Consumption-Based Asset Pricing with Higher Cumulants

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Consumption-Based Asset Pricing with Higher Cumulants"

Transcription

1 Review of Economic Studies (2013) 80, doi: /restud/rds029 The Author Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Review of Economic Studies Limited. Advance access publication 10 September 2012 Consumption-Based Asset Pricing with Higher Cumulants IAN W. R. MARTIN Graduate School of Business, Stanford University First version received January 2009; final version accepted April 2012 (Eds.) I extend the Epstein Zin-lognormal consumption-based asset-pricing model to allow for general i.i.d. consumption growth. Information about the higher moments equivalently, cumulants of consumption growth is encoded in the cumulant-generating function. I use the framework to analyse economies with rare disasters, and argue that the importance of such disasters is a double-edged sword: parameters that govern the frequency and sizes of rare disasters are critically important for asset pricing, but extremely hard to calibrate. I show how to sidestep this issue by using observable asset prices to make inferences without having to estimate higher moments of the underlying consumption process. Extensions of the model allow consumption to diverge from dividends, and for non-i.i.d. consumption growth. Keywords: Consumption-based asset pricing, Rare disasters, Cumulants JEL Codes: G10, E44. The combination of power utility and i.i.d. lognormal consumption growth makes for a tractable benchmark model in which asset prices and expected returns can be found in closed form. This article demonstrates that the lognormality assumption can be dropped without sacrificing tractability, thereby allowing for straightforward and flexible analysis of the possibility that, say, consumption is subject to rare disasters. There has recently been considerable interest in reviving the idea of Rietz (1988) that the presence of such disasters, or fat tails more generally, can help to explain asset pricing phenomena such as the riskless rate, equity premium and other puzzles (Barro, 2006; Jurek, 2008). Here, I take a different line, closer in spirit to Weitzman (2007), and argue that the importance of rare, extreme events is a double-edged sword: those model parameters that are most important for asset prices, such as disaster parameters, are also the hardest to calibrate, precisely because the disasters in question are rare. Working under the assumptions that there is a representative agent with Epstein Zin preferences (Epstein and Zin, 1989) and that consumption growth is i.i.d., Section 1 shows that the equity premium, riskless rate, consumption wealth ratio and mean consumption growth (the fundamental quantities ) can be simply expressed in terms of the cumulant-generating function (CGF). CGFs crop up elsewhere in the literature; one contribution of this article is to demonstrate how neatly they dovetail with the standard consumption-based asset-pricing approach. Importantly, the framework allows for the possibility of disasters, but is agnostic about whether or not they occur. The expressions derived relate the fundamental quantities directly to the cumulants (equivalently, moments) of consumption growth. I show, for example, how the precautionary savings effect, which influences the riskless rate in a lognormal model, 745

2 746 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES can be generalized in the presence of higher cumulants. By shifting the focus from moments to cumulants, I retain tractability without needing to truncate Taylor expansions (as in, say, Kraus and Litzenberger, 1976), to avoid the critique of Brockett and Kahane (1992). Section 2 illustrates the framework by investigating a continuous-time model featuring rare disasters, and shows that the model s predictions are sensitively dependent on the calibration assumed. As a stark example, take a consumption-based model in which the representative agent has relative risk aversion equal to 4. Now add to the model a certain type of disaster that strikes, on average, once every 1,000 years, and reduces consumption by 64 per cent. (Barro (2006) documents that Germany and Greece each suffered such a fall in per capita real GDP during the Second World War.) The introduction of this disaster drives the riskless rate down by 5.9 percentage points and increases the equity premium by 3.7%. 1 Very rare, very severe events exert an extraordinary influence on the benchmark model, and we do not expect to estimate their frequency and intensity directly from the data. I document this more formally in Section 2.2, where I present the results of a GMM exercise as in Hansen and Singleton (1982). I use samples consisting of 100 years of simulated data in the model economy with disasters, and show that in such a relatively short sample, GMM leads to biased and extremely inaccurate estimators of the true population parameters. In economies with still fatter tails, GMM may not be valid even asymptotically. The remainder of this article is devoted to finding ways around this disheartening fact. We can, for example, detect the influence of disaster events indirectly, by observing asset prices. I argue, therefore, that the standard approach calibrating a particular model and trying to fit the fundamental quantities is not the way to go. I turn things round, viewing the fundamental quantities as observables, and making inferences from them. It then becomes possible to make non-parametric statements that are robust to the details of the consumption growth process. In this spirit, I derive, in Section 3, sharp and robust restrictions on preference parameters that are valid in any Epstein Zin-i.i.d. model that is consistent with the observed fundamentals. The key idea is to exploit an important property of CGFs: they are always convex. The results restrict the time-preference rate, ρ, and elasticity of intertemporal substitution, ψ, to lie in a certain subset of the positive quadrant. (See Figure 7.) These parameters are of central importance for financial and macroeconomic models. The restrictions depend only on the Epstein Zin-i.i.d. assumptions and on observed values of the fundamental quantities, and not, for example, on any assumptions about the existence, frequency or size of disasters. They are complementary to econometric or experimental estimates of ψ and ρ, and are of particular interest because there is little agreement about the value of ψ. (Campbell (2003) summarizes the conflicting evidence.) I also show how good-deal bounds (Cochrane and Saá-Requejo, 2000) can be used to provide upper bounds on risk aversion, based once again on the fundamental quantities, without calibrating a consumption process. Why work with cumulants and CGFs, rather than with moments and moment-generating functions? Aside from the fact that they are what drop out of the algebra, cumulants are in many respects more intuitive than moments. The first cumulant is the mean; the second is variance, σ 2 ; the third and fourth cumulants are skewness times σ 3 and excess kurtosis times σ 4, respectively. These are easier to grasp intuitively than the corresponding non-central moments. A second, equally important, reason is that CGFs have the convexity property mentioned above. Momentgenerating functions (as exponentials of CGFs) are convex too, but this is a much cruder, and therefore less useful, fact. 1. The effect is smaller with Epstein Zin preferences if the elasticity of substitution is greater than 1, but even with an elasticity of intertemporal substitution equal to 2, the riskless rate drops by 3.5%.

3 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 747 Section 4 extends the analysis in two directions. The majority of the article sets dividends equal to consumption or adopts the highly tractable approach, taken by Campbell (1986, 2003) and also advocated by Abel (1999), of modelling dividends as a power of consumption. However, several authors have argued for the importance of allowing log consumption and log dividends to be imperfectly correlated. 2 Section 4.1 shows how the CGF approach can be extended to allow for this possibility, and presents a heterogeneous-agent model as a motivating application. Consistent with the argument of the rest of the article, I find that heterogeneity is a double-edged sword. The good news is that heterogeneity interacts well with disasters in the sense that it can potentially give a huge boost to risk premia. The bad news is that heterogeneity only matters to the extent to which it occurs at times of aggregate disaster, so the fundamental empirical difficulty highlighted in the rest of the paper is not avoided. Again, though, it is possible to make statements that are robust to what is going on in the tails. Finally, although presumably the framework is a good approximation to reality over time horizons long enough that the economy looks roughly i.i.d., it is of interest to weaken the i.i.d. assumption, and I do so in Section 4.2. When not included in the body of the article, proofs are in the appendix. Related literature. Campbell and Cochrane (1999) and Bansal and Yaron (2004) modify the textbook model along different dimensions, but take care to remain in a conditionally lognormal environment. This article explores different features, and implications, of the data, so is complementary to their work. It would, of course, be interesting to extend these papers by allowing for the possibility of jumps, but doing so would obscure the main point of this article. Various authors have presented analytical solutions in similar models. Eraker (2008) prices assets from the perspective of an Epstein Zin representative agent, but relies on a loglinearization of the return on aggregate wealth for tractability. This approximation is likely to be particularly problematic in a disaster model in which aggregate wealth may experience severe declines. Bonomo et al. (2011) provide analytical pricing formulas in a long-run risks environment with generalized disappointment aversion, although their focus is not on rare disasters. Martin (2011, 2013) uses CGFs in multi-asset models in which consumption growth is not i.i.d. A large body of literature applies Lévy processes to derivative pricing (Carr and Madan, 1998, Cont and Tankov, 2004) and portfolio choice (Cvitanić, Polimenis, and Zapatero, 2005, Aït-Sahalia, Cacho-Diaz, and Hurd, 2006). Lustig, Van Nieuwerburgh, and Verdelhan (2008) present estimates of the wealth consumption ratio. Backus, Foresi, and Telmer (2001) derive expressions relating cumulants to risk premia, though their approach is very different from that taken here. Garcia, Luger, and Renault (2003) expand the range of assets, using options prices to obtain information about preference parameters, though they work in a conditionally lognormal framework. Backus, Chernov, and Martin (2011) explore the evidence for disasters in option prices, but leave unresolved the finding of Coval and Shumway (2001) that all option prices, at-the-money options included, appear mysteriously high. Why might this be? Perhaps because at-the-money put options are assets with potentially enormous payoffs in the very bad times we do not have enough of in the data. (If so, at-the-money calls would also look expensive, by putcall parity.) Julliard and Ghosh (2008) argue that the cross-section of asset price data is hard to square with disaster explanations of the equity premium. Consistent with the above discussion, 2. For example, Cecchetti, Lam, and Mark (1993), Bonomo and Garcia (1996), Campbell and Cochrane (1999), Longstaff and Piazzesi (2004), and Bansal and Yaron (2004). With the exception of Longstaff and Piazzesi (2004), consumption and dividends are not cointegrated in any of these papers.

4 748 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES their parameter estimates have large standard errors. They also carry out a Generalized Empirical Likelihood estimation whose results are similar to those of Section ASSET PRICING AND THE CGF Define G t logc t /C 0 and write G G 1. I make two assumptions. A1 There is a representative agent with Epstein Zin preferences, time preference rate ρ, relative risk aversion γ, and elasticity of intertemporal substitution ψ. A2 The consumption growth, logc t /C t 1, of the representative agent is (or is perceived to be) i.i.d., and the CGF of G (defined below) exists on a neighbourhood of [ γ,1]. 3 Assumption A1 allows risk aversion γ to be disentangled from the elasticity of intertemporal substitution ψ. To keep things simple, those calculations that appear in the main text restrict to the power utility case in which ψ is constrained to equal 1/γ ; in this case, the representative agent maximizes ρt C1 γ t E e 1 γ t=0 if γ =1, or E e ρt logc t if γ =1. t=0 Cogley (1990) and Barro (2009) present evidence in support of A2 in the form of variance-ratio statistics close to one, on average, across 9 (Cogley) or 19 (Barro) countries. We need expected utility to be well defined in that C1 γ t E e ρt < if γ =1. (1) 1 γ t=0 I discuss this requirement further below. Consider an asset that pays dividend stream {D t } t 0. The Euler equation relates the price of an asset this period, P 0, to the payoff next period, P 1 +D 1. Expectations are calculated with respect to the measure perceived by the representative agent: P 0 =E 0 ( ( ) γ e ρ C1 (D 1 +P 1 )). C 0 Iterating forward and imposing a no-bubble condition, we have the familiar equation P 0 =E ( t=1 ( ) ) γ e ρt Ct D t. C 0 Suppose that D t (C t ) λ for some constant λ. Ifλ=0 then the asset is a riskless bond; if λ=1 then it is the wealth portfolio that pays consumption as its dividend. As suggested by 3. If not, the consumption-based asset-pricing approach is invalid. This assumption implies that all cumulants, and hence all moments, of G are finite. See Billingsley(1995, Section 21).

5 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 749 Campbell (1986, 2003) and Abel (1999), it is possible to view values λ>1 as a tractable way of modelling levered claims. Writing P 0 for the price of this asset at time 0, we have ( ) γ P 0 =E e ρt Ct C λ t =D 0 e ρt Ee (λ γ )G ( t =D 0 e ρt Ee (λ γ )G) t. (2) C t=1 0 t=1 t=1 The last equality follows from the assumption that log consumption growth is i.i.d. To make further progress, I now introduce a pair of definitions. Definition 1. Given some arbitrary random variable, G, the moment-generating function m(θ) and cumulant-generating function or CGF c(θ) are defined by for all θ for which the expectations are finite. m(θ) Eexp(θG) c(θ) logeexp(θg), Here, G is an annual increment of log consumption, G=logC t+1 logc t. Notice that c(0)=0 for any growth process and that c(1) is equal to log mean gross consumption growth, so we will want c(1) 2%. The CGF summarizes information about the cumulants (or, equivalently, moments) of G. We can expand c(θ) as a power series in θ, κ n θ n c(θ)=, (3) n! n=1 which defines κ n as the n-th cumulant of log consumption growth. Some algebra shows that the first few cumulants are familiar: κ 1 μ is the mean, κ 2 σ 2 the variance, κ 3 /σ 3 the skewness, and κ 4 /σ 4 the excess kurtosis of log consumption growth. Knowledge of the cumulants of a random variable implies knowledge of the moments, and vice versa. With this definition, (2) becomes P 0 =D 0 e [ρ c(λ γ )]t e [ρ c(λ γ )] =D 0. 1 e [ρ c(λ γ )] t=1 It is convenient to define the log dividend yield d/p log(1+d 0 /P 0 ). Then, d/p=ρ c(λ γ ). Two special cases are of particular interest. The first is λ=0, in which case the asset in question is the riskless bond, whose dividend yield is the riskless rate R f. Again, it is convenient to work with the log riskless rate, r f =log(1+r f ). The above calculation shows that r f =ρ c( γ ). The second is λ=1, in which case the asset pays consumption as its dividend, and can therefore be interpreted as aggregate wealth. The dividend yield is then the consumption wealth ratio; when λ=1, I write c/w in place of d/p. This calculation also shows that the necessary restriction on consumption growth for the expected utility to be well defined in (1) is that ρ c(1 γ )>0, or equivalently that the consumption wealth ratio is positive. The gross return on the λ-asset is 1+R t+1 = D t+1 +P t+1 = P ( t+1 1+ D ) t+1 = D ( t+1 e ρ c(λ γ )), P t P t P t+1 D t so the expected gross return is ( (Ct+1 ) ) λ 1+ER t+1 =E e ρ c(λ γ ) =e ρ c(λ γ )+c(λ). C t

6 750 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES Once again, it is more convenient to work with log expected gross return, er log(1+ ER t+1 )=ρ +c(λ) c(λ γ ). Finally, I define the risk premium rp=er r f. The following result summarizes and extends the above calculations by expressing the riskless rate, dividend yield, and risk premium in terms of the CGF in the Epstein Zin case. Result 1. Defining ϑ (1 γ )/(1 1/ψ), we have r f = ρ c( γ )+c(1 γ )(1 1/ϑ) (4) d/p = ρ c(λ γ )+c(1 γ )(1 1/ϑ) (5) rp = c(λ)+c( γ ) c(λ γ ). (6) The Gordon growth model holds (note that c(λ)=loge(d t+1 /D t )): d/p=rp+r f c(λ). (7) The consumption wealth ratio c/w is given by (5) with λ=1. As in the power utility case, these expressions are well defined so long as c/w>0. Equation (6) shows that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution does not affect the risk premium. It also shows that the CGF of the driving consumption process must have a significant amount of convexity over the range [ γ,λ] to generate an empirically reasonable risk premium. These expressions can be written out as power series using (3). In the power utility case, for example, Equation (4) implies that r f =ρ +κ 1 γ κ 2 2 γ 2 + κ 3 3! γ 3 κ 4 4! γ 4 +higher order terms. By definition of the first four cumulants, this can be rewritten as r f =ρ +μγ 1 2 σ 2 γ 2 + skewness σ 3 γ 3 3! excess kurtosis σ 4 γ 4 +higher order terms. (8) 4! If consumption growth is lognormal, skewness, excess kurtosis, and all higher cumulants are zero, so this reduces to the familiar r f =ρ +μγ σ 2 γ 2 /2. More generally, the riskless rate is low if mean log consumption growth μ is low (an intertemporal substitution effect); if the variance of log consumption growth σ 2 is high (a precautionary savings effect); if there is negative skewness; or if there is a high degree of kurtosis. Similarly, the dividend yield is d/p = ρ +μ(γ λ) 1 2 σ 2 (γ λ) 2 + skewness σ 3 (γ λ) 3 3! excess kurtosis σ 4 (γ λ) 4 +higher order terms, 4! and the risk premium (in either the power utility or the Epstein Zin case) is rp = λγ σ 2 + skewness σ 3( λ 3 γ 3 (λ γ ) 3) + 3! excess kurtosis + σ 4( λ 4 +γ 4 (λ γ ) 4) +higher order terms. 4!

7 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 751 To understand what happens with Epstein Zin preferences, it is helpful to focus on the case λ=1,γ >1. (The logic is the same if λ =1; some signs are reversed if γ<1.) The coefficients on κ n /n! in the power series expansions are r f : ( 1) n+1 γ n +( 1) n (γ 1) n (1 1/ϑ) c/w: ( 1) n+1 (γ 1) n /ϑ rp: 1+( 1) n γ n +( 1) n+1 (γ 1) n c(1): 1 The Gordon growth formula (7) implies that the n-th coefficient for c/w is equal to the n-th coefficient for r f, plus that for rp, minus that for (log) expected consumption growth, c(1). So it suffices to understand the comparative statics of the risk premium and of the riskless rate. The comparative statics of the risk premium are the same in the power utility and Epstein Zin cases. The n-th coefficient is 1+( 1) n γ n +( 1) n+1 (γ 1) n. The third of these terms is smaller in magnitude than the second, but has the opposite sign, so exerts an offsetting effect. Thus the n-th coefficient is positive for even n 2: the risk premium is increasing in variance and higher even cumulants. For odd n 3, the coefficient is negative, so the risk premium is decreasing in skewness and higher odd cumulants. The comparative statics of the riskless rate depend on both ψ and γ. With power utility, the n-th coefficient in the expansion of r f is ( 1) n+1 γ n. This is positive if n is odd and negative if n is even, leading to the comparative statics discussed below Equation (8). There is no offsetting term in (γ 1) n, so the riskless rate is more sensitively dependent on higher cumulants than the risk premium. In the Epstein Zin case, we gain an extra term ( 1) n (γ 1) n (1 1/ϑ). If ψ =1 then 1/ϑ =0 and the n-th coefficient is ( 1) n+1 γ n +( 1) n (γ 1) n, which does have the offsetting term, resulting in a riskless rate that is less sensitively dependent on the higher cumulants than in the power utility case. More generally, if 1/ϑ <0 if γ>1 and ψ>1 then for small n the term ( 1) n (γ 1) n (1 1/ϑ) may even dominate. For large n, though, the first term always prevails, so the riskless rate depends less sensitively on high cumulants than it does in the power utility case. We are now in a position to understand the comparative statics of the consumption wealth ratio. With power utility, the riskless rate is the dominant influence: it is increasing in odd cumulants and decreasing in even cumulants, and the consumption wealth ratio inherits that property. With Epstein Zin preferences and 1 1/ϑ > 0 i.e. ψ > 1/γ, assuming γ > 1 the effects of higher cumulants on the riskless rate are muted. If ψ =1, the movements of the riskless rate exactly offset the movements of the risk premium, so that the consumption wealth ratio is constant. If ψ>1, so that 1/ϑ <0, then the risk premium effect is dominant; the consumption wealth ratio is then increasing in even cumulants and decreasing in odd cumulants. Put differently, larger even cumulants lead to a lower wealth consumption ratio; this is an important component of Bansal and Yaron s (2004) long-run risk model. Equations (4) (6), together with the Gordon growth model (7), provide another way to look at a point made by Kocherlakota (1990). In principle, given sufficient asset price and consumption data, we could determine the riskless rate, the risk premium, and CGF c( ) to arbitrary accuracy. Since γ is the only preference parameter that determines the risk premium, it could be calculated from (6), given knowledge of c( ). On the other hand, knowledge of the riskless rate leaves ρ and ψ indeterminate in Equation (4), even given knowledge of γ and c( ). So the time discount rate and elasticity of intertemporal substitution cannot be disentangled on the basis of the four fundamental quantities.

8 752 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES 2. THE CONTINUOUS-TIME CASE In continuous time, the analogue of the i.i.d. growth assumption is that the log consumption path, G t, of the representative agent follows a Lévy process. If so, Ee θg t = ( Ee θg) t for arbitrary t 0. Given this property, we have the following result in the limit as the period length dt (which was equal to one in the discrete-time calculations) goes to zero. Result 2 (The continuous-time case). The instantaneous riskless rate, R f, dividend yield, D/P, and instantaneous risk premium on aggregate wealth, RP, are R f = ρ c( γ )+c(1 γ )(1 1/ϑ) D/P = ρ c(λ γ )+c(1 γ )(1 1/ϑ) RP = c(λ)+c( γ ) c(λ γ ). The Gordon growth model holds: D/P =R f +RP c(λ) A concrete example: disasters In this section, I show how to derive a convenient continuous-time version of Barro (2006), and show that the predictions of an i.i.d. disaster model are sensitively dependent on the parameter values assumed. Suppose that log consumption follows a jump-diffusion N(t) G t = μt +σ B B t + Y i i=1 where B t is a Brownian motion, N(t) is a Poisson counting process with parameter ω, and Y i are i.i.d. random variables. The CGF is c(θ)=logm(θ), where m(θ)=ee θg 1 =e μθ Ee σ BθB1 Ee θ N(1) i=1 Y i. Separating the expectation into two separate products is legitimate since the Poisson jumps and Y i are independent of the Brownian component B t. The middle term is the expectation of a lognormal random variable: Ee θσ BB 1 =e σ B 2θ 2 /2. The final term is slightly more complicated, but can be evaluated by conditioning on the number of jumps that take place before t =1: N(1) Eexp θ { } Y i = e ω ω n n Eexp θ Y i n! i=1 0 1 e ω ω n = [Eexp{θY 1 }] n n! 0 = exp { ω ( m Y1 (θ) 1 )}, Finally, c(θ)= μθ +σb 2θ 2 /2+ω ( m Y1 (θ) 1 ), so the cumulants κ n (G)=c (n) (0) are μ+ω EY n=1 κ n (G)= σ B 2 +ω EY 2 n=2 ω EY n n 3.

9 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 753 (a) (b) Figure 1 (a) The CGF with (solid) and without (dashed) jumps. The figure assumes that ρ =0.03 and γ =4. (b) Zooming out. Without jumps, we need enormously high γ to avoid the riskless rate and equity premium puzzles Figure 2 The risk premium. The figure assumes that γ =4 Take the case in which Y N( b,s 2 ); b is assumed to be greater than zero, so the jumps represent disasters. The CGF is then c(θ)= μθ σ 2 B θ 2 +ω(e θb+ 1 2 θ 2 s 2 1). (9) Figure 1a plots the CGF (9) against θ. I choose parameters according to Barro s (2006) baseline calibration γ =4,σ B =0.02,ρ=0.03, μ=0.025,ω=0.017 and set b=0.39 and s=0.25 to match the mean and variance of the distribution of jumps used in the same paper. I also plot the CGF that results in the absence of jumps (ω =0). In the latter case, I adjust the drift of consumption growth to keep mean log consumption growth constant; in the figure, this means that the two curves are tangent at the origin. Zooming out on Figure 1a, we obtain Figure 1b, which further illustrates the equity premium and riskless rate puzzles. With jumps, the CGF is visible at the right-hand side of the figure; the CGF explodes so quickly as θ declines that it is only visible for θ greater than about 5. The jump-free lognormal CGF has incredibly low curvature. For a realistic riskless rate and equity premium, the model requires a risk aversion above 80.

10 754 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES TABLE 1 The impact of different assumptions about the distribution of disasters ω b s R f C/W RP R f C/W RP Baseline case High ω Low ω High b Low b High s Low s μ=0.025, σ =0.02. Unasterisked group assumes power utility, ρ =0.03, γ =4. Asterisked group assumes Epstein Zin preferences, ρ =0.03, γ =4, ψ =1.5. TABLE 2 The impact of approximating the disaster model by truncating at the n-th cumulant n R f C/W RP R f C/W RP 1 deterministic lognormal true model Unasterisked group assumes power utility; asterisked group assumes Epstein Zin preferences. All parameters as in baseline case of Table 1. The riskless rate, consumption wealth ratio, and mean consumption growth can be read directly off the graph, as indicated by the arrows in Figure 1a. The risk premium can be calculated from these via the Gordon growth formula, or read directly off the graph, as in Figure 2, by drawing a line from ( γ,c( γ )) to (1,c(1)) and another from (1 γ,c(1 γ )) to (0,0). The midpoint of the first line lies above the midpoint of the second by convexity of the CGF. The risk premium is twice the distance from one midpoint to the other. The standard lognormal model predicts a counterfactually high riskless rate: in Figure 1a, this is reflected in the fact that the no-jumps CGF lies well below ρ for reasonable values of θ. Similarly, the standard lognormal model predicts a counterfactually low equity premium: the no-jump CGF is practically linear over the range [ γ,1]. Conversely, the disaster CGF has a shape that allows it to match observed fundamentals closely. Table 1 shows how changes in the calibration of the distribution of disasters affect the fundamental quantities. I consider the power utility case with ρ =0.03 and γ =4, and the Epstein Zin case with the same time-preference rate and risk aversion but higher elasticity of intertemporal substitution, ψ = 1.5. The model s predictions are sensitively dependent on the parameter values. Small changes in any of ω, b,ors have large effects on the equity premium (and, with power utility, on the riskless rate; this effect is muted in the Epstein Zin case). Given that these parameters are hard to estimate disasters happen very rarely this is problematic. Table 2 investigates the consequences of truncating the CGF at the n-th cumulant. When n=2, this is equivalent to making a lognormality assumption, as noted above. With n=3, it can be thought of as an approximation that accounts for the influence of skewness; n=4 also allows for kurtosis. As is clear from the table, even calculations based on fourth- or fifth-order approximations do not fully capture the impact of disasters.

11 2.2. A GMM exercise IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 755 What would estimates of ρ and γ look like if the baseline disaster model were a literal description of reality? This section carries out a GMM exercise using the baseline calibration. I simulate 100 years of annual consumption data, back out asset prices and returns using the above results, and estimate the parameters ρ and γ from the sample analogues of the moment conditions 4 [ ( ) [ γ ( ) γ E e ρ Ct+1 (R t+1 R f,t+1 )] =0 and E e ρ Ct+1 ( ) ] 1+Rf,t+1 =1. (10) C t C t These equations apply in the power utility case; the conclusions of this section also apply in the Epstein Zin case if ρ is replaced by ρ ρ +(1 1/ϑ) c(1 γ ). The moment conditions (10) identify ρ and γ in the model; see the Appendix for a proof. Explicitly, the estimates ρ and γ are computed by solving T ( ) γ Ct+1 (R t+1 R f,t+1 )=0 t=1 for γ, and using the result to determine ρ from 1 T T t=1 C t ( ) γ e ρ Ct+1 ( ) 1+Rf,t+1 =1. C t I show in the Supplementary Appendix that the standard regularity conditions hold in this calibration, so that GMM estimates are consistent and asymptotically Normal. It turns out, though, that 100 years is not enough data for these asymptotic results to apply even approximately. Figure 3 shows what happens when the GMM procedure is repeated 100,000 times. Each black dot represents an estimate ( ρ, γ ) generated from 100 years of annual data simulated in the baseline disaster calibration; for clarity, the left panel excludes 7 estimates for which γ lies above 300 (with a maximum of 416). In each of the 100,000 histories, I also compute the mean realized equity premium and mean consumption growth. Across the 100,000 histories, the sample means of these variables line up perfectly with their population counterparts, at 5.7% and 2.0% respectively, and both have a standard deviation of 0.5%. The mean estimate (ρ,γ ) =( 0.086,29.5), generated by averaging the resulting 100,000 estimates ( ρ, γ ), is marked with a white dot. (For comparison, Kocherlakota (1996) carries out the same exactly identified GMM exercise in real-world data. In my notation, he estimates ρ = and γ =17.95.) The true value (ρ,γ)=(0.03,4) is also marked with a white dot. The standard deviation of the estimates ρ is 0.426; the standard deviation of the estimates γ is 43.5; and the correlation between ρ and γ is The dashed ellipses show confidence regions within which 50% (small ellipse) and 95% (large ellipse) of the sample points would lie if the data were Normally distributed. Larger estimates of risk aversion tend to be associated with smaller estimates of the time preference rate: the procedure is struggling to match the data by increasing risk aversion, at the cost of having to assuming extreme patience in order to match the riskless 4. In this section, I assume that λ=1, so we consider the unlevered consumption claim. If the exercise is repeated with levered assets, λ>1, the results discussed below apply with even more force: the small-sample properties of the various estimators are dramatically worse. This suggests that the fact that at-the-money options appear so expensive (Coval and Shumway, 2001) might be expected to remain a puzzle even longer than the equity premium puzzle.

12 756 (a) REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES (b) Figure 3 Each of the 100,000 small black dots represents a GMM estimate of (ρ,γ ) from 100 years of simulated annual data in the disaster model. The ellipses indicate confidence regions in which 50% (inner ellipse) and 95% (outer ellipse) of the mass of the distribution of ( ρ, γ ) would lie if ( ρ, γ ) were Normally distributed. Dotted lines in each panel indicate the model-free parameter restrictions derived in Section 3: just 10 of the estimates ( ρ, γ ) lie in the lower admissible region, visible in the right-hand panel, in which γ < 1 rate. Finally, dotted lines indicate model-free parameter restrictions that will be derived in the next section. The figures demonstrate three features of GMM estimation in the disaster calibration. First, there is extraordinary dispersion in the estimates. Estimates of γ extend up to more than 400. Estimates of ρ, the time discount rate, range between about 2 and 6: in time-discount-factor ρ, these correspond to β = 7.39 and β = , respectively. Second, ρ terms, writing β = e is a downward-biased estimator of ρ and γ is an upward-biased estimator of γ. Third, the estimates ( ρ, γ ) are far from Normally distributed when using 100 years of data: the confidence ellipses utterly fail to capture the shape of the distribution. (Contrast Figure 3a with Figure 4b.) A formal test of Normality is superfluous, since amongst the 100,000 sample points there are several estimates ρ that lie more than 10 standard deviations above the mean ρ (i.e. are larger than about 4.2). The probability of a 10-sigma event under the Normal distribution is about 10 23, so even one such occurrence in 100,000 samples would be sufficient to reject the hypothesis of Normality at the % level. These conclusions are not driven by extreme outliers. Figure 4a shows the result of trimming the data by discarding the largest 5% of pairs ordered by γ. The GMM estimates are still biased (ρ,γ ) = ( 0.076,23.6) and the confidence ellipses are still large. As a sanity check, and as a contrast with the disaster calibration, Figure 4b shows what happens in a lognormal world. It reports the results of carrying out the same exercise in a calibration without disasters (ω = 0), with σb adjusted upwards so that the risk premium remains constant. As one would expect, GMM provides an accurate estimate of the underlying population parameters, and the sample distribution is approximately Normal. With more extreme specifications of disaster sizes, even worse behavior is possible (Kocherlakota, 1997). If the random variables inside the expectations in (10) do not have finite second moment, the GMM estimators are not even asymptotically Normal. In the case of the moment condition for the riskless bond, we require c( 2γ ) to be finite; in the case of the consumption claim, we require c(2 2γ ) to be finite. If the former is finite, the latter is too, so in summary the GMM approach is only valid if c( 2γ ) is finite. This is not assured by the assumptions that ensure finite utility, or a finite consol price. Below, I construct an example for [14:22 4/4/2013 rds029_online.tex] RESTUD: The Review of Economic Studies Page:

13 IAN MARTIN (a) CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 757 (b) Figure 4 (a) The message of the previous figure is unaltered if the most extreme 5% of realizations ( ρ, γ ) is discarded. (b) GMM estimates of (ρ,γ ) from 100 years of simulated annual data in a lognormal model which the GMM approach fails not only in finite samples, but even asymptotically: Figure 6b plots the CGF of (an extreme case of) such a distribution. 3. RESTRICTIONS ON PREFERENCE PARAMETERS I now assume that the riskless rate, consumption wealth ratio, and risk premium (and hence expected consumption growth, via the Gordon growth model (7)) are observable and take the values given in Table 3.5 The observables provide us with information about the shape of the CGF; this section shows how to use this information to derive restrictions on the preference parameters that must hold in any Epstein Zin/i.i.d. model, no matter what is going on in the tails. The restrictions are of particular interest when there are small sample biases, as in the previous section, and they continue to be valid when GMM breaks down entirely, as discussed at the end of the previous section. TABLE 3 Assumed values of the observables riskless rate risk premium consumption wealth ratio rf rp c/w For example, rf = ρ c( γ ) in the power utility case, so observation of the riskless rate tells us something about ρ and something about the value taken by the CGF at γ. Similarly, observation of the consumption wealth ratio tells us something about ρ and something about the value taken by the CGF at 1 γ. Next, c(1) = loge(c1 /C0 ) is pinned down by the Gordon 5. As noted in the above GMM exercise, the equity premium can be accurately estimated, even in a world with rare disasters: in the baseline calibration, the equity premium conditional on no disasters is very close to the unconditional equity premium. [14:22 4/4/2013 rds029_online.tex] RESTUD: The Review of Economic Studies Page:

14 758 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES growth formula (7), and c(0)=0 by definition. How, though, can we get control on the enormous range of possible consumption processes and CGFs? One approach is to exploit Fact 1. CGFs are convex. Proof Since c(θ)=logm(θ), we have c (θ) = m(θ) m (θ) m (θ) 2 m(θ) 2 = EeθG EG 2 e θg ( EGe θg) 2 m(θ) 2. The numerator of this expression is positive by a version of the Cauchy Schwartz inequality that states that EX 2 EY 2 E( XY ) 2 for any random variables X and Y. In this case, we need to set X =e θg/2 and Y =Ge θg/2. (See Billingsley (1995), for further discussion of this and other properties of CGFs.) This fact can be used to derive sharp preference parameter bounds based on observables. Result 3. In the power utility case, we have r f c/w c/w ρ γ 1 rp+r f c/w. (11) In the Epstein Zin case, we have r f c/w c/w ρ 1/ψ 1 rp+r f c/w. (12) Moreover, these bounds are sharp: for any ε>0 there are distributions of consumption growth, and parameter choices for ρ, γ, and ψ that are consistent with the observables and satisfy c/w ρ 1/ψ 1 <r f c/w+ε; and other distributions of consumption growth and parameter choices that are consistent with the observables and satisfy c/w ρ 1/ψ 1 >rp+r f c/w ε. Proof The result is best understood geometrically. Look at Figure 5, which plots a generic CGF: it is convex and passes through the origin. We know from Result 2 that asset prices provide information about some key points on the CGF c( γ ), c(1 γ ), and c(1) and therefore about the gradients of the dashed lines marked X, Y, and Z. Now, because c(θ) is convex, the gradients of X, Y, and Z, in that order, are increasing: c(1 γ ) c( γ ) (1 γ ) ( γ ) These inequalities can be rearranged to give c(0) c(1 γ ) 0 (1 γ ) But from Equation (5) we have, in the Epstein Zin case, c(1) c(0). 1 0 c( γ ) γ c(1 γ ) c(1). (13) 1 γ c/w ρ 1/ψ 1 = c(1 γ ) 1 γ. (14)

15 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 759 (a) Figure 5 Convexity of the CGF implies that line X has the smallest slope and line Z the largest (b) Figure 6 CGFs of two possible distributions of consumption growth that are consistent with the observables and illustrate why Putting (13) and (14) together, we have the bounds in Result 3 cannot be improved c( γ ) γ c/w ρ 1/ψ 1 c(1). The result (12) follows on rearranging the left-hand inequality using (4) and (5), and substituting out c(1) using the Gordon growth model; and (11) is a special case of (12). The detailed proof that the bounds are sharp is in the Appendix, but the main idea can be understood by comparing the generic CGF depicted in Figure 5 to the two CGFs shown in Figure 6, which indicate how the two extremes can be approximately attained. The Appendix demonstrates that there are distributions of consumption growth whose CGFs look like those in Figure 6 i.e. have the properties that (i) they are almost linear on the intervals [ γ,0] in the case represented by Figure 6a, or on [1 γ,1] in the case represented by Figure 6b; and (ii) they are consistent with the observables, which pins down c(1) and the gap c(1 γ ) c( γ ). The intuition is that as ψ approaches one, the consumption wealth ratio approaches ρ. Therefore, if the consumption wealth ratio is to be far from ρ, ψ must be far from one. Result 3 turns this qualitative statement into a quantitative one, without making assumptions about what is going on in the tails. Using the values rp=6%,r f =2%,c/w=6%, we have the restriction that

16 760 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES (a) (b) Figure 7 Parameter restrictions for i.i.d. models with rp=6%, r f =2%, and c/w=6% 0.04 (0.06 ρ)/(1/ψ 1) The shaded areas in Figure 7 illustrate where the parameters must lie. If ψ>1, then ρ is constrained to lie between 0.02 and 0.08; if also ψ<2, then ρ must lie between 0.04 and If γ =1 in the power utility case, or if ψ =1 in the Epstein Zin case, then ρ is exactly identified by the consumption wealth ratio. To the extent that D t =C λ t is a reasonable approximation of leverage, we can say even more. For, we observe the consumption wealth ratio c/w, wealth risk premium rp w and the dividend yield on the market d/p and market risk premium rp m (that is, observe (4) (6), together with the expressions that result on substituting in λ=1). The following relationships hold: By convexity, we have c/w d/p = c(λ γ ) c(1 γ ) ϑ(ρ c/w)+c/w d/p = c(λ γ ) rp m +r f d/p = c(λ) c(λ γ ) c(1 γ ) λ 1 Substituting in, we have joint bounds on ρ, γ, and ψ: c/w d/p λ 1 ϑ(ρ c/w)+c/w d/p λ γ c(λ γ ) λ γ c(λ) λ. rp m +r f d/p. λ 3.1. Hansen Jagannathan and good-deal bounds Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) derived a bound that relates the standard deviation and mean of the stochastic discount factor, M, to the Sharpe ratio on an arbitrary asset, SR: SR σ (M) EM. (15) In the Epstein Zin-i.i.d. setting, the right-hand side of (15) becomes σ (M) EM = EM 2 (EM) 2 1 = e c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ) 1. (16)

17 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 761 Combining (15) and (16), we obtain the Hansen Jagannathan bound in CGF notation: ( log 1+SR 2) c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ). (17) Cochrane and Saá-Requejo (2000) observe that inequality (15) suggests a natural way to restrict asset-pricing models. Suppose σ (M)/EM h; then (15) implies that the maximal Sharpe ratio is less than h. In CGF notation, the good-deal bound is written ( c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ) log 1+h 2). (18) Suppose, for example, that we wish to impose the restriction that Sharpe ratios above 1 are too good a deal to be available. Then the good-deal bound is c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ) log2. This expression can be evaluated under particular parametric assumptions about the consumption process. In the case in which consumption growth is lognormal, with volatility of log consumption equal to σ, it supplies an upper bound on risk aversion: γ log2/σ (which is about 42 if σ =0.02). However, this upper bound is rather weak, and in any case the postulated consumption process is inconsistent with observed features of asset markets such as the high equity premium and low riskless rate. Alternatively, one might model the consumption process as subject to disasters in the sense of Section 2.1. In this case, the good-deal bound implies tighter restrictions on γ, but these restrictions are sensitively dependent on the disaster parameters. In order to progress from (18) to a bound on γ and ρ that does not require parametrization of the consumption process, we want to relate c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ) to quantities that can be directly observed. For example, the Hansen Jagannathan bound (17) improves on a conclusion that follows from the convexity of the CGF, namely, that 0 c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ). (19) This trivial inequality follows by considering the value of the CGF at the three points c(0), c( γ ), and c( 2γ ). Convexity implies that the average slope of the CGF is more negative (or less positive) between 2γ and γ than it is between γ and 0: c( γ ) c( 2γ ) γ c(0) c( γ ). γ Equation (19) follows immediately, given that c(0)=0. Combining (18) and (19), we obtain the (underwhelming!) result that 0 log ( 1+h 2). However, we can sharpen (19) by comparing the slope of the CGF between 2γ and γ to the slope between γ and 1 γ (rather than between γ and 0): c( γ ) c( 2γ ) γ c(1 γ ) c( γ ). 1 This implies, by Result 1, that c( 2γ ) 2c( γ ) (γ 1)(c/w r f )+ϑ(c/w ρ), and hence Result 4. If the maximal Sharpe ratio is less than or equal to h, then we must have ( (γ 1)(c/w r f )+ϑ(c/w ρ) log 1+h 2). (20)

18 762 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES (a) (b) Figure 8 Shaded areas indicate admissible parameter values for i.i.d. models with rp=6%, r f =2%, c/w=6%, and a maximal Sharpe ratio of 0.75 The important feature of this result is that by exploiting the observable consumption wealth ratio and riskless rate, we do not need to take a stand on what is going on in the tails. Figure 8 reproduces the bounds of Figure 7, adding in the good deal bound (20) with h=0.75, i.e. ruling out Sharpe ratios above Shaded areas indicate admissible parameter values. In Figure 8b, admissible values lie below the line marked good deal bound when ψ<1 and above it when ψ>1. There are also admissible values of ρ and ψ not visible in the figure, with ρ large and ψ close to zero. The figure assumes γ =4, but the admissible regions are unaltered for any value of γ between 0 and 8.5. The line marked good deal bound steepens as γ increases, while continuing to pass through the point (0.06,1); once γ rises above 8.5, the good deal bound starts to impose tighter constraints on ψ and ρ. I repeat this exercise in the Supplementary Appendix for a maximum Sharpe ratio of 1.25 rather than With power utility, this increase in h shifts the good deal bound upwards, meaning that higher values of γ are permissible for fixed ρ. With Epstein Zin preferences, the good deal bound flattens out, which has no effect on the visible admissible region if γ is held constant at EXTENSIONS 4.1. Log consumption not proportional to log dividends Thus far we have operated under the assumption that log dividends are proportional to log consumption. This section considers more general scenarios in which consumption and dividends may differ, with a motivating application to a heterogeneous-agent economy. Again, the goal will be to make statements that are independent of particular assumptions about tail behaviour. To introduce some notation, suppose that a power utility agent with consumption C t is pricing an asset paying dividends D t, so that the asset s price satisfies ( ) γ P 0 =D 0 E e ρt Ct Dt dt. t=0 C 0 D 0 Defining the bivariate CGF c(θ 1,θ 2 ) logee θ 1log(C t+1 /C t )+θ 2 log(d t+1 /D t ), it is almost immediate, following the same logic as before, that D 0 /P 0 =ρ c( γ,1). The next result, whose proof is straightforward, collects this fact together with the riskless rate and risk premium.

19 IAN MARTIN CONSUMPTION-BASED ASSET PRICING 763 Result 5. If consumption growth G t logc t /C 0 and dividend growth H t logd t /D 0 are distinct, potentially correlated, Lévy processes, then D 0 /P 0 = ρ c( γ,1) R f = ρ c( γ,0) RP = c(0,1)+c( γ,0) c( γ,1). Constantinides and Duffie (1996) have shown that accounting for heterogeneity may contribute to an understanding of the equity premium puzzle. On the other hand, Grossman and Shiller (1982) have shown that if agents consumption processes follow diffusions, risk premia are unaffected by heterogeneity. The tension between these two results will be resolved by showing that heterogeneity matters to the extent that it is present at times of aggregate jumps. The presence of jumps lends a discrete-time flavor to the model, and as a result it lies closer on the spectrum to Constantinides Duffie than to Grossman Shiller. I assume that agents suffer idiosyncratic shocks to consumption, perhaps because agents have labour income risk that is uninsurable for moral hazard reasons. 6 All agents have power utility. Agent i s log consumption process is given by log C N t i,t = μt +σ B t + Y j C i,0 j=1 }{{} common to all agents +σ 1 B it 1 2 σ 1 2 t }{{} type (i) N i,t + N t X i,j + Y i,j j=1 j=1 }{{}}{{} type (ii) type (iii) Here B t is a Brownian motion, and Y j are the i.i.d. sizes of jumps, which occur at times dictated by the Poisson process N t, with arrival rate ω; these shocks are common to all agents. I assume that the jumps are bad or at least, not good news on average, so Ee Y j 1. There are also three types of idiosyncratic shocks: (i) an idiosyncratic Brownian motion component, B i,t ; (ii) jumps whose size X i,k and timing (determined by the Poisson process N i,t ) are idiosyncratic; and (iii) jumps of idiosyncratic size Y i,k, whose timing coincides with aggregate disasters, to capture the fact that disasters do not have the same impact on all agents. I assume that X i,j and Y k,l are i.i.d. across i,j,k and l, and N i,t are Poisson processes, independent across i, with arrival rate ω 2. Finally, σ 1 and ω 2 are constant across all agents i. Aggregate quantities are computed by summing over agents i; I assume that a law of large numbers holds so that this process is equivalent to taking an expectation over i. With this assumption, together with the normalization that for all i and k, Ee X i,k =Ee Y i,k =1, (21) implies that aggregate consumption evolves according to log C t C 0 =μt +σ B t + N t j=1 Y j. The upshot is that all agents attach the same value to the equity claim to aggregate consumption, so as in Constantinides and Duffie (1996) there is a no-trade equilibrium in which agent i consumes C i,t at time t. The Euler equation holds for each agent i, so the price of equity, P, must satisfy ( ) γ P =E e ρt Ci,t C t dt. (22) 0 C i,0 Result 5 now applies with G t =logc it /C i0 and H t =logc t /C 0. Defining m D (θ) Ee θy j, m 2 (θ) Ee θx i,k, and m 3 (θ) Ee θy i,j, the CGF of (G 1,H 1 )isc(θ 1,θ 2 )=μ(θ 1 +θ 2 )+ 1 2 σ 2 (θ 1 +θ 2 ) 2 + (21) 6. Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004) show that idiosyncratic shocks are highly persistent, and large, with a standard deviation of about 0.25.

Consumption-Based Asset Pricing with Higher Cumulants

Consumption-Based Asset Pricing with Higher Cumulants Consumption-Based Asset Pricing with Higher Cumulants Ian Martin 6 November, 2007 Abstract I extend the Epstein-Zin-lognormal consumption-based asset-pricing model to allow for general i.i.d. consumption

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

Disasters Implied by Equity Index Options

Disasters Implied by Equity Index Options Disasters Implied by Equity Index Options David Backus (NYU) Mikhail Chernov (LBS) Ian Martin (Stanford GSB) November 18, 2009 Backus, Chernov & Martin (Stanford GSB) Disasters implied by options 1 / 31

More information

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets

A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets A Unified Theory of Bond and Currency Markets Andrey Ermolov Columbia Business School April 24, 2014 1 / 41 Stylized Facts about Bond Markets US Fact 1: Upward Sloping Real Yield Curve In US, real long

More information

Online Appendix for Variable Rare Disasters: An Exactly Solved Framework for Ten Puzzles in Macro-Finance. Theory Complements

Online Appendix for Variable Rare Disasters: An Exactly Solved Framework for Ten Puzzles in Macro-Finance. Theory Complements Online Appendix for Variable Rare Disasters: An Exactly Solved Framework for Ten Puzzles in Macro-Finance Xavier Gabaix November 4 011 This online appendix contains some complements to the paper: extension

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

+1 = + +1 = X 1 1 ( ) 1 =( ) = state variable. ( + + ) +

+1 = + +1 = X 1 1 ( ) 1 =( ) = state variable. ( + + ) + 26 Utility functions 26.1 Utility function algebra Habits +1 = + +1 external habit, = X 1 1 ( ) 1 =( ) = ( ) 1 = ( ) 1 ( ) = = = +1 = (+1 +1 ) ( ) = = state variable. +1 ³1 +1 +1 ³ 1 = = +1 +1 Internal?

More information

SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, )

SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, ) Econometrica Supplementary Material SUPPLEMENT TO THE LUCAS ORCHARD (Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 1, January 2013, 55 111) BY IAN MARTIN FIGURE S.1 shows the functions F γ (z),scaledby2 γ so that they integrate

More information

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle? Christian Julliard and Anisha Ghosh Working Paper 2008 P t d b J L i f NYU A t P i i Presented by Jason Levine for NYU Asset Pricing Seminar, Fall 2009

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory

Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory Skewness in Expected Macro Fundamentals and the Predictability of Equity Returns: Evidence and Theory Ric Colacito, Eric Ghysels, Jinghan Meng, and Wasin Siwasarit 1 / 26 Introduction Long-Run Risks Model:

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Pierre Collin-Dufresne, Michael Johannes and Lars Lochstoer Parameter Learning in General Equilibrium The Asset Pricing Implications

Pierre Collin-Dufresne, Michael Johannes and Lars Lochstoer Parameter Learning in General Equilibrium The Asset Pricing Implications Pierre Collin-Dufresne, Michael Johannes and Lars Lochstoer Parameter Learning in General Equilibrium The Asset Pricing Implications DP 05/2012-039 Parameter Learning in General Equilibrium: The Asset

More information

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Jerry Tsai University of Oxford Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 12, 2014 and NBER A The iid model This section

More information

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing Nicola Pavoni October 21, 2016 The Lucas Tree Model This is a general equilibrium model where instead of deriving properties of

More information

Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015

Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015 ECON-UB 233 Dave Backus @ NYU Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015 I ll focus again on the big picture to give you a sense of what we ve done and how it fits together. For each topic/result/concept,

More information

On modelling of electricity spot price

On modelling of electricity spot price , Rüdiger Kiesel and Fred Espen Benth Institute of Energy Trading and Financial Services University of Duisburg-Essen Centre of Mathematics for Applications, University of Oslo 25. August 2010 Introduction

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in Durable Consumption Wei Yang 1 This draft: October 2009 1 William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester, Rochester,

More information

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences

International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences p. 1/3 International Asset Pricing and Risk Sharing with Recursive Preferences Riccardo Colacito Prepared for Tom Sargent s PhD class (Part 1) Roadmap p. 2/3 Today International asset pricing (exchange

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

The Shape of the Term Structures

The Shape of the Term Structures The Shape of the Term Structures Michael Hasler Mariana Khapko November 16, 2018 Abstract Empirical findings show that the term structures of dividend strip risk premium and volatility are downward sloping,

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Merton-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 18 The Black-Merton-Scholes-Merton (BMS) model Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton

More information

Risks For The Long Run And The Real Exchange Rate

Risks For The Long Run And The Real Exchange Rate Riccardo Colacito, Mariano M. Croce Overview International Equity Premium Puzzle Model with long-run risks Calibration Exercises Estimation Attempts & Proposed Extensions Discussion International Equity

More information

Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints

Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh June 27, 2006 Additional Figures and Tables Calibration of Expenditure

More information

Rare Disasters, Asset Markets, and Macroeconomics

Rare Disasters, Asset Markets, and Macroeconomics Rare Disasters, Asset Markets, and Macroeconomics Assess implications of neoclassical growth model for real rates of return. In steady state (i.e. long run), real rates of return on assets (claims to capital

More information

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Bryan Kelly NYU Stern and Chicago Booth Outline Introduction An Economic Framework Econometric Methodology Empirical Findings Conclusions Tail Risk

More information

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING Agenda The Notional Amount Approach Price Sensitivity Measure for Derivatives Weakness of the Greek Measure Define Value at Risk 1 Day to VaR to 10 Day

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Petr Zemčík CERGE-EI April 2005 1 Mean Reversion Equity returns display negative serial correlation at horizons longer than one year.

More information

Assicurazioni Generali: An Option Pricing Case with NAGARCH

Assicurazioni Generali: An Option Pricing Case with NAGARCH Assicurazioni Generali: An Option Pricing Case with NAGARCH Assicurazioni Generali: Business Snapshot Find our latest analyses and trade ideas on bsic.it Assicurazioni Generali SpA is an Italy-based insurance

More information

Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund?

Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund? Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund? Pierre Collin-Dufresne EPFL & SFI, and CEPR April 2016 Outline Endowment Consumption Commitments Return Predictability and Trading Costs General

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Fall 2017 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL Byamungu Mjella CONDITIONAL CHARACTERISTICS OF RISK-RETURN TRADE-OFF: A STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR FRAMEWORK Master s Thesis Department of Finance November 2017 Unit Department of

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets (Hull chapter: 12, 13, 14) Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 17 The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model Black and Scholes

More information

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Virginia Olivella and Jose Ignacio Lopez October 2008 Motivation Menu costs and repricing decisions Micro foundation of sticky

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

Some Characteristics of Data

Some Characteristics of Data Some Characteristics of Data Not all data is the same, and depending on some characteristics of a particular dataset, there are some limitations as to what can and cannot be done with that data. Some key

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

Mean-Variance Analysis

Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-variance analysis 1/ 51 Introduction How does one optimally choose among multiple risky assets? Due to diversi cation, which depends on assets return covariances, the attractiveness

More information

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Persistent than You Think October 19th, 2009 Introduction: Habit Preferences Habit preferences: can generate a higher equity premium for a given curvature

More information

Online Appendix: Structural GARCH: The Volatility-Leverage Connection

Online Appendix: Structural GARCH: The Volatility-Leverage Connection Online Appendix: Structural GARCH: The Volatility-Leverage Connection Robert Engle Emil Siriwardane Abstract In this appendix, we: (i) show that total equity volatility is well approximated by the leverage

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILITATION OF STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR METHODOLOGY. John H. Cochrane

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILITATION OF STOCHASTIC DISCOUNT FACTOR METHODOLOGY. John H. Cochrane NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A REHABILIAION OF SOCHASIC DISCOUN FACOR MEHODOLOGY John H. Cochrane Working Paper 8533 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8533 NAIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Information Processing and Limited Liability Information Processing and Limited Liability Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University January 2012 Abstract Decision-makers often face limited liability

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Critical Finance Review, 2012, 1: 141 182 The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Jason Beeler 1 and John Y. Campbell 2 1 Department of Economics, Littauer Center,

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles Risks For the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles Ravi Bansal and Amir Yaron ABSTRACT We model consumption and dividend growth rates as containing (i) a small long-run predictable

More information

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Dynamic Relative Valuation Dynamic Relative Valuation Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr from Morgan Stanley October 15, 2013 Liuren Wu (Baruch) Dynamic Relative Valuation 10/15/2013 1 / 20 The standard approach

More information

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia Diverse and Risk The Diverse and Time Variability of M. Kurz, Stanford University M. Motolese, Catholic University of Milan August 10, 2009 Individual State of SITE Summer 2009 Workshop, Stanford University

More information

Disaster Risk and Asset Returns: An International. Perspective 1

Disaster Risk and Asset Returns: An International. Perspective 1 Disaster Risk and Asset Returns: An International Perspective 1 Karen K. Lewis 2 Edith X. Liu 3 February 2017 1 For useful comments and suggestions, we thank Charles Engel, Mick Devereux, Jessica Wachter,

More information

Chapter 14 : Statistical Inference 1. Note : Here the 4-th and 5-th editions of the text have different chapters, but the material is the same.

Chapter 14 : Statistical Inference 1. Note : Here the 4-th and 5-th editions of the text have different chapters, but the material is the same. Chapter 14 : Statistical Inference 1 Chapter 14 : Introduction to Statistical Inference Note : Here the 4-th and 5-th editions of the text have different chapters, but the material is the same. Data x

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén PORTFOLIO THEORY Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Portfolio Theory Investments 1 / 60 Outline 1 Modern Portfolio Theory Introduction Mean-Variance

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices

An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices An Empirical Evaluation of the Long-Run Risks Model for Asset Prices Ravi Bansal Dana Kiku Amir Yaron November 11, 2011 Abstract We provide an empirical evaluation of the Long-Run Risks (LRR) model, and

More information

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that: hapter Review Questions. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that: T = t where t is the marginal tax rate. a. What is the new relationship between

More information

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 1. Default dynamics of a single obligor. 2. Model the dependence structure of defaults

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Environmental Protection and Rare Disasters

Environmental Protection and Rare Disasters 2014 Economica Phillips Lecture Environmental Protection and Rare Disasters Professor Robert J Barro Paul M Warburg Professor of Economics, Harvard University Senior fellow, Hoover Institution, Stanford

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Rahul Giri Contact Address: Centro de Investigacion Economica, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico (ITAM). E-mail: rahul.giri@itam.mx

More information

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997 Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997 Seminar in Asset Pricing Theory Presented by Saki Bigio November 2007 1 /

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg :

More information

Long-Run Risks, the Macroeconomy, and Asset Prices

Long-Run Risks, the Macroeconomy, and Asset Prices Long-Run Risks, the Macroeconomy, and Asset Prices By RAVI BANSAL, DANA KIKU AND AMIR YARON Ravi Bansal and Amir Yaron (2004) developed the Long-Run Risk (LRR) model which emphasizes the role of long-run

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory Fall 2010 ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND Magnus Dahlquist 1 Ofer Setty 2 Roine Vestman 3 1 Stockholm School of Economics and CEPR 2 Tel Aviv University 3 Stockholm University and Swedish House

More information

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

Animal Spirits in the Foreign Exchange Market

Animal Spirits in the Foreign Exchange Market Animal Spirits in the Foreign Exchange Market Paul De Grauwe (London School of Economics) 1 Introductory remarks Exchange rate modelling is still dominated by the rational-expectations-efficientmarket

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Ian Dew-Becker and Stefano Giglio Duke Fuqua and Chicago Booth 11/27/13 Dew-Becker and Giglio (Duke and Chicago) Frequency-domain asset pricing

More information

A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails

A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails Florida International University FIU Digital Commons Economics Research Working Paper Series Department of Economics 11-26-2008 A Long-Run Risks Model of Asset Pricing with Fat Tails Zhiguang (Gerald)

More information

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers Final Exam Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, 2004 Answers This exam consists of two parts. The first part is a long analytical question. The second part is a set of short discussion questions.

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Identifying : A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania CEPR and NBER Dongho Song University of Pennsylvania Amir Yaron University of Pennsylvania NBER February 12,

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LIX, NO. 4 AUGUST 004 Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles RAVI BANSAL and AMIR YARON ABSTRACT We model consumption and dividend growth rates

More information