ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations"

Transcription

1 ECONOMICS 723 Models with Overlapping Generations 5 October 2005 Marc-André Letendre Department of Economics McMaster University c Marc-André Letendre (2005).

2 Models with Overlapping Generations Page i Contents 1 Endowment Economy: An Overview of the Model Agent s Optimization Problem Feasible, Efficient and Optimal Consumption Allocation Competitive Equilibrium Extension I: Population Growth Extension II: Heterogeneity within a Cohort (2-Countries) Production Economy: an Overview of the Model Households The Savings Decision Supply of Inputs Firms Competitive Equilibrium and Transition Equation Growth, Transition Period and Steady State Computing Time Paths Comparative Dynamics Growth in Population and Technology Growth in Population Growth in Technology

3 Models with Overlapping Generations Page ii 2.8 (Un)Importance of Initial Conditions Fiscal Policy in the Diamond Model Government Budget Constraint and National Income Identity Fiscal Policy with a Zero Deficit Household Savings Decision with Taxes and Transfers The Transition Equation Taxing the Young Taxing the Old Pay-as-you-go Social Security System

4 Models with Overlapping Generations Page iii Acknowledgements This set of notes borrows from McCandless with Wallace (1991) Introduction to dynamic macroeconomic theory: an overlapping generations approach, Harvard University Press; Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1998) Macroeconomics: an integrated approach, MIT Press; and lecture notes by Gregor Smith (1999). For more on OLG models, consult these sources and Romer (2001, 1996).

5 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 1 Introduction Most of the discussion in the section of the course on two-period economies focused on models where all agents are identical (representative agents models). As we have seen in the section on open-economy models, allowing for heterogeneity across agents in that framework is relatively easy. Obviously economic agents can differ in many respects. A fundamental characteristic of overlapping generations (OLG) models is that there are agents from different age groups (or cohorts) alive at the same time. Just like in the section on two-period economies, we assume that an individual lives for two periods. Note however that the economy itself goes on forever. Since a new cohort of agents is born each period, this implies that in any given period there are young and old agents in the economy. We will see that many (but not all) results from the section on two-period economies carry over to the OLG framework. OLG models are appealing for a number of reasons. First, they are tractable and relatively easy to work with even though they can be used to analyze complex issues. Second, they allow us to study behaviour of economic agents over their life-cycle. Third, many policy issues (like transfer payments) make more sense when the population is heterogeneous. Fourth, they provide examples of competitive equilibria which are not Pareto optimal. Our study of OLG models starts with an endowment economy framework that is related in a number of ways to the two-period economy setting we studied in section II of the course. Then we consider a model with production related to the Diamond OLG model. We are going to use it to study growth and fiscal policy issues. While we will encounter a version of the model with money and will look at fiscal policies, the discussion of macro policy will be quite limited compare to what you will have a chance to see in other graduate courses like ECON 728 and ECON Endowment Economy: An Overview of the Model We work in discrete time and the time index t can take values from to (the economy never ends). By convention, we normally look at the economy starting in period t = 1. The history of the economy (periods to 0) is taken as given and determines initial conditions.

6 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 2 Individuals live for two periods only. Each period t, a new generation/cohort is born. This generation is called generation t and has N t members. At this point we assume that all members of a generation are identical. 1 We will relax this assumption in section 1.5. A member of generation t lives in period t (young) and t + 1 (old). Therefore, in period t, there are N t young agents and N t 1 old agents (who were born in period t 1). Figure 1.1 below explains the overlapping generations pattern FIGURE 1.1 Time periods old 0 young-0 old-0 1 young-1 old-1 Generations 2 young-2 old-2 3 young-3 old-3. young We assume there is only one good each period. In period t, we talk of the period-t good (or the time-t good). We normalize to price of that good to unity. Therefore, we measure all real variables in the model in units of this unique good (e.g. bushels of corn). For now there is no storage technology allowing agents to carry goods from period t into period t + 1. Since we work with an endowment economy, there is no firms producing goods. Rather, each individual is endowed with a non-negative quantity of goods in both periods of life. 1.1 Agent s Optimization Problem An person born in period t has preferences defined over his consumption in young age (denoted c 1t ) and consumption in old age (denoted c 2t+1 ). Notice that consumption has two subscripts. The first one indicates the age of the person (1=young age and 2=old age) and the second one indicates the period in the economy. The preferences of a person born in period t are represented by the utility function U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ). 1 That is, all members of a generation have the same preferences and same endowments.

7 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 3 Like in the two-period economy setting, we mostly work with the logarithmic utility function U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) = ln c 1t + ln c 2t+1, 0 < < 1 (1) where is a discount factor indicating how the person value consumption in old age versus consumption in young age. A person born in period t (a member of generation t) is provided with an endowment stream {y 1t, y 2t+1 }. Since the agent owns her endowments, she can lend part of it to other agents when she is young and get the proceeds from the loan one period later. Obviously, an old person has no incentives to lend part of his endowment since he will not be alive next period when the loan repayment is made. Similarly, a young person is not interested in lending to an old since he will never have the loan paid back by the old who will not be alive next period. As a result, we won t observe intergenerational trade (i.e. trade among members of different generations). Therefore, we need only allow for intragenerational trade (i.e. trade among members of a given generation). Obviously, if all individuals born in a given period are identical, then there will be no trade in equilibrium just like there was no trade in equilibrium in the two-period endowment economy model when all agents were identical. In such a case, the equilibrium interest rate adjust to insure that a person s savings is exactly zero. The savings of an individual born in period t is and his consumption in old age is s t = y 1t c 1t (2) c 2t+1 = y 2t+1 + (1 + r t+1 )s t (3) where by convention r t+1 denotes the real interest rate linking periods t and t + 1. The sequence budget constraint (2)-(3) implies the present value budget constraint or intertemporal buget constraint for someone born in period t c 1t + c 2t r t+1 = y 1t + y 2t r t+1. (4) Therefore, the optimization problem solved by an individual born in period t is to choose c 1t and c 2t+1 to maximize U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) subject to budget constraint (4). Figure 1.2 provides a graphical representation of the agents optimization problem. In the figure, we measure consumption in old age along the vertical axis while we measure consumption in young age along the horizontal axis. Intertemporal budget constraint (4) makes

8 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 4 clear that this constraint is linear and has a slope equal to (1 + r t+1 ). Accordingly, 1 + r t+1 represents the price of young age consumption in terms of old age consumption. To see this, think about how much old age consumption is given up in order to increase consumption in young age by one unit. The triangle OAB in Figure 1.2 represents the individual budget set for a given endowment stream (y 1t, y 2t+1 ). Consumption bundles that are outside of this budget set are not affordable at the current endowments and interest rate. The curves in Figure 1.2 are indifference curves. An indifference curve represents the combinations of consumption in young age and in old age that yield the same level of utility. Obviously, indifference curves are related to preferences and the utility function. The further from the origin an indifference curve is, the higher the level of utility. Accordingly, the individual prefers the consumption allocation given by point E over allocations given by points D or F because point E lies on a higher indifference curve. Actually, since point E is the point where the indifference curve for utility level u 2 is tangent to the intertemporal budget constraint, u 2 is the highest level of utility that can be achieved at the current interest rate, given endowments (y 1t, y 2t+1 ). While consumption allocations lying on the indifference curve for utility level u 3 are preferred to point E, these allocations are not affordable. Mathematically, when the individual preferences are represented by utility function (1) then the agent s optimization problem can be transformed into the following unconstrained maximization problem: The first-order condition is which implies Equations (4) and (7) imply c 2t+1 = max c 1t ln(c 1t ) + ln[y 2t+1 + (1 + r t+1 )(y 1t c 1t )]. (5) 1 (1 + r t+1 ) c 1t y 2t+1 + (1 + r t+1 )(y 1t c 1t ) = 0 (6) c 1t = 1 [ y 1t + y ] 2t+1 c 1t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ). (7) r t [(1 + r t+1)y 1t + y 2t+1 ] c 2t+1 (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ). (8) Except for the slightly different notation, equations (7) and (8) are identical to the consumption functions derived in the section on two-period economies (see Smith page 20).

9 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 5 Finally, the savings function of an agent born in period t is given by s t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ) = y 1t c 1t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ) = 1 + y y 2t+1 1t (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ). (9) 1.2 Feasible, Efficient and Optimal Consumption Allocation Aggregate quantities are calculated by aggregating over all individuals (young and old) alive in a given period. For example, aggregate consumption of the time-t good is denoted C t and is calculated as C t = N t 1 c 2t + N t c 1t. (10) Similarly, aggregate endowment of the time-t good is denoted Y t and is calculated as Y t = N t 1 y 2t + N t y 1t. (11) A time-t consumption allocation is given by the period-t consumption of a representative young agent (c 1t ) and the period-t consumption of a representative old agent (c 2t ). In short, a time-t consumption allocation is the pair {c 1t, c 2t }. A consumption allocation is the sequence of time-t consumption allocations for all t 1. In short, a consumption allocation is the sequence {c 1t, c 2t } t=1. A feasible consumption allocation is a consumption allocation that can be achieved with the given total resources and the technology. More formally, a consumption allocation is feasible if the sequence of aggregate consumption {C t } t=1 satisfies C t Y t for all t 1. A feasible consumption allocation is efficient if there is no alternative feasible allocation with more total consumption of some good and no less of any other good. An efficient consumption allocation is a consumption allocation where C t = Y t for all t 1. Loosely speaking, a consumption allocation is efficient when there is no waste. Consumption allocation A is Pareto superior to consumption allocation B if (i) no one strictly prefers B to A, and (ii) at least one person strictly prefers A to B. A consumption allocation is Pareto optimal if it is feasible and if there does not exist a feasible consumption allocation that is Pareto superior to it.

10 Models with Overlapping Generations Page Competitive Equilibrium In most cases, competitive equilibria are not Pareto optimal in OLG models. Therefore, we have to solve for the competitive equilibrium explicitly instead of using the second welfare theorem and a central planner problem. We first define a competitive equilibrium. A competitive equilibrium is a consumption allocation and a price system such that (i) the quantities that are relevant for a particular person maximize that person s utility subject to the relevant budget constraint, taking prices as given. (ii) the quantities clear all markets at all dates. Note that in any given period, there are only two markets. A market for the consumption good and a market for private borrowing and lending. Recall that there is no intergenerational trade in the model (see subsection 1.1). Therefore, only the young agents are involved in the borrowing and lending market. Obviously, for the borrowing and lending market to clear in period t the sum of the savings of all young agents alive in period t must be zero. When solving for a competitive equilibrium, the key is to use the competitive equilibrium condition S t (r t+1 ) = 0. (12) where the function S t (r t+1 ) represents total savings of all young people alive in period t. In an abuse of notation, we write the total savings of all young people alive in period t S t (r t+1 ) when this savings function also depends on current and next period endowments. When all individuals who are born in period t are identical and have log utility, then we simply have S t (r t+1 ) = N t s t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ) = 1 + N N t y 2t+1 ty 1t (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ) (13) where the last equality comes from using (9). Equilibrium condition (12) can be used to solve for the equilibrium interest rate. Then the consumption allocation is simply found by substituting the equilibrium interest rate in the consumption functions ((7) and (8) for the log utility case). The competitive equilibrium condition (12) is derived using the two conditions appearing in the definition of a competitive equilibrium. We start with the market clearing condition for good t N t c 1t + N t 1 c 2t = N t y 1t + N t 1 y 2t. (14)

11 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 7 Then summing the budget constraint of the old agents alive in period t we have (see equation(3)) N t 1 c 2t = N t 1 y 2t + (1 + r t )N t 1 s t 1 (15) Clearing of the period t 1 borrowing and lending market implies that N t 1 s t 1 = 0 which in turn implies N t 1 c 2t = N t 1 y 2t. (16) Subtracting (16) from (14) implies N t c 1t = N t y 1t N t (y 1t c 1t ) = 0. (17) Note that utility maximization implies the consumption function c 1t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ) for a young agent alive in period t. To ease notation, we drop the endowments from the list of arguments of the consumption and savings functions. Substituting the consumption function in (17) implies N t (y 1t c 1t (r t+1 )) = 0 N t s t (r t+1 ) = 0 S t (r t+1 ) = 0 (18) where s t (r t+1 ) denotes the saving function of a young agent alive in period t and S t (r t+1 ) the aggregate saving function of the young agents alive in period t. The derivation of the competitive equilibrium condition S t (r t+1 ) = 0 highlights the fact that this condition takes into account of market clearing on the goods market and on the financial market as well as utility maximization. We complete this section by solving for the competitive equilibrium consumption allocation and interest rate for the case where all members of a generation are identical and have log utility. The first step is to perform utility maximization and derive the consumption and savings functions. This yields equations (7), (8) and (9). Then we impose the equilibrium condition (12) which implies the equilibrium interest rate 1 + N N t y 2t+1 ty 1t (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ) = 0 r t+1 = y 2t+1 1. (19) y 1t To find consumption of a person born in period t in equilibrium, plug the equilibrium interest rate (19) into consumption functions (7) and (8) to get c 1t = y 1t and c 2t+1 = y 2t+1. As expected, because all members of a generation are identical, we end up with an autarkic competitive equilibrium. Example below works out a numerical example.

12 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 8 Example Suppose that in each period, 100 identical individuals are born (e.g. N t = 100 for t = 0, 1, 2,...). The utility of an individual born in period t is given by U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) = ln c 1t ln c 2t+1. (20) Finally, an individual born in period t has the following endowment stream {y 1t, y 2t+1 } = {1, 1.25}. Performing the utility maximization for an agent born in period t yields the consumption functions (7) and (8). Using the numerical values in the current example we have c 1t = 1 [ ] = c 1t (r t+1 ). (21) r t r t+1 The individual savings function is then and the aggregate savings function is s t (r t+1 ) = y 1t c 1t (r t+1 ) = r t+1 (22) S t (r t+1 ) = 100 s t (r t+1 ) = r t+1. (23) Imposing the equilibrium condition S t (r t+1 ) = 0 yields the equilibrium real interest rate Using this result in the consumption functions yields r t+1 = = (24) c 1t = 1, c 2t+1 = (25) Since all periods are identical in this example, the competitive equilibrium is the sequence of interest rate {r t+1 } t=1 = {0.3157} t=1 and the consumption allocation {c 1t, c 2t } t=1 = {1, 1.25}. This equilibrium consumption allocation is not surprising. In an economy where nobody trades, agents always consume their endowments. 1.4 Extension I: Population Growth Allowing for population growth is straightforward. Instead of having a constant cohort size over time (i.e. N t constant for all t) we have N t = (1 + η)n t 1. (26)

13 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 9 The net population growth rate is given by η. To calculate the gross growth rate, divide the population in period t by the population in period t 1 N t + N t 1 N t 1 + N t 2 = (1 + η)2 N t 2 + (1 + η)n t 2 (1 + η)n t 2 + N t 2 = (1 + η)[(1 + η) + 1] [(1 + η) + 1] = 1 + η. (27) Population growth at rate η implies that aggregate endowment (Y t ) and aggregate consumption (C t ) also grow at rate η. For example, the gross growth rate of Y is Y t Y t 1 = N t 1 y 2t + N t y 1t N t 2 y 2t + N t 1 y 1t = (1 + η) = 1 + η (28) N t 2 y 2t 1 + N t 1 y 1t 1 N t 2 y 2t 1 + N t 1 y 1t 1 where the last equality comes from the fact that all members of all generations receive the same endowment stream which implies y 1t = y 1t 1 and y 2t = y 2t 1. Little else is changed. We still impose the equilibrium condition (12) to solve for the equilibrium interest rate. The sequence of equilibrium interest rate and the consumption allocation is unchanged by the addition of population growth. Exercise: Use the environment described in example with the addition of population growth. Assume N 0 = 1000 and that η = 0.1. Show that in the competitive equilibrium of this economy with population growth, the sequence of interest rate is {r t+1 } t=1 = {0.3157} t=1 and the consumption allocation is {c 1t, c 2t } t=1 = {1, 1.25} (as in example 4.1). 1.5 Extension II: Heterogeneity within a Cohort (2-Countries) As seen in previous sections, when all members of a cohort are identical, there is no trade in equilibrium. However, allowing for heterogeneity within a cohort can create incentives for trade. In this section we see how the model can be extended to deal with heterogeneity within cohorts. We assume there are two types of agents born in each period. To facilitate the exposition (and to make an obvious parallel to what we did in the section on two-period economies earlier in the course), think of two countries in free trade (same interest rate in both countries). In the home country, N t agents are born in period t. These agents have preferences given by the utility function U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) and receive the endowment stream {y 1t, y 2t+1 }. In the foreign country Nt agents are born in period t. These agents have preferences given by the utility function u (c 1t, c 2t+1) and receive the endowment stream {y1t, y2t+1}. Note that the two countries can differ in three respects. First, there can be a different number of agents

14 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 10 born at home and abroad (i.e. N t does not necessarily equal Nt ). Second, the preferences can be different across countries (for example, there could be differences in the discount factor at home and abroad). Third, the endowment streams can differ across countries. 2 Let us consider the case where all residents of a country are identical and that cross-country differences come from differences in the discount factor ( in the home country and in the foreign country) and in the endowment stream. We assume everyone has log utility. The total savings of all young people alive in period t in the home country is given by S t (r t+1 ) = N t s t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1 ) = 1 + N N t y 2t+1 ty 1t (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ) (29) while in the foreign country we have S t (r t+1 ) = N t s t (r t+1, y 1t, y 2t+1) = 1 + N t y1t Nt y2t+1 (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ). (30) In equilibrium, the total savings of all young people in both countries should be equal to zero (when one country is a net lender, the other country must be a net borrower) so the equilibrium condition used to solve for the equilibrium interest rate is now S t (r t+1 ) + S t (r t+1 ) = 0 or [ 1 + N ty 1t which implies ] [ N t y 2t+1 + (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ) 1 + N t y1t 1 + r t+1 = N t y 2t+1 + N t y 2t+1 (1+) (1+ ) 1+ N ty 1t + 1+ N t y 1t Nt y2t+1 ] (1 + )(1 + r t+1 ) = 0 (31) The world interest rate can then be plugged in consumption functions (like (7) and (8)) for the home country residents and foreign country residents to find out the consumption allocation. The following example shows a case where endowment streams and country size differ. Example Consider two countries where individuals differ in their endowment streams. The characteristics of the two countries are summarized in the following table 2 Note that we talk of heterogeneity within a cohort when the agents in the two countries have different endowment streams or have different utility functions (or both). (32) If the only difference between the two groups is that N t N t, then the model reduces to the model discussed in previous sections.

15 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 11 Home country Foreign country N t = 60, t 0 N t = 40, t 0 {y 1t, y 2t+1 } = {1, 1.25}, t 0 {y 1t, y 2t+1} = {1, 1}, t 0 U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) = ln c 1t ln c 2t+1, t 0 U(c 1t, c 2t+1) = ln c 1t ln c 2t+1, t 0 From (7)-(9) we can easily calculate the consumption and savings functions for an agent born in period t in the home country c 1t = r t+1, c 2t+1 = (1 + r t+1 ) , s t (r t+1 ) = r t+1 (33) and for an agent born in period t in the foreign country c 1t = r t+1, c 2t+1 = (1 + r t+1 ) , s t (r t+1 ) = r t+1. The aggregate savings function in each countries are (34) S t (r t+1 ) = r t+1, S t (r t+1 ) = r t+1. (35) We solve for the equilibrium interest rate by imposing the condition that savings of all young agents equal zero S t (r t+1 ) + S t (r t+1 ) = r t+1 = 0 r t+1 = (36) Using the value of the equilibrium interest rate in equations (33)-(34) we find the solutions c 1t = 1.04, c 2t+1 = 1.20, s t (r t+1 ) = 0.04 (37) c 1t = 0.94, c 2t+1 = 1.08, s t (r t+1 ) = (38) Note that contrary to example 1.3.3, there is intragenerational trade in equilibrium. The heterogeneity of agents across countries creates opportunity for trade. We can easily verify whether free trade is superior to autarky by comparing the welfare of home and foreign agents in free trade and in autarky. In free trade, the utility of a domestic agent is ln ln 1.20 = and the utility of a foreign agent is ln ln 1.08 = In autarky, all agents simply consume their endowments so the utility of a domestic agent is ln ln 1.25 = and the utility of a foreign agent is ln ln 1 = 0. Clearly, free trade is Pareto superior to autarky.

16 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 12 2 Production Economy: an Overview of the Model Endowment and production economies share several characteristics, so here we outline only the difference between the two structures. First, individuals are endowed with time rather than units of goods. Second, there is still only one good but it is storable. So it can be used for consumption and investment. Third, the model includes firms who employ workers and capital to produce. The model we work with in section 2 is closely related to the Diamond model. 2.1 Households The Savings Decision As usual, the preferences of an agent born in period t are represented by the utility function U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ). We continue working with the logarithmic utility function U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) = ln c 1t + ln c 2t+1, 0 < < 1 (1) Each person has the following time endowment: 1 unit in young age and 0 unit in old age. As you can see from the utility function above, we simplify the analysis by leaving leisure out of the utility function. Accordingly, a young person always supply his/her entire unit of time inelastically to the labour market. We assume that people do not work in old age. Therefore, the young people in the economy are the workers while the old people are the retirees. Deciding how much to consume in young age and in old age involves a savings decision. Recall that individuals do not work in their second period of life. Therefore, they must save in their first period of life to finance consumption in old age. The real labour income earned in young age is simply equal to real wage rate (w) since a young person works exactly one unit of time. The savings made in young age will be carried over to old age and invested in physical capital at the very beginning of old age. Since investment in physical capital provides a riskless positive rate of return (r), and there are no other investment instruments, all of an individual s savings end up being invested in physical capital. We assume that capital does not depreciate. Therefore, at the end of the old age period, the individual gets

17 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 13 back his/her entire investment in physical capital plus the return on that investment. As a result, an individual born in period t faces the following sequence of budget constraints when making consumption and savings decisions: s t + c 1t = w t (39) c 2t+1 = s t (1 + r t+1 ) (40) The timing on the real interest rate r in the latter equation reflects the fact that savings from period t are invested in physical capital only at the very beginning of period t + 1. Note that individuals are price takers. Accordingly, they take w and r as given when making consumption and savings decisions. The utility maximization problem solved by someone born in period t can be represented graphically. With this graphical analysis in mind, we derive the intertemporal budget constraint faced by an individual born in period t. We derive the intertemporal budget constraint by combining budget constraints (39) and (40) is such a way that we eliminate s t c 2t+1 = w t (1 + r t+1 ) (1 + r t+1 )c 1t. (41) The intertemporal budget constraint is also referred to as the present-value budget constraint because it can also be written as c 1t + c 2t r t+1 = w t (42) where the left-hand side represents the present-value of consumption whereas the right-hand side represents the present value of labour income. In Figure 2.1, we measure consumption in old age along the vertical axis while we measure consumption in young age along the horizontal axis. Intertemporal budget constraint (41) makes clear that this constraint is linear and has a slope equal to (1 + r t+1 ). Accordingly, 1 + r t+1 represents the price of young age consumption in terms of old age consumption. To see this, think about how much old age consumption is given up in order to increase consumption in young age by one unit. The triangle OAB in Figure 2.1 represents the individual budget set for a given wage rate and real interest rate. Consumption bundles that are outside of this budget set are not affordable at the current wage rate and interest rate. The curves in Figure 2.1 are indifference curves. An indifference curve represents the combinations of consumption in young age and in old age

18 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 14 that yield the same level of utility. Obviously, indifference curves are related to preferences and the utility function. The further from the origin an indifference curve is, the higher the level of utility. Accordingly, the individual prefers the consumption allocation given by point E over allocations given by points D or F because point E lies on a higher indifference curve. Actually, since point E is the point where the indifference curve for utility level u 2 is tangent to the intertemporal budget constraint, u 2 is the highest level of utility that can be achieved at the given wage rate and interest rate. While consumption allocations lying on the indifference curve for utility level u 3 are preferred to point E, these allocations are not affordable. Formally, the problem solved by a person born in period t is to choose c 1t, c 2t+1 and s t to maximize (1) subject to (39) and (40) [or (41), or (42)] taking w t and r t+1 as given. While there are a few different ways to solve this maximization problem in order to get savings and consumption functions, perhaps the easier way to proceed is to use equations (39) and (40) to substitute out c 1t and c 2t+1 from the objective function (1). Proceeding that way leaves us with the optimization problem max s t U(s t ) = ln(w t s t ) + ln(s t (1 + r t+1 )). (43) The first-order condition corresponding to problem (43) is found by setting equal to zero the partial derivative of the function U(s t ) with respect to s t (the only remaining choice variable). This first-order condition is which yields U(s t ) s t = 1 w t s t ( 1) + s t = s t (1 + r t+1 ) (1 + r t+1) = 0 (44) 1 + w t s t (w t ). (45) where s t (w t ) denotes the savings function of a young person alive in period t. The consumption function in young age and in old age (still for someone born in period t) is found by substituting the above savings function in budget constraints (39) and (40) c 2t+1 = c 1t = w t c 1t (w t ) (46) 1 + w t(1 + r t+1 ) c 2t+1 (w t, r t+1 ). (47) Notice that the consumption function in young age does not depend on the interest rate at all. You can think of the consumption function in young age as generally having the

19 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 15 following format: consumption is equal to a fraction of the present value of lifetime income (see for example equation (7)). Here, the present value of lifetime resources is simply w t (which does not depend on r) since there is no labour income earned in old age. For this reason, changes in the interest rate have no wealth effects on consumption. 3 The fraction of lifetime resources here is constant because the utility function we are employing is such that the income and substitution effects of interest rate changes perfectly cancel out. However, This is not the case for all utility functions. Exercise: Derive the savings function of an individual who has a lifetime utility function of the type U(c 1t, c 2t+1 ) = c1 1/σ 1t 1 1/σ + c1 1/σ 2t+1 1 1/σ, σ > 0 where σ is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution Supply of Inputs Let L t denote the labour input used by firms in period t. What is the labour supply in period t? Well, we know that (1) only young people work, (2) each young person is endowed with one unit of time, (3) individuals supply their entire time endowment to the job market. Since there are N t young people in period t, and that they all work one unit of time, labour supply in period t is simply N t. Accordingly, the labour supply curve is vertical and we have L t = N t since there are no frictions in the model preventing the labour market from clearing. As we will see in the next section, production depends on another input, physical capital. Let K t denote the capital stock installed in the economy and available for production at the beginning of period t. As mentioned above, the savings of a young person in period t are carried over to old age to be invested in physical capital. Therefore, new capital in the amount N t s t (w t ) is formed at the beginning of period t + 1. Since the old people alive in period t completely reverse their investment in capital at the end of period t to finance their consumption 4 in that period, we have K t+1 = N t s t (w t ). Therefore, the capital stock in period t comes entirely from the savings of all young people in period t. 3 This will no longer be true once we allow for taxes to be paid in old age. 4 Since old age is the last period of life, an old person consumes everything he/she owns. For an old person, there is no point giving up consumption (and therefore reducing utility) to save since the savings cannot be used to finance consumption in the period following old age.

20 Models with Overlapping Generations Page Firms We assume there is a large number of identical firms (that is, all firm use the same technology) acting as perfect competitors. We assume that the production technology is represented by a production function F (K, L) which has constant returns to scale (CRS), is increasing in both inputs, is concave and satisfies the Inada conditions lim F 1(K, L) =, K 0 lim F 1(K, L) = 0, K lim F 2 (K, L) =, L 0 lim F 2 (K, L) = 0 (48) L where F i (K, L) denotes the partial derivative of the production function with respect to its i th argument. In cases where we have identical firms and a CRS production function, the number of firms is indeterminate. For convenience, we analyze the model as if there were a single firm. Aggregate output in period t is denoted Y t function and is given by a Cobb-Douglas production Y t = A t K α t L 1 α t, 0 < α < 1 (49) where A t represents the level of technology in the economy in period t. We measure profits in units of the consumption/investment good in the economy. Therefore, total revenue in period t equals Y t. Since the firm must pay workers a wage rate w and must pay a rental rate (or rate of return) on the capital invested by households, its period t profits are given by Π t = Y t w t L t r t K t. (50) The firms optimization problem is to maximize profits given the technological constraint represented by equation (49). Because all markets are competitive, firms take factor prices (w and r) as given. Therefore, the firm s problem can be written max Π t = A t Kt α L 1 α t w t L t r t K t. (51) K t, L t The first-order conditions corresponding to the above problem are Π t = αa t Kt α 1 K t L 1 α t r t = 0 (52) Π t L t = (1 α)a t K α t L α t w t = 0. (53) Condition (52) shows that the rental rate/real interest rate is equal to the marginal product of capital while equation condition (53) shows that the wage rate is equal to the marginal

21 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 17 product of labour. Plugging the factor prices implied by conditions (52) and (53) in the profit function shows that profits are zero in equilibrium. At various stage of our analysis of the life-cycle model, it will prove convenient to write conditions (52) and (53) in a few different ways. Here are different versions of (52) and (53) r t = α Y t K t, r t = αa t k α 1 t (54) w t = (1 α) Y t L t, w t = (1 α)a t k α t (55) where k t denotes the capital-labour ratio, that is k t = K t /L t. Equations (54) and (55) make clear that factor prices depend on the size of the capital stock relative to the labour supply. The larger the capital stock is relative to the labour supply (i.e. the larger k), the smaller is the return on capital and the larger is the wage rate. Looking at the signs of the first and second derivatives of the marginal product of capital and labour, we find that w is a concave function of k whereas r is a convex function of k. Let s summarize the interactions between households and firms before studying the equilibrium of the model. Young people supply the labour input needed by firms. The savings of the young people alive in a given period will be invested to form the capital stock in the following period. Firms hire workers (young people) and rent capital to produce output. With their output, they pay wages to workers and a return to investors. Young people take their wage income and allocate a share 1 to immediate consumption and a share to savings Old people get back their initial investment in capital plus the return on that investment and consume all of that. 2.3 Competitive Equilibrium and Transition Equation In the current environment, a competitive equilibrium is a price system (w, r) and an allocation (c 1, c 2, K) such that (1) individuals maximize utility subject to their budget constraints (taking prices as given), (2) firms maximize profits given prices and technology, and (3) all markets clear. As we know by now, the capital stock K t+1 is equal to the savings of all young people in

22 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 18 period t. Therefore, we have the equilibrium condition on the capital market K t+1 = N t s t (w t ) K t+1 = 1 + N tw t. (56) Using equation (53) to substitute out the wage rate we get K t+1 = 1 + N tw t = 1 + (1 α)a tkt α L 1 α t (57) where the last equality uses the fact that N t = L t. Now, dividing both sides by L t+1 yields the transition equation (1 α) k t+1 = A t kt α. (58) (1 + )L t+1 /L t Unless otherwise indicated, we assume that there is no growth in technology nor in population (that is, L t+1 /L t = 1 and A t = A for all t). In such a case, the transition equation becomes k t+1 = (1 α) 1 + Akα t. (59) 2.4 Growth, Transition Period and Steady State As we will see shortly, the model without growth in technology and in population eventually reaches a steady state where all variables are constant over time. By convention we denote the steady-state value of a variable using. capital-labour ratio is denoted k. For example, the steady-state value of the The key variable to focus on to determine whether the economy has reached its steady state is the capital-labour ratio. If in period t it is the case that k t k, then the economy is not in steady state. When the economy is not in steady state, then it is going through a transition period. The adjustments taking place during a transition period are referred to as transitional dynamics. Obviously, we need to solve for k if we want to be able to check whether the economy is in steady state or not. This is simple to do. Using the fact that k t1 = k t = k in steady state, replace both k t and k t+1 by k in transition equation (59) k = [ ] (1 α)ak α k 1 α = (1 α)a. (60) 1 + To find out the convergence properties of the model we use a transition path diagram (see Figure 2.2). The transition path diagram measures k t+1 on the vertical axis and k t on the

23 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 19 horizontal axis. It includes a 45 o line and a transition line corresponding to the transition equation (59). Since k t1 = k t = k in steady state, the value of k on the graph is found at the intersection of the 45 degree line and of the transition line. The first and second derivatives of the right hand side of the transition equation with respect to k t indicate that the transition line is increasing and concave. Since the first partial derivative goes to zero as k (and vice versa), we know that the slope of the transition line is very steep for small values of k t and almost flat for very large values of k t. Therefore, we know that the transition line cuts the 45 o line only once for positive values of k t and that it cut it from above. Therefore, the steady state is unique and stable. That is, for any positive k 0, the time path of k will always converge to k. Figure 2.2 shows an example where the capital stock is initially small such that k 0 < k. An immediate implication of the fact that the economy with constant population and constant technology eventually converges to a steady state is that there cannot be growth in the long-run in this model. If the economy has too much capital for its number of workers, the economy shrinks in the transition period to attain its steady state. If the economy has too little capital for its number of workers, the economy grows in the transition period to attain its steady state (so there could be economic growth in the short-run). 2.5 Computing Time Paths The previous section focussed exclusively on the capital labour ratio. In this section, we show how to calculate the time path of all variables appearing in the model. The first step is to calculate the time path of the capital-labour ratio. This is accomplished by iterating on the transition equation starting from some given initial condition k 0 k 1 = 1 + (1 α)akα 0 k 2 = 1 + (1 α)akα 1 k 3 = 1 + (1 α)akα 2 and so forth. With the time path of k on hands, we can easily calculate the time path of the wage rate and interest rate using (54) and (55). r 0 = αak α 1 0, w 0 = (1 α)ak α 0

24 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 20 and so forth. r 1 = αak α 1 1, w 1 = (1 α)ak α 1 r 2 = αak α 1 2, w 2 = (1 α)ak α 2 r 3 = αak α 1 3, w 3 = (1 α)ak α 3 Since L t = N we have that K t = Nk t and Y t = ANk α t. Therefore K 0 = Nk 0, Y 1 = ANk α 0 K 1 = Nk 1, Y 1 = ANk α 1 K 2 = Nk 2, Y 2 = ANk α 2 and so forth. K 3 = Nk 3, Y 3 = ANk α 3 Using the factor prices calculated above, we calculate individual savings and consumption using (45), (46) and (47) s 1 = 1 + w 1, c 11 = w 1, c 21 = 1 + w 0(1 + r 1 ) and so forth. s 2 = s 3 = 1 + w 2, c 12 = w 2, c 22 = 1 + w 1(1 + r 2 ) 1 + w 3, c 13 = w 3, c 23 = 1 + w 2(1 + r 3 ) Aggregate consumption is calculated by summing the consumption of all young and old people. Since there are N young people and N old people alive in any given period, aggregate consumption in period t is given by C t = Nc 1t + Nc 2t (61) Obviously, using the time paths of consumption in young age and in old age calculated above we find C 1 = Nc 11 + Nc 21 C 2 = Nc 12 + Nc 22 C 3 = Nc 13 + Nc 23

25 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 21 and so forth. Finally, the definitions of national savings (S) and national investment (I) are S t = Y t C t, I t = K t+1 K t (62) where the formula for national investment is consistent with our assumption of zero capital depreciation. Using the latter definitions, we calculate S 1 = Y 1 C 1, I 1 = K 2 K 1 and so forth. S 2 = Y 2 C 2, I 2 = K 3 K 2 S 3 = Y 3 C 3, I 3 = K 4 K 3 The steady-state values of all variables can be computed following the steps above but starting with the steady-state value of the capital-labour ratio (see (60)) rather that some arbitrary initial condition k 0. The MS-Excel file timepaths.xls shows the time paths calculated for the case k 0 = 1, N = 100, = 0.9, α = 0.3 and A = 20. In that numerical example, it is clear that the capital-labour ratio is smaller than its steady state value. In other words, the capital stock is very small. Therefore, it is not surprising to see that savings by young people in period 0 is larger than the dissaving of the old people. Equation (55) shows that w depends positively on k, so an increase in k between period 0 and 1 increases the wage rate (w 1 > w 0 ). Since the wage rate determines savings of the young people, the fact that young people in period 1 have a larger labour income means that they will invest more in capital than the previous generation which means an even larger capital stock in period 2. This story repeats itself up to a point where the economy reaches its steady state. We know that such a state will arise because as capital accumulation proceeds, diminishing marginal returns to capital imply smaller and smaller increases in the wage rate over time. At some point, the wage rate stops growing completely. At that point, each generation saves as much as the previous one and the capital stock (and capital-labour ratio) does not change anymore. Since all other variables depend on k, when k becomes constant, that is also the case for all the other variables. Remember that the real interest rate depend inversely on the ratio K/L. Since L is constant and there is capital accumulation in the transition, then the real interest rate falls to its steady- state value over time. Also, capital accumulation means that there is output growth in the transition period. The growth in the wage rate in the transition implies that

26 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 22 young age consumption grows. The effect on old age consumption depends on the wage rate and the interest rate (see (47)). As seen in the Excel file, the wage effect dominates and old age consumption is also growing in the transition. As a result, aggregate consumption is growing as well. As explained above, growth in the wage rate over time means national investment is positive since in any given period in the transition, the group of young people saves more than the old dissaves. However, because of diminishing marginal returns to capital, increases in the wage rate become smaller and smaller so national investment (I) actually falls in the transition. With zero capital depreciation, national investment is zero in steady state. The last column of the timepaths.xls shows the utility levels attained by the various generations. We see that in the transition period, any new generation is better off than the generation preceding it, which is not surprising given that both young age consumption and old age consumption grow in the transition. To understand the effect of growth on the utility maximization problem, refer to Figure 2.1. In the transition, the wage rate is increasing which pushes the intertemporal budget constraint up and to the right over time. The budget constraint does not shift up in a parallel fashion because the interest rate is falling. Therefore, the upward shift tends to be smaller than the rightward shift. 2.6 Comparative Dynamics The thought experiment in this sections are conducted as follows: (i) take the economy where there is no growth in population nor in technology and suppose that it is in steady state. (ii) describe a change in a parameter or a shock hitting the economy and study its implications for the capital-labour ratio. We start by looking at an increase in. Figure 2.3 provides a graphical representation of our first thought experiment. The economy is initially at point A, on the lower of the two transition lines represented on the graph. Then suppose that new generations of agents become more patient so that increases ( > say). How does that change affect the transition equation? To find that out, let s define h(k t ) = (1 α)akt α /(1 + ) and write transition equation (59) as k t+1 = h(k t ). You can show that for positive values of k, h(k t )/ k t > 0 which implies a counterclockwise rotation in the transition line in Figure 2.3. The capitallabour ratio k is no longer the steady-state capital labour ratio after the change in. So

27 Models with Overlapping Generations Page 23 the economy embarks on a transition path which creates some positive economic growth. As k, grows the economy converges to its new steady-state equilibrium denoted by point B. Once the economy has reached point B, economic growth stops and the economy is again in a steady state. However, this new steady state is characterized by a larger capital-labour ratio, k > k. What is the economics of this experiment? More patient individuals save more than impatient individuals. So, when rises, savings increase which pushes up k which pushes up w, which in turn pushes savings even higher. As k rises, diminishing marginal returns kick in and the increases in w become smaller and smaller, up to a point where k and w do not change over time anymore (a new steady-state is reached). In our second thought experiment, we look at the effect of a permanent increase in the level of technology (i.e. A > A). Clearly, an increase in A implies a counterclockwise rotation in the transition line in Figure 2.4. The capital-labour ratio k is no longer the steady-state capital labour ratio after the change in. So the economy embarks on a transition path which creates some positive economic growth. As k, grows the economy converges to its new steady-state equilibrium denoted by point B. Once the economy has reached point B, economic growth stops and the economy is again in a steady state. However, this new steady state is characterized by a larger capital-labour ratio, k > k. What is the economics of this experiment? The increase in A pushes the wage rate up (workers are more productive so their wage rate goes up), triggering an increase in savings which implies an increase in k, which pushes up w, which in turn pushes savings even higher. So the effect of an increase in A are similar to the effects of a change in. The third experiment is about a shock that hits the economy. Suppose the economy is in steady in period 0 and that a catastrophic event (the typical example is a war) destroys part of the capital stock at the beginning of period 1. The destruction of part of the capital stock does not imply a rotation of the transition line in Figure 2.5 since none of the parameters are affected. Rather, the economy jumps from point A to point B as a result of the destruction of the capital stock. As is evident from Figure 2.5, k 1 is not equal to the steady state capitallabour ratio. Therefore, the economy cannot stay at point B. There will occur a period of capital accumulation that will take place until the economy returns to point A. How does it work? For concreteness, suppose that K 0 = K which implies k 0 = k and that K 1 = K /2 which implies k 1 = k /2. Then, k 1 /k 0 = 0.5 and w 1 /w 2 = (k 1 /k 0 ) α > 0.5 because 0 < α < 1. Therefore, because of diminishing marginal returns, the drop in k is greater than the drop in w which implies that the drop in savings is less than the drop in k. This means that after the shock, the savings are large enough to push up the capital-labour ratio, which pushes

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130 Notes on Macroeconomic Theory Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130 September 2006 Chapter 2 Growth With Overlapping Generations This chapter will serve

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium 2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium Partial equilibrium tax incidence misses out on a lot of important aspects of economic activity. Among those aspects : markets are interrelated, so that prices of

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid September 2015 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model September 2015 1 / 43 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ). ECON 8040 Final exam Lastrapes Fall 2007 Answer all eight questions on this exam. 1. Write out a static model of the macroeconomy that is capable of predicting that money is non-neutral. Your model should

More information

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Econ 305 Prof. Kasa Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring 2012 PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) 1. (10 points). Using your knowledge of National Income Accounting,

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1 Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1 1.1 (from Romer Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 1) Basic properties of growth rates which will be used over and over again. Use the

More information

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (20 Marks)

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (20 Marks) Answers for ECON222 exercise 2 Winter 2010 Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (20 Marks) Part a): (6 Marks) Start by taking the derivative of the production wrt labour, which is then set equal

More information

International Macroeconomics

International Macroeconomics Slides for Chapter 3: Theory of Current Account Determination International Macroeconomics Schmitt-Grohé Uribe Woodford Columbia University May 1, 2016 1 Motivation Build a model of an open economy to

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 33 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model Suppose that there are H households who live two periods They are endowed with E 1 units of labor in period 1 and E 2 units of labor in period 2, which they

More information

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics Chapter 5 A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Instructor: Xiaohui Huang Department of Economics University of Virginia c Copyright 2014 Xiaohui Huang.

More information

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model ECON 4335 Economics of Banking, Fall 2016 Jacopo Bizzotto 1 Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model The model in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) incorporates important features of the real world:

More information

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework We just studied the consumption-leisure model as a one-shot model in which individuals had no regard for the future: they simply worked to earn income, all

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics 202: Dynamic Macroeconomics Solow Model Mausumi Das Delhi School of Economics January 14-15, 2015 Das (Delhi School of Economics) Dynamic Macro January 14-15, 2015 1 / 28 Economic Growth In this course

More information

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

More information

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712 Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712 Prof. Peck Fall 2015 1. (5 points) The following economy has two consumers, two firms, and two goods. Good 2 is leisure/labor.

More information

004: Macroeconomic Theory

004: Macroeconomic Theory 004: Macroeconomic Theory Lecture 14 Mausumi Das Lecture Notes, DSE October 21, 2014 Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Macro October 21, 2014 1 / 20 Theories of Economic Growth We now move on to a different dynamics

More information

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals. Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals. We will deal with a particular set of assumptions, but we can modify

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations? Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 7, 0. Consider an individual faced with two job choices: she can either accept a position with a fixed annual salary of x > 0 which requires L x units of labor

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable outlines

More information

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame Consumption ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2018 1 / 27 Readings GLS Ch. 8 2 / 27 Microeconomics of Macro We now move from the long run (decades

More information

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25 Department of Applied Economics Johns Hopkins University Economics 60 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Midterm Exam Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 00 NAME: The Exam has a total of four

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET Chapter 2 Theory y of Consumer Behaviour In this chapter, we will study the behaviour of an individual consumer in a market for final goods. The consumer has to decide on how much of each of the different

More information

Inflation. David Andolfatto

Inflation. David Andolfatto Inflation David Andolfatto Introduction We continue to assume an economy with a single asset Assume that the government can manage the supply of over time; i.e., = 1,where 0 is the gross rate of money

More information

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn: Chapter 5 The Solow Growth Model By Charles I. Jones Additions / differences with the model: Capital stock is no longer exogenous. Capital stock is now endogenized. The accumulation of capital is a possible

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn: Chapter 5 The Solow Growth Model By Charles I. Jones Additions / differences with the model: Capital stock is no longer exogenous. Capital stock is now endogenized. The accumulation of capital is a possible

More information

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies Introduction In macroeconomics, we study the behavior of economy-wide aggregates e.g. GDP, savings, investment, employment and so on - and

More information

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Introduction to economic growth (2) Introduction to economic growth (2) EKN 325 Manoel Bittencourt University of Pretoria M Bittencourt (University of Pretoria) EKN 325 1 / 49 Introduction Solow (1956), "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization Kai Hao Yang 09/26/2017 1 Production Function Just as consumer theory uses utility function a function that assign

More information

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

1 Multiple Choice (30 points) 1 Multiple Choice (30 points) Answer the following questions. You DO NOT need to justify your answer. 1. (6 Points) Consider an economy with two goods and two periods. Data are Good 1 p 1 t = 1 p 1 t+1

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Alberto Bisin October 29, 2009 Question Consider a two period economy. Agents are all identical, that is, there is

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Consumption and Saving

Consumption and Saving Chapter 4 Consumption and Saving 4.1 Introduction Thus far, we have focussed primarily on what one might term intratemporal decisions and how such decisions determine the level of GDP and employment at

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises C H A P T E R 0 Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises 0A Answers for Section A: Graphical Preliminaries Exercise 0A.1 Consider the set [0,1) which includes the point 0, all the

More information

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Consumption and Savings (Continued) Consumption and Savings (Continued) Lecture 9 Topics in Macroeconomics November 5, 2007 Lecture 9 1/16 Topics in Macroeconomics The Solow Model and Savings Behaviour Today: Consumption and Savings Solow

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

We will make several assumptions about these preferences: Lecture 5 Consumer Behavior PREFERENCES The Digital Economist In taking a closer at market behavior, we need to examine the underlying motivations and constraints affecting the consumer (or households).

More information

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section (jwjung@ucdavis.edu) Department of Economics, UC Davis November 4, 2014 Slides revised: November 4, 2014 Outline 1 2 Fall 2012 Winter 2012 Midterm:

More information

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) BANKING AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) Professor Todd Keister Rutgers University May 2017 Objective Want to develop a model to help us understand: why banks and other

More information

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function: Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function: β t log(c t ), where C t is consumption and the parameter β satisfies

More information

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section (jwjung@ucdavis.edu) Department of Economics, UC Davis October 27, 2014 Slides revised: October 27, 2014 Outline 1 Announcement 2 Review: Chapter 5

More information

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Chapter 5 Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Economics Division University of Southampton February 21, 2008 Chapter 5 1/40 Topics in Macroeconomics Closing the Model

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Econ 204A - Henning Bohn * Most of modern macroeconomics involves models of agents that optimize over time. he basic ideas and tools are the same as in microeconomics,

More information

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1. FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal Consumption-Saving and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer 21 ECON 422:Fisher 1 Reading PCBR, Chapter 1 (general overview of financial decision making)

More information

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS Determination of Income and Employment Chapter 4 We have so far talked about the national income, price level, rate of interest etc. in an ad hoc manner without investigating the forces that govern their

More information

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M Macroeconomics MEDEG, UC3M Lecture 5: Consumption Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Spring, 2016 Introduction A key component in NIPA accounts and the households budget constraint is the consumption It represents

More information

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model The representative household model is a dynamic general equilibrium model, based on the assumption that the

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25 Department of Economics Boston College Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory Midterm Exam Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 203 NAME: The Exam has a total of four (4) problems and

More information

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model 1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model We look at a standard neoclassical growth model. The representative consumer maximizes U = β t u(c t ) (1) t=0 where c t is consumption in period

More information

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle Consumption with a Perfect Capital Market Consider a simple two-period world in which a single consumer must decide between consumption c 0 today

More information

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies Michael Peters December 27, 2013 1 Profit Maximization Firms transform goods from one thing into another. If there are two goods, x and y, then a firm can

More information

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame Consumption ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2016 1 / 36 Microeconomics of Macro We now move from the long run (decades and longer) to the medium run

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley Theoretical Tools of Public Finance 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley 1 THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL TOOLS Theoretical tools: The set of tools designed to understand the mechanics

More information

A Theory of Current Account Determination

A Theory of Current Account Determination Chapter 2 A Theory of Current Account Determination In this chapter, we build a model of an open economy, that is, of an economy that trades in goods and financial assets with the rest of the world. We

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright 2002 Pearson Education, Inc. and Dr Yunus Aksoy Slide 1 Discussion So far: How to measure variables of macroeconomic

More information

Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I. In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations!

Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I. In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations! Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations! Question 1. Consider an Overlapping Generation (OLG) model. Let N t and N t 1

More information

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011 ECON 6022B Problem Set Suggested Solutions Fall 20 September 5, 20 Shocking the Solow Model Consider the basic Solow model in Lecture 2. Suppose the economy stays at its steady state in Period 0 and there

More information

Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009

Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009 Department of Economics University of Maryland Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009 Instructions: Written (typed is strongly

More information

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I April 2005 PREPARING FOR THE EXAM What models do you need to study? All the models we studied

More information

3Choice Sets in Labor and Financial

3Choice Sets in Labor and Financial C H A P T E R 3Choice Sets in Labor and Financial Markets This chapter is a straightforward extension of Chapter 2 where we had shown that budget constraints can arise from someone owning an endowment

More information

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory ECON 3510 - Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Fall 2015 Mankiw, Macroeconomics, 8th ed., Chapter 3 Chapter 3: A Theory of National Income Key points: Understand the aggregate production function Understand

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty Economics 101 Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty 1 Intertemporal Setting Consider a consumer who lives for two periods, say old and young. When he is young, he has income m 1, while when

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle Theory Paul Scanlon November 29, 2010 1 Introduction The emphasis here is on technology/tfp shocks, and the associated supply-side responses. As the term suggests, all the shocks are

More information

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed). Chapter 7: Labor Market So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed). Key idea: In the medium run, rising GD will lead to lower unemployment rate (more

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2018 1 / 21 Readings GLS Chapter 11 2 / 21 Production and

More information

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification by Lawrence Christiano Incorporating Financial Frictions into a Business Cycle Model General idea: Standard model

More information

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2 Econ 301 Midterm 2 (Group A) You have 70 minutes to complete the exam. The midterm consists of 4 questions (25,30,25 and 20 points). Problem 1 (25p). (Uncertainty and insurance) You are an owner of a luxurious

More information

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK! University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS TIME: 1 HOUR AND 50 MINUTES DO NOT HAVE A CELL PHONE ON YOUR DESK OR ON YOUR PERSON. ONLY AID ALLOWED: A

More information

Solutions to Assignment #2

Solutions to Assignment #2 ECON 20 (Fall 207) Department of Economics, SFU Prof. Christoph Lülfesmann exam). Solutions to Assignment #2 (My suggested solutions are usually more detailed than required in an I. Short Problems. The

More information

Exercises on chapter 4

Exercises on chapter 4 Exercises on chapter 4 Exercise : OLG model with a CES production function This exercise studies the dynamics of the standard OLG model with a utility function given by: and a CES production function:

More information

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (30 Marks)

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (30 Marks) ECON 222 Macroeconomic Theory I Fall Term 2010 Assignment 2 Due: Drop Box 2nd Floor Dunning Hall by noon October 15th 2010 No late submissions will be accepted No group submissions will be accepted No

More information

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3) FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS These notes are missing interpretation of the results, and especially toward the end, skip some steps in the mathematics. But they should be useful

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 02

More information