The Government Spending Multiplier in a Model with the Cost Channel

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Government Spending Multiplier in a Model with the Cost Channel"

Transcription

1 The Government Spending Multiplier in a Model with the Cost Channel Salem Abo-Zaid 248 Holden Hall, Department of Economics, Texas Tech University, Lubbock, TX, Abstract This paper studies the government spending multiplier in the presence of the cost channel of the nominal interest rate. I find that the multiplier of normal times declines markedly when this channel is introduced. The drop in the multiplier is bigger for more flexible prices, bigger responses to inflation in the interest rate rule, more persistent government spending and lower intertemporal elasticity of substitution in the utility function. The rise in government spending leads to a rise in the nominal interest rate and, with the cost channel, to a rise in the marginal cost and inflation. In turn, this leads to a bigger rise in the nominal interest rate and the expected real interest rate than in the model that abstracts from the cost channel. Higher marginal costs also reduce the incentives to produce and, thus, weaken the response of output to government spending shocks. On the other hand, to the extent that firms borrowing costs rise at the zero-lower bound following government spending shocks, the cost channel makes the government spending multiplier larger than in a model that abstract from it. The cost channel strengthens the expected inflation channel, which leads to a bigger drop in the expected real interest rate and thus to a larger government spending multiplier. Therefore, by ignoring the cost channel, the spending multiplier is overestimated in normal times and underestimated in liquidity trap episodes. Keywords: Government Spending Multiplier; Cost Channel; Fiscal Policy; Monetary Policy; Zero-Lower Bound. JEL Classification: E52; E58; E62; E Introduction The main goal of this paper is to study the government spending multiplier in a model with the cost channel of the nominal interest rate. It is found that the cost channel matters a great deal for the size of the spending multiplier but the exact effects depend on the episode considered. In normal times, during which the nominal interest rate is not fixed, the cost channel reduces the multiplier considerably. Depending on the strength of this channel, the multiplier can drop from above one to zero or even a negative multiplier just because of the address: salem.abozaid@ttu.edu (Salem Abo-Zaid) August 14, 2015

2 mere introduction of the cost channel. This effect is stronger for less rigid prices, stronger response of the nominal interest rate to inflation, more persistent government spending and lower intertemporal elasticity of substitution in the utility function. However, when the nominal interest rate is fixed, as can happen because of the Zero-Lower Bound (ZLB) constraint, the cost channel makes the spending multiplier larger provided that the borrowing costs of firms rise in response to a government spending shock. For plausible calibration of the model, the liquidity-trap spending multiplier more than doubles in the presence of the cost channel comapred to its value in a model that does not account for this channel. This effect is stronger when prices are less rigid and the responses of the firms borrowing interest rates to government spending shocks are bigger. The intuition behind these results is as follows. When the nominal interest rate is free to adjust, the rise in government spending raises this interest rate and, as a result, the marginal costs of firms. In turn, this leads a a larger increse in inflation and inflation expectations than in a model that abstracts from this channel. However, since the nominal interest rate increases by more than one-for-one with inflation (and the expected infaltion rate), the rise in inflation triggers even a larger increase in the nominal interest rate. The result is a larger increase in the expected real interest rate, which implies a smaller rise in consumer spending. In turn, the multiplier will be smaller than in an otherwise model without the cost channel. In this respect, the cost channel weakens the expected inflation channel that is essential for a large government spending multiplier to materialize in this class of models. When the ZLB constraint is binding, the cost channel actually strengthens the expected inflation channel. A rise in the borrowing costs of firms raises the marginal cost, and thus inflation and expected inflation by more than in the absence of this channel. However, at the ZLB, the nominal interest rate that is relevant for consumer spending remains unchanged (and it is unaffected by the cost channel). Therefore, the decline in the expected real interest rate is larger than in the absence of this channel, which in turn implies a larger spending multiplier during this type episodes. Therefore, previous estimates of the multiplier that did not account for the cost channel underestimated the multiplier of stress times and overestimated the multiplier of normal times. This study extends an otherwise standard New Keynesian (NK) model by allowing for the cost channel to be operative. Following Christiano et al. (2005) and Ravenna and Walsh (2006), among others, I assume that the wage bill of firms is paid before production takes place, thus giving rise to borrowing by firms (which, in turn, leads to supply-side effects of the nominal interest rate on inflation as in the standard cost channel of monetary policy). In particular, the marginal cost of firms becomes a function of the nominal interest rate on borrowing. The basic setup assumes that one interest rate in the economy, but to address the change in firms borrowing interest rates at the ZLB, I assume that these rates differ from the policy interest rate. The deviation between these interest rates can possibly result from market power in the intermdiation sector, adjustment costs of loans and other costs associated with changes in the scale of operation of banks. See Elyasiani et al. (1995), Freixas and Rochet (1997) and Kopecky and VanHoose (2012), among others, for a discussion. 2

3 The paper adds to the recent literature on the government spending multiplier. Christiano et al. (2011) first show that the multiplier is modest (slightly above 1) when the nominal interest rate is governed by a standard Taylor rule. However, they show that the government-spending multiplier can be much larger than one if the nominal interest rate does not respond to an increase in government spending, as can happen when the nominal interest rate hits the zero lower bound. The rise in government spending raises output and inflation expectations. When the nominal interest rate is at the lower bound, that leads to a decline in the real interest rate and to a further rise in consumption, output and expected inflation, leading to a loop of rising inflation expectations and output. The multiplier, thus, can be large. Quantitatively, the benchmark calibration of their model with the ZLB delivers a multiplier of more than three times the size of the multiplier of normal times. One implication of this result is that the asymmetries between liquidity trap episodes and normal times can be very significant. Carlstrom et al. (2014) consider the effects of the duration of interest rate peg on the size of the spending multiplier within a New-Keynesian framework. They compare the results when the monetary-fiscal expansion lasts a certain number of periods ( deterministic duration ) with the results when the expansion is stochastic (with a mean that is equal to the fixed number of periods under the deterministic case). They find that the size of the stochastic multiplier is large and clearly larger than the deterministic multiplier. For example, when the interest rate is fixed for 4 periods (or the mean is 4), the stochastic multiplier is 66.9 and the deterministic multiplier is 2.3. Using a model similar to Carlstrom et al. (2014), but for normal times, Dupor and Li (2015) study the expected inflation channel and its implications for the government spending multiplier. They show that having a large multiplier requires a large response of expected inflation to government spending. However, according to their empirical evidence, that has not been the case in the U.S. over the periods and and, therefore, the expected inflation channel has no support in U.S. data or it has been too small to generate large fiscal multipliers. Furthermore, their analyses distinguish between passive monetary policy, which occurs when the central bank increases the nominal interest rate by less than one-for-one with the change in expected inflation and active monetary policy, when the opposite occurs. It is found that under a passive monetary policy the multiplier is above one and under the active policy, it is less than one. The size of the fiscal multiplier at the ZLB has recently been questioned by the empirical findings of Ramey and Zubairy (2015). The authors construct quarterly U.S. data for to test whether government spending multipliers differ according to the amount of slack in the economy and being near the ZLB. They find that the amount of slack in the economy does not affect the size of the multiplier. Further, the analysis does not point out to any statistically different multipliers between normal times and ZLB episodes, particulary when the full sample is used. Therefore, contrary to recent findings, government spending multipliers were not necessarily higher than average during the Great Recession. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012), on the other hand, use U.S. for 1947:Q1-2008:Q4 and find large 3

4 differences in the size of spending multipliers between recessions and expansions. In particular, government spending is considerably more effective in recessions than in expansions, which aligns with the predictions of qunatitative models. Existing literature also considered other aspects that can be important for the size of the fiscal multiplier. Gali et al. (2007) extend a standard NK modelto account for rule-of-thumb consumers. They show that the exact agent s preferences matter for the size of the multiplier, including being larger than or less than unity. Monacelli and Perotti (2008) first document that variations in government purchases generate a rise in consumption, the real wage and the product wage, and a fall in the markup. They then build an otherwise standard business cycle model with price rigidity, in which preferences can be consistent with an arbitrarily small wealth effect on labor supply and show that the model can match the empirical evidence on the effects of government spending shocks well. This highlights again the role of preferences for the size of the multiplier. Zubairy (2014) studies the government spending multiplier in a stochastic general equilibrium model that features other distortionary taxes and finds that the impact government spending multiplier is In addition, private consumption responds positively to government spending shocks and the multipliers for labor and capital taxes on impact are 0.13 and 0.34, respectively. In light of the wide range of findings about the fiscal multiplier, Leeper et al. (2011) study the fiscal multipliers in five nested models: a simple real business cycle (RBC) model, the RBC model with real frictions, a standard new Keynesian model, the new Keynesian model with hand-to-mouth agents and an open economy version of the new Keynesian model. They use Bayesian prior predictive tools and conclude that model specifications and prior distributions can tightly limit the range of possible spending multipliers. Moreover, a passive monetary policy yields strong multipliers for output, consumption and investment. 1 Despite its empirical validity, the cost channel of the nominal interest rate has not been addressed in the context of the government spending multiplier. This paper aims for filling that gap in the literature. To this end, I first provide more updated evidence regarding the existence of a cost channel and then examine the fiscal multiplier in a computable model with this channel and compare it to a model that abstracts from it. I find that the cost channel became more significant since 1984, that the firms credit spread surged during the current ZLB episode and that firms s borrowing costs are responsive to government spending shocks, which supports the choice of a model that distinguishes between the policy interest rate and the borrowing rates of firms as a platform to study the implications of the cost channel for the size of the multiplier when the ZLB constraint is binding. The effects of the cost channel on the fiscal multiplier are robust to multiple specifications about agent s preferences, the degree of price rigidity, the responses to inflation in the interest-rate rule, the significance of the cost channel (in the empirically relevant range) and other parameters. In particular, the differences between the multipliers with and without 1 In frictionless real business cycle models this multiplier is typically less than one (see, e.g., Aiyagari et al. (1992), Aiyagari et al. (1993), Ramey and Shapiro (1998) and Burnside et al. (2004)). 4

5 the cost channel are bigger for less rigid prices. This happens because the coefficient of the nominal interest rate in the New-Keynesian Phillips Curve is bigger for lower price rigidity. When prices approach full stickiness, the cost channel does not affect the size of the fiscal multiplier as the marginal cost, through which the cost channel operates, becomes immaterial for inflation and the economy in general. The results of the paper are compared to those of Christiano et al. (2011), Carlstrom et al. (2014) and Dupor and Li (2015). I conduct the analyses for passive and active central banks as defined in the latter study. Interestingly, I find that the cost channel weakens the multiplier in the presence of active monetary policy but strengthens the multiplier of a passive monetary policy. The reason for these results are as follows. When the interest rate initially rises in response to government spending shocsk, the marginal cost rises, and so do inflation and the expected inflation rate. With a passive central bank, the nominal interest rate rises by less than one-for-one with the rise in the expected inflation rate, leading to a bigger drop in the expected real interest rate compared to the model with no cost channel. The result will be a higer spending multiplier. With an active monetary policy, the nominal interest rate rises by more than one-for-one with the rise in the expected inflation rate, which makes the rise in the expceted real interest rate with the cost channel lower than in an otherwise model without it, leading a lower multiplier. When the central bank is neutral, in the sense that the nominal interest rate rises by one-for-one with the expected inflation rate, the cost channel does not affect the size of the multiplier. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the model economy. Section 3 provides empirical evidence on the existence of the cost channel. Section 4 presents the government spending multiplier of normal times and the numerical results. Section 5 presents robustness analyses using alternative preferences and monetary policy rule. The spending multiplier of constant interest rate and evidence regarding the responsivness of firms s borrowing costs to government spending shocks are presented in 6. Finally, Section 7 concludes. 2. The Model Economy The economy is populated by a continuum of infinitely-lived households who derive utility from consumption and leisure. Households also hold cash and they are engaged in the intermediation sector by holding some of their assets in the form of interest-earning deposits. Intermediate-good firms operate in an environment of monopolistic competition. They hire labor as the only input to produce differentiated products, set prices in a staggered fashion and borrow from intermediaries to finance their wage bill as in a standard model with the working capital requirement. The products of these firms are sold to final-good firms (retailers) who package them into final goods using a one-to-one technology. The basic setup through which the cost channel is introduced follows Ravenna and Walsh (2006) and Christiano et al. (2005), and the reader may refer to these studies for more details. 5

6 2.1. Households The problem of the representative household is to choose consumption c t, labor supply n t, deposits D t and cash M t to maximize: E 0 t=0 β t ( [cγ t (1 n t ) 1 γ ] 1 σ 1 ) (1) 1 σ where β is the subjective discount factor, E 0 is the expectation operator, σ > 0 and γ (0, 1). The assumption of non-separable utility function follows Christiano et al. (2011), but I will also show the results with seperable preferences in what follows. At the beginning of the period, households make deposits at the financial intermediary and the remaining amount M t + W t n t D t, with W t being the nominal wage, is used for consumption. At the end of the period, households receive profits from the financial intermediary and intermediate-good firms as well as the principle and interest on their deposits at the intermediary. The corresponding constraints that households face and a full description of their problem is presented in Appendix A.1. The optimization by households leads to the following standard consumption Euler equation and the labor supply condition, respectively, expressed in log deviations from the steady state: [γ(1 σ) 1]ĉ t (1 γ)(1 σ) n 1 n n t = R t E t [ π t+1 [γ(1 σ) 1]ĉ t+1 (1 γ)(1 σ) n 1 n n t+1] (2) ĉ t + n 1 n n t = ŵ t (3) where x denotes the non-stochastic steady state and x t is the log deviation from this steady state for any variable x t, π t = P t /P t 1 is the gross inflation rate, w t is the real wage and R t is the gross nominal policy (or market) interest rate. As expected, these conditions hold regardless of the cost channel and they are similar to the corresponding conditions in Christiano et al. (2011). With logarithmic preferences (σ = 1), condition (2) restores the more familar form of the log-lineraized Euler condition The Production Sector As is standard in the literature, two types of firms operate in this sector: monopolistically competitive intermediate-good firms who produce differentiated products and perfectly competitive firms who transform intermediate goods into final goods using a constant return to scale technology Final-Good Firms Firms in this sector operate in a perfectly competitive environment. They purchase a continuum of intermediate goods from intermediate-good producers, indexed by j (0, 1), and assemble them into final goods using the following technology: 6

7 y t = ( 0 1 y ε 1 ε j,t with y j,t being the quantity of intermediate-good j that is purchased by a final-good firm and ε > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between two differentiated types of intermediate goods. Profit maximization by intermediate-good producers gives the following downward-sloping demand function for the product variety j: dj) ε ε 1 (4) y j,t = ( P ε j,t ) y t (5) P t where P t = ( 1 0 P j,t 1 ε dj) 1 1 ε minimization. is the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregate price level that results from cost Intermediate-Good Firms Firms in this sector are monopolistically competitive. Each firm j hires labor as the only input to produce a differentiated product using the following technology: y j,t = n j,t. (6) Firms in this sector borrow from intermediaries, at the beginning of each period at an interest rate of Rt L in order to pay their wage bills. This is in line with the working capital requirement as in Christiano et al. (2005), Tillmann (2008) and Ravenna and Walsh (2006), among others. Following these studies, I assume in this section that the intermediation sector is perfectly competitive and complete pass through from the policy interest rate to the loan rate. Therefore Rt L = R t. However, in what follows I also show the results when the loan rate is a markup over the market rate. Each period, a firm j has the probability 1 θ of changing its price as in Calvo (1983). With this characterization of the intermediate-good sector, the time t real profit function of firm j is given by: Π f j,t = y j,t R δ t w t n j,t (7) subject to (5)-(6). The parameter δ measures the strength of the cost channel. As is standard in the NK literature, optimization leads to the following forward-looking Philips Curve: π t = β E t π t+1 + κ mc t (8) and labor demand condition: with κ = (1 θ)(1 βθ) θ. Letting s t = wtnt y t mc t = ŵ t + δ R t. (9) be the labor share of output and using the log-linearized 7

8 version of the production function, condition (9) can be re-written as: mc t = ŝ t + δ R t, (10) which is the standard condition of the real marginal cost in models with the cost channel (see, for example, Ravenna and Walsh (2006) and Tillmann (2008)). The Philips Curve then reads: π t = β E t π t+1 + κ (ŝ t + δ R t ) (11) and, thus, the nominal interest rate directly affects the behavior of inflation Market Clearing and Monetary Policy In equilibrium, the resource constraint of the economy reads: y t = c t + g t (12) Denoting the steady-state values of government spending and output by g and y, respectively, log linearization of the resource constraint yields: ŷ t = (1 g)ĉ t + gĝ t (13) where g = g y is the steady-state government spending-output ratio. Government spending evolves according to the following AR(1) process: ĝ t = ρĝ t 1 + u t (14) with ρ being the AR(1) coefficient and u t N (0, σ 2 u). In addition, monetary policy is governed by the following interest-rate rule: In what follows, I will also consider other monetary policy rules. 3. The Cost Channel: Empirical Evidence R t = φ π π t + φ y ŷ t. (15) This section provides some evidence about the existence of the cost channel using pre-crisis U.S data (1960:Q1-2007:Q3). The sample ends in the third quarter of 2007 to avoid any biases in the results after the reach of the nominal interest rate the zero-lower bound. The estimation is then provided for the second half of the sample (1984:Q1-2007:Q3) to asses whether the cost channel has become weaker or stronger over time. I choose 1984 as the beginning of the second period because it is well known by now that many macroeconomic aggregates have experienced changes since that year. It also happens to be in the middle of the sample in hand. 8

9 In particular, I estimate condition (11). I use the 3 month treasury bill as a proxy for R t, the non-farm business labor share of output for s t and the rate of change in the GDP deflator for π t. Following Ravenna and Walsh (2006), the model is estimated using the Generalized Method of Moments with instrumental variables. All data have been detrended using the Hodrick and Prescott (HP) filter using a standard smoothing parameter of The results are reported in Table 1. Description 1960:Q1-2007:Q3 1984:Q1-2007:Q3 κ δ Price Duration κ Price Duration (0.015, 0.054) (0.005, 0.040) (0.991, 1.113) (1.818, 5.939) (4.567, 7.848) (5.148, ) (0.029, 0.070) (0.012, 0.049) (4.089, 5.869) (4.765, 8.431) Obs Table 1: Empirical results- estimation of condition (11). The list of instruments includes four lags of nonfarm business sector real unit labor cost, output gap, inflation rate (GDP deflator), commodity price index inflation, 10 year minus 3 month U.S. government bond spread, non-farm business sector hourly compensation inflation and 3-month T-bill rate. 95% confidence intervals in parentheses. The point estimates of κ for the full sample period are in line with previous findings and with the standard values of this parameter that are used in the literature on the government spending multiplier (e.g. Christiano et al. (2011), Carlstrom et al. (2014) and Dupor and Li (2015)). The cost channel is very strong and the value of δ is about unity, which is similar to the findings of Ravenna and Walsh (2006) and Chowdhury et al. (2006). Over the period 1984:Q1-2007:Q3, the cost channel became significantly stronger: δ exceeds 2 and the 95% confidence interval indicates that it can reach roughly 6. Given these findings, my initial estimates of the spending multiplier will consider values of δ between 1 and 6, with the focus being on the range 1-3 where the point estimates of this parameter lie. The botttom panel shows the estimation of the Phillips curve using the (non-farm business) unit labor cost (ULC), which is defined as total labor compensation divided by real output (wl/y). Given our linear technology, the ULC is essentially the real marginal cost. The results indicate a slightly higher κ than in the estimations with the labor share and the interest rate and they also show a reduction in the size of κ in the second sub period. The table also reports the corresponding price durations, which can be found by using the condition κ = (1 θ)(1 βθ) θ and the fact that the price duration is given by 1 1 θ. All cases indicate 9

10 that the price duration is above 4 quarter, mostly 6 quarters or more, and can reach as high as 12 quarters. These estimates are clearly higher than micro evidence about the duration of price contracts: Bils and Klenow (2004) find that the, even after excluding temporary price cuts (sales), half of prices last up to 5.5 months. Nakamura and Steinsson (2008) report a higher price duration: with the exclusion of product substitutions, the uncensored durations of regular prices of between 8-11 months. Allowing for price changes associated with product substitutions, the median duration until either the price changes or the product disappears is 7-9 months. Christiano et al. (2005) find a price duration of 2.5 quarters and Smets and Wouters (2007) suggest an average duration of prices of 3 quarters. All of these estimates lie within the 4 quarters range. Therefore, to be consistent with literature on government spending multipliers, my analyses will first use the values of κ as in Table 1. Then, I will also other values of κ that are consistent with the existing evidence about the average duration prices, particularly the micro evidence, which suggests average price durations between 2 and 4 quarters. 4. The Government Spending Multiplier The main analyses regarding the government spending multiplier are presented in this section. By using conditions (3), (8) and (9), the Philips Curve can then be written as: π t = β E t π t+1 + κ (ĉ t + n 1 n n t + δ R t ) (16) Following the literature, the model is solved using the method of undetermined coefficients. Under the assumption that φ π > 1, the solution yields: where: ŷ t = Aĝ t (17) A = g κ(φ π ρ) + (1 ρ)(1 βρ δκφ π )[γ(σ 1) + 1] (1 βρ δκφ π )[1 + (1 g)φ y ρ] + (1 g)(φ π ρ)κ [ 1 1 g + n 1 n + δφ y] The government spending multiplier is then given by: (18) or, alternatively, dy t dg t = A g. (19) dy t = g ĉ t. (20) dg t g ĝ t By setting δ = 0, we get the exact government spending multiplier as in Christiano et al. (2011). Clearly, the multiplier is affected by the presence of the cost channel, but the exact effect is not possible to tell without further information and it may depend on the size of 10

11 δ and other parameters. There is a clear case, however, when the role of the cost channel is easy to see: if prices approach full stickiness (θ 1), κ approaches zero, and the cost channel will not affect the size of the multiplier. This result is as expected since, according to condition (9), the interest rate does not affect the behavior of the marginal cost (hence, inflation), and the cost channel is immaterial. Indeed, as will be outlined below, the size of κ is very important for the size of the multiplier and for the effects of the cost channel on the multiplier. Condition (20) makes it clear that the size of the multiplier depends on the response of consumption to government spending disturbances. If consumption rises ( crowding in ), then the multiplier will be larger than one. If it falls ( crowding out ), the multiplier will less than one. And, if consumption does not respond to shocks to government spending, then the multiplier will be exactly Results Table 2 summarizes the parameter values that I use in the benchmark analyses. The parameters mostly follow Christiano et al. (2011), with the only exception being κ, which is set based on the empirical analyses that are presented above. These parameter values are widely accepted in the literature, but I will conduct comprehensive robustness analyses by changing the values of these and examine how the cost channel affects their effects on the spending multiplier. I will also compare my results to Christiano et al. (2011) using their value of κ = Parameter β σ ρ κ g φ π φ y n Value /3 Table 2: Values of the Parameters. Figure 1 shows the government spending multiplier for values of δ between 1 and 6 using the benchmark calibration of the model. Without the cost channel, the multiplier is slightly above one (as in Christiano et al. (2011)), but it decline rapidly as the significance of the cost channel rises. At roughly δ = 6, the multiplier becomes negative. This figure confirms the conjectures regarding the effects of the cost channel on the size of the multiplier and it suggests that not only this effect can be large, but it rises exponentially as the significance of this channel increases within the empirically plausible range. Within the range of δ = 1-3, the multiplier drops from 1.03 to 0.85, which is relatively muted. Notice, however, that this calculation is based on a value of κ = 0.835, which implies an average price duration of more than 6 quarters. As discussed above, this lies outside the range of average price durations that have been found in empirical work, particularly at the micro level. For this reason, I will experiment on the price rigidity parameter θ within the plausible range of average durations of price contracts and consider the implications of changing this parameter for the size of the government spending multiplier. 11

12 Multiplier Figure 1: The government spending multiplier for various values of δ. The key intiution behind the effects of the cost channel on the spending multiplier can be seen through the response of the expected real interest rate to government spending shocks. As shown in Appendix A.2, the expected real interest rate is give by: E t r t+1 = (φ π ρ)qĝ t (21) and, therefore, its response to a government spending shock depends on the response of inflation to this shock (captured by Q). In particular, since φ π > ρ, the expected real interest rate will rise by more than in the model without the cost channel as the response of inflation to spending shocks is bigger. Indeed, Figure B.1 shows that the response of the expected real interest rate to spending shocks is an increasing function of δ. With higher values of δ, the rise in the expected real interest rate is bigger and, therefore, the multiplier is lower. Furthermore, the shape of this graph is exactly the opposite of the multiplier (Figure 1), which further supports the intiution behind the results of this subsection. The rise in the actual real interest rate is also bigger when the cost channel is operative. The actual real interest will rise provided that φ π > 1, which is the standard assumption in this class of assumption. This results from the fact that the nominal interest rises by more than one-for-one the rise in the actual inflation rate. The cost channel makes Q larger and thus leads to a bigger actual real interest rate. The derivations are shown in Appendix A.2. When the nominal policy interest rate responds to output alongside inflation (φ y > 0), the same arguments hold. In this case, the expected real interest rate is given by: E t r t+1 = [(φ π ρ)q + φ y A] ĝ t (22) 12

13 which shows a larger increase in the expected real interest rate than in the model with response to inflation only. Therefore, the government spending multiplier in this case is lower than in the model with φ y = 0 even in the absence of the cost channel, which is in line with the findings of Christiano et al. (2011). Figure B.2 shows the numerical results with the cost channel, and they are very similar to the results of Figure 1. Since the effects of the cost channel are similar to the model with no response to output, I procced with the assumption that the nominal interest rate responds to inflation only Changing the Price Rigidity Parameter Figure 2a reports the results of varying δ for three values of the price rigidity parameter. 1 Defining the duration of prices as 1 θ, these values correspond to price durations of 2, 3 and 4 quarters, which are the most consistent with the empirical evidence. The impact of the cost channel in this case is clearly stronger than with higher degrees of price rigidity. With 4 quarters, the multiplier falls from 0.90 to 0.29 in this range of δ. With shorter price durations, the multiplier drops faster and it even becomes negative at values of δ between 2 and 3. Furthermore, the impact of the cost channel is magnified as the price duration drops and δ rises. This is well illustrated by the fact that the difference between the bottom and the middle lines is significantly bigger than the difference between the first and the second lines (even though the difference between the values of θ is smaller). (a) (b) 1 Multiplier =0.50 =0.67 = Multiplier =0 =1 =2 = Figure 2: The government spending multiplier, the cost channel and price rigidity. In Figure 2b, I show the results by varying the degree of price flexibility (1 θ) for the relevant values of δ. I use values of θ between 0.5 (a price duration of 2 quarters) and 1 13

14 (fully-rigid prices). The main insights can be summarized as follows. First, regardless of the cost channel, a decrease in price rigidity leads to a decline in the multiplier. For example, with no cost channel, the multiplier drops from 1.29 to In fact, even when prices have a high duration of 4 quarters (1 θ = 0.25), the multiplier is 0.90, which is significant drop from the multiplier of fully-rigid prices. Second, when prices approach full rigidity, the cost channel is immaterial, which is in line with out earlier discussions. Intiuitively, when κ approaches zero, the nominal interest rate does not affect the pricing behavior of firms. Third, the cost channel magnifies the drop in the multiplier as prices become more flexible. With a relatively small value of δ, the multiplier drops to nearly 0.50 at a price duration of 2 quarters and to 0.80 at a price duration of 4 quarters. With higher values of δ, the multiplier drops to either (roughly) zero or even a considerably negative value. With an intermediate value of δ, the multiplier is only 0.64 at a price duration of 4 quarters, which is half of its value with fully rigid prices Robustness In this subsection, I show that the effects of the cost channel on the size of the multiplier depends on other parameters as well. The results are summarized in Figure 3. Consider first the response of the nominal interest to inflation (φ π ). A bigger response of the interest rate to inflation leads to a higher rise in the nominal interest following a government spending shock, which lowers the size of the multiplier, with and without the cost channel. The cost channel makes this effect stronger, particularly as δ rises. The spending multiplier is lower for more persistent government expenditures, which results from a bigger negative wealth effect on consumption when government spending is more persistent as the present discounted value of taxes needed to finance these expenditures is bigger. This effect is stronger in the presence of the cost channel: the bigger negative wealth effect is coupled by a bigger substitution effect that results from a bigger rise in the interest rates, thus leading to a bigger drop in consumption and to a lower multiplier. The multiplier is increasing in both σ and γ. A higher γ increases the marginal utility of consumption and thus leads to a stronger response of consumption to government spending shocks. Given the non-separable preferences in consumption and labor, the the marginal utility of consumption is increasing in the amount of labor supplied. This effect is stronger for higher values of σ. The cost channel in this case weakens this effect: the desire to consume more is partially offset by the bigger rise in the interest rate in the presence of the cost channel. In fact, with δ = 4, the multiplier becomes virtually unaffected by the rise in γ, for δ = 5, the multiplier is decreasing in γ (but remains slightly positive), and with δ = 6, the multiplier drops markedly with the rise in γ and becomes negative even for γ = The same result holds for σ. Therefore, not only that the cost channel renders the multiplier lower, but it also flattens its increase in σ and γ, and even reverses the effects of these two parameters on the size of the multiplier. 14

15 Multiplier 0.8 Multiplier =0 =1 =2 = Multiplier Multiplier Figure 3: The government spending multiplier for various values the model s parameters. 5. Robustness Analyses: Model Specification In this section, I redo the analyses using a separable utility function as in Carlstrom et al. (2014) with the rest of the model specifics remaining unchanged. I then use this model to change the interest-rate rule. In particular, the second experiment considers an interest-rate rule where the central bank responds to the expected inflation rate and the strength of this response matters for the size of the multiplier. This modeling follows Dupor and Li (2015), and the analyses with the cost channel will allow good comparisons with these two recent studies. 15

16 5.1. Separable Utility Function The period utility function in this setup is given by: u(c t, n t ) = c1 σ t 1 σ χ n1+ν t 1 + ν which yields the following Euler and labor supply conditions: (23) R t E t π t+1 = σ(e t ĉ t+1 ĉ t ) (24) ν n t + σĉ t = ŵ t. (25) By using conditions (8), (9) and (25), the Phillips Curve can then be written as: π t = β E t π t+1 + κ (ν n t + σĉ t + δ R t ) (26) The solution for the spending multiplier, under the assumption φ π > 1, then yields: dy t dg t = κσ(φ π ρ) + σ(1 ρ)(1 βρ δκφ π ) κ [ν(1 g) + σ + δ(1 g)φ y ] (φ π ρ) + [σ(1 ρ) + (1 g)φ y ] (1 βρ δκφ π ) (27) Once more, the multiplier is affected by the cost channel, κ matters markedly, and the cost channel will not affect the size of the multiplier when κ = 0. Furthermore, the multiplier is clearly less than one, and that holds even when the cost channel is absent (δ = 0). With ρ y = 0 and ν = 0, which implies an infinite labor supply elasticity, the multiplier is exactly one, and the cost channel does not change this conclusion Multiplier Figure 4: The government spending multiplier for various values of δ. 16

17 I set β = 0.99, σ = 2, ν = 0.5, ρ = 0.8, κ = 0.034, φ π = 1.5, φ y = 0.0 and g = 0.2. The first four parameters are as in Carlstrom et al. (2014), κ follows the empirical findings and the rest follow Christiano et al. (2011). 2 As in the model with non-separable preferences, the spending multiplier is decreasing in the size of δ, and effects of the cost channel on the multiplier are exponentially rising in the size of this parameter. Overall, the shape of this graph is similar to that of Figure 1 and, therefore, the particular assumption about preferences is not behind the benchmark results of the paper. The analyses also reveal that the multiplier is very sensitive to changes in average price duration and that the cost channel becomes more significant for less rigid prices. For example, at δ = 3 and a price duration of 3 quarters, the multiplier is 0.27 as opposed to 0.87 in the model without the cost channel. For δ = 3 and a price duration of 2 quarters, the multiplier is compared to 0.85 in the model that abstracts from this channel An Alternative Interest Rate Rule: Active vs. Passive Monetary Policy The model is similar to the one from subsection, but with one modification. Dupor and Li (2015), the interest rate is governed by the following rule: Following R t = (1 + ψ)e t π t+1 (28) Monetary policy is active if the nominal interest rate rises by more than one-for-one following a rise in inflation expectations (which occurs when ψ > 0), passive if the interest rate rises by less than one-for-one (ψ < 0), and neutral if the interest rate rises by exactly one-for-one (ψ = 0). This specification directly addresses the expected inflation rate channel that has been frequently mentioned in the fiscal multiplier literature. The government spending multiplier is then given by: dy t dg t = κρψσ + σ(1 ρ)[1 βρ δκρ(1 + ψ)] κρψ[σ + ν(1 g)] + σ(1 ρ)[1 βρ δκρ(1 + ψ)] First notice that by setting δ = 0, we get the exact government spending multiplier as in Dupor and Li (2015). The spending multiplier has a value of 1 when the central bank is neutral (ψ = 0) and less that one for an active monetary policy (ψ > 0). The multiplier is larger than one if monetary policy is passive (ψ < 0) provided that the denominator is positive, which happens for most values of ψ that are between (-1) and zero. Clearly, ψ = 1 is the lower bound on this parameter, otherwise the nominal interest rate will decline following a rise in inflation expectations, which is not plausible. These observations hold whether or not the cost channel exists. The intuition behind these finding is as follows: an active central bank raises the interest rate by more than one-for-one in response to inflation, thus increasing the expected real interest rate and reducing consumer spending in response to a rise government spending. (29) 2 Carlstrom et al. (2014) analyze the multiplier at the ZLB and their multiplier does not include the last three parameters. For this reason, I use the values from the other study. 17

18 In particular (E t ĉ t+1 ĉ t ) declines. A passive central bank increases the expected interest rate by less than one-for-one, thus leading to a rise in consumer spending. And, a neutral central bank does not influence the expected real interest rate, thus leading to no change in consumer spending: the left-hand side of equation (24) does not change, and the right-hand side does not change either. The implications of the cost channel for the size of the multiplier can be seen in condition (29). With ψ < 0, both the numerator and denominator are larger than in the model without the cost channel. But since κρψσ < κρψ[σ + ν(1 g)], the numerator rises by more than the denominator when the cost channel is introduced, leading to a rise in the multiplier. With ψ < 0, the opposite happens, and the multiplier is lower. And, with ψ = 0, the cost channel is immaterial for the size of the multiplier. In this respect, this setup allows for a clearer illustration of the role of the cost channel in determining the size of the multiplier. (a) Passive (b) Active Multiplier Multiplier Figure 5: The government spending multiplier and the cost channel: active vs. passive monetary policy. The parameterization is based on Dupor and Li (2015) to allow for good comparisons with the latter study. I set β = 0.995, σ = 1, ν = 4, ρ = 0.75, κ = and g = 0.2, ψ = 0.5 for a passive central bank and ψ = 0.5 for an active central bank. The starting point of each graph replicates exactly the multipliers in Dupor and Li (2015): a multiplier of 2.25 with a passive central bank and a multiplier of 0.75 with an active central bank. As expected, for a passive central bank, the cost channel strengthens the impact of government spending shocks on consumption and increases the multiplier. The reason for this finding is the following: the cost channel increases the expected inflation rate beyond the corresponding increase in the expected inflation rate that would materialize when this channel is absent. But, since 18

19 the nominal interest rate rises by less one-for-one, the actual decline in the expected real interest rate is larger than when the cost channel is not operative, which in turn leads to a higher government spending multiplier. The opposite holds for the active central bank. The decline in the expected real interest rate with the cost channel is higher than otherwise, which makes the cost-channel multiplier lower. Furthermore, the impact of the cost channel on the size of the multiplier is more significant for passive monetary policy. This observation may reflect the fact that the government spending multiplier with the active bank is already (relatively) low and the cost channel has a relatively less ability to lower even further. The result about the active central bank is in line with the benchmark analyses (section 4). In the benchmark analyses, the central bank increases the nominal interest rate by more than one-for-one with the increase in the inflation rate. In particular, φ π = 1.5, which implies that the response to the expected inflation rate is φπ ρ = > 1. In both cases, the decline in the expected real interest with the cost channel is larger than otherwise, and the spending multiplier is lower accordingly. The gaps between the multiplier with the cost and without the cost channel is larger for higher values of ψ for the active central bank and for more negative values of ψ for the passive central bank. This is particularly true for the passive central bank; for example, with ψ = 0.7, the multiplier with no cost channel is roughly 6, and the multiplier with δ = 3 is above 11. Furthermore, the effects are stronger for more flexible prices. These results can be provided upon request. More generally, the analyses of this section support the findings of the benchmark model after changes in the model s specification and the interest-rate rule. The cost channel has implications for the strength of the expected inflation channel, and accounting for it provides a more accurate estimation of the strength of this channel and its implications for the government spending multiplier. 6. The Constant Interest-Rate Government Spending Multiplier So far, the anlayses assumed that the nominal interest rate is free to adjust and it is not at the zero lower-bound. In what follows, I relax this assumption by assuming that the nominal (policy) interest rate is fixed. In particular, it is assumed that the ZLB constraint on the nominal policy interest rate binds. As discussed in the introduction, it is well known by now that this class of models predicts a large spending multiplier when conventional monetary policy becomes powerless. Another assumption that is relaxed in this section is that the loan interest rate and the ploicy interest rate are exactly the same. If they were equal, then at the ZLB the cost channel would not affect the size of the multiplier, and the results of this analysis would converge to those of Christiano et al. (2011). Furthermore, if the loan rate equals the policy rate, then the loan rate is zero as well, which goes against the evidence that I will present in this section. 19

20 The first subsection presents the the fiscal multiplier in the model with a constant policy interest rate. The second subsection shows evidence regarding the size of the corporate credit spread and the effects of government spending multiplier on the this spread. The third subsection then presents the numerical findings with robusntess analyses. I close by a short description of the results with the separable utility function Analytical Analyses To account for possible deviations between the loan and the policy interest rates, I assume that there is a spread (η t ) between these two rates as follows: R L,t = R t + η t (30) which, at a constant policy rate, can be rewritten in log deviations from the steady state as: R L,t = η R + η η t (31) and, since the interest rate that is relevant for consumer is R t, condition (2) remains unaltered. On the other hand, the Phillips curve is now given by: π t = β E t π t+1 + κ (ĉ t + n 1 n n t + δ R L,t ) (32) The response of the credit spread to changes in government spending is governed by: η t = Zĝ t (33) Since we have no endogenous state variable and ĝ outsides the ZLB state, all endogenous control variables jump on impact, but they revert back to their steady state values when the shock expires (i.e. when the nominal interest rate is no longer at the ZLB). For this reason, following the literature, we can write E t π t+1 = pπ t and E t ĉ t+1 = pc t, where p is the probability that the ZLB remains in effect next period, and thus the expected duration of the ZLB is T = 1 1 p. The solution then yields: g(1 βp)(1 p)[γ(σ 1) + 1] gpκ + (1 g)pκλz A = (1 βp)(1 p) pκ(1 g) [ 1 1 g + n 1 n ] (34) and the government spending multiplier will be giveb by dyt dg t = A g, with λ = η δ, which at R+η the ZLB is given by λ = η 1+ηδ. With δ = 0, which implies λ = 0, or when the borrowing costs of firms do not respond to government spending shocks (Z = 0), the constant-interest rate government spending multiplier restores that of Christiano et al. (2011). The cost channel alters the size of the multiplier, but the exact effect depends on the response of the spread to government spending shock and the strength of the cost channel. Crucially, it also depends on the size of the denominator, which will be refered to as. 20

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Michael Woodford Columbia University New Approaches to Fiscal Policy FRB Atlanta, January 8-9, 2010 Woodford (Columbia) Analytics of Multiplier

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

The New Keynesian Model

The New Keynesian Model The New Keynesian Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 1 / 37 Research strategy policy as systematic and predictable...the central bank s stabilization

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Margarita Rubio 1 Fang Yao 2 1 University of Nottingham 2 Reserve Bank of New Zealand. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions Matthew Canzoneri Fabrice Collard Harris Dellas Behzad Diba March 10, 2015 Matthew Canzoneri Fabrice Collard Harris Dellas Fiscal Behzad Multipliers Diba (University in

More information

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence Insu Kim University of California, Riverside October 29 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/18345/ MPRA Paper No.

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 Monetary Economics Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 2014 1 This class Monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler and J. David López-Salido Preliminary draft, June 2001 Abstract Galí and Gertler (1999) developed a hybrid

More information

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6 Contents 1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) 2 1.1 Question (a).................................................... 2 1.2 Question (b).................................................... 6 2 Countercyclical

More information

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates at the effective lower bound for interest rates Bank of England 12 March 2010 Plan Introduction The model The policy problem Results Summary & conclusions Plan Introduction Motivation Aims and scope The

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 1 / 52 Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba 2 / 52 Policy Practice Motivation Standard policy practice: Fiscal expansions during recessions as a means of stimulating

More information

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy Matthieu Lemoine and Jesper Lindé Banque de France and Sveriges Riksbank The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those

More information

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno,

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model Jordi Gali Monetary Policy, inflation, and the business cycle Lian Allub 15/12/2009 In The Classical Monetary economy we have perfect competition and fully flexible prices in all markets. Here there is

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB of New York 1 Michael Woodford Columbia University National Bank of Belgium, October 28 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not necessarily re ect the position

More information

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014 Macroeconomics Basic New Keynesian Model Nicola Viegi April 29, 2014 The Problem I Short run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks I I I persistent e ects on real variables slow adjustment of aggregate price

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money

More information

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound? Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound? Jianjun Miao Phuong V. Ngo October 28, 214 Abstract This paper compares the Calvo model with the Rotemberg model in a fully nonlinear dynamic new Keynesian

More information

DISCUSSION OF NON-INFLATIONARY DEMAND DRIVEN BUSINESS CYCLES, BY BEAUDRY AND PORTIER. 1. Introduction

DISCUSSION OF NON-INFLATIONARY DEMAND DRIVEN BUSINESS CYCLES, BY BEAUDRY AND PORTIER. 1. Introduction DISCUSSION OF NON-INFLATIONARY DEMAND DRIVEN BUSINESS CYCLES, BY BEAUDRY AND PORTIER GIORGIO E. PRIMICERI 1. Introduction The paper by Beaudry and Portier (BP) is motivated by two stylized facts concerning

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) Credit Frictions and

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SIMPLE ANALYTICS OF THE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIER. Michael Woodford

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SIMPLE ANALYTICS OF THE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIER. Michael Woodford NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SIMPLE ANALYTICS OF THE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIER Michael Woodford Working Paper 15714 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15714 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy and Imperfect Financial Markets: A Case for Negative Nominal Interest Rates?

Optimal Monetary Policy and Imperfect Financial Markets: A Case for Negative Nominal Interest Rates? Optimal Monetary Policy and Imperfect Financial Markets: A Case for Negative Nominal Interest Rates? Salem Abo-Zaid Department of Economics Texas Tech University Julio Garín Department of Economics University

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop, Mendoza (AER) Sudden Stop facts 1. Large, abrupt reversals in capital flows 2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic production, absorption, asset prices, credit & leverage 3. Capital,

More information

Interest Rate Peg. Rong Li and Xiaohui Tian. January Abstract. This paper revisits the sizes of fiscal multipliers under a pegged nominal

Interest Rate Peg. Rong Li and Xiaohui Tian. January Abstract. This paper revisits the sizes of fiscal multipliers under a pegged nominal Spending Reversals and Fiscal Multipliers under an Interest Rate Peg Rong Li and Xiaohui Tian January 2015 Abstract This paper revisits the sizes of fiscal multipliers under a pegged nominal interest rate.

More information

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Michael Woodford Columbia University January 1, 2010 Abstract This paper explains the key factors that determine the effectiveness of government

More information

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux Online Appendix: Non-cooperative Loss Function Section 7 of the text reports the results for

More information

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility Luca Dedola and Anton Nakov ECB and CEPR May 24 Dedola and Nakov (ECB and CEPR) SDP and the Paradox of Flexibility 5/4 / 28 Policy rates in major

More information

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance (J.Gali et al., JME 2003) Miguel Angel Alcobendas, Laura Desplans, Dong Hee Joe March 5, 2010 M.A.Alcobendas, L. Desplans, D.H.Joe

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

A Model with Costly-State Verification

A Model with Costly-State Verification A Model with Costly-State Verification Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 19, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 1 / 47 A Model with Costly-State

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model Glenn D. Rudebusch Eric T. Swanson Economic Research Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco John Taylor s Contributions to Monetary Theory and Policy Federal

More information

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania Vol. 3, No.3, July 2013, pp. 365 371 ISSN: 2225-8329 2013 HRMARS www.hrmars.com The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania Ana-Maria SANDICA

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Economics 3307 - Intermediate Macroeconomics Aaron Hedlund Baylor University Fall 2013 Econ 3307 (Baylor University) The Real Business Cycle Model Fall 2013 1 / 23 Business

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier.

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier. Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Michael Woodford Discussion Paper No.: 0910-09 Department of Economics Columbia

More information

Is Government Spending: at the Zero Lower Bound Desirable?

Is Government Spending: at the Zero Lower Bound Desirable? Is Government Spending: at the Zero Lower Bound Desirable? Florin Bilbiie (Paris School of Economics and CEPR) Tommaso Monacelli (Università Bocconi, IGIER and CEPR), Roberto Perotti (Università Bocconi,

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont) Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont) 1 New Keynesian Model Demand is an Euler equation x t = E t x t+1 ( ) 1 σ (i t E t π t+1 ) + u t Supply is New Keynesian Phillips Curve π

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 5 - Money Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 February A brief history of money in macro 1. 1. Hume: money has a wealth effect more money increase in aggregate demand Y 2. Friedman

More information

Stefan Kühn, Joan Muysken, Tom van Veen. Government Spending in a New Keynesian Endogenous Growth Model RM/10/001

Stefan Kühn, Joan Muysken, Tom van Veen. Government Spending in a New Keynesian Endogenous Growth Model RM/10/001 Stefan Kühn, Joan Muysken, Tom van Veen Government Spending in a New Keynesian Endogenous Growth Model RM/10/001 Government Spending in a New Keynesian Endogenous Growth Model Stefan Kühn Joan Muysken

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools Andrea Ferrero Richard Harrison Benjamin Nelson University of Oxford Bank of England Rokos Capital 20 th Central Bank Macroeconomic Modeling

More information

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Christopher J. Erceg and Jesper Lindé Federal Reserve Board October, 2012 Erceg and Lindé (Federal Reserve Board) Fiscal Consolidations

More information

The new Kenesian model

The new Kenesian model The new Kenesian model Michaª Brzoza-Brzezina Warsaw School of Economics 1 / 4 Flexible vs. sticky prices Central assumption in the (neo)classical economics: Prices (of goods and factor services) are fully

More information

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II ECON 815 A Basic New Keynesian Model II Winter 2015 Queen s University ECON 815 1 Unemployment vs. Inflation 12 10 Unemployment 8 6 4 2 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Core Inflation 14 12 10 Unemployment

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1 Contents Preface xvii 1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1 1.1 Measuring Business Cycles 1 1.2 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 4 1.3 Business Cycles in Poor, Emerging, and Rich Countries 7 1.4

More information

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function Eurilton Araújo Insper Working Paper WPE: 23/2008 Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy Iklaga, Fred Ogli University of Surrey f.iklaga@surrey.ac.uk Presented at the 33rd USAEE/IAEE North American Conference, October 25-28,

More information

The Zero Bound and Fiscal Policy

The Zero Bound and Fiscal Policy The Zero Bound and Fiscal Policy Based on work by: Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003, The Zero Interest Rate Bound and Optimal Monetary Policy, Brookings Panel on Economic Activity. Christiano, Eichenbaum,

More information

Quadratic Labor Adjustment Costs and the New-Keynesian Model. by Wolfgang Lechthaler and Dennis Snower

Quadratic Labor Adjustment Costs and the New-Keynesian Model. by Wolfgang Lechthaler and Dennis Snower Quadratic Labor Adjustment Costs and the New-Keynesian Model by Wolfgang Lechthaler and Dennis Snower No. 1453 October 2008 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Düsternbrooker Weg 120, 24105 Kiel, Germany

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44 TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Marija Vukotić Banque de France NBS, April 27, 2012 NBS, April 27, 2012 1 / 44 Motivation 1 Well Known Facts about the

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes Christopher J. Erceg and Jesper Lindé Federal Reserve Board June, 2011 Erceg and Lindé (Federal Reserve Board) Fiscal Consolidations

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER MFM Summer Camp June 12, 2016 DISCLAIMER: The views expressed are solely the responsibility of the authors and

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Virginia Olivella and Jose Ignacio Lopez October 2008 Motivation Menu costs and repricing decisions Micro foundation of sticky

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

State-Dependent Output and Welfare Effects of Tax Shocks

State-Dependent Output and Welfare Effects of Tax Shocks State-Dependent Output and Welfare Effects of Tax Shocks Eric Sims University of Notre Dame NBER, and ifo Jonathan Wolff University of Notre Dame July 15, 2014 Abstract This paper studies the output and

More information

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Proceedings of 3th International Conference Mathematical Methods in Economics DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data Introduction Miroslav Hloušek Abstract. Czech data shows positive

More information

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation Le Thanh Ha (GRIPS) (30 th March 2017) 1. Introduction Exercises

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade Money Macro and Finance Research Group 47 th Annual Conference Jonathan Benchimol 1 This presentation does not necessarily reflect the views of

More information

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models By Mohamed Safouane Ben Aïssa CEDERS & GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée & Université Paris X-anterre

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound? Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound? Jianjun Miao Phuong V. Ngo December 3, 214 Abstract This paper compares the Calvo model with the Rotemberg model in a fully nonlinear dynamic new Keynesian

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy

Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy Eric M. Leeper & Xuan Zhou Indiana University 5 August 2013 KDI Journal of Economic Policy Conference Policy Institution Arrangements Advanced economies

More information

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10 Macro II John Hassler Spring 27 John Hassler () New Keynesian Model: 4/7 / New Keynesian Model The RBC model worked (perhaps surprisingly) well. But there are problems in generating enough variation in

More information

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan Mathilde Le Moigne 1 Francesco Saraceno 2,3 Sébastien Villemot 2 1 École Normale Supérieure 2 OFCE Sciences Po 3 LUISS-SEP

More information

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT Discussion Paper No. 779 A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT Ryu-ichiro Murota Yoshiyasu Ono June 2010 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka University

More information

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh * Journal of Monetary Economics Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for monetary policy in Japan Carl E. Walsh * Department of Economics, University of California,

More information

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions DSGE Models with Financial Frictions Simon Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER September 2014 Overview OLG Model New Keynesian Model with Capital New Keynesian Model with Financial Accelerator Introduction

More information

A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 11 A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright Chapter 11 Topics Construct a real intertemporal model that will serve as a basis for studying money and business cycles in Chapters 12-14.

More information

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime Dennis Bonam Jasper Lukkezen Structure 1. Theoretical predictions 2. Empirical evidence 3. Our model SOE NK DSGE model (Galì and

More information

Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy

Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy Behzad Diba Georgetown University May 2013 (Institute) Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Stabilization Policy May 2013 1 / 19 New Keynesian Models Over a

More information

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary) The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary) Yunfan Gu August 28, 2017 Abstract It is documented that over the past 60 years, the safe assets as a percentage share of total assets in the U.S. has

More information

Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES)

Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES) Aleš Maršál (NBS) Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES) Modern Tools for Financial Analysis and ing - Matlab 4.6.2015 Outline Calibration output stabilization spending reversals Table : Impact of QE

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities 14.452. Topic 7. Nominal rigidities Olivier Blanchard April 2007 Nr. 1 1. Motivation, and organization Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? In monetary models, the price level (the

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve Econometrics II Fall 2017 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve The Case: Inflation tends to be pro-cycical with high inflation during times of

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates Bank of Japan Working Paper Series Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates Tomohiro Sugo * sugo@troi.cc.rochester.edu Yuki Teranishi ** yuuki.teranishi

More information

Risk Shocks and Economic Fluctuations. Summary of work by Christiano, Motto and Rostagno

Risk Shocks and Economic Fluctuations. Summary of work by Christiano, Motto and Rostagno Risk Shocks and Economic Fluctuations Summary of work by Christiano, Motto and Rostagno Outline Simple summary of standard New Keynesian DSGE model (CEE, JPE 2005 model). Modifications to introduce CSV

More information