Advances in Macroeconomics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Advances in Macroeconomics"

Transcription

1 Advances in Macroeconomics Volume 1, Issue Article 7 Population Changes and Capital Accumulation: The Aging of the Baby Boom José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania, vr0j@econ.upenn.edu Copyright c 2001 by the authors. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher, bepress, which has been given certain exclusive rights by the author. Advances in Macroeconomics is produced by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress).

2 Population Changes and Capital Accumulation: The Aging of the Baby Boom José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Abstract In this paper I explore the quantitative implications for savings of population aging. In doing so, I pay particular attention to some features that have been partially over-looked in the literature. These features include the details of the population aging process, the initial conditions with respect to assets holdings, and the relation between age and household size. In order to do so, I develop recursive methods capable of dealing with overlapping generations environments where the population is stochastic. The main findings are: i) If population patterns revert to the averages of the last 50 years, the reduction in aggregate savings due to changes in the age structure of the population is small. ii) If, however, the demographic process is such that fertility patterns remain at their current low levels, then the effects of the aging of the baby boom are very large. iii) Initial conditions matter: both the choice for initial assets and the choice for the mechanism through which current fertility reverts to its long run average have implications for the economic allocations. And iv) The contribution of general equilibrium effects is to exacerbate the reduction of savings since population aging tends to make labor relatively scarce, and, therefore, to reduce rates of return of capital, which in turn reduces savings even further. KEYWORDS: Savings, Population Aging, Wealth Distribution

3 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation 1 Introduction The demographic structure of most western countries is changing. The key feature of this process is that the population is getting increasingly older. The smooth but continuous decrease in mortality together with the reduction in fertility after the huge number of births in the baby boom of the 50 s and early 60 s are the main culprits of this process. The aging of the population brings forth a variety of very important social issues since so many features of individual behavior are age-dependent. Economists have been especially concerned with the fiscal implications of aging, mainly social security. There is a large literature devoted to study the implications of alternative policies that started with the seminal work of Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987). 1 In general this literature has concentrated its effort in the implications of the policies themselves. The purpose of this paper is to investigate how certain details in the modelling of populations affected by severe demographic changes shape the answers provided by explicit general equilibrium models of the overlapping generations variety. The items that I look at in detail are the demographic process that generates the aging of the population and the initial conditions that are used to propagate the economy forward. I find that these features are quantitatively very important and that we should perhaps devote more resources to better understand the demographic processes that are behind the aging of the population. This paper fills a void in the literature that so far has looked mostly at steady states, or at the transition between steady states. In the few cases that the demographic details have been looked at in some detail (Huang et al. (1997), De Nardi et al. (1998), and Auerbach et al. (1989)) by using official population projections, the initial assets used when computing the transition have been those corresponding to a steady state that is different from the final one to which the economy is converging. Moreover, the literature has taken population projections at face value and has not explored in any detail what would happen under different demographic assumptions (except the occasional differences in growth rates of the population). 1 Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1984), Auerbach et al. (1991), Auerbach et al. (1989), Hubbard and Judd (1987), Danthine and Surchat (1991), Chauveau and Loufir (1993), Imrohoroğlu et al. (1995), Huang et al. (1997), Bohn (1998), Bütler (1998), De Nardi et al. (1998), Huggett and Ventura (1998), Storesletten et al. (1998), Conesa and Krueger (1999), Fuster (1999). Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

4 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 To make matters concrete I look at the implications of the demographic changes for savings rates because they are a clear indicator of the economic implications of the demographic process. I could have looked at other properties of the allocation, but savings rates nicely summarize the economic behavior of the system. In this paper I make three important modelling choices. The first one is that I assume that all assets are held for life cycle reasons. There is an very good case against this assumption since the seminal work of Kotlikoff and Summers (1981). 2 The reason for this assumption is in part to be in line with the literature of population aging that have always used overlapping generations models with little role for bequests. The reason is also that we do not have yet models that integrate a suitable theory of wealth inequality and a sophisticated demographic structure, although I have no doubt that those models will appear soon. The second assumption that I make is to completely abstract from the government and hence from social security. The last assumption that I make is to have leisure enter the utility function. The first two choices simplify the analysis (actually the first makes it feasible), while the last assumption complicates it. The reason for the last two choices lies in the fact that I am not interested per se in the actual value of the saving rate but in an exploratory investigation of the relevance of certain details of the demographic process and of the initial conditions in shaping the properties of the economic allocations. That these details have fiscal implications is sort of obvious, but what I want to know is whether they also matter for the properties of the equilibrium allocations. The reason to account explicitly for leisure is that I want to have another margin through which agents can adjust to the changes in prices. I believe that by making these assumptions, it is harder for the demographic details to be quantitatively important. I build a general equilibrium overlapping generations model where agents choose to work, consume, and save and where the demographic process is modeled in some detail. Then, I solve the model and I calibrate a baseline model economy to Spanish data. 3 The nature of the exercise is to propagate 2 See Quadrini and Ríos-Rull (1997) and Castañeda et al. (2000) for further arguments of what is a good theory of the wealth distribution. 3 To look at Spain rather than at the U.S. given the data shortage on some dimensions that Spain has is due to the fact that migratory movements have not been very important in the period under study. Spain presents a standard pattern of a baby boom in the late 50 s and early 60 s together with a sharp reduction of fertility in the eighties and nineties. Compared to the rest of the western countries the demographic process in Spain might be 2

5 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation the model from 1998 onwards and to look at the savings rates along the equilibrium path. To do this, I have to specify not only the calibration details, but also the initial conditions that have to be mapped to 1998 Spain, and that in all cases specify the age structure of the Spanish population in It is in the calibration process and in the specification of the initial conditions that the paper focuses on. In particular, I look at various possibilities for the initial distribution of assets and for the future path of fertility and mortality. The initial conditions of the model are the age distribution of the population that is always set to the one in 1998 Spain, an initial age-wealth distribution and the initial values for shocks that are used to forecast fertility. I look at various age wealth distributions: those of the steady state of the deterministic version of the model, the age wealth distribution in the U.S. and some age wealth distributions generated endogenously by the model through simulations. The reason for the latter is that the 1998 age-structure of the population is very different from the steady state age structure, and it does not seem very interesting to use the age-wealth distribution associated to a very different age structure. To get around this I run many simulations of the model until its age structure is similar to that in 1998 Spain and then use the age-wealth distribution of the simulations as initial conditions. In order to do this a stochastic model is needed, capable of having fertility being subject to shocks. Another contribution of this paper is to develop such a model. In addition, I perform standard robustness analysis on some of the parameter choices and, by looking at a partial equilibrium version of the baseline model economy, I separate the direct demographic effects from those that appear through changes in prices. The key findings of the paper can be summarized by: 1. If the current drop in fertility is temporary and the demographic process is such that fertility will return to the average of the last fifty or sixty years, then there will be a small reduction in savings rates of around 2% of GNP until the latter part of the twenty first century. 2. The specific set of initial conditions that we choose matter for the allocations. Both the choice for initial assets and the choice for the mechanism through which current fertility reverts to its long run average have implications for the economic allocations. seen as slightly delayed, and, perhaps, sharper in its features. Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

6 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art If, however, the current drop in fertility is permanent, then there will be dramatic implications for savings rates that will suffer a huge and steady reduction towards to almost zero. 4. The contribution of the general equilibrium effects is to exacerbate the reduction of savings. The reason for this result is that the aging of the population generates a relative scarcity of labor relative to capital. This reduces rate of return of capital (interest rates) and make people to save less. There is a large literature on the interaction between population and capital accumulation. Among the work that considers fertility as endogenous, Barro and Becker (1989) develop a model where parents are altruistic and there is capital accumulation. They also perform comparative statics experiments when different parameters of their model change. They discuss the dynamic behavior of their economy and its stability and are able to partially characterize non steady-state behavior. However, their approach to study the dynamics does not easily extend to economies with more than two periods. In Eckstein and Wolpin (1985), parents are not altruistic but their utility depends on their children s consumption. Razin and Ben-Zion (1975) analyze steady states in their formulation that makes the number of children and the utility per child separable in their parents preferences. Another theoretical analysis of steady states is Willis (1988), who investigates comparative statics under different rates of population growth in a model with exogenous fertility. None of these papers is quantitative in nature, and it is hard to think of suitable extensions of their specifications capable of accommodating the analysis of economies were agents live a large number of periods, and where the initial conditions of the economy do not lead to a steady state. None of this works is quantitative in nature. There is some work that addresses the interrelations between economics and demographics quantitatively. For instance, Lee and Lapkoff (1988) carefully study of intergenerational transfers empirically both within and outside the family with special attention to the allocation of time. Their study assumes a steady state equilibrium with constant relative prices. They also compare properties of the transfers in steady states that differ in the rate of population growth and consider some specifications that endogenize fertility. Among the work that treats fertility as exogenous, but is quantitative in nature, Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1984), Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987), Auerbach et al. (1991) and, in particular, Auerbach et al. (1989), consider 4

7 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation the effects of demographic transitions. Their work is similar in spirit to the work in this paper. They use OEDC population projections to propagate the population for a certain number of years. After that, population is reset to replacement levels by fixing birth rates equal to death rates. The key differences between these papers and the present study are (i) howthepop- ulation predictions are made, and (ii) the assumptions of the nature of the economy. In their world, population patterns include first a drastic aging of the population as predicted by the OEDC, but, after that, they assume that population reverts to a replacement regime, with a population pyramid shaped as a perfect rectangle. Their model is also deterministic, which, as we will see, prevents the use of simulations to generate endogenously assets distributions. 4 They also find a rise in wages associated to the aging of the population. As they are interested in the relative welfare of different generations, the increase in wages for the relatively scarce young people in the near future, will counteract the reduction in their welfare associated to the higher burden of social security. An excellent survey on other recent work on computational models of social security isimrohoroğlu et al. (1999). 5 4 Their procedure consists on calibrating a set of parameters so that the steady state matches certain properties of what is thought of as initial conditions. Next, another set of parameters is also chosen so that they have a steady state that corresponds to what is thought of as the long run of the economy. A change in the initial parameters is then postulated. This change might include the number of births for a hundred years, or a vector of policy parameters. After a certain number of periods the model s parameters become those associated with the final steady state. A large number of periods is taken to be associated with the transition, after which the economy is assumed to have converged to the new steady state. This procedure is ingenious, as it reduces the computation of the equilibrium to solving three nonlinear systems of equations: the two steady states, and the transition. 5 Other work with computational overlapping generations models includes Danthine and Surchat (1991) also study the quantitative implications of population changes for the case of Switzerland. However, in their model agents are naive they are incapable of properly predicting prices. Ríos-Rull (1996) analyzes quantitatively the business cycle behavior of large overlapping generations economies where the population is in steady state but the economy is not (both fertility and mortality are exogenous and constant). The model economies studied are stochastic in nature and the methods used enable the computation of equilibria that are not converging to deterministic steady states. Finally, another important contribution is Laitner (1990) computes transition paths from one steady state to another after a surprising change in one of the model s exogenous parameters by linearizing around the steady state. Although he only applies his methods to changes in the tax structure, they could be adapted to changes in fertility that change the age structure of the population slowly towards a new steady state. Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

8 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 Section 2 describes the model, with special emphasis on its demographics. Section 3 defines the equilibrium, and discusses the advantages of a recursive definition. In Section 4 I discuss the nature of the computational experiments, the choices for initial conditions and for the specific versions of the model that I use. Section 5 describes the calibration of the baseline model economy, both its demographics (mainly that mortality stays constant and that fertility reverts to its historical average) and its economics, that is the one with the preferred parameterization and that acts as a reference with respect to the other experiments. Section 6 describes the properties of the baseline model economy as is propagated towards the future. Section 7 discusses the implications of a different demographic scenario than that of the baseline, that fertility will remain at its current low levels. The robustness exercises are performed in Section 8 while Section 9 concludes. The Appendix includes details of the computational procedures (Section A) and some tables with the parameters chosen for the baseline model economy and with interesting statistics referred to in the text (Section B). 2 The Model 2.1 Demographic Structure The model consists of overlapping generations of agents that live up to I periods. The probability of surviving between age i and age i +1 is s i. Therefore, the unconditional probability of reaching age i is s i = i 1 j=1 s j. These probabilities are assumed to be constant over time. The number of births is, however, stochastic. Let x t R I be the age distribution across age groups in period t. Then x 1,t+1, the number of newborns the following period, is the product of x t and the vector of age specific fertility rates φ i,t. Following Lee (1974), this product can be approximated by x 1,t+1 = i φ ix i,t +z t,where φ i are average age specific fertility rates, and where z t is an error term that follows some ARMA(p,q) process. The population changes through changes in fertility, which subsequently induce changes in the age distribution. Let ˆΓ be the matrix representing the law of motion of a population with the same survival and fertility rates as above but with deterministic fertility. Then, 6

9 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation φ 1 φ 2 φ 3... φ I s ˆΓ = 0 s s I 0 It is a well-known mathematical property that the biggest eigenvalue of this matrix determines the long run rate of growth of the population regardless of the initial conditions, and that its associated eigenvector is the age distribution to which the population converges (note that the Perron- Frobenius Theorem guarantees that both are non-negative), often denoted the stable population. If the largest eigenvalue is different from one, the population will be non-stationary. To achieve stationarity, fertility and survival parameters are renormalized by dividing every element by the largest eigenvalue of ˆΓ. The normalized matrix has a biggest eigenvalue of one and its associated eigenvector is its stationary population. We can think of this eigenvector as the deterministic steady state of our stochastic population. The law of motion of the stochastic population together with the shock for fertility following, for example, an AR(2), is defined in the following way: x 1,t+1 x 2,t+1. x I,t+1 z t+1 z t ρ 1 ρ 2 ˆΓ 0 0 = ρ 1 ρ x 1,t x 2,t. x I,t z t z t 1 + ν t ν t+1 0, (1) where the ρ s denote the coefficients in the AR(2) representation of z t and where ν t+1 is the innovation to the process. ( ) I write this compactly, denoting next period s variables with primes, as x =Γ ( ) x z z + ν. 2.2 Preferences and Technology After birth, the agents remain children for a number of periods I 0 in which they do not consume, nor work, nor make any decision. After these first periods, they become adults and have standard preferences over streams of consumption and leisure for the remainder of their life. Agents are endowed Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

10 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 with an age dependent profile of efficiency units of labor, denoted ɛ i. E ach period agents have one unit of time that the can transform into leisure or efficient units of labor. Preferences of an agent born in period t can be summarized by the following utility function where the expectation is taken with respect to the moment where the agent is first capable of making decisions: { I } E t+i0 β i s i u i (c i,t,l i,t ), (2) i=i 0 +1 where (c i,t,l i,t ) are the consumption and leisure of an agent of age i born in period t. β i can be given at least two interpretations; it could represent pure time preference, but it could also reflect changes in family size (so that a given consumption is enjoyed differently at different ages). Capital and efficiency units of labor transform into output through a deterministic neoclassical production function. Capital depreciates at rate δ. 2.3 Market Structure Every period there are spot markets for labor and the consumption good. Agents can also accumulate real assets, whose total is the amount of real capital in the economy. There are no state contingent markets. If there were, agents could write contracts contingent on the period s fertility rate. The computational methods for finding the equilibrium in a complete markets world are cumbersome, and recent research (Ríos-Rull (1994) in overlapping generations models with aggregate shocks, Krusell and Smith (1997) in models with idiosyncratic as well as aggregate shocks, and Storesletten et al. (1999) in overlapping generations models with idiosyncratic as well as aggregate shocks) indicate that the differences implied by these two market structures are quantitatively unimportant as the resulting risk premium is minute. There are, however, annuities markets to cover the eventuality of early death. The simplest implementation of annuities is to allow agents to write a contract with the members in their own cohort that make the survivors share the wealth or debts of those who die prematurely. I make this assumption because closing this market implies choosing an arbitrary important alternative, and this paper does not investigate the implications of this assumption. 8

11 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation The real assets that agents accumulate and whose return they collect may be negative. 6 These considerations imply that every period, the budget constraint of an age i agent born in period t is: c i,t + y i,t = a i,t (1 + r t+i 1 )+(1 l i,t ) ɛ i w t+i 1, (3) a i+1,t = y i,t /s i. (4) Here, y i,t is gross savings of the age i agent born in t, anda i,t is his wealth, while r t+i 1 is the rental price of capital (net of depreciation), and w t+i 1 is the price of one unit of efficient labor in period t+i 1. Note that the second constraint reflects the existence of the annuities markets introduced above. 3 Equilibrium I define equilibrium recursively. This is particularly appropriate given that there are shocks to the system. 7 As an added bonus for using recursive methods, the objects that I define are precisely those objects that I calculate in the computational process. The literature typically either looks only at steady states, where the prices are constant, or it defines equilibria as sequences. Equilibria defined as sequences can only be computed when they converge to a steady state when it becomes a well behaved system of finitely many equations (see Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) and Laitner (1990)). At any point in time, the economy is characterized by a certain distribution of the population x, by the values of the fertility shock needed to make accurate predictions of its future values z, and by the assets owned by individuals in each age group k. The vector (x, z, k) S IR I + IR M IR I I 0 is the state of the economy, where M is the number of lags in the process for z required to predict its future values. It depends on the order of the ARMA process. The individual state is (x, z, k, a) S = S IR, where the last element is the agent s own asset holdings. The definition includes a set of age-specific value functions, decision rules, and the aggregate law of motion for capital. Formally: 6 Negative assets can be thought of loans with returns that are perfectly correlated with the rate of return of capital. 7 The notion of recursive equilibria is partly based on the work of Prescott and Mehra (1980) and Ríos-Rull (1996). Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

12 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 Definition 1 A Recursive Competitive Equilibrium for a closed economy is a set of value functions v i : S IR, fori = I 0 +1,...,I, a set of decision rules for gross savings, consumption and leisure y i : S IR, l i : S [0, 1], c i : S IR +,fori = I 0 +1,...,I, laws of motion for the population, Γ, and for the capital stock G : S IR I I 0, and functions for prices w : S IR +, and R : S IR +, for aggregate capital K : S IR +, and for aggregate labor input N : S IR +, such that: (i) The allocation is feasible, i. e. for all(x, z, k) S, (y i (x, z, k, k i )+c i (x, z, k, k i )) x i = f (K(x, z, k),n(x, z, k)). i (ii) Prices are competitively determined, i.e., they are the marginal productivities of the factors of production: r(x, z, k) = f 1 (K(x, z, k) δ, N(x, z, k)), w(x, z, k) = f 2 (K(x, z, k),n(x, z, k)). (iii) Given the laws of motion of the aggregate state variables, Γ, andg, the decision rules of the agents y i, c i,andl i, solve their maximization problem: {y i (x, z, k, a),c i (x, z, k, a), l i (x, z, k, a)} arg max y,c,l u i (c, l)+β i s i E {v i+1 (x,z,k,a ) z} s.t. k = G(x, z, k), ( ) ( ) x x z = Γ + ν, z c i, +y i = a [1 + r (x, z, k)] + (1 l i ) ɛ i w(x, z, k), a = y i /s i. (iv) The value functions are generated by the decision rules of the agents and by using the fact that v I+1 (x, z, k, a) =0: v i (x, z, k, a) = u i (c i (x, z, k, a),l i (x, z, k, a)) + ( β i s i E {v i+1 Γ ( x z ) + ν, G(x, z, k),y i (x, z, k, a)/s i ) z }. 10

13 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation (v) The law of motion of the capital stocks is generated by the decision rules of the agents: G i+1 (x, z, k) =y i (x, z, k, k i )/s i. (vi) Aggregate functions K, andn, are generated by aggregation and the decision rules of the agents: K(x, z, k) = i N(x, z, k) = i x i k i, x i (1 l i (x, z, k, k i )). Equilibrium conditions for a small open economy with internationally determined factor prices at levels r and w can be defined in a similar way with minor changes. These changes pertain to condition (i) that is not required now; the marginal productivities of condition (ii) which are required to equate the internationally determined prices; and in (vi), where the first of the two conditions need not hold, as international capital movements will make prices be the same across countries. 4 The Nature of the Experiments As stated above, this paper explores the implications of a variety of demographic and initial conditions for the study of life cycle savings. To do this, a number of experiments have to be performed. I start by constructing a baseline model economy designed to match some crucial features of the Spanish economy. I propagate this economy from different initial conditions and compare the implications of those initial conditions. All the initial conditions share the same population age distribution, that of Spain in 1998, but differ in the asset distribution and in the lagged values of the demographic shocks that affect the future path of fertility. The different set of initial conditions for assets include those generated endogenously by the model in the steady state, the U.S. age wealth distribution (there is no available data for Spain), and others that are obtained by simulating the model economy. The rationale for the latter require some explanation: we do not observe the actual wealth distribution in Spain. Moreover, the empirical wealth distribution is not consistent with a pure life-cycle model (see Quadrini and Ríos-Rull (1997), and Castañeda et al. (2000)), and Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

14 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 the current population distribution is very far from the steady state, so it is hard to argue that the wealth distribution of the steady state is appropriate as an initial condition when the accompanying population distribution is so different. Therefore, I simulate the model for a large number of periods and use as initial conditions the asset distribution that prevails in the model economy when the simulated population is close to the actual age distribution of 1998 Spain. With respect to the initial values for the fertility shock, I use zero (its unconditional average) when using steady state or empirical asset distributions as initial conditions and I use those generated by the simulations themselves when using simulated asset distributions. Obviously, when propagating the model into the future, I shut off any further innovations to the shocks to the system. I run additional experiments to ask a variety of other questions. The first one (Section 7) is particularly important as it asks a fundamental question that has to do with the nature of the current level of fertility. What are the implications of fertility not recovering and staying at its current low levels? I then run a variety of experiments under the heading of robustness analysis (Section 8) where I explore the implications of alternative assumptions both about demographics and economics. In Section 8.1 I ask what are the implications of a further decrease in mortality. In Section 8.2 I explore the implications of higher productivity growth, by looking at a model where the growth rate is the average since 1950 rather than the average of the last twenty years as it is assumed in the baseline model economy. Sections 8.3 and 8.4 explore how the answers to our main question depend on specific assumptions about preferences (intertemporal elasticity of substitution and relative value of leisure versus the consumption good). Finally, I run an additional experiment with constant exogenous prices. An interpretation of this experiment is that the demographic processes in the world as a whole compensate each other so that there are no price fluctuations. Next, I describe the calibration of the baseline model economy. 5 The Baseline Model Economy To determine the parameterization of the baseline model economy, I use Spanish demographic information, and as much as possible Spanish economic data, but when the latter is unavailable, I use their U.S. counterpart. I start describing the modelization of the demographics in Section 5.1 and then I 12

15 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation follow with the economics in Section Demographics of the Baseline Model Economy Mortality The Spanish population has a very high life expectancy (second only to Japan): years in This is almost a year higher than in the rest of Europe. To properly model this, one has to use a very large number for the maximum life length, more than is standard in the literature. 9 Iuse 100 years. A period is set to be five years so that the maximum number of periods that an agent lives is 20. However, all numbers are presented in yearly terms for ease of comparison. Agents become adults at age 21, when they start making decisions about how much to work, consume, and save. 10 However, they can become parents before that age (as they do in the data). Probabilities of survival into the next age group are taken to be those of the Spanish population for 1994, the latest for which there are definitive numbers Fertility With respect to fertility, recall that following Lee (1974) the process for fertility can be written as: x 1,t+1 = i φ i x i,t + z t where φ i is an age specific fertility rate. The φ s were taken to be average from the period divided by the rate of population growth jointly implied by those same fertility rates and by the age specific mortality rates of Note that I have assumed that there is no migration. 11 z t, the residual 8 Source: INE. 9 Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) use 74, Conesa and Krueger (1999) use 85, and Storesletten (2000) uses This may seem too old. However, Spaniards are well known for living at home until a very high age. 11 As it will be seen later in the context of endogenous assets, this assumption is not as unrealistic for the Spanish society as it would be for the U.S. The current Spanish age distribution can be obtained from simulations using the law of motion obtained from its historic fertility rates and its current mortality rates. This is not the case for the U.S. Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

16 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 process for fertility, was estimated as a univariate process, and it turned out that the best match was an AR(2), the same process that Lee (1974) found for the U.S. The values estimated for the parameters are ρ 1 =1.09 and ρ 2 = 0.72, with a standard deviation of innovations of This comes to no surprise: AR(2) processes with complex roots, as this one is, typically generate long cycles. This is exactly the behavior of fertility since World War II for most western countries as there is both a baby boom and a recent decay in fertility Population Path The process of the population implies a rate of growth of the population of 0.83% annually. This demographic regime will be referred to as historic or average fertility. Figure 1 shows the path of the population age distribution implied by this process starting with the actual 1998 age structure and setting the variance of the fertility shocks equal to zero. There are some important characteristics that should be noted. First, the fact that fertility switches dramatically to its historical average implies that the model forecasts fertility to be much higher than in the recent past. Consequently, the fraction of the population under 20 years of age, that now stands at around 23%, is forecasted to grow until its stable level of around 32%. Note that there is a small baby bust associated to the echo of the current low number of children, that oscillates in a vanishing wave kind of fashion as the model moves towards the future. The fraction of the population older than 65, currently set at around 16% will not grow much more than that. In fact, it will peak at just below 20% in It is interesting to note that the dependence ratio (population under 20 plus population over 65 over population in working age) will have an early peak in 2020 and will be high again after It is also interesting to note that the very low fertility of the last twenty years of the twentieth century has its influence on the following century through a small series of booms where the large number of immigrants affects the age distribution to the extent that it is impossible to generate the current age distribution from simulations that only use data on fertility and mortality rates. The assumption of no immigration can be relaxed in a variety of ways. For instance, under the assumption of an existing infinitely sized set of prospective immigrants it can be relaxed by stating an immigration policy that depends linearly on the age distribution or on features of the wealth distribution. See Storesletten (2000) for an excellent study of the role of migrations with an extended version of the OLG model. 14

17 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation Population 0-20 Population Population Population Population > Percentage Year Figure 1: Population Structure in the Baseline Scenario. Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

18 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 and busts that show up more clearly in the middle age groups. 12 But this overall picture is of very little change. The population age structure is not bound to be dramatically different from the one today under the demographic assumptions of the baseline model economy. 5.2 Economics of the Baseline Model Economy Calibration is not parameter picking. It is a process where the parameters are chosen so that certain statistics of the model economy have the values desired by the researchers. The target values are chosen so that the model economies have certain properties in common with the economies under study. The key target for the calibration of the baseline model economy is the capital (wealth) to output ratio for which I choose a value of 3.0 (see Castañeda et al. (2000)). I chose an investment to output ratio of one fifth. Productivity growth is the average growth rate of the Spanish output to employment ratio since 1980, which is 2.09%. 13 The labor share of income is set at 0.64, larger than recent assessments of this statistic that include the public sector. When we abstract from public capital a value of labor share of.64 or even higher seems appropriate. The assessment of leisure is chosen so that households never work more than 30% of their time, even at their peak. I have not been able to obtain a series for age specific wages (that are needed to construct the age specific efficiency units of labor) of Spanish workers, so I have used American data. In particular, I used the series obtained by Gary Hansen from CPS data. 14 I also make some adjustments for family size that assumes that consumption enjoyed is an age-specific fraction of consumption spent. In particular, I adapt the coefficients used in Cubeddu and Ríos-Rull (1996) (who in turn obtains them from the household equivalence scales of the OEDC) and I adapt them to account for the fact that this is a one sex model. As is traditional in growing economies, I use utility and production functions that are consistent with a balanced growth path. In particular, I use 12 These oscillations occur for all ages. The middle age groups are the smallest in length so they show the oscillations more sharply. 13 The value of this parameter is obtained from David Taguas who maintains this series, first published as Corrales and Taguas (1989). 14 Hourly wages by age and sex groups are used to obtain an index of relative efficiency across individuals of different ages that is later aggregated by sex and decomposed into the age groups that I use in this paper. See Hansen (1986) and Ríos-Rull (1996) for details. 16

19 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation a constant relative risk aversion instantaneous utility function and a Cobb- Douglas production function with exogenous productivity growth. The specific utility function that I use is ( ) ci,t u i (c i,t,l i,t )=u,l i,t = η i (( ci,t η i ) α ) 1 σ l 1 α i,t 1, for all i {I 0,I 0 +1,I}. 1 σ where {η i } is the vector of adjustments for family size that account for the consumption of the children. For the coefficient of risk aversion, also referred to as the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, 15 thechoiceisnotclearauerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) describe the literature and choose a value of 4 as a compromise between different studies, which is also the value that I chose. 16 Table 1 shows the parameter values used to calibrate the baseline model economy as well as the age structure of the population in Findings: The Baseline Model Economy I start describing the main features of the baseline model economy as it is propagated towards the future. I use mainly figures since they are a better tool to see what happens. 17 The figures show the paths of relevant variables as predicted by the model between 1998 and Our main objects of interest are savings rates. Figure 2 shows the paths for savings rates for the baseline model economy under various initial conditions, all of which have patterns in common: the aging of the population associated to the low fertility of the last 25 years is such that current savings are slightly above their long run average, and the oscillations of the savings rate are not very large. The savings rates for most of the initial conditions oscillate between 7.5% and 10.5%. There will be also a continuous decrease of savings until 2010, and then, around 2035, savings will increase for the next 25 years, after which there is a slow decrease towards the long run level of 9.8%. 15 In economies with leisure this convention of names is confusing. Note that for retired households the actual coefficient of risk aversion is not σ, but ασ. I simply use those words to refer to the parameter σ. 16 See Ríos-Rull (1996) for a more detailed discussion. 17 The data upon which these figures are based are available in Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

20 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art Saving Rates with Initial Conditions from the St St Saving Rates with U.S. Initial Conditions and Equal Total Capital Saving Rates from Simulations and its own Total Wealth 1 Saving Rates from Simulations and Ave Fert Total Wealth 1 Saving Rates from Simulations and its own Total Wealth 2 Saving Rates from Simulations and Ave Fert Total Wealth 2 Assets in Percentage Age Figure 2: Savings rates for different initial wealth distributions for the baseline economy. 18

21 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation Besides those patterns that are common to all initial conditions there are some specificities depending on the initial conditions. To analyze them, we start by discussing those various initial conditions in detail; the asset distributions and the recent values for the fertility shocks. 6.1 The different initial conditions There are three alternative types of aggregate variables, the age structure of the population, the age-wealth distribution, and the lagged values of the shocks that affect future fertility through their role in the AR(2). So specifying initial conditions means choosing values for each of the three vectors. In all the experiments, the initial age structure of the population is the same, that observed in 1998 Spain. The initial conditions that I use differ in the choices of wealth structure and values for the lagged shocks. The initial conditions that I use can be divided in three types: the steady state age-wealth distribution, the U.S. age-wealth distribution and those generated by the model through simulations. I now describe them in detail. The steady state age-wealth distribution as initial condition. Iuse the age-wealth distribution of the steady state of the economy as one of the possible initial conditions. The values of the shock are set to zero. There is no especial rationale for using this age-wealth distribution as initial condition except for the fact that it is very easy to calculate; researchers often claim that they do not have any particular bias when they use it (for example, see Auerbach et al. (1989) and Conesa and Krueger (1999)). The age-wealth distribution of the U.S. as initial condition. Here we use the age wealth distribution actually observed. 18 I normalize the U.S. age-wealth assets so that total wealth is the same as for the previous initial conditions. The differences between the U.S. asset distribution and the steady state assets distribution are, perhaps surprisingly, not very large, as shown in Figure The graph is constructed so that total wealth is the same for the two distributions. 20 The graph shows that the elderly in the 18 In our case, the age wealth distribution observed in the U.S. is the one found in the 1998 Survey of Consumer Finances. 19 This information is also available in Table This means that the area below the curves weighted by the population in each age group is the same. Obviously, there are many more people below 65 than above 65 years Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

22 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art Steady State Age-Wealth Distribution U.S. Data Age-Wealth Distribution 0.3 Assets in Percentage Figure 3: Steady State Asset Distribution for the baseline economy and U.S. Asset Distribution. Age 20

23 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation U.S. hold less assets than what is predicted by the pure life cycle theory used in this paper, but overall, the two profiles are not very different. The main difference between the two distributions is that, in the model, assets are held later in life, but the steepness of the age-assets profile is quite similar, showing, perhaps the importance of the social security system in shaping the age-assets profile. This is relatively surprising because of the often argued fact that the U.S. asset distribution is not well accounted for by life cycle reasons. This point was argued pretty forcefully and convincingly by Kotlikoff and Summers (1981), and more recently by Castañeda et al. (2000) in their theory of the U.S. asset distribution. Of course, it is important not to forget that in the U.S. there are large differences in assets held within cohorts while in this OLG model there are none. Initial conditions obtained through simulations of the model. The population age-structure in Spain in 1998 is very different from that implied by the model that we have used to model it. The reason is, as I have said above, that fertility in the last twenty five years has been well below its long run average and the model assumes that fertility will revert to this long run average. For this reason, perhaps the age-wealth distribution of the steady state is not the most appropriate one to associate with the population age structure of To obtain an age wealth asset distribution predicted by the model but consistent with the 1998 age-structure of the population, I simulated the model a large number of periods until the age distribution of the simulation was similar to that of 1998 Spain. Once this is done I then recorded the age wealth profiles at that point and then used them as initial conditions. These simulations do not necessarily yield the same total assets as in the previous sets of initial conditions. Therefore, for the sake of comparison, I looked at simulated wealth distributions both normalized and normalized to the same total wealth as that implied by the steady state age-wealth distribution. Moreover, because these simulations include sampling error, I looked at more than one simulation. Figure 2 includes two simulations, labeled 1 and 2, each generating two sets of initial conditions depending on whether or not total wealth is normalized. Finally, the actual simulations carry different initial conditions for the values of past shocks that are used to forecast fertility. Those used are the ones implied by the simulations themselves. of age. Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

24 Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 [2001], Iss. 1, Art. 7 Differences in the initial values for the shocks turned out to be quite important: Figure 4 shows the predictions of the model for the shares of population under 20 and over 65 years of age starting from the same age structure that of 1998 Spain and differing in the value of the initial shocks that are used to propagate fertility. The system is stationary so the three forecasts will eventually converge, but, as Figure 4 shows, it takes a long time to do so. Notice that the population over 65 is quite smooth and this is partly due to the fact that it is the aggregate of a large number of ages. The population under twenty belongs to a more compact set of age groups and we can see clearly the oscillations in its size. It is also interesting to note that the two simulated paths of initial conditions are quite different. The reason is that the shocks have different signs: one of them starts forecasting a boom and then a bust of births while the other starts with the bust. In any case we see that there may be large differences in the path of the population Population 0-20 Population > 65 Population 0-20 with initial shocks 1 Population > 65 with initial shocks 1 Population 0-20 with initial shocks 2 Population > 65 with initial shocks 2 35 Percentage Year Figure 4: Shares of the youngest and the oldest without initial shocks and with the values of the initial shocks obtained from simulations. 22

25 Ríos-Rull: Population Changes and Capital Accumulation 6.2 Behavior of the Savings Rate under the Different Initial Conditions When we compare the paths for savings rates of the different initial conditions we see that they all have an early dip with a short lived recovery around 2020, another dip with lowest point in 2035, and then a smooth recovery towards the steady state (which, recall, is the same for all economies) level of 9.8%. The first thing that we see is that there are large differences in between the different paths. Perhaps, the path that stands out is the one using initial conditions obtained from U.S. age-wealth data. In this case savings fall by around one third between the first period of the simulation and By the mid of the century this path has got very close to that with steady state assets, the only other path with whom it shares the population path. Among the paths that are generated by simulations we see that those coming from different simulated populations are quite different from each other, while those that have the same population but different total initial capital start within one percentage point of each other and end up converging. We see that both the steady state path and the U.S. wealth distribution path are in between the simulated paths, one of which shows a much larger dip than the other. From these observations we can conclude that the mechanics of the age structure of the population induced by the very low recent fertility will imply a sharp reduction of the savings rate of up to one third during the next forty years even if there is a complete recovery of fertility. We also conclude that the form of the recovery, whether the long swing carries on or whether it suddenly reverts to its historic average also matters, but it is not clear in which way, it depends on whether one thinks of the current low fertility, as either a temporary development such as a baby bust, or whether one thinks of it as a permanent phenomenon. Figure 5 describes the savings rates by age implied by the previous exercise in the case where the initial condition is that implied by the steady state. There are various observations to make here. First, unlike the aggregate savings rate changes that are due both to changes in the age structure of the population and to changes in response to prices, all responses depicted in this table are due to changes in prices. Second, the values of the savings rates vary quite a lot. Changes of more than 25 percentage points can be seen between contiguous cohorts. Finally, note that the movements in savings rates are not perfectly correlated across age groups as can also be seen Published by The Berkeley Electronic Press,

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls Lucas (1990), Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review, Oxford Economic Papers When I left graduate school, in 1963, I believed that the single most desirable change in the U.S. structure would be the

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan

Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan Akira Okamoto (Okayama University) * Toshihiko Shima (University of Tokyo) Abstract This paper aims to establish guidelines for public pension

More information

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation Mariacristina De Nardi 1 Fang Yang 2 1 UCL, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, IFS, and NBER 2 Louisiana State University June 8, 2015 De Nardi and

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 April Last week two benchmarks: autarky and complete markets non-state contingent bonds:

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

The Saving Rate in Japan: Why It Has Fallen and Why It Will Remain Low

The Saving Rate in Japan: Why It Has Fallen and Why It Will Remain Low CIRJE-F-535 The Saving Rate in Japan: Why It Has Fallen and Why It Will Remain Low R.Anton Braun University of Tokyo Daisuke Ikeda Northwestern University and Bank of Japan Douglas H. Joines University

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role John Laitner January 26, 2015 The author gratefully acknowledges support from the U.S. Social Security Administration

More information

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Public Pension Reform in Japan ECONOMIC ANALYSIS & POLICY, VOL. 40 NO. 2, SEPTEMBER 2010 Public Pension Reform in Japan Akira Okamoto Professor, Faculty of Economics, Okayama University, Tsushima, Okayama, 700-8530, Japan. (Email: okamoto@e.okayama-u.ac.jp)

More information

Movements on the Price of Houses

Movements on the Price of Houses Movements on the Price of Houses José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Penn, CAERP Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria, Penn Tue Dec 14 13:00:57 2004 So Preliminary, There is Really Nothing Conference on

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University November 17, 2008 Abstract We extend a standard overlapping-generations

More information

The Japanese saving rate between 1960 and 2000: productivity, policy changes, and demographics

The Japanese saving rate between 1960 and 2000: productivity, policy changes, and demographics Economic Theory (2007) 32: 87 104 DOI 10.1007/s00199-006-0200-9 SYMPOSIUM Kaiji Chen Ayşe İmrohoroğlu Selahattin İmrohoroğlu The Japanese saving rate between 1960 and 2000: productivity, policy changes,

More information

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Selahattin İmrohoroğlu 1 Shinichi Nishiyama 2 1 University of Southern California (selo@marshall.usc.edu) 2

More information

ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations

ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations ECONOMICS 723 Models with Overlapping Generations 5 October 2005 Marc-André Letendre Department of Economics McMaster University c Marc-André Letendre (2005). Models with Overlapping Generations Page i

More information

Policy Uncertainty and the Cost of Delaying Reform: A case of aging Japan

Policy Uncertainty and the Cost of Delaying Reform: A case of aging Japan RIETI Discussion Paper Series 6-E-03 Policy Uncertainty and the Cost of Delaying Reform: A case of aging Japan KITAO Sagiri Keio University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/

More information

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families Jay H. Hong José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University of Pennsylvania CAERP, CEPR, NBER Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21 Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach Roozbeh Hosseini University of Georgia Ali Shourideh Wharton School QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21 Roozbeh Hosseini(UGA) 0 of 34 Background and Motivation

More information

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Wealth Distribution and Bequests Wealth Distribution and Bequests Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ821 February 9, 2016 1 / 20 Contents Introduction 3 Data on bequests 4 Bequest motives 5 Bequests and wealth inequality 10 De Nardi (2004) 11 Research

More information

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States André C. Silva Nova School of Business and Economics April 2008 Abstract I relate hours worked with taxes on consumption and labor for Portugal,

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality . 1 Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality Lutz Hendricks Iowa State University, CESifo, CFS March 28, 2004. 1 Introduction 2 Wealth is highly concentrated in U.S. data: The richest 1% of households

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016 Evolution of top wealth inequality

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales, Sydney July 2009, CEF Conference Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several

More information

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS?

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS? D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO Applications of Behavioural Economics and Multiple Equilibrium Models to Macroeconomic Policy Conference July 3, 2017

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective Gary D. Hansen and Selahattin İmrohoroğlu April 3, 212 Abstract Past government spending in Japan is currently imposing a significant

More information

Pension Reform in an OLG Model with Multiple Social Security Systems

Pension Reform in an OLG Model with Multiple Social Security Systems ERC Working Papers in Economics 08/05 November 2008 Pension Reform in an OLG Model with Multiple Social Security Systems Çağaçan Değer Department of Economics Middle East Technical University Ankara 06531

More information

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Greg Kaplan José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University of Minnesota, Mpls Fed, and CAERP EFACR Consumption

More information

The Implications of a Graying Japan for Government Policy

The Implications of a Graying Japan for Government Policy FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA WORKING PAPER SERIES The Implications of a Graying Japan for Government Policy R. Anton Braun and Douglas H. Joines Working Paper 2014-18 November 2014 Abstract: Japan is

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

Policy Uncertainty and Cost of Delaying Reform: A Case of Aging Japan

Policy Uncertainty and Cost of Delaying Reform: A Case of Aging Japan Policy Uncertainty and Cost of Delaying Reform: A Case of Aging Japan Sagiri Kitao August 1, 216 Abstract With aging demographics and generous pay-as-you-go social security, reform to reduce benefits is

More information

On the Distributional Effects of Social Security Reform*

On the Distributional Effects of Social Security Reform* Review of Economic Dynamics 2, 498 531 (1999) Article ID redy.1999.0051, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on On the Distributional Effects of Social Security Reform* Mark Huggett Centro de

More information

Understanding the U.S. Distribution of Wealth

Understanding the U.S. Distribution of Wealth Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol. 21, No. 2, Spring 1997, pp. 22 36 Understanding the U.S. Distribution of Wealth Vincenzo Quadrini Assistant Professor Department of Economics Universitat

More information

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation Capital Income Taxes, Labor Income Taxes and Consumption Taxes When thinking about the optimal taxation of saving

More information

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract This note shows that a public pension system with a

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital University of Mannheim, University of Cologne, Munich Center for the Economics of Aging 13th Annual Joint Conference of the RRC

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPAGATION AND SMOOTHING OF SHOCKS IN ALTERNATIVE SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEMS. Alan Auerbach Lorenz Kueng Ronald Lee

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPAGATION AND SMOOTHING OF SHOCKS IN ALTERNATIVE SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEMS. Alan Auerbach Lorenz Kueng Ronald Lee NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROPAGATION AND SMOOTHING OF SHOCKS IN ALTERNATIVE SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEMS Alan Auerbach Lorenz Kueng Ronald Lee Working Paper 19137 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19137 NATIONAL

More information

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR THE MASSES James Bullard (FRB of St. Louis) Riccardo DiCecio (FRB of St. Louis) Swiss National Bank Research Conference 2018 Current Monetary Policy Challenges Zurich, Switzerland

More information

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession The Lost Generation of the Great Recession Sewon Hur University of Pittsburgh January 21, 2016 Introduction What are the distributional consequences of the Great Recession? Introduction What are the distributional

More information

The Japanese Saving Rate between : Productivity, Policy Changes, and Demographics

The Japanese Saving Rate between : Productivity, Policy Changes, and Demographics The Japanese Saving Rate between 1960-2000: Productivity, Policy Changes, and Demographics Kaiji Chen Ayşe İmrohoroğlu Selahattin İmrohoroğlu February, 2006 Abstract In this paper, we use an overlapping

More information

A Life-Cycle Overlapping-Generations Model of the Small Open Economy Ben J. Heijdra & Ward E. Romp

A Life-Cycle Overlapping-Generations Model of the Small Open Economy Ben J. Heijdra & Ward E. Romp Mortality and Macroeconomics: Tilburg University 1 A Life-Cycle Overlapping-Generations Model of the Small Open Economy & Ward E. Romp Mortality and Macroeconomics Tilburg University Version 1. 7 December

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples

Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples Applied Economics Letters, 2004, 11, 693 697 Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples CARMEN D. ALVAREZ-ALBELO Departamento de

More information

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University March 22, 2010 Abstract We extend a

More information

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO Nonlinear Models in Macroeconomics and Finance for an Unstable World Norges Bank Jan. 26, 2018 Oslo, Norway Any opinions

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ). ECON 8040 Final exam Lastrapes Fall 2007 Answer all eight questions on this exam. 1. Write out a static model of the macroeconomy that is capable of predicting that money is non-neutral. Your model should

More information

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018 Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018 Lecture 8: Safe Asset, Government Debt Pertti University School of Business March 19, 2018 Today Safe Asset, basics Government debt, sustainability, fiscal

More information

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Davide Porcellacchia 8 February 2017 Abstract The canonical New Keynesian model features a zero lower bound on the interest rate. In the simple setting

More information

1 No capital mobility

1 No capital mobility University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #7 1 1 No capital mobility In the previous lecture we studied the frictionless environment

More information

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy Tomoaki Yamada Rissho University 2, December 2007 Motivation Objectives Introduction: Motivation Rapid aging of the population combined

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013 .. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective Gary Hansen (UCLA) and Selo İmrohoroğlu (USC) May 10, 2013 Table of Contents.1 Introduction.2 Model Economy.3 Calibration.4 Quantitative

More information

Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan

Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-013 Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan KITAO Sagiri RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Discussion

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

1. Money in the utility function (continued) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (continued) a. Welfare costs of in ation b. Potential non-superneutrality

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010 Booms and Busts in Asset Prices Klaus Adam Mannheim University & CEPR Albert Marcet London School of Economics & CEPR May 2010 Adam & Marcet ( Mannheim Booms University and Busts & CEPR London School of

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Life-cycle Labour Supply The simple static labour supply model discussed so far has a number of short-comings For example, The

More information

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler and J. David López-Salido Preliminary draft, June 2001 Abstract Galí and Gertler (1999) developed a hybrid

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare Shutao Cao Bank of Canada Césaire A. Meh Bank of Canada José Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Yaz Terajima

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Analysis and Application Max Gillman UMSL 27 August 2014 Gillman (UMSL) Modern Macro 27 August 2014 1 / 23 Overview of Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 1: Overview of the

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Optimal time consistent taxation with international mobility of capital

Optimal time consistent taxation with international mobility of capital Optimal time consistent taxation with international mobility of capital Paul Klein, Vincenzo Quadrini and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull October 23, 2003 Abstract The United States relies for its government revenues

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

O PTIMAL M ONETARY P OLICY FOR

O PTIMAL M ONETARY P OLICY FOR O PTIMAL M ONETARY P OLICY FOR THE M ASSES James Bullard (FRB of St. Louis) Riccardo DiCecio (FRB of St. Louis) Norges Bank Oslo, Norway Jan. 25, 2018 Any opinions expressed here are our own and do not

More information

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall 2003 Notes Section 4 Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods We consider now solution methods for discrete time models in which decisions

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

The Effect of Population Age Structure on Economic Growth in Iran

The Effect of Population Age Structure on Economic Growth in Iran International Research Journal of Finance and Economics ISSN 1450-2887 Issue 72 (2011) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2011 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm The Effect of Population Age Structure

More information

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators 1/27 Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators Gary Venter University of New South Wales 2/27 STATISTICAL CONCEPTUAL BACKGROUND "All models are wrong but some are useful"; George Box

More information

Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth

Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth Tamara Fioroni Lucia Zanelli 5th October 2007 Abstract The aim of this paper is to analyze the effect of child mortality and fertility reductions

More information

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis Santanu Chatterjee University of Georgia Felix Rioja Georgia State University October 31, 2017 John Gibson Georgia State University Abstract

More information

Endogenous labour supply, endogenous lifetime and economic growth: local and global indeterminacy

Endogenous labour supply, endogenous lifetime and economic growth: local and global indeterminacy Endogenous labour supply, endogenous lifetime and economic growth: local and global indeterminacy Luca Gori 1 and Mauro Sodini 2 SIE October 23-25, 2014 *** 1. University of Genoa luca.gori@unige.it 2.

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Asset Prices and Finance Max Gillman Cardi Business School 0 December 200 Gillman (Cardi Business School) Chapter 7 0 December 200 / 38 Chapter 7: Asset Prices and Finance

More information

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University. The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil Brown University December 2007 Goal: analyze quantitatively the economic effects of interventions

More information

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl) University of California, Davis Date: September 1, 2011 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Macroeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Directions: Answer all

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Propagation and Smoothing of Shocks in Alternative Social Security Systems

Propagation and Smoothing of Shocks in Alternative Social Security Systems Propagation and Smoothing of Shocks in Alternative Social Security Systems Alan Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Lorenz Kueng Northwestern University Ronald Lee University of California, Berkeley

More information