Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models 1"

Transcription

1 Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models 1 Abhay Abhyankar Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2002 Preliminary; please do not Quote or Distribute address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Wariwck Business School University of Warwick Coventry, CV4 7AL United Kingdom a.stremme@wbs.warwick.ac.uk 1 We thank Keng-Yu Ho for research assistance. We would also like to thank Wayne Ferson for helpful discussions. We also thank Kenneth French and Martin Lettau for making available the data used in this study. All remaining errors are ours. 1

2 Portfolio-Based Tests of Conditional Factor Models November 2002 Preliminary; please do not Quote or Distribute Abstract In this paper, we construct portfolio-based tests of conditional factor models, developed by exploiting the close link between the stochastic discount factor framework and unconditional mean-variance efficiency. We show that an asset pricing model admits a conditional factor representation if and only if there is some combination of the factor mimicking portfolios that is unconditionally mean-variance efficient. Conversely, for a given set of factors, our analysis allows us to construct a managed portfolio of the factor mimicking portfolios that attains the maximum Sharpe ratio generated by the factors. We thus obtain the factor loadings, as functions of the conditioning information, of the optimal conditional factor model for given choice of factors. We use our results to empirically test several factor models proposed in the literature. We find that the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model, scaled by lagged consumptionwealth ratio, as well as the model of Harvey and Siddique (2000) perform comparatively well as conditional asset pricing models, while the Fama and French (1992) model does less well. JEL Classification: C31, G11, G12 2

3 1 Introduction The objective of this paper is to develop portfolio-based tests of conditional factor models. These tests are constructed by exploiting the close links between the stochastic discount factor framework and mean-variance efficiency. The concept of mean-variance efficiency has important implications for tests of asset pricing models. In the presence of conditioning information, one can construct managed portfolios that expand the mean-variance efficient frontier. This places tighter restrictions on conditional asset pricing models, since the set of attainable pay-offs that the model must price correctly is larger. In the presence of conditioning information, the study of conditional efficiency is not always appropriate since it focuses on the ex-post rather than ex-ante optimal use of this information, as highlighted also by Dybvig and Ross (1985). Moreover, tests based on conditional efficiency require the evaluation of conditional moments, which poses problems in practical implementations. Therefore, we focus our attention on unconditional efficiency, as considered also in Ferson and Siegel (2002b). We develop techniques to construct and test conditional factor models, by relating them to the unconditional mean-variance efficiency of the associated factor-mimicking portfolios. A similar approach, without conditioning information, is developed in Huberman, Kandel, and Stambaugh (1987). We show that, if a model admits a conditional factor representation in the sense that a linear combination of factors constitutes an admissible stochastic discount factor for the model, then a combination of the factor mimicking portfolios is in fact unconditionally mean-variance efficient. This provides a necessary condition for a factor model to be viable. Conversely, for a given set of factors we construct a managed combination of the factor mimicking portfolios that attains the maximum Sharpe ratio generated by the factors. If 3

4 this Sharpe ratio is equal to the maximum Sharpe ratio generated by the base assets, then this portfolio can be lifted to a conditional linear factor pricing model. Moreover, even if exact factor pricing cannot be achieved, our methodology allows us to construct the loadings of the best possible conditional factor model for a given choice of factors. We use our results to test various conditional factor models. We test the three-factor Fama and French (1992) model, the augmented Fama-French model with a skewness factor similar to the one proposed by Harvey and Siddique (2000), and the Consumption CAPM. Using dividend yield and consumption-wealth ratio (Lettau and Ludvigson 2001a) as conditioning variables we find that, while the skewness factor clearly improves the performance of the Fama-French model, the augmented model still only accounts for at most 82% of the Sharpe ratio generated by the base assets. In contrast, for the Consumption CAPM, with aggregate consumption growth rate as the factor, this figure rises to 90%. Our paper is most closely related to Ferson and Harvey (1999), who study the performance of the Fama-French model on conditional expected returns. They test the ability of the model to capture common dynamic patterns in returns, modelled using a set of lagged predictor variables, and find that the model does not perform well as a conditional asset pricing model. The same is true of the four-factor model of Carhart (1997). Ferson and Harvey (1999) allow both models to have time-varying coefficients which are linear in the predictive variables. Our analysis extends theirs to allow for non-traded factors. Moreover, we show that the coefficients of the optimal factor model for given choice of factors are in fact non-linear functions of the conditioning variable, in contrast to their analysis. Ferson and Siegel (2002b) develop tests for stochastic discount factors and portfolio efficiency with conditioning information. They refine tests of portfolio efficiency to include conditioning 4

5 information and find that these tests reject the Fama-French model in any fixed-weight combination. Our analysis focuses on testing for the unconditional mean-variance efficiency of factor mimicking portfolios by deriving an explicit expression for the maximum achievable Sharpe ratio from a set of factors. We extend the analysis of Ferson and Siegel (2002b) by considering factor models with coefficients that are non-linear functions of the conditioning variables. Moreover, our results yield necessary and sufficient conditions for a given set of factors to constitute a viable conditional asset pricing model. Breeden, Gibbons, and Litzenberger (1989) construct factor-mimicking portfolios for consumption growth in their tests of the consumption-based Capital Asset Pricing Model (C- CAPM). We extend their analysis to include conditioning information and find that the conditional C-CAPM seems to perform comparatively well when consumption-wealth ratio is used as conditioning variable. Our results thus broadly agree with those of Lettau and Ludvigson (2001b), while our analysis differs from theirs in that we use the traded mimicking portfolio for consumption growth rather than consumption growth itself. Kraus and Litzenberger (1976) and Harvey and Siddique (2000) consider asset pricing models which allow the skewness risk in the return distribution to be priced. We extend these models to incorporate conditioning information and find that the inclusion of a skewness factor considerably enhances their performance as conditional asset pricing models. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows; Section 2, briefly reviews the theoretical background and establishes our notation. In Section 3, we discuss conditional factor models and factor mimicking portfolios, and state our main results. In Section 4, we develop tests for conditional factor models based on their maximum Sharpe ratio. Our empirical results are reported in Section 5. Section 6 concludes. Most proofs are given in the mathematical appendix. 5

6 2 Theoretical Background In this section, we provide a brief outline of the underlying asset pricing theory, and establish our notation. We first construct the space of state-contingent pay-offs, and within it the space of traded pay-offs, augmented by the use of conditioning information. Next, we define a generalized notion of return within this space. 2.1 Set-Up and Notation We begin by constructing the space of state-contingent pay-offs. We fix a probability space (Ω, F, P ), endowed with a discrete-time filtration (F t ) t. We fix t > 0, and consider the period beginning at time t 1 and ending at t. Denote by L 2 t the Hilbert space of all F t - measurable random variables that are square-integrable with respect to P, endowed with the canonical inner product E ( x t y t ). We interpret Ω as the set of states of nature, and L 2 t as the space of all (not necessarily attainable) state-contingent pay-off claims. Conditioning Information: To incorporate conditioning information, we take as given a sub-σ-field G t 1 F t. We think of G t 1 as summarizing all information on which investors base their portfolio decisions at time t 1. In particular, asset prices at time t 1 will typically depend on G t 1. In most practical applications, G t 1 will be chosen as the σ-field generated by a set of conditioning instruments, variables observable at time t 1 that contain information about the distribution 6

7 of future asset returns 1. By replacing the inner product on L 2 t by its conditional version, E ( x t y t G t 1 ), and completing the space with respect to the implied norm if necessary, we turn L 2 t into a conditional Hilbert space (Hansen and Richard 1987). To emphasize the conditional structure, we denote this space by L 2 t ( G t 1 ). Traded Base Assets: Throughout this paper, we focus on the case in which the space of traded pay-offs is generated by a finite 2 set of base assets. Specifically, we assume there are n traded risky assets, indexed k = 1... n. We denote the gross return (per dollar invested) of the k-th asset by rt k L 2 t, and by R t := ( rt 1... rt n ) the n-vector of risky asset returns. In addition to the risky assets, we assume that a risk-free is traded with gross return rt 0 = r f. We now define X t as the space of all elements x t L 2 t that can be written in the form, n x t = θt 1r 0 f + ( rt k r f )θt 1, k (1) k=1 for G t 1 -measurable functions θt 1. k To simplify notation, we write this in vector form as x t = θt 1r 0 f + ( R t r f e ) θ t 1, where θ t 1 = ( θt θt 1 n ) is the vector of weights on the risky assets, and e is an n-vector of ones. We interpret X t as the space of managed pay-offs, obtained by forming combinations of the base assets with weights θt 1 k that are functions of the conditioning information. Throughout this paper, we will often refer to X t as the augmented pay-off space. 1 Examples of such variables considered in the literature include dividend yield (Fama and French 1988), interest rate spreads (Campbell 1987), or consumption-wealth ratio (Lettau and Ludvigson 2001a). 2 Note that, unlike in the fixed-weight case, the space of managed pay-offs is infinite-dimensional even when there is only a finite number of base assets. 7

8 Pricing Function: Since the base assets are characterized by their returns, we set Π t 1 ( rt k ) = 1, and extend the function Π t 1 to all of X t by conditional linearity. In other words, the cost of a portfolio of base assets is given by the sum of the weights it assigns to the base assets. Since the weights on the risky assets in (1) are applied to their excess returns, we simply obtain, n [ Π t 1 ( x t ) = θt 1Π 0 t 1 ( r f ) + Πt 1 ( rt k ) Π t 1 ( r f ) ] θt 1 k = θt 1. 0 (2) k=1 By construction, X t is a conditionally linear subspace of L 2 t ( G t 1 ). Replacing X t by its closure if necessary, we can also assume that X t is complete and hence itself a conditional Hilbert space. By definition, the function Π t 1 is conditionally linear on X t, and continuous by Cauchy-Schwartz. In other words, the pricing rule satisfies the law of one price, a weak from of no-arbitrage condition. Throughout the remainder of this paper, we will refer to the pair ( X t, Π t 1 ) as the conditional market model generated by the given set of base assets. 2.2 A Generalized Notion of Return By an admissible stochastic discount factor (SDF), we mean an element m t L 2 t that prices all base assets conditionally correctly, that is E t 1 ( m t rt k ) = 1 for all k = 0, 1... n. Note that, for an arbitrary managed pay-off x t X t, conditional linearity then implies, n [ E t 1 ( m t x t ) = θt 1E 0 t 1 ( m t r f ) + Et 1 ( m t rt k ) E t 1 ( m t r f ) ] θt 1 k = θt 1 0 (3) k=1 In other words, an SDF that prices all base assets correctly is necessarily compatible with the pricing function Π t 1 for managed pay-offs in the sense that E t 1 ( m t x t ) = Π t 1 ( x t ). 8

9 Finally, taking unconditional expectations in (3), one obtains the unconditional restriction, E( m t x t ) = E( Π t 1 ( x t ) ) =: Π 0 ( x t ). (4) Using an unconditional orthogonality argument, it is easy to show that a candidate m t is an admissible SDF if and only if (4) folds for all x t X t. In a slight abuse of terminology, we refer to Π 0 as the generalized pricing function induced by the base assets on the space of managed payoffs. We now define the space of generalized returns as 3, R t = { r t X t Π 0 ( r t ) = 1 }. (5) An element r t R t is called unconditionally efficient if it has minimum unconditional variance among all elements r t R t with the same unconditional mean. Note that, in the presence of conditioning information, one could also consider the concept of conditional efficiency. However, we are interested in the ex-ante efficiency of managed portfolios, rather than the ex-post efficiency once conditioning information is known 4. To conclude this section, we define the generalized Sharpe ratio in the space R t, E( r t ) r f λ = sup. (6) r t R t σ( r t ) In Section 4, we derive an explicit expression for λ in terms of the conditional moments of the base asset returns. The maximum generalized Sharpe ratio constitutes the benchmark 3 The Gallant, Hansen, and Tauchen (1990) (GHT) discount factor bounds, and their implementation by Bekaert and Liu (2001), are implicitly based on this space of generalized returns. 4 As Dybvig and Ross (1985) show, when portfolio managers possess information not known to outside investors, their (conditionally efficient) strategies may seem conditionally inefficient to outsiders. Hence, the notion of unconditional efficiency is a more appropriate measure of performance in this case. 9

10 against which factor models will be tested. We use the fact that a generalized return is unconditionally efficient if and only if its implied generalized Sharpe ratio equals λ. Remark: Ferson and Siegel (2001) extensively study portfolio efficiency in the space of conditional returns, defined by the more restrictive constraint Π t 1 ( r t ) 1. While this notion of return may be more intuitive, the resulting return space is much smaller 5. In the context of asset pricing model tests, it is reasonable to focus on the largest possible return space, since it delivers the tightest testable restrictions. It should be noted, however, that all our results hold equally well in the case of conditional returns, and even in the fixed-weight case without conditioning information. In particular, our results applied to conditional returns, extend those of Ferson and Siegel (2002b). 3 Factor Models and Mimicking Portfolios The purpose of this section is twofold. First, we show that a given market model admits a factor representation if and only if there is a linear combination of factor mimicking portfolios that is unconditionally efficient. This result is at the heart of the factor model tests developed in Section 4. Second, for a given choice of factors, we show how to construct an optimal factor representation that comes as close as possible to pricing the assets correctly. It turns out that the optimal factor loadings are non-linear functions of the conditioning information, which is in contrast to Ferson and Harvey (1999). 5 In fact, while the space R t of generalized returns has co-dimension one in the augmented pay-off space, the space of conditional returns is of infinite co-dimension. 10

11 3.1 Conditional Factor Models Our focus here is not the selection of factors, but rather the construction and testing of models for a given set of factors. Therefore, we take as given m factors, F i t L 2 t, indexed i = 1... m. Note that in general we do not assume that the factors are traded, we may have Ft i X t. Denote by F t = ( Ft 1,..., Ft m ) the m-vector of factors. To define what we mean by a conditional factor model, we use the characterization in terms of SDFs 6. Definition 3.1 We say that the model ( X t, Π t 1 ) admits a conditional factor structure, if there exist G t 1 -measurable functions a t 1 and b i t 1 such that, m t = α t 1 + m i=1 F i t b i t 1 (7) is an admissible SDF for the model, that is E t 1 ( x t m t ) = Π t 1 ( x t ) for all x t X t. In vector notation, we write (7) as m t = α t 1 + F t b t 1, where b t 1 = ( b 1 t 1,..., b m t 1 ) denotes the vector of factor loadings. It is important to emphasize that the above specification defines a conditional factor model, in that the coefficients a t 1 and b i t 1 are allowed to be functions of the conditioning information. In the case where an admissible stochastic discount factor of the form (7) can be found with unconditionally constant coefficients, we say that the model admits a fixed-weight factor structure. 6 It is easy to show (Cochrane 2001) that this characterization is equivalent to the more traditional formulation in terms of expected base asset returns. 11

12 3.2 Factor-Mimicking Portfolios Since in general, the factors cannot be assumed to be traded assets, we must first construct factor-mimicking portfolios in order to relate factor models to portfolio efficiency. Definition 3.2 An element f i t factor F i t L 2 t if and only if Π t 1 ( f i t ) = 1, and ρ 2( f i t, F i t R t is called a factor-mimicking portfolio (FMP) for the ) ( ) ρ 2 r t, Ft i for all r t R t with Π t 1 ( r t ) = 1. (8) Note that we require the FMP to be a conditional return. This is necessary because we wish to study the unconditionally efficient frontier spanned by the FMPs as base assets. Denote by f t = ( ft 1,..., ft m ) the m-vector of FMPs for the given factors. In the following section, we show (Theorem 4.1) that the model admits a conditional factor representation if and only if there is a portfolio of FMPs that is unconditionally efficient. We now give an explicit characterization of the FMPs in terms of their base asset weights. To simplify notation, we write E t 1 ( ) for the conditional expectation operator with respect to G t 1. We define the conditional moments, µ t 1 = E t 1 ( R ( t r f e ), and Λ t 1 = E t 1 ( Rt r f e )( R t r f e ) ) (9) In other words, excess returns can be written as R t r f e = µ t 1 + ε t, where µ t 1 is the conditional expectation given conditioning information, and ε t is the residual term with zero conditional mean and variance-covariance matrix Σ t 1 = Λ t 1 µ t 1 µ t 1. This is the formulation of the asset pricing model with conditioning information used in Ferson and 12

13 Siegel (2001) 7. Similarly, we denote the mixed conditional moments of the factors by ν t 1 = E t 1 ( Ft ), and Qt 1 = E t 1 ( ( Rt r f e ) F t ) (10) Remark: Note that, if an admissible SDF of the form (7) exists, this implies, ( ) 0 E t 1 ( Rt r f e )m t = at 1 µ t 1 + Q t 1 b t 1. Conversely, if a t 1 and b t 1 exist so that a t 1 µ t 1 + Q t 1 b t 1 = 0, then m t in (7) prices all excess returns correctly and can hence be modified to be an admissible SDF. In other words, the model admits a conditional factor structure if and only if the image of the conditional linear operator Q t 1 contains µ t 1. Proposition 3.3 For a given factor F i t, the factor-mimicking portfolio can be written as, ft i = r f + ( Rt r f e ) ( ) θ i t 1 with θt 1 i = Λ 1 t 1 q i t 1 κ i µ t 1 where q i t 1 is the column of Q t 1 corresponding to factor i, and κ i is a constant. (11) Proof: Appendix A.1. Note that the constant κ i in the above expression is directly related to the unconditional mean of the FMP. In the case where a risk-free asset is present, this constant is not uniquely determined, since the first-order condition arising from maximizing the correlation in (8) is independent of that mean. It will be convenient to write yt 1 i = qt 1 i κ i µ t 1, and define Y t 1 as the matrix whose columns are the yt 1. i With this notation, we obtain, 7 Note however that our notation differs slightly from that used in Ferson and Siegel (2001), who define Λ t 1 to be the inverse of the conditional second-moment matrix. 13

14 Corollary 3.4 The conditional moments of the factor mimicking portfolios are given by, E t 1 ( ft r f e ) = Y t 1Λ 1 t 1µ t 1, and E t 1 ( ( ft r f e )( f t r f e ) ) = Y t 1Λ 1 t 1Y t 1. In the following sections, we use these results to obtain an explicit expression for the maximum generalized Sharpe ratio generated by the factor mimicking portfolios. 4 Tests of Conditional Linear Factor Models In this section, we develop a Sharpe ratio based test for conditional factor models. We show that the model admits a conditional factor representation if and only if the maximum generalized Sharpe ratio generated by the factor mimicking portfolios equals that generated by the base assets. Obviously, this is the case if and only if there exists a portfolio of FMPs that is unconditionally efficient in the augmented pay-off space. In order to study the efficiency of the factor mimicking portfolios, we treat them as base assets of a hypothetical pay-off space. More specifically, denote by Xt F the space of managed pay-offs x t L 2 t that can be written in the form, x t = φ 0 t 1r f + m ( ft i r f )φ i t 1, (12) i=1 for G t 1 -measurable functions φ i t 1. In other words, Xt F is the space of pay-offs that are attainable by forming managed portfolios of the factor mimicking portfolios. Since the mimicking portfolios are by construction conditional returns, we have Π t 1 ( x t ) = φ 0 t 1 for any x t Xt F of the form (12). Mimicking the construction in Section 2.2, we define the space of generalized returns spanned by the FMPs as, Rt F = R t Xt F. 14

15 Denote by λ F the maximum generalized Sharpe ratio in the space R F t, λ F = sup r t R F t E( r t ) r f σ( r t ). (13) In other words, λ F is the maximum generalized Sharpe ratio that can be achieved by forming portfolios of factor-mimicking portfolios. We now formulate the main result of this section, which builds the basis for the factor model tests estimated in the following section. Theorem 4.1 The model ( X t, Π t 1 ) admits a conditional factor structure if and only if λ F = λ Proof: The proof of Theorem 4.1 is based on a series of propositions and lemmas which are of independent interest and therefore are stated explicitly in the subsequent sections. The proof of the theorem is concluded in Appendix A.4. As a consequence of the above result, the difference λ λ F can be interpreted as a test of whether it is possible to construct a conditional linear asset pricing model from a given set of factors. Since by construction R F t R t, we always have λ F λ, with equality if and only if there exists a portfolio r t R F t that is unconditionally efficient in the space R t. Corollary 4.2 The model ( X t, Π t 1 ) admits a conditional factor structure if and only if there exist G t 1 -measurable functions φ i t 1 with E( φ 0 t 1 ) = 1, such that φ 0 t 1r f + m i=1 ( ) φ i t 1 f i t r f is unconditionally efficient in the space R t of generalized returns. (14) Proof: Follows directly from Theorem

16 4.1 Maximum Generalized Sharpe Ratios The following proposition provides an explicit characterization of the maximum Sharpe ratio in terms of the conditional moments of the base asset returns. Proposition 4.3 The maximum generalized Sharpe ratio in the space R t is given by λ = h, where h 2 = E( H 2 t 1 ), and H 2 t 1 = µ t 1 Σ 1 t 1 µ t 1, (15) Proof: The proof is given in Appendix A.2. Expression (15) for the maximum Sharpe ratio has many interesting features; first, it extends the expression given in Equation (16) of Jagannathan (1996) to the case with conditioning information. It is well-known (Cochrane 2001) that in the fixed-weight case without conditioning information the maximum (squared) Sharpe ratio is given by an expression of the form (15), with conditional moments replaced by unconditional ones. In other words, H t 1 represents the maximum conditional Sharpe ratio, once the realization of the conditioning information is known. Hence, the maximum squared unconditional Sharpe ratio is simply given by the expectation of the maximum squared conditional Sharpe ratio. For the case of only one risky asset, this result was also shown in Cochrane (1999). Ferson and Siegel (2001) calculate the maximum Sharpe ratio in their setting. Unfortunately, their expression does not admit an interpretation of this sort. To see this, we note the in our notation their maximum squared Sharpe ratio can be written as, λ 2 F S = E ( H 2 t H 2 t 1 )/ ( E 1 ). (16) 1 + Ht

17 Moreover, since the space of conditional returns is smaller than the space of generalized returns considered here, the Sharpe ratio in their setting will be lower than ours 8. As a consequence, in contrast to the tests developed in this paper, tests based on the Ferson and Siegel (2001) Sharpe ratio will in general yield necessary but not sufficient conditions. Corollary 4.4 The maximum generalized Sharpe ratio in the space R F t is given by λ F = h F, where h 2 F = E( H 2 F,t 1 ), and H 2 F,t 1 = µ t 1Λ 1 t 1Y t 1 [ Y t 1Λ 1 t 1Σ t 1 Λ 1 t 1Y t 1 ] 1Y t 1Λ 1 t 1µ t 1, (17) Proof: We apply Proposition 4.3, using the factor-mimicking portfolios as base assets. Using the conditional moments from Corollary 3.4 to substitute for µ t 1 and Σ t 1 in (15) gives the desired result. Finally, we characterize the weights on the mimicking portfolios of the portfolio that attains the maximum Sharpe ratio in (17). These weights are in fact proportional to the factor loadings in the optimal conditional factor model for given choice of factors. Proposition 4.5 The maximum generalized Sharpe ratio in (17) is attained by, rt = φ 0 t 1 r f + ( f t r f e ) φ t 1 with φ 0 t 1 = 1 + H2 F,t h 2 F (18) and φ t 1 = r f 1 + h 2 F Proof: The proof is given in Appendix A.3. [ Y t 1Λ 1 t 1Σ t 1 Λ 1 t 1Y t 1 ] 1 Y t 1Λ 1 t 1µ t 1 8 This can also be shown directly using Jensen s inequality. 17

18 5 Empirical Analysis In this section, we use the theory developed in Sections 3 and 4 to test several conditional factor models. The models considered are the Consumption CAPM, the Fama-French threefactor model, and finally the Fama-French model augmented with a skewness-based term following Harvey and Siddique (2000). We specialize the set-up of the preceding sections to the case of a single instrument. Specifically, let y t 1 be a given F t 1 -measurable conditioning variable, and set G t 1 = σ( y t 1 ). For the estimation, we will use the de-meaned variable yt 1 0 = y t 1 E ( y t 1 ). To estimate the conditional moments, we postulate that the base asset returns and the factors depend on the conditioning instrument via a linear relationship of the form, ( Rt r f e F t ) ( µ = ν ) ( β + γ ) yt ( εt η t ) (19) where ε t and η t are independent of y 0 t 1 with E t 1 ( ε t ) = E t 1 ( η t ) = 0. In the notation of Section 3, we can then calculate the conditional moments as, µ t 1 = µ + βy 0 t 1 and Λ t 1 = ( µ + βy 0 t 1 )( µ + βy 0 t 1 ) + E t 1 ( ε t ε t ) ν t 1 = ν + γy 0 t 1 and Q t 1 = ( µ + βy 0 t 1 )( ν + γy 0 t 1 ) + E t 1 ( ε t η t ) The maximum generalized Sharpe ratios generated by the base assets and the factor mimicking portfolios, respectively, are then calculated using (15) and (17). 18

19 5.1 Results As base assets, we use monthly returns on the twelve industry portfolios of Kenneth French 9, for the period beginning in 1959:01 and ending in 2001:07. The conditioning variables used are dividend yield (DY) and the consumption-wealth ratio 10 (CAY) as considered in Lettau and Ludvigson (2001a), for the same sampling period. For a given set of factors, we estimate a joint regression of the form (19). As a benchmark, we use Proposition 4.3 to compute the maximum generalized Sharpe ratio generated by the base assets. The results are reported in Table 1. For monthly returns on the twelve industry portfolios, we obtain an annualized Sharpe ratio of 1.16 and 1.09, using CAY and DY as conditioning variables, respectively. We also report the corresponding Sharpe ratios using quarterly data. As observed in Ferson and Siegel (2002a), the (annualized) quarterly Sharpe ratios are considerably higher (1.28) than those obtained from monthly data. In order for any of the factor models considered below to be viable, the Sharpe ratio generated by the factor mimicking portfolios must equal this benchmark. Note that in Table 1, we also report the fixed-weight Sharpe ratios, reflecting the case where conditioning information is not used. The difference between the generalized and the fixed-weight Sharpe ratios provides a diagnostic tool to assess the extent to which conditioning information expands the efficient frontier 11. While the use of DY increases annual Sharpe ratios by about 40%, CAY at monthly frequency has a much stronger effect, raising the annual Sharpe ratio by about 48%. In other words, when CAY is used 9 Available at 10 Available at mlettau. 11 In Abhyankar, Basu, and Stremme (2002) the difference between the optimal and the fixed-weight Sharpe ratio is used to construct a test that measures the economic value of return predictability. 19

20 as conditioning variable, a conditional asset pricing model has to work harder to price the assets correctly. a) Fama-French Model: The Fama-French model augments the classic CAPM with two zero-cost portfolios, based on firm size (factor SMB, small minus big ), and book-to-market ratio (factor HML, high minus low ). We estimate (19), using monthly excess returns on the base assets and the three factors as dependent variables, and lagged CAY or DY as explanatory variables, and construct the corresponding factor mimicking portfolios. Following the results of Section 3, for the Fama- French model to be a viable conditional asset pricing model, the maximum Sharpe ratio generated by the factors must equal that of the base assets. The corresponding results are reported in Table 1. We find that the maximum (annualized) Sharpe ratios generated by the factors are 0.85 and 0.83, respectively, using CAY and DY as conditioning variables. These account for only 73% respectively 76% of the maximum Sharpe ratios generated by the base assets. Our results broadly confirm those of Ferson and Harvey (1999) and Ferson and Siegel (2002b), who find that the Fama-French model does not work well conditionally. Panel A of Figures 1 and 2 plots the frontiers spanned by the base assets (bold-faced line) and the factor mimicking portfolios (light-weighted line). As a benchmark, we also plot the fixed-weight frontier (dashed line) spanned by the base assets. The factor mimicking portfolios themselves are shown as dots in the graph. As it displays the poorest performance of the models considered in this study, we chose this model to construct the optimal factor structure for the given choice of factors. The optimal factor loadings, as functions of the conditioning variable CAY, are shown in Figure 3. 20

21 b) Fama-French Model with Skewness Factor: Harvey and Siddique (2000) propose augmenting the the Fama-French model with a factor that captures the skewness risk of returns. They construct this additional factor by orthogonalizing the squared excess return on the market portfolio with respect to the market portfolio. In contrast, we consider a model in which the skewness factor is given directly by the square of the excess market return. This is because in our setting, factor correlations are accounted for in the construction of the conditional factor loadings, so that no orthogonalization is necessary. The model considered here is also closely related to Kraus and Litzenberger (1976). The Sharpe ratios generated by the augmented model are 0.93 and 0.90, respectively (see also Table 1), which account for 81% and 82% of the respective maximum Sharpe ratios generated by the base assets. The corresponding efficient frontiers are plotted in Panel B of Figures 1 and 2. Note that the factor mimicking portfolio for the skewness factor is very close to the efficient frontier, which may account for the superior performance of this model. c) The Consumption CAPM For the Consumption CAPM, the single factor is the growth rate in aggregate consumption. Since consumption is measured only quarterly, we use quarterly data for both the base asset returns and the conditioning variable CAY. Note first that the effect of CAY on the efficient frontier is much weaker at quarterly frequency, increasing the annual Sharpe ratio by only 26% compared with the fixed-weight case. We then construct the mimicking portfolio for this factor, and compute the implied maximum Sharpe ratio. The results, reported in Panel B of Table 1, indicate that the Consumption CAPM, augmented by the optimal use of the lagged CAY, seems to work relatively well as a conditional factor model (the factor accounts 21

22 for about 89% of the maximum asset Sharpe ratio). Our results are thus in broad agreement with those of Lettau and Ludvigson (2001b), but our methodology differs from theirs in that we use a traded portfolio (the factor mimicking portfolio). Figure 4 plots the corresponding efficient frontiers in this case. In fact, the factor mimicking portfolio itself (represented by the dot in the figure) appears to be close to being unconditionally mean-variance efficient. 6 Conclusion This paper develops portfolio based tests of conditional factor models both with and without conditioning information. These tests are developed by exploiting the close links between the stochastic discount factor (SDF) framework developed in Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) and mean-variance efficiency. We show that if m = a+b F is a true SDF, then a combination of the factor mimicking portfolios of m is in fact unconditionally mean-variance efficient. This provides a necessary condition for a factor model a + b F to be an SDF. Conversely given a set of factors we construct a managed portfolio of the factor-mimicking portfolios which a attains the maximum Sharpe ratio generated by the factors. If this Sharpe ratio is equal to the maximum Sharpe ratio of the assets, then this portfolio can be lifted to a conditional asset pricing model. We use these results to test various conditional factor models and to construct the optimal managed combination of the factors. We find that the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model scaled by consumption-wealth ratio as well as the model of Harvey and Siddique (2000) perform well as conditional asset pricing models 22

23 A Mathematical Appendix A.1 Proof of Proposition 3.3: [TO BE DONE] A.2 Proof of Proposition 4.3: We use Lemma 3.3 in Hansen and Richard (1987), applied to the trivial σ-field. It implies that the unconditionally efficient generalized return with mean m can be written as rt + w(m) zt, with w(m) = m E( r t ). (20) E( zt ) Here, r t R t is the unique generalized return with minimal second moment, and z t is the Riesz representation of the expectation functional on the space Z t of excess returns, see (3.8) in Hansen and Richard (1987). From (20) it follows by orthogonality that the variance of the efficient return with mean m is given by, σ 2 ( m ) = E( r t ) E( r t ) r f ( m r f ) 2. Hence, the frontier even in the case of generalized returns has the familiar wedge shape, and the maximum (squared) unconditional Sharpe ratio is given by, λ 2 = r f E( rt ). (21) E( rt ) From Lemma A.1 below we obtain the weights for the generalized return r t. A straightforward calculation then yields E( r t ) = r f / ( 1 + h 2 ). This, together with (21) gives the desired result. 23

24 Lemma A.1 The generalized return r t with minimum unconditional second moment is, r t = θ 0 t 1r f + ( Rt r f e ) θt 1 with θ t 1 = r f 1 + h 2 Σ 1 t 1µ t 1 and θt 1 0 = 1 + H2 t h 2 Proof: Throughout the proof, we will omit the time subscript. To characterize the weights of the minimum second moment return, we use calculus of variation. Let θ 0 (ε) and θ(ε) be differentiable one-parameter families of admissible weights, and define r(ε) = θ 0 (ε)r f + ( R r f e ) θ(ε). We assume E( θ 0 (ε) ) = 1 for all ε, so that the r(ε) are indeed generalized returns for all ε. Suppose that the minimum second moment is attained at ε = 0, then we must have, d dε E ( r(ε) ) 2 = 0 (22) ε=0 We will use this condition to determine the solutions θ 0 and θ separately. Part (i): Characterizing θ 0 Let φ 0 be an arbitrary weight function, and set a = 1/E( φ 0 ). Define θ 0 (ε) = (1 ε)θ 0 + εaφ 0, θ(ε) θ By construction, E( θ 0 (ε) ) = 1 for all ε, so that this specification indeed generates a family of generalized returns. In this case, the first-order condition (22) becomes, 0 = 2r 2 fe ( θ 0 (aφ 0 θ 0 ) ) + 2r f E ( (aφ 0 θ 0 )µ θ ) 24

25 Multiplying this equation by E( φ 0 ) = 1/a, we obtain, E ( [ r f θ 0 + µ θ ]φ ) 0 = γe ( φ ) 0 for some unconditional constant γ. Since this equation must hold for all φ 0, we obtain r f θ 0 + µ θ = γ (23) Finally, since E( θ 0 ) = 1, taking unconditional expectations implies, γ = r f + E ( µ θ ) (24) Part (ii): Characterizing θ Let φ be an arbitrary vector of weights for the risky assets, and set θ 0 (ε) θ 0, θ(ε) = θ + εφ Since E( θ 0 (ε) ) = E( θ 0 ) = 1, this specification generates a family of generalized returns. Hence, we can apply the first-order condition (22) to obtain, 0 = 2r f E ( θ 0 µ φ ) + 2E ( θ Λφ ) Since this equation must hold for all φ, we obtain, r f θ 0 µ = Λθ = [ Σ + µµ ] θ Substituting from (23) into the left-hand side of this equation, we can write, θ = γσ 1 µ, Multiplying this by µ and taking unconditional expectations, we obtain, E ( µ θ ) = γe ( µ Σ 1 µ ) = γe( H 2 ) =: γh 2 (25) 25

26 Finally, equating (24) and (25), γh 2 = E ( µ θ ) = γ r f, which implies γ = r f 1 + h 2 Hence, the weights for the risky assets are given by, r f θ = γσ 1 µ = 1 + h 2 Σ 1 µ Finally, using (23), we obtain the weight for the risk-free asset, r f θ 0 = γ µ θ = γ + r fh 2 This completes the proof of Lemma A h 2, which implies θ0 = 1 + H2 1 + h 2 A.3 Proof of Proposition 4.5: [TO BE DONE] A.4 Proof of Theorem 4.1 We first show the only if part. Suppose that there exist conditional coefficients a t 1 and b i t 1 such that (7) indeed is a viable SDF for the model. [TO BE DONE] 26

27 References Abhyankar, A., D. Basu, and A. Stremme (2002): The Economic Value of Asset Return Predictability: A Sharpe Ratio Based Test, working paper, Warwick Business School. Bekaert, G., and J. Liu (2001): Conditioning Information and Variance Bounds on Pricing Kernels, working paper, Columbia Business School. Breeden, D., M. Gibbons, and R. Litzenberger (1989): Empirical Test of the Consumption-Oriented CAPM, Journal of Finance, 44(2), Campbell, J. (1987): Stock Returns and the Term Structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 18, Carhart, M. (1997): On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance, Journal of Finance, 52(1), Cochrane, J. (1999): Portfolio Advice for a Multi-Factor World, Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 23(3), Cochrane, J. (2001): Asset Pricing. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Dybvig, P., and S. Ross (1985): Differential Information and Performance Measurement using a Security Market Line, Journal of Finance, 60, Fama, E., and K. French (1988): Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 22,

28 Fama, E., and K. French (1992): The Cross-Section of Expected Returns, Journal of Finance, 47, Ferson, W., and C. Harvey (1999): Conditioning Variables and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns, Journal of Finance, 54, Ferson, W., and A. Siegel (2001): The Efficient Use of Conditioning Information in Portfolios, Journal of Finance, 56(3), Ferson, W., and A. Siegel (2002a): Stochastic Discount Factor Bounds with Conditioning Information, forthcoming, Review of Financial Studies. Ferson, W., and A. Siegel (2002b): Testing Portfolio Efficiency with Conditioning Information, working paper, University of Washington. Gallant, R., L. Hansen, and G. Tauchen (1990): Using Conditional Moments of Asset Payoffs to Infer the Volatility of Intertemporal Marginal Rates of Substitution, Journal of Econometrics, 45(1), Hansen, L., and R. Jagannathan (1991): Implications of Security Markets Data for Models of Dynamic Economies, Journal of Political Economy, 99(2), Hansen, L., and S. Richard (1987): The Role of Conditioning Information in Deducing Testable Restrictions Implied by Dynamic Asset Pricing Models, Econometrica, 55(3), Harvey, C., and A. Siddique (2000): Conditional Skewness in Asset Pricing Tests, Journal of Finance, 55(3),

29 Huberman, G., S. Kandel, and R. Stambaugh (1987): Mimicking Portfolios and Exact Arbitrage Pricing, Journal of Finance, 42(1), 1 9. Jagannathan, R. (1996): Relation between the Slopes of the Conditional and Unconditional Mean-Standard Deviation Frontier of Asset Returns, in Modern Portfolio Theory and its Applications: Inquiries into Asset Valuation Problems, ed. by S. Saito et al. Center for Academic Societies, Osaka, Japan. Kraus, A., and R. Litzenberger (1976): Skewness Preference and the Valuation of Risky Assets, Journal of Finance, 31, Lettau, M., and S. Ludvigson (2001a): Consumption, Aggregate Wealth and Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance, 56(3), Lettau, M., and S. Ludvigson (2001b): Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A Cross-Sectional Test when Risk Premia are Time-Varying, Journal of Political Economy, 109(6),

30 Panel A: Fama-French Model Factor Frontier Asset Frontier Fixed-Weight Expected Return Standard Deviation Panel B: Fama-French Model with Skewness Factor Factor Frontier Asset Frontier Fixed-Weight Expected Return Standard Deviation Figure 1: Using CAY as Predictor Variable These figures show the estimated efficient frontier generated by the base assets, both in the fixed-weight case (dashed line) and with conditioning information (bold-faced line), and the frontier generated by the factor mimicking portfolios (light-weighted line), for the three-factor Fama-French model (Panel A) and the Fama-French model augmented by a skewness factor (Panel B). The predictor variable used is CAY. The factor mimicking portfolios themselves are shown as dots. 30

31 Panel A: Fama-French Model Factor Frontier Asset Frontier Fixed-Weight Expected Return Standard Deviation Panel B: Fama-French Model with Skewness Factor Factor Frontier Asset Frontier Fixed-Weight Expected Return Standard Deviation Figure 2: Using DY as Predictor Variable These figures show the estimated efficient frontier generated by the base assets, both in the fixed-weight case (dashed line) and with conditioning information (bold-faced line), and the frontier generated by the factor mimicking portfolios (light-weighted line), for the three-factor Fama-French model (Panel A) and the Fama-French model augmented by a skewness factor (Panel B). The predictor variable used is DY. The factor mimicking portfolios themselves are shown as dots. 31

32 Factor Weight 0-10 Mkt-Rf -20 SMB HML Rf Realization of CAY Figure 3: Optimal Factor Model This graph shows the optimal weights, as functions of the predictor variable CAY, on the factor mimicking portfolios and the risk-free asset, for the three-factor Fama-French model. 32

33 Predictor (annualized) Factors Variable Sharpe ratios (fw) assets fmp s Panel A: Monthly Returns RMF HML SMB CAY RMF HML SMB SKEW CAY RMF HML SMB DY RMF HML SMB SKEW DY Panel B: Quarterly Returns CONSGR CAY Table 1: Test Results This table reports the maximum (annualized) Sharpe ratios generated by the base assets and the factor mimicking portfolios, respectively. The factor models tested are the three factor (RMF, HML and SMB) Fama-French model, the Fama-French model augmented by the skewness factor (SKEW), and the consumption growth (CONSGR) model. The predictor variables used are CAY and DY as indicated. 33

34 0.030 Factor Frontier Asset Frontier Fixed-Weight Expected Return Standard Deviation Figure 4: Consumption CAPM This figures show the estimated efficient frontier generated by the base assets, both in the fixed-weight case (dashed line) and with conditioning information (bold-faced line), and the frontier generated by the consumption growth factor (light-weighted line). The predictor variable used is CAY. The factor mimicking portfolio is shown as a dot. 34

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM?

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? WORKING PAPERS SERIES WP05-04 CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? Devraj Basu and Alexander Stremme CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? 1 Devraj Basu Alexander

More information

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick January 2006 address

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

The Global Price of Market Risk and Country Inflation

The Global Price of Market Risk and Country Inflation The Global Price of Market Risk and Country Inflation Devraj Basu, Cass Business School, City University London, d.basu@city.ac.uk Chi-Hsiou Hung, Durham Business School, University of Durham, d.c.hung@durham.ac.uk

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) A stochastic discount factor is a stochastic process {M t,t+s } such that

More information

Department of Finance Working Paper Series

Department of Finance Working Paper Series NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LEONARD N. STERN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Department of Finance Working Paper Series FIN-03-005 Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch, Jessica Wachter

More information

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M VIALE I Markowitz-Tobin Mean-Variance Portfolio Analysis Assumption Mean-Variance preferences Markowitz 95 Quadratic utility function E [ w b w ] { = E [ w] b V ar w + E [ w] }

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

The Global Price of Market Risk and Country Inflation

The Global Price of Market Risk and Country Inflation The Global Price of Market Risk and Country Inflation Devraj Basu, Cass Business School, City University London, d.basu@city.ac.uk Chi-Hsiou Hung, Durham Business School, University of Durham, d.c.hung@durham.ac.uk

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DYNAMIC TRADING STRATEGIES AND PORTFOLIO CHOICE. Ravi Bansal Magnus Dahlquist Campbell R. Harvey

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DYNAMIC TRADING STRATEGIES AND PORTFOLIO CHOICE. Ravi Bansal Magnus Dahlquist Campbell R. Harvey NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DYNAMIC TRADING STRATEGIES AND PORTFOLIO CHOICE Ravi Bansal Magnus Dahlquist Campbell R. Harvey Working Paper 10820 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10820 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Non replication of options

Non replication of options Non replication of options Christos Kountzakis, Ioannis A Polyrakis and Foivos Xanthos June 30, 2008 Abstract In this paper we study the scarcity of replication of options in the two period model of financial

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line Lars Tyge Nielsen INSEAD Maria Vassalou 1 Columbia University This Version: January 2000 1 Corresponding

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM Yan Zeng Version 1.0.2, last revised on 2012-05-30. Abstract A summary of mean variance analysis in portfolio management and capital asset pricing model. 1. Mean-Variance

More information

Predictability of Stock Returns

Predictability of Stock Returns Predictability of Stock Returns Ahmet Sekreter 1 1 Faculty of Administrative Sciences and Economics, Ishik University, Iraq Correspondence: Ahmet Sekreter, Ishik University, Iraq. Email: ahmet.sekreter@ishik.edu.iq

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Prepared by Kevin Pei for The Fund @ Sprott Abstract: In this document, I will model and back test our portfolio with various proposed models. It goes without

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Ian Dew-Becker and Stefano Giglio Duke Fuqua and Chicago Booth 11/27/13 Dew-Becker and Giglio (Duke and Chicago) Frequency-domain asset pricing

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILITATION OF STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR METHODOLOGY. John H. Cochrane

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILITATION OF STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR METHODOLOGY. John H. Cochrane NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILIAION OF SOCHASIC DISCOUN FACOR MEHODOLOGY John H. Cochrane Working Paper 8533 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8533 NAIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

An Analysis of Theories on Stock Returns

An Analysis of Theories on Stock Returns An Analysis of Theories on Stock Returns Ahmet Sekreter 1 1 Faculty of Administrative Sciences and Economics, Ishik University, Erbil, Iraq Correspondence: Ahmet Sekreter, Ishik University, Erbil, Iraq.

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework

More information

Common Macro Factors and Their Effects on U.S Stock Returns

Common Macro Factors and Their Effects on U.S Stock Returns 2011 Common Macro Factors and Their Effects on U.S Stock Returns IBRAHIM CAN HALLAC 6/22/2011 Title: Common Macro Factors and Their Effects on U.S Stock Returns Name : Ibrahim Can Hallac ANR: 374842 Date

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments T. Fischer Darmstadt University of Technology November 11, 2003 Abstract This brief paper explains how to obtain upper boundaries of shortfall

More information

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns

The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Stock and Bond Returns The Cross-Section and Time-Series of Ralph S.J. Koijen, Hanno Lustig, and Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh University of Chicago, UCLA & NBER, and NYU, NBER & CEPR UC Berkeley, September 10, 2009 Unified Stochastic

More information

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM

Addendum. Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Addendum Multifactor models and their consistency with the ICAPM Paulo Maio 1 Pedro Santa-Clara This version: February 01 1 Hanken School of Economics. E-mail: paulofmaio@gmail.com. Nova School of Business

More information

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Spring 2016 Overview The inputs of portfolio problems Using the single index model Multi-index models Portfolio

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri Basics of Asset Pricing Ali Nejadmalayeri January 2009 No-Arbitrage and Equilibrium Pricing in Complete Markets: Imagine a finite state space with s {1,..., S} where there exist n traded assets with a

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model?

Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model? Improving the asset pricing ability of the Consumption-Capital Asset Pricing Model? Anne-Sofie Reng Rasmussen Keywords: C-CAPM, intertemporal asset pricing, conditional asset pricing, pricing errors. Preliminary.

More information

Asset-pricing Models and Economic Risk Premia: A Decomposition

Asset-pricing Models and Economic Risk Premia: A Decomposition Asset-pricing Models and Economic Risk Premia: A Decomposition by Pierluigi Balduzzi and Cesare Robotti This draft: September 16, 2005. Abstract The risk premia assigned to economic (non-traded) risk factors

More information

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract

Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing. Abstract Empirical Test of Affine Stochastic Discount Factor Model of Currency Pricing Alex Lebedinsky Western Kentucky University Abstract In this note, I conduct an empirical investigation of the affine stochastic

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015

Best-Reply Sets. Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis. This version: May 2015 Best-Reply Sets Jonathan Weinstein Washington University in St. Louis This version: May 2015 Introduction The best-reply correspondence of a game the mapping from beliefs over one s opponents actions to

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER First Version: 15 November 2002 Current Version:

More information

Exploiting the Informational Content of Hedging Pressure: Timing the Market by Learning from Derivatives Traders

Exploiting the Informational Content of Hedging Pressure: Timing the Market by Learning from Derivatives Traders EDHEC RISK AND ASSET MANAGEMENT RESEARCH CENTRE 393-400 promenade des Anglais 06202 Nice Cedex 3 Tel.: +33 (0)4 93 18 32 53 E-mail: research@edhec-risk.com Web: www.edhec-risk.com Exploiting the Informational

More information

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model he Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model Vladimir Vovk he Game-heoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper #39 September 6, 011 Project web site: http://www.probabilityandfinance.com

More information

Models of asset pricing: The implications for asset allocation Tim Giles 1. June 2004

Models of asset pricing: The implications for asset allocation Tim Giles 1. June 2004 Tim Giles 1 June 2004 Abstract... 1 Introduction... 1 A. Single-factor CAPM methodology... 2 B. Multi-factor CAPM models in the UK... 4 C. Multi-factor models and theory... 6 D. Multi-factor models and

More information

Time-Series Restrictions for the Cross-Section of Expected Returns: Evaluating Multifactor CCAPMs

Time-Series Restrictions for the Cross-Section of Expected Returns: Evaluating Multifactor CCAPMs Time-Series Restrictions for the Cross-Section of Expected Returns: Evaluating Multifactor CCAPMs Jinyong Kim Department of Economics New York University November 15, 2004 Abstract A number of recent papers

More information

Analyzing Oil Futures with a Dynamic Nelson-Siegel Model

Analyzing Oil Futures with a Dynamic Nelson-Siegel Model Analyzing Oil Futures with a Dynamic Nelson-Siegel Model NIELS STRANGE HANSEN & ASGER LUNDE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS, BUSINESS AND SOCIAL SCIENCES, AARHUS UNIVERSITY AND CENTER FOR RESEARCH

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

1 Introduction The two most important static models of security markets the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)

1 Introduction The two most important static models of security markets the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) Factor Pricing in Multidate Security Markets 1 Jan Werner Department of Economics, University of Minnesota December 2001 1 I have greatly benefited from numerous conversation with Steve LeRoy on the subject

More information

Does the Fama and French Five- Factor Model Work Well in Japan?*

Does the Fama and French Five- Factor Model Work Well in Japan?* International Review of Finance, 2017 18:1, 2018: pp. 137 146 DOI:10.1111/irfi.12126 Does the Fama and French Five- Factor Model Work Well in Japan?* KEIICHI KUBOTA AND HITOSHI TAKEHARA Graduate School

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes A Simple Martingale Method Approach Frank Thomas Seifried University of Kaiserslautern March 20, 2009 F. Seifried (Kaiserslautern) Deferred Capital

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2013 GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 1 / 37 Squared log returns for CRSP daily GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 2 / 37 Absolute value

More information

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Jan Werner University of Minnesota SPRING 2019 1 I.1 Equilibrium Prices in Security Markets Assume throughout this section that utility functions

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM Campbell R. Harvey and Akhtar Siddique ABSTRACT Single factor asset pricing models face two major hurdles: the problematic time-series properties

More information

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance The main question in portfolio theory is the following: Given an initial capital V (0), and opportunities (buy or sell) in N securities

More information

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Nicola Pavoni October 21, 2016 The Lucas Tree Model This is a general equilibrium model where instead of deriving properties of

More information

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Bryan Kelly NYU Stern and Chicago Booth Outline Introduction An Economic Framework Econometric Methodology Empirical Findings Conclusions Tail Risk

More information

where T = number of time series observations on returns; 4; (2,,~?~.

where T = number of time series observations on returns; 4; (2,,~?~. Given the normality assumption, the null hypothesis in (3) can be tested using "Hotelling's T2 test," a multivariate generalization of the univariate t-test (e.g., see alinvaud (1980, page 230)). A brief

More information

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Lecture 8: Asset pricing BURNABY SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY BRITISH COLUMBIA Paul Klein Office: WMC 3635 Phone: (778) 782-9391 Email: paul klein 2@sfu.ca URL: http://paulklein.ca/newsite/teaching/483.php Economics 483 Advanced Topics

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem Chapter 8: CAPM 1. Single Index Model 2. Adding a Riskless Asset 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM 5. The One-Fund Theorem 6. The Characteristic Line 7. The Pricing Model Single Index Model 1 1. Covariance

More information

Mean-Variance Theory at Work: Single and Multi-Index (Factor) Models

Mean-Variance Theory at Work: Single and Multi-Index (Factor) Models Mean-Variance Theory at Work: Single and Multi-Index (Factor) Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Spring 2017 Outline and objectives The number of parameters in MV problems and the curse

More information

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TESTING PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY WITH CONDITIONING INFORMATION. Wayne E. Ferson Andrew F. Siegel

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TESTING PORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY WITH CONDITIONING INFORMATION. Wayne E. Ferson Andrew F. Siegel NBER WORKING AER ERIE TETING ORTFOLIO EFFICIENCY WITH CONDITIONING INFORMATION Wayne E. Ferson Andrew F. iegel Working aper 198 http://www.nber.org/papers/w198 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC REEARCH 15 Massachusetts

More information

Principles of Finance

Principles of Finance Principles of Finance Grzegorz Trojanowski Lecture 7: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Principles of Finance - Lecture 7 1 Lecture 7 material Required reading: Elton et al., Chapter 16 Supplementary reading: Luenberger,

More information

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing Section A Arbitrage and Asset Pricing 4 Section A. Arbitrage and Asset Pricing The theme of this handbook is financial decision making. The decisions are the amount of investment capital to allocate to

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version

Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version Bernard Herskovic, Alan Moreira, and Tyler Muir March 15, 2018 Abstract Standard risk factors can be hedged with minimal reduction in average return. This is true

More information

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Hui Guo a, Christopher J. Neely b * a College of Business, University of Cincinnati, 48

More information

Regret-based Selection

Regret-based Selection Regret-based Selection David Puelz (UT Austin) Carlos M. Carvalho (UT Austin) P. Richard Hahn (Chicago Booth) May 27, 2017 Two problems 1. Asset pricing: What are the fundamental dimensions (risk factors)

More information

Conditioning Information and Variance Bounds on Pricing Kernels with Higher-Order Moments: Theory and Evidence

Conditioning Information and Variance Bounds on Pricing Kernels with Higher-Order Moments: Theory and Evidence Conditioning Information and Variance Bounds on Pricing Kernels with Higher-Order Moments: Theory and Evidence Fousseni CHABI-YO Financial Markets Department, Bank of Canada March 6, 005 Abstract We show

More information

Foundations of Asset Pricing

Foundations of Asset Pricing Foundations of Asset Pricing C Preliminaries C Mean-Variance Portfolio Choice C Basic of the Capital Asset Pricing Model C Static Asset Pricing Models C Information and Asset Pricing C Valuation in Complete

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Fall 2017 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models Preliminary Lecture Notes Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University November 2014 Contents 1 Static Moral Hazard

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

What is the Expected Return on the Market?

What is the Expected Return on the Market? What is the Expected Return on the Market? Ian Martin May, 25 Abstract This paper presents a new bound that relates the equity premium to a volatility index, SVIX, that can be calculated from index option

More information

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach Applied Financial Economics, 1998, 8, 51 59 A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach SHIGEYUKI HAMORI* and SHIN-ICHI KITASAKA *Faculty of Economics,

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: An Investment Process for Stock Selection Fall 2011/2012 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements December, 20 th, 17h-20h:

More information

Global Currency Hedging

Global Currency Hedging Global Currency Hedging JOHN Y. CAMPBELL, KARINE SERFATY-DE MEDEIROS, and LUIS M. VICEIRA ABSTRACT Over the period 1975 to 2005, the U.S. dollar (particularly in relation to the Canadian dollar), the euro,

More information

Answer FOUR questions out of the following FIVE. Each question carries 25 Marks.

Answer FOUR questions out of the following FIVE. Each question carries 25 Marks. UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA School of Economics Main Series PGT Examination 2017-18 FINANCIAL MARKETS ECO-7012A Time allowed: 2 hours Answer FOUR questions out of the following FIVE. Each question carries

More information

EIEF/LUISS, Graduate Program. Asset Pricing

EIEF/LUISS, Graduate Program. Asset Pricing EIEF/LUISS, Graduate Program Asset Pricing Nicola Borri 2017 2018 1 Presentation 1.1 Course Description The topics and approach of this class combine macroeconomics and finance, with an emphasis on developing

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET Vol 18 No 2 Journal of Systems Science and Complexity Apr 2005 CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET SUN Wangui (School of Economics & Management Northwest University Xi an 710069 China Email: wans6312@pubxaonlinecom)

More information

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing THE UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON Paul Klein Office: Murray Building, 3005 Email: p.klein@soton.ac.uk URL: http://paulklein.se Economics 3010 Topics in Macroeconomics 3 Autumn 2010 Lecture 8: Introduction

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review AN EMPIRICAL VALIDATION OF FAMA AND FRENCH THREE-FACTOR MODEL (1992, A) ON SOME US INDICES

Asian Economic and Financial Review AN EMPIRICAL VALIDATION OF FAMA AND FRENCH THREE-FACTOR MODEL (1992, A) ON SOME US INDICES Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): 2222-6737/ISSN(p): 2305-2147 journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 AN EMPIRICAL VALIDATION OF FAMA AND FRENCH THREE-FACTOR MODEL (1992, A)

More information