prevent the parameters of the habit persistence model from being estimated. It is only when trying to estimate the risk premium itself that the problem with the habit persistence model becomes evident. 9

11 2.3 CAPM CAPM relates the expected excess return to the excess return of the market portfolio: E t (r t+1 r f t )=β t E t (r m t+1 r f t ) where and β t = Cov t(r t+1,r m t+1 ) V t (r m t+1 ) E t (r m t+1 r f t )=σ t V t (r m t+1). It follows that E t (r t+1 r f t )=σ t Cov t (r t+1,r m t+1) We also note that (1 + rt+1) m = W t+1 W t,wherew t is real wealth. And if consumption is proportional to wealth, as in the life cycle model, we obtain E t (r t+1 r f t )=σ t Cov t (r t+1, c t+1 ) Thus we can interpret CAPM as an SDF model in which the discount factor is σ t (1 + r m t+1 ) -or σ t W t+1 W t - and no Jensen effect is needed. The corresponding expressions for nominal returns are E t (i t+1 i f t )=σ t Cov t (i m t+1,i t+1 ) as adjusting real returns by E t π t+1 has no effect on conditional covariances The relation between equity returns and volatility The finding that the return on equity is related to its own variance does not in general satisfy a no-arbitrage condition. Much of the current view of this relation between mean and variance dates from Campbell (1987) who find that the relation is generally insignificantly positive when the conditional variance term is modelled as a GARCH-in-mean term. This result on the monthly CRSP market-wide index has been further reinforced by Baillie and DeGennero (1990) using a similar methodology. However, the results of Glosten, L.R., Jagannathan R. and D.E. Runkle (1993) and Campbell (1987) have subsequently found evidence of a significant negative relationship between mean and conditional variance. In the case of Glosten et al. the inclusion of seasonal effects to the GARCH-M model appears to be of importance whilst Campbell adopts a different approach deriving the unconditional implications of a conditional model using GMM to carry out the estimation. Recently, focus on additional factors has provided more support for a positive 10

12 (partial) relation between mean and variance; see Scruggs (1998) and Campbell, J.Y. and L. Hentschel (1992). A closely related approach is that of Lettau, M. and S.C. Ludvigson (2002) who examine the behaviour of the Sharpe ratio. Instead of using an ad hoc model of this, it is possible to infer the behaviour of the Sharpe ratio from the SDF model by re-writing the SDF no-arbitrage condition as E t (r t+1 r f t ) = 1 SD t (r t+1 ) 2 SD t(r t+1 ) ρ t (m t+1,r t+1 )SD t (m t+1 ) where ρ t (m t+1,r t+1 ) is the conditional correlation and SD t denotes a conditional standard deviation. Lettau and Ludvigson simple relate the Sharpe ratio to the conditional standard deviation of returns. Both the previous model and the Sharpe ratio models can therefore be easily tested within the SDF framework since they imply that conditional covariances can be excluded from the conditional mean and the coefficient on the own conditional variance should not be restricted to satisfy the Jensen effect. 2.4 Other SDF models The SDF model shows how any source of risk can be incorporated into an explanation of the risk premium in a way that satisfies the no-arbitrage conditiond. If z it (i =1,..., n) are n factors which are jointly log normally distributed with equity returns then the discount factor can be written m t+1 = X n β iz i,t+1 i=1 This implies the no-arbitrage condition E t (r t+1 r f t )+ 1 2 V t(r t+1 ) = X i β i Cov t (z i,t+1,r t+1 ) = X i β i f it, where the f it are known as common factors. In the absence of the sort of clear theoretical foundations provided by general equilibrium theories of asset pricing, the problem is to identify potential souces of risk to include in the SDF model. The latent factor literature simply assumes that unobserved processes can be specified for the factors. As noted above, general equilibrium models imply that investors are concerned with future consumption, and in particular, consumption next period. The main holders of equity are financial institutions, especially pension funds. They act on behalf of investors consumption at amuchmoredistantpointinthefuture. Inassessingrisk,financial institutions focus largely on 11

13 short-term performance, and on the value of the portfolio. This suggests that the market equity risk premium may be more influenced by short-term price risk than longer-term considerations of consumption. The sort of factors that are likely to affect the price of equity in the short term are associated with the business cycle and inflation. We therefore examine whether output is an additional source of equity risk to consumption and inflation. 2.5 A taxonomy of SDF models The following is a summary of the models above. 1. C-CAPM (a) based on time-separable power utility model (i) with real returns (ii) with nominal returns (b) based on the Epstein-Zin time non-separable utility model (i) with nominal returns and an explicit market return (ii) with nominal returns but no explicit market return 2. SDF model (a) based on two macroeconomic factors: consumption and inflation (b) based on three macroeconomic factors: consumption, inflation and industrial production 3. General model The SDF model based on three macroeconomic factors but removing the Jensen restriction on V t (i t+1 ) as in the E-Z model These can all be represented as restricted versions of the SDF model E t (i t+1 i f t ) = β 1 V t (i t+1 )+β 2 Cov t (i t+1 c t+1 )+β 3 Cov t (i t+1 π t+1 ) +β 5 Cov t (i t+1 q t+1 )+β 4 Cov t (i t+1 i m t+1) where q t is the logarithm of a measure of output. The SDF model restricts the coefficient on the conditional variance of equity returns to be β 1 = 1/2 (the Jensen effect). In general, the different SDF models can be distinguished by restricting selected β i to be zero. We note, however, that in SDF models which include the market return as a factor, because the market portfolio includes equity, we have found that we can replace i m t+1,setβ 5 =0and remove the restriction on β 1. The various models are summarised in Table 1 below. The statistical approach relating the conditional mean to its conditional variance implies that β 1 is unrestricted and all other β i =0 (i =2,...). Table 1 : Model Taxonomy 12

14 Model β 1 β 2 β 3 β 4 β 5 CAPM σ PU:real returns 1 2 σ PU:nominal returns 1 2 σ 1 EZ-standard θ(1 γσ) 1 γ 1 σ 1 γ SDF EZ-restricted γσ 1 γ 1 σ 1 γ Two factors 1 2 δ 1 δ 2 γ(1 σ) 1 γ γ(1 σ) 1 γ Three factors 1 2 γ 1 γ 2 γ 3 3 The Econometric Framework 3.1 Multivariate conditional heteroskedasticity models We need to model the distribution of the excess return on equity jointly with the macroeconomic factors in such a way that the mean of the conditional distribution of the excess return in period t +1, given information available at time t, satisfies the no-arbitrage condition. The conditional mean of the excess return involves selected time-varying second moments of the joint distribution. We therefore require a specification of the joint distribution that admits a time-varying variancecovariance matrix. A convenient choice is the multi-variate GARCH-in-mean (MGM) model. Let x t+1 =(r t+1 r f t,z 1,t+1,z 2,t+1,...) 0, where the variables z 1,t+1,z 2,t+1,... are the macroeconomic variables in the SDF. The MGM model can then be written x t+1 = α + Γx t + Bg t + ε t+1 where ε t+1 I t D[0, H t+1 ] g t = vech{h t+1 } The vech operator converts the lower triangle of a symmetric matrix into a vector. The distribution is the multivariate t distribution. The first equation of the model is restricted to satisfy the noarbitrage condition. Thus, in general, the first row of Γ is zero and the first row of B is ( 1 2, β 11, β 12, β 13,...). It will be noted that the theory requires that the macroeconomic variables display conditional heteroskedasticity. This is not something traditionally assumed in macro-econometrics, but seems 13

15 to be present in our data. Ideally, we would like to use high frequency data for asset returns, but very little macroeconomic data are published for frequencies higher than one month, and then only a few variables are available. Although more macroeconomic variables are published at lower frequencies, they tend not to display conditional heteroskedasticity. Whilst the MGM model is convenient, it is not ideal. First, it is heavily parameterised which can create problems for the numerical convergence of the maximum likelihood due to the likelihood being surface being relatively flat, and hence uninformative. Second, asset returns tend to be excessively volatile. Assuming a non-normal distribution such as a t distribution can sometimes help in this regard by dealing with thick tails. The main problem, however, is not thick tails, but a small number of extreme values. The coefficients of the variance process of the MGM model have a tendency to produce a near unstable variance process in their attempt to fit these extreme values. In principle, a stochastic volatility model, which includes an extra random term in the variance, could capture these extreme values. Unfortunately, as far as we are aware, no multivariate stochastic model with in mean effects in the conditional covariances has been proposed in the literature. In view of the need to restrict the number of coefficients to estimate, a commonly used specification of H t+1 is the Constant Conditional Correlation model of Bollerslev (1990) where the dynamics of the conditional covariances are driven by individual GARCH processes for the variances of each variable. Given that the SDF approach focusses on the importance of the contribution of covariances, restricting their dynamics in this way, and not allowing the correlations to be time-varying, seems too restrictive. 1 As a result, we specify H t+1 using the BEKK model originally proposed by Engle and Kroner (1995). This takes the form: vech(h t+1 )=Λ + Σ p 1 i=0 Φ ivech(h t i )+Σ q 1 j=0 Θ jvech(ε t j ε 0 t j) where Λ, Φ and Θ may be unrestricted. With n 1 factors z it then Φ and Θ are both square matrices of size n(n +1)/2 and Λ is a size n(n +1)/2 vector. A formulation of this model which can make implementation easier is the error-correction formulation or VECM BEKK: H t+1 = V 0 V + A 0 (H t V 0 V)A + B 0 (ε t ε 0 t V 0 V)B. where the first term on the RHS is the long-run or unconditional covariance matrix. This can be initialised with starting values from sample averages. The remaining terms capture short-run 1 The attraction of the reduction in parameterisation offered by the CCC model has led to an extension to the dynamics in the DCC proposed recently by Engle (2000). 14

16 deviations from this long run. A restricted version of this formulation is to specify V to be lower triangular and A and B to be symmetric matrices which further reduces parameter numbers. A comparison of parameterisation for n =3and p = q =1is then: BEKK= n(n +1)/2+(p + q)n 2 (n +1) 2 /4 = 78;VECM BEKK= 3n 2 =27; Restricted VECM BEKK= 3n(n +1)/2 =18; Constant Correlation= 3n+n(n 1)/2 =12. We require that the covariance function is stationary. This is satisfied if the absolute value of the eigenvalues of (A A)+(B B) lie inside the unit circle where is the Kronecker product. The structure of the VECM BEKK model that we employ is common to all of the models that we estimate. In each case we condition on the same set of variables in the macroeconomic environment even though the terms in the no-arbitrage condition for the excess return differ between models. Thus the vector x t+1 for the models of the nominal equity return is x t+1 =(i t+1 i f t, π t+1, c t+1, q t+1 ) 0 whilstthatfortherealreturnis:x t+1 =(r t+1 r f t, π t+1, c t+1, q t+1 ) 0. A first order vector autoregression for the macroeconomic variables is found to be sufficient to capture the serial dependence in their means, a VECM BEKK(1,1) model is found to be adequate for the multivariate variance-covariance process. 3.2 GMM Estimation It is informative to contrast the above approach with the GMM estimation of the Euler equation of the general equilibrium condition. This may be written E t [(M t+1 (θ)(r t+1 r f t )] = 0 where we denote that the discount factor depends on the parameters θ. GMM estimation exploits the lack of correlation between the discounted pay-off and the information set used in conditioning. The null hypothesis is that E[(M t+1 (θ)(r t+1 r f t )I t ]=0 I t is the information set which by implication contains no information about M t+1 (θ)(r t+1 r f t ), the discounted excess return in period t +1. Two things may be noted. First, unless the information set has time-varying volatility, it will be unlikely to prove a suitable basis for a time varying risk premium. Surprisingly perhaps, in practice, this has not usually been a consideration. Second, the risk premium itself cannot be obtained even if we knew θ. 15

17 4 Results and Risk Premia 4.1 The Data The data are monthly for the US ( ) and UK: ( ). The US data consists of the excess return on equity of Fama and French, 2 real non-durable growth consumption from FRED, CPI inflation from Datastream and the volume index of industrial production volume index from Datastream. The UK data are the MSCI total equity return index, from Datastream, totalrealnon-durableconsumptiongrowth specially provided by the NIESR, RPI inflation and the volume index of industrial production both from Datastream. All data are express in equivalent annual percentages. Table 2 reports various descriptive statistics for the data, including sweness, kurtosis and autocorrelations of levels and squares. Table 2. DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS FOR THE WHOLE SAMPLE, RAW DATA FOR THE UK AND US i us t+1 i uk t+1 π us t+1 π uk t+1 c us t+1 c uk t+1 qt+1 us qt+1 uk Mean Std. Dev Skewness Excess Kurtosis Normality ρ(x t,x t 1 ) ρ(x t,x t 2 ) ρ(x t,x t 3 ) ρ(x t,x t 4 ) ρ(x t,x t 5 ) ρ(x t,x t 6 ) ρ(x 2 t,x 2 t 1) ρ(x 2 t,x 2 t 2) ρ(x 2 t,x 2 t 3 ) ρ(x 2 t,x 2 t 4) ρ(x 2 t,x 2 t 5) ρ(x 2 t,x 2 t 6) Estimates A complete set of estimates for one model To illustrate, a full set of model estimates with their restrictions is reported for the variables x(t +1) 0 = {i t+1 i f t, π t+1, c t+1, q t+1 } based on UK data, Jan Nov 2001 (321 obs). 2 Available from Ken French s web site: 16

18 The model is CCAPM with power utility and nominal (ex-post real) returns. The production variable is included in the joint distribution but not in the excess return equation. In this way output growth is allowed to be jointly distributed with the other macroeconomic variables which will in general affect the estimates of the variance-covariance matrix. Also a dummy variable is included for October 1987 on the grounds that the excess return for this observation is drawn from adifferent distribution. This prevents an extreme observation from contaminating the estimates of the GARCH parameters for the whole sample. The main points to note at this stage are that the multivariate GARCH process is well determined with the macroeconomic variables displaying conditional heteroskedasticity, conditional covariance of returns with consumption growth is highly sugnificant, but the size of the coefficient implies a very large coefficient of relative risk aversion. Thus these results display the equity premium puzzle ( ) (6.50) (0.17) (4.18) (0.48) (0.78) α = Γ = (8.64) (1.27) (1.14) (4.49) (1.14) (2.22) (1.82) (0.30) (1.53) (4.68) (2.54) (1.53) Φ = (1.41) (2.69) (3.70) A = (1.31) (2.24) (3.43) B = (3.51) (2.68) (4.05) (3.34) (3.19) (0.09) (6.46) (1.98) (2.60) (0.59) (0.12) (2.10) (4.77) (7.61) The eigenvalues for GARCH process are: 0.958, 0.919, 0.902, 0.882, 0.802, etc. 17

19 4.2.2 US estimates Estimates of the no-arbitrage condition for the US data are pre- Theno-arbitrageequation sented in Table 3. Table 3. Estimates of the no-arbitrage equation for all US models US General SDF EZ1 PU-N-H1PU-R-H0PU-N-H0 EZ2 CAPM1 CAPM V t (i us t+1) (0.72) t+1) C t (i us t+1, π us C t (i us t+1, c us (1.58) t+1) (2.34) C t (i us t+1, qt+1) us (0.08) Dummy (α) (1.98) Deg of Freedom (3.10) (1.68) (2.89) (0.29) (2.02) (3.15) (0.75) (1.65) (2.38) (1.95) (3.13) (1.69) (2.94) (1.90) (3.21) (0.63) (0.63) (3.10) (1.80) (3.25) (3.10) (1.80) (3.25) (2.38) (1.88) (3.18) (0.63) (2.11) (3.60) (3.60) (1.69) (1.47) (2.67) (3.07) Log-likelihood Mean risk premium 8.83% 9.75% 8.85% 9.99% 12.01% 12.00% 10.79% 7.01% 10.66% λ max ε t V(φ t+1 ) V(φ t+1 ) V(i us t V t(i us t+1 ) bαd) Estimates in parentheses are t statistics In reverse order of the number of restrictions, estimates of CCAPM with power utility assuming all variables are measured in ex-ante real terms are reported in column 5. Column 6 assumes that all variables are measured in nominal (real ex-post) terms and column 4 is the equivalent SDF model where the restriction on coefficient on Cov t (i us t+1, π us t+1) is removed. All of the estimates of the coefficient of relative risk aversion display the equity premium puzzle effect of being far too large. Removing the restriction on the inflation term only reduces the estimate of the CRRA a little. The inflation coefficient suggests that the restrictions are satisfied by the data. Estimates of the restricted Epstein-Zin model are reported in column 7. Column 3 removes the restriction on the inflation covariance term. Neither the restricted nor the unrestricted model is significantly different from the corresponding power utility model. The χ 2 (2) test statistic is 0.62, which is not significant. We conclude that, in practice, the Epstein-Zin model offers only a minor generalisation of power utility. Column 2 reports estimates of the more general SDF model that includes output. Column 1 includes the market return as an extra variable in the SDF model, but assumes that this is 18

20 a weighted average of the return on equity and the risk-free rate and so affects the coefficient on the own conditional variance. Neither variable seems to be significantly priced. The lack of significance of the own variance from -0.5 suggests that the market return may not be priced. The results also show that statistical models that relate excess returns just to volatility can be rejected in favour of an SDF model with consumption and inflation risk. Risk premia Table 3 reports the mean risk premia for the models and the proportion of the variance of excess returns explained by each model. The power utility models give an estimated average risk premium of about 12%, while the other models give much lower values. The lowest is about 9% for the more general models. Correspondingly, the most restricted power utility model explains 2.25% of the variance of excess returns by variations in the risk premium, and the other models explain up 3.6%. Thus, the size of the risk premium is linked to the explanatory power of the model. Figure 1 gives a plot of excess returns together with the estimates risk premia, and a comparison of the risk premia for restricted and unrestricted CCAPM with power utility and the SDF model. The latter graph shows that removing the restriction on the coefficient of the inflation covariance term gives a much more variable risk premium. In the restricted CCAPM model, consumption is in effect the only source of time variation in the risk premium and this reduces the variability of the risk premium considerably. 19

21 i s,t V t ( i s,t + 1 ) - US φ s,t - US Figure 1. Plots of the US risk premia UK estimates The no-arbitrage equation Estimates for the UK data are presented in Table 4. The results for the UK differ various respects. The estimates of the CRRA are smaller, but are still far too large. Inflation seems to be a more significant source of risk than for the US. The Epstein-Zin model is again a minor generalisation of power utility; the χ 2 (2) statistic is Risk premia The mean risk premium for the UK is somewhat higher than for the US, and is higher for the more general models than for power utility. The proportion of the variance of excess returns explained by the variations in the risk premium is about the same size. Figure 2 plots the excess returns and estimates risk premia, and gives a comparison of the risk premia for restricted and unrestricted CCAPM with power utility and the SDF model. The results are similar to those of the US, except that the risk premia are slightly more volatile. 20

22 Table 4. Estimates of the no-arbitrage equation for all UK models UK General SDF EZ1 PU-N-H1 PU-N-H0 PU-R-H0 EZ2 CAPM1 CAPM V t (i uk t+1) (0.74) C t (i uk t+1, πuk t+1 ) (1.72) C t (i uk t+1, c uk t+1) C t (i uk t+1, q uk (1.95) t+1) (1.07) Dummy (α) (1.86) Deg of Freedom (3.32) (2.06) (1.85) (0.60) (1.80) (3.37) (0.45) (2.73) (1.38) (1.65) (3.42) (2.75) (1.57) (1.70) (3.43) (2.03) (2.03) (2.54) (1.53) (3.16) (2.54) (1.53) (3.16) (1.50) (1.54) (3.05) (0.83) (2.67) (1.74) (3.43) (3.24) (3.24) (1.45) (3.06) Loglikelihood Mean risk premium 10.54% 10.41% 10.81% 10.65% 7.23% 7.21% 9.76% 10.84% 9.70% λ max ε t V(φ t+1 ) V(φ t+1 ) V(i uk t V t(i uk t+1 ) bαd) i s, t V t ( i s,t + 1 ) - UK φ s, t - UK Figure 2. Plots of the UK risk premia 21

23 5 Conclusions In this paper, we have undertaken a critical re-examination of models of the equity risk premium and have proposed an alternative approach to testing these theories based on direct estimation of the implied risk premium. The theoretical framework is the SDF model and a new econometric model is suggested. Using this new methodolgy, we have provided some of the first estimates of a time-varying risk premium for the US and UK based on standard models of risk. The estimated risk premia are about 10% for both countries, but the estimates differ for different models. Our results suggest that the Epstein-Zin model adds little in empirical terms to power utility. They also support the prevailing evidence obtained using very different methods, that the coefficient of relative risk aversion seems too large to be plausible. We therefore find strong evidence of the equity premium puzzle. The most successful model is a general SDF model based on consumption and inflation both of which appear to be priced for the US and UK. Output does not appear to be priced. Our results also show that statistical models that relate excess returns just to volatility canberejectedinfavourofansdfmodelwithconsumptionandinflation risk. References Abel, A. (1990): Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 80, Bollerslev, T. (1990): Modelling the Coherence in Short-Run Nominal Exchange Rates: A Multivariate Generalised ARCH Model, The Review of Economics and Statistics, pp Campbell, J., and J. Cochrane (1999): By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior, Journal of political economy, pp Campbell, J. Y. (1987): Stock Returns and the Term Structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 18, Campbell, J.Y., L. A., and A. MacKinlay (1997): The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton University Press, second printing edn. Campbell, J.Y. (2002): Consumption-Based Asset Pricing, Chapter prepared for the Handbook of the Economics of Finance, George Constantinides, Milton Harris, and Rene Stulz eds., North-Holland, Amsterdam. Campbell, J.Y. and L. Hentschel (1992): No News is Good News, Journal of Financial Economics, pp Cochrane, J. (2001): Asset Pricing. Princeton University Press, 1 edn. Constantinides, G. (1990): Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle, Journal of Political Economy, 98, Engle, R. (2000): Dynamic Conditional Correlation - A Simple Class of Multivariate GARCH Models, Mimeo, University of California San Diego, USA. 22

24 Engle, R., and K. Kroner (1995): Multivariate Simultaneous Generalised ARCH, Econometric Theory, pp Epstein, L., and S. Zin (1989): Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework, Econometrica, pp (1991): Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Political Economy, pp Glosten, L.R., Jagannathan R. and D.E. Runkle (1993): On the Relation between the expected value and the volatility of the nominal excess returns on stocks, The Journal of Finance, pp Hansen, L., and K. Singleton (1983): Stochastic Consumption, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Asset Returns, Journal of political economy, pp Kreps, D., and E. Porteus (1978): Temporal Resolution of Uncertainty and Dynamic Choice Theory, Econometrica, 46, Lettau, M. and S.C. Ludvigson (2002): Measuring and Modeling Variation in The Risk- Return Tradeoff, Manuscript, Chapter prepared for Handbook of Financial Econometrics. Mehra, R. and E. C. Prescott (1985): The Equity Premium: A Puzzle, Journal of Monetary Economics, pp. p Scruggs, J. (1998): Resolving the Puzzling Intertemporal Relation between the Market Riskpremium and Conditional Market Variance: A Two-Factor Approach, Journal of Finance, pp

The asymmetric effect of the business cycle on the relation between stock market returns and their volatility

The asymmetric effect of the business cycle on the relation between stock market returns and their volatility The asymmetric effect of the business cycle on the relation between stock market returns and their volatility P.N. Smith, S. Sorensen and M.R. Wickens University of York First draft, January 2005 Abstract

More information

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Nicola Pavoni October 21, 2016 The Lucas Tree Model This is a general equilibrium model where instead of deriving properties of

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

Is asset-pricing pure data-mining? If so, what happened to theory?

Is asset-pricing pure data-mining? If so, what happened to theory? Is asset-pricing pure data-mining? If so, what happened to theory? Michael Wickens Cardiff Business School, University of York, CEPR and CESifo Lisbon ICCF 4-8 September 2017 Lisbon ICCF 4-8 September

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 15, 2013 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 15, 2013 1 / 56 Consumption-based Asset Pricing Even if we cannot easily solve

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Ian Dew-Becker and Stefano Giglio Duke Fuqua and Chicago Booth 11/27/13 Dew-Becker and Giglio (Duke and Chicago) Frequency-domain asset pricing

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2013 GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 1 / 37 Squared log returns for CRSP daily GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 2 / 37 Absolute value

More information

Inflation prediction from the term structure: the Fisher equation in a multivariate SDF framework

Inflation prediction from the term structure: the Fisher equation in a multivariate SDF framework Inflation prediction from the term structure: the Fisher equation in a multivariate SDF framework Chiona Balfoussia University of York Mike Wickens University of York and CEPR December 2004 Preliminary

More information

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework

More information

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M VIALE I Markowitz-Tobin Mean-Variance Portfolio Analysis Assumption Mean-Variance preferences Markowitz 95 Quadratic utility function E [ w b w ] { = E [ w] b V ar w + E [ w] }

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) A stochastic discount factor is a stochastic process {M t,t+s } such that

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri Basics of Asset Pricing Ali Nejadmalayeri January 2009 No-Arbitrage and Equilibrium Pricing in Complete Markets: Imagine a finite state space with s {1,..., S} where there exist n traded assets with a

More information

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008)

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Backus, Routledge, & Zin Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Asset pricing with Kreps-Porteus preferences, starting with theoretical results from Epstein

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Volume 2009, Article ID 743685, 9 pages doi:10.1155/2009/743685 Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and

More information

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Petr Zemčík CERGE-EI April 2005 1 Mean Reversion Equity returns display negative serial correlation at horizons longer than one year.

More information

Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model

Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model Chikashi TSUJI December 30, 2007 Abstract This paper examines the pricing of month-by-month time-varying risks on the Japanese stock

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets Andrey Ermolov Columbia Business School April 24, 2014 1 / 41 Stylized Facts about Bond Markets US Fact 1: Upward Sloping Real Yield Curve In US, real long

More information

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997 Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997 Seminar in Asset Pricing Theory Presented by Saki Bigio November 2007 1 /

More information

Lecture 11. Fixing the C-CAPM

Lecture 11. Fixing the C-CAPM Lecture 11 Dynamic Asset Pricing Models - II Fixing the C-CAPM The risk-premium puzzle is a big drag on structural models, like the C- CAPM, which are loved by economists. A lot of efforts to salvage them:

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation 200 2 Ó Ó 4 4 Dec., 200 OR Transactions Vol.4 No.4 Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation Xie Yao Liang Zhi An 2 Abstract For one-period investors, fixed income securities

More information

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing Alex Lebedinsky Western Kentucky University Abstract In this note, I conduct an empirical investigation of the affine stochastic

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM Campbell R. Harvey and Akhtar Siddique ABSTRACT Single factor asset pricing models face two major hurdles: the problematic time-series properties

More information

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007 Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert February 15, 2007 Abstract In this paper we use a simple model with a single Cobb Douglas firm and a consumer with

More information

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models Indian Institute of Management Calcutta Working Paper Series WPS No. 797 March 2017 Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models Vivek Rajvanshi Assistant Professor, Indian Institute of Management

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market Measurement of volatility is an important issue in financial econometrics. The main reason for the prominent role that volatility plays in financial

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK Master s Thesis Department of Finance November 2017 Unit Department of

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Implications of Long-Run Risk for. Asset Allocation Decisions

Implications of Long-Run Risk for. Asset Allocation Decisions Implications of Long-Run Risk for Asset Allocation Decisions Doron Avramov and Scott Cederburg March 1, 2012 Abstract This paper proposes a structural approach to long-horizon asset allocation. In particular,

More information

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Time-Series Time-series is a sequence fx 1, x 2,..., x T g or fx t g, t = 1,..., T, where t is an index denoting

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

Consumption CAPM and Cross Section of Expected Returns. Master Thesis

Consumption CAPM and Cross Section of Expected Returns. Master Thesis Consumption CAPM and Cross Section of Expected Returns Master Thesis In pursuit of the degree Master of Arts in Economics and Management Science at the School of Business and Economics of Humboldt University

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Asset Prices and Finance Max Gillman Cardi Business School 0 December 200 Gillman (Cardi Business School) Chapter 7 0 December 200 / 38 Chapter 7: Asset Prices and Finance

More information

The Equity Premium. Blake LeBaron Reading: Cochrane(chap 21, 2017), Campbell(2017/2003) October Fin305f, LeBaron

The Equity Premium. Blake LeBaron Reading: Cochrane(chap 21, 2017), Campbell(2017/2003) October Fin305f, LeBaron The Equity Premium Blake LeBaron Reading: Cochrane(chap 21, 2017), Campbell(2017/2003) October 2017 Fin305f, LeBaron 2017 1 History Asset markets and real business cycle like models Macro asset pricing

More information

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE Abstract Petr Makovský If there is any market which is said to be effective, this is the the FOREX market. Here we

More information

Long Run Labor Income Risk

Long Run Labor Income Risk Long Run Labor Income Risk Robert F. Dittmar Francisco Palomino November 00 Department of Finance, Stephen Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 4809, email: rdittmar@umich.edu

More information

One-Factor Asset Pricing

One-Factor Asset Pricing One-Factor Asset Pricing with Stefanos Delikouras (University of Miami) Alex Kostakis Manchester June 2017, WFA (Whistler) Alex Kostakis (Manchester) One-Factor Asset Pricing June 2017, WFA (Whistler)

More information

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM?

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? WORKING PAPERS SERIES WP05-04 CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? Devraj Basu and Alexander Stremme CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? 1 Devraj Basu Alexander

More information

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial

More information

One-Factor Asset Pricing

One-Factor Asset Pricing One-Factor Asset Pricing with Stefanos Delikouras (University of Miami) Alex Kostakis MBS 12 January 217, WBS Alex Kostakis (MBS) One-Factor Asset Pricing 12 January 217, WBS 1 / 32 Presentation Outline

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Alberto Bisin Corporate Finance: Lecture Notes Class 1: Valuation updated November 17th, 2002 1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Consider an economy with two states of nature {s 1, s 2 } and with

More information

A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails

A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails Florida International University FIU Digital Commons Economics Research Working Paper Series Department of Economics 11-26-2008 A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails Zhiguang (Gerald)

More information

Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles Ravi Bansal and Amir Yaron ABSTRACT We model consumption and dividend growth rates as containing (i) a small long-run predictable

More information

ARCH and GARCH models

ARCH and GARCH models ARCH and GARCH models Fulvio Corsi SNS Pisa 5 Dic 2011 Fulvio Corsi ARCH and () GARCH models SNS Pisa 5 Dic 2011 1 / 21 Asset prices S&P 500 index from 1982 to 2009 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200

More information

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions Cynthia Royal Tori, PhD Valdosta State University Langdale College of Business 1500 N. Patterson Street, Valdosta, GA USA 31698

More information

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime Lecture 8: Markov and Regime Switching Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring 2016 Overview Motivation Deterministic vs. Endogeneous, Stochastic Switching Dummy Regressiom Switching

More information

Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model?

Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model? Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model? Anne-Sofie Reng Rasmussen Keywords: C-CAPM, intertemporal asset pricing, conditional asset pricing, pricing errors. Preliminary.

More information

Review of the Equity Premium Puzzle

Review of the Equity Premium Puzzle 7 Review of the Equity Premium Puzzle Vol I Review of the Equity Premium Puzzle Benjamin Große-Rüschkamp * Meet the Equity Premium Puzzle The equity premium, the excess return of equity over relatively

More information

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Persistent than You Think October 19th, 2009 Introduction: Habit Preferences Habit preferences: can generate a higher equity premium for a given curvature

More information

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings, State Pricing 1/ 40 Introduction We now consider a consumption-savings decision along with the previous portfolio choice decision. These

More information

APPLYING MULTIVARIATE

APPLYING MULTIVARIATE Swiss Society for Financial Market Research (pp. 201 211) MOMTCHIL POJARLIEV AND WOLFGANG POLASEK APPLYING MULTIVARIATE TIME SERIES FORECASTS FOR ACTIVE PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Momtchil Pojarliev, INVESCO

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILITATION OF STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR METHODOLOGY. John H. Cochrane

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILITATION OF STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR METHODOLOGY. John H. Cochrane NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILIAION OF SOCHASIC DISCOUN FACOR MEHODOLOGY John H. Cochrane Working Paper 8533 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8533 NAIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models 1

Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models 1 Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models 1 Abhay Abhyankar Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2002 Preliminary; please do not Quote or Distribute

More information

Time-Varying Risk Premium in the Czech Capital Market: Did the Market Experience a Structural Shock in ?

Time-Varying Risk Premium in the Czech Capital Market: Did the Market Experience a Structural Shock in ? JEL Classification: C32, E44, G12 Keywords: CAPM, CCAPM, multivariate GARCH-in-mean, risk premium, structural changes Time-Varying Risk Premium in the Czech Capital Market: Did the Market Experience a

More information

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period Cahier de recherche/working Paper 13-13 Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period 2000-2012 David Ardia Lennart F. Hoogerheide Mai/May

More information

Volatility Analysis of Nepalese Stock Market

Volatility Analysis of Nepalese Stock Market The Journal of Nepalese Business Studies Vol. V No. 1 Dec. 008 Volatility Analysis of Nepalese Stock Market Surya Bahadur G.C. Abstract Modeling and forecasting volatility of capital markets has been important

More information

One-Period Valuation Theory

One-Period Valuation Theory One-Period Valuation Theory Part 2: Chris Telmer March, 2013 1 / 44 1. Pricing kernel and financial risk 2. Linking state prices to portfolio choice Euler equation 3. Application: Corporate financial leverage

More information

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption Problem Set 3 Thomas Philippon April 19, 2002 1 Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption The goal of the question is to derive the formulas on p13 of Topic 2. This is a partial equilibrium analysis

More information

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods. Introduction In ECON 50, we discussed the structure of two-period dynamic general equilibrium models, some solution methods, and their

More information

Ec2723, Asset Pricing I Class Notes, Fall Complete Markets, Incomplete Markets, and the Stochastic Discount Factor

Ec2723, Asset Pricing I Class Notes, Fall Complete Markets, Incomplete Markets, and the Stochastic Discount Factor Ec2723, Asset Pricing I Class Notes, Fall 2005 Complete Markets, Incomplete Markets, and the Stochastic Discount Factor John Y. Campbell 1 First draft: July 30, 2003 This version: October 10, 2005 1 Department

More information

Asset Pricing and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review Essay

Asset Pricing and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review Essay Asset Pricing and the Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review Essay Wei Pierre Wang Queen s School of Business Queen s University Kingston, Ontario, K7L 3N6 First Draft: April 2002 1 I benefit from discussions

More information

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences p. 1/3 International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences Riccardo Colacito Prepared for Tom Sargent s PhD class (Part 1) Roadmap p. 2/3 Today International asset pricing (exchange

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in Durable Consumption Wei Yang 1 This draft: October 2009 1 William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester, Rochester,

More information

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis WenShwo Fang Department of Economics Feng Chia University 100 WenHwa Road, Taichung, TAIWAN Stephen M. Miller* College of Business University

More information

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter 3 Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter Three Random Variables and Probability Distributions 3. Introduction An event is defined as the possible outcome of an experiment. In engineering

More information

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Christian Julliard and Anisha Ghosh Working Paper 2008 P t d b J L i f NYU A t P i i Presented by Jason Levine for NYU Asset Pricing Seminar, Fall 2009

More information

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen Outline Introduction Equity premium puzzle Recent contribution Contribution of this paper Long-Run Risk Model

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

Does High-Order Consumption Risk Matter? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX)

Does High-Order Consumption Risk Matter? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) Does High-Order Consumption Risk Matter? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) Marco Rossi May 31, 2007 Abstract High order moments of consumption growth cannot adequately explain the equity

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Stochastic Discount Factor Models and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Stochastic Discount Factor Models and the Equity Premium Puzzle Stochastic Discount Factor Models and the Equity Premium Puzzle Christopher Otrok University of Virginia B. Ravikumar University of Iowa Charles H. Whiteman * University of Iowa November 200 This version:

More information

STOCK MARKET RETURNS, RISK AVERSION AND CONSUMPTION GROWTH: EVIDENCE FROM THE NIGERIAN ECONOMY

STOCK MARKET RETURNS, RISK AVERSION AND CONSUMPTION GROWTH: EVIDENCE FROM THE NIGERIAN ECONOMY STOCK MARKET RETURNS, RISK AVERSION AND CONSUMPTION GROWTH: EVIDENCE FROM THE NIGERIAN ECONOMY Favoured Mogbolu Department of Economics and Statistics, University of Benin, Benin City E-mail: favoured.mogbolu@uniben.edu,

More information

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS

EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS 1 / 24 EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS WITH FINANCE CONSTRAINTS THROUGH THE LENS OF ASSET PRICING Lars Peter Hansen Benheim Lectures, Princeton University EXAMINING MACROECONOMIC MODELS WITH FINANCING CONSTRAINTS

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions TA: B. B. Deng Unless otherwise stated, e t is iid N(0,s 2 ) 1. (12 points) Consider the three series y1, y2, y3, and y4. Match

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Yin-Wong Cheung University of California, U.S.A. Frank Westermann University of Munich, Germany Daily data from the German and

More information

Portfolio construction by volatility forecasts: Does the covariance structure matter?

Portfolio construction by volatility forecasts: Does the covariance structure matter? Portfolio construction by volatility forecasts: Does the covariance structure matter? Momtchil Pojarliev and Wolfgang Polasek INVESCO Asset Management, Bleichstrasse 60-62, D-60313 Frankfurt email: momtchil

More information

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime Lecture 9: Markov and Regime Switching Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring 2017 Overview Motivation Deterministic vs. Endogeneous, Stochastic Switching Dummy Regressiom Switching

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2017, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2017, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2017, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam Problem A: (40 points) Answer briefly the following questions. 1. Describe

More information

Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998

Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998 economics letters Intertemporal substitution and durable goods: long-run data Masao Ogaki a,*, Carmen M. Reinhart b "Ohio State University, Department of Economics 1945 N. High St., Columbus OH 43210,

More information