By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should:

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should:"

Transcription

1 Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year The format and structure of the examination may change in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning environment (VLE). Information about the subject guide Unless otherwise stated, all cross-references will be to the latest version of the subject guide (011). You should always attempt to use the most recent edition of any Essential reading textbook, even if the commentary and/or online reading list and/or subject guide refers to an earlier edition. If different editions of Essential reading are listed, please check the VLE for reading supplements if none are available, please use the contents list and index of the new edition to find the relevant section. General remarks Learning outcomes By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should: be able to define and describe: the determinants of consumer choices, including inter-temporal choices and those involving risk firms behaviour how firms behaviour differs in different market structures and may help to determine those structures how firms and households determine factor prices. be able to analyse and assess: efficiency and welfare optimality of perfectly and imperfectly competitive markets the effects of externalities and public goods on efficiency government policies aimed at improving welfare. be prepared for further units which require a knowledge of microeconomics. Time management Section A comprises eight questions, all of which must be answered (accounting for 40% of the total marks). Section B comprises six questions of which three must be answered (accounting for 60% of the total marks). Candidates are strongly advised to divide their time accordingly. On average, only nine minutes should be allocated to any individual Section A question. On average, only 36 minutes should be allocated to any individual Section B question. 1

2 Key steps to improvement You need to be able to apply relevant microeconomic theory to questions that you may not have encountered before. To prepare for this, you need not only to gain a thorough understanding of microeconomic models but also (and importantly) to practise using relevant models to answer specific questions. Practice is the key, not the learning of specific answers. You should spend time planning your answers and make sure that you respond to all parts of a question and to key words like define, explain and compare. Precise and concise answers are to be preferred to vague and long-winded answers. You should be aware that, for most answers, diagrams and/or mathematical analysis are essential. These should be correct and diagrams should be well-labelled. In addition, you should always accompany them with appropriate explanations. Again, practice makes perfect. Essential reading: Important information The subject guide refers to Morgan, Katz and Rosen as the principal text. In addition to this, you should practise questions from other texts. Two auxiliary texts that are good sources for practice questions are listed below. Further, the auxiliary texts often develop applications not covered in the principal text. You should study these to broaden, as well as deepen, your understanding. In some cases, reading several treatments of the same topic might help to clarify the basic idea. You should use the auxiliary texts for this purpose as well. The coverage of game theory is often inadequate in texts. You should make sure that you understand the key ideas covered in some detail in the subject guide. Principal text Wyn Morgan, Michael Katz and Harvey Rosen, Microeconomics (Boston, Mass.: Irwin/McGraw-Hill, 009) second edition [ISBN ]. Auxiliary texts Jeffrey M. Perloff, Microeconomics with Calculus (Pearson Education, 013) third edition [ISBN ]. Robert S. Pindyck and Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics (Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Prentice Hall/Pearson, 01) eighth edition [ISBN ].

3 Question spotting Many candidates are disappointed to find that their examination performance is poorer than they expected. This can be due to a number of different reasons and the Examiners commentaries suggest ways of addressing common problems and improving your performance. We want to draw your attention to one particular failing question spotting, that is, confining your examination preparation to a few question topics which have come up in past papers for the course. This can have very serious consequences. We recognise that candidates may not cover all topics in the syllabus in the same depth, but you need to be aware that Examiners are free to set questions on any aspect of the syllabus. This means that you need to study enough of the syllabus to enable you to answer the required number of examination questions. The syllabus can be found in the Course information sheet in the section of the VLE dedicated to this course. You should read the syllabus very carefully and ensure that you cover sufficient material in preparation for the examination. Examiners will vary the topics and questions from year to year and may well set questions that have not appeared in past papers every topic on the syllabus is a legitimate examination target. So although past papers can be helpful in revision, you cannot assume that topics or specific questions that have come up in past examinations will occur again. If you rely on a question spotting strategy, it is likely you will find yourself in difficulties when you sit the examination paper. We strongly advise you not to adopt this strategy. 3

4 Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year The format and structure of the examination may change in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning environment (VLE). Information about the subject guide Unless otherwise stated, all cross-references will be to the latest version of the subject guide (011). You should always attempt to use the most recent edition of any Essential reading textbook, even if the commentary and/or online reading list and/or subject guide refers to an earlier edition. If different editions of Essential reading are listed, please check the VLE for reading supplements if none are available, please use the contents list and index of the new edition to find the relevant section. Comments on specific questions Zone A Text: We use the following abbreviations: M,K& R - Wyn Morgan, Michael Katz and Harvey Rosen, Microeconomics, McGraw-Hill, second edition, 009, ISBN: For each question, we point out the relevant sections from the main text (M,K & R) as well as the subject guide. Candidates should answer ELEVEN of the following FOURTEEN questions: all EIGHT of Section A (5 marks each) and THREE from Section B (0 marks each). Candidates are strongly advised to divide their time accordingly. If more questions are answered than requested, only the first answers attempted will be counted. 1

5 Section A Answer all eight questions in this section (5 marks each). Question 1 Consider the following simultaneous-move game with two players, 1 and. If 1 and/or have any dominated strategies, eliminate them. Once you have done this, consider the remaining game. In this remaining game, eliminate any dominated strategies of 1 and/or and so on. This method is called iterated elimination of dominated strategies. Find the equilibrium using this method. Your answer must show each round of elimination clearly. Player A B C A 1, 4, 0,4 Player 1 B 1 4,0 6,8, C 1 6,4 4,0 0,6 The coverage of game theory in M,K& R (Chapter 16) is not ideal. See Chapter 9 (Game theory: an introduction) of the subject guide for a detailed discussion. If you know what a dominated strategy is, this is easy. However, many candidates seem to confuse dominated strategy calculation with best response calculation. When you say for player 1 strategy B 1 dominates strategy A 1 that means the payoff of 1 from playing B 1 is better than that from playing A 1 no matter what player does. In other words, for every box in the row B 1, the first number (1 s payoff) must be higher than the first number in the box above. As you can see, this is true here. So we can conclude that B 1 dominates A 1. A best response, on the other hand, refers to the best response against a specific strategy. For player 1, the best response to A is C 1. This sort of calculation is not useful here we want to compare all possible payoffs of one strategy against all possible payoffs of another to determine whether one of these dominates the other. Once you understand the above, the answer is straightforward. Here B 1 dominates A 1, and C dominates A. So eliminate A 1 and A. After eliminating A 1 and A, we have the following reduced game: Player B C Player 1 B 1 6,8, C 1 4,0 0,6 In this game, B 1 dominates C 1. Eliminate C 1. We now have the further reduced game: Player B C Player 1 B 1 6,8, In the game above, B dominates C. Eliminate C. We are then left with B 1, B. Therefore, using the method of iterated elimination of dominated strategies, we get the equilibrium B 1, B.

6 Question Consider an exchange economy with two goods (milk and honey) and two consumers (A and B). There are 10 units available of each of the two goods. Consumer A is endowed with 6 units of milk and 4 units of honey. Consumer B is endowed with 4 units of milk and 6 units of honey. Let M denote units of milk and H denote units of honey. Consumer A has the following utility function: U A (M, H) = min[m, H] Consumer B has the following utility function: U B (M, H) = M + H Draw an Edgeworth box and show the area of mutually beneficial trades between the two consumers. M,K& R Chapter 1; subject guide Chapter 11 (General equilibrium and welfare economics) Milk and honey are perfect substitutes for consumer A and perfect complements for consumer B. You should know how to draw indifference curves for these preferences. The area of mutually beneficial trades is given by the shaded area EYZ. The question does not ask you this, but let us also understand where the equilibrium trades would lie in this box. Any equilibrium must be on the contract curve. So equilibrium trades lie somewhere on the part of the contract curve contained in the area EYZ. This is shown in the picture as the line ZA. 3

7 Question 3 A monopolist has a well-defined supply function. Is this true or false? Explain your answer. M,K& R Chapter 13; subject guide Chapter 8 (Competition and monopoly). Many candidates answered this question by saying that the statement is false because profit maximisation by the monopolist gives rise to a deadweight loss. You should understand that the presence or absence of deadweight loss has nothing to do with presence or absence of a supply function. Consider, for example, a firm in a competitive market. We know that a competitive firm has a well-defined supply function. Of course, we also know that there is no deadweight loss in the market. But now suppose the government imposes a per-unit tax. You know that this would distort the market equilibrium and give rise to a deadweight loss. But the supply function is still well-defined. So what is the answer? The crucial point is that a monopolist s optimisation is not independent of the market demand curve. Given a market demand (which is the average revenue curve), the monopolist chooses the best point on this curve (the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost). So if demand changes, the monopolist s optimal price-quantity bundle changes. Therefore, for a monopolist, there is no unique relationship between price and quantity supplied. Therefore a monopolist does not have a well-defined supply function. The statement is false. Question 4 A bond pays a fixed sum of 100 per year for ever (i.e. the bond is a perpetuity). The annual interest rate is 5%. What is the maximum amount an agent should pay to buy this bond? M,K& R Chapter 5.3; subject guide Chapter 5 (Saving, investment and choice over time). The discount factor is δ = 1 where r is the interest rate. The maximum price P should equal 1 + r the present value of payments received from next period onwards: P = δ100 + δ = δ 1 δ 100. Using the value of δ, P = 100/r. Since r = 0.05 = 1/0, P = 000. Question 5 In 010, price of petrol was 10 and Kara purchased 600 units over the year. In 013, price of petrol was 15 and Kara consumed 800 units over the year. It follows that Kara s demand function for petrol is upward sloping. Is this true or false? Explain your answer. 4 M,K& R Chapter 3; subject guide Chapter 3 (Consumer theory).

8 This is false. From the data it does not follow that the demand is upward sloping. Another possible explanation (and a much more likely one) is that the demand curve is downward sloping as usual, but the demand shifted up between 010 and 013. This could happen because of a variety of factors. For example, Kara s income might have increased over the years and petrol is a normal good, or Kara s preferences for driving might have changed so that at any price of petrol she used more petrol in 013, or the price of alternative means of transport might have increased forcing a substitution towards greater car use. Question 6 The compensated (Hicksian) demand curve for a Giffen good is upward sloping. Is this true or false? Explain your answer. M,K& R Chapter 4; subject guide Chapter 3 (Consumer theory). This is an easy question. You should know that only the substitution effect matters for the compensated demand curve. Since the substitution effect is always negative, the compensated (Hicksian) demand curve is always downward sloping. The statement is therefore false. Question 7 There are 3 consumers of a public good. The demand functions of the consumers are as follows: P 1 = 60 Q (Consumer 1) (.1) P = 100 Q (Consumer ) (.) P 3 = 140 Q (Consumer 3) (.3) where Q is the quantity of public good and P i is the price consumer i is willing to pay, i {1,, 3}. The public good can be produced at a constant marginal cost of 180, and there are no fixed costs. Find the efficient level of production of the public good. M,K& R Chapter 18; subject guide Chapter 13 (Externalities and public goods). All you need to do here is to calculate the total willingness to pay at any quantity, and see at which quantity this equals 180. In other words, Q should be such that the total willingness to pay at Q equals 180: which gives us 3Q = 10 implying Q = Q Q Q = 180 5

9 Question 8 Identical firms in a competitive industry use capital (K) and labour (L) to produce output (Q). The labour supply curve is upward sloping, while the supply of capital is infinitely elastic in the long run. It follows that the long run industry supply curve is upward sloping. Is this true or false? Explain your answer. M,K& R Chapter 10.1; subject guide Chapter 8 (Competition and monopoly). This is true. While the cost of capital is constant, higher demand for labour implies a higher wage rate. Therefore this is an increasing cost industry. It follows that the long run supply curve is upward sloping. In the long run, the industry can produce higher output only at a higher price, which is needed to compensate for the rise in unit labour costs. Section B Answer three questions from this section (0 marks each). Question 9 Suppose there are two identical firms in an industry. The output of firm 1 is denoted by q 1 and that of firm is denoted by q. Each firm can produce output at a constant marginal cost of 6. There are no fixed costs. Let Q denote total output, i.e. Q = q 1 + q. The inverse demand curve in the market is given by P = 30 Q (a) Find the Cournot-Nash equilibrium quantity produced by each firm and the market price. (b) What would be the quantities produced by each firm and market price under Stackelberg duopoly if firm 1 moves first? (c) Calculate the deadweight loss arising from Cournot-Nash and Stackelberg duopoly. Which market structure is more efficient? (d) Suppose, as in part (b), firm 1 moves first and decides how much to produce. Firm moves second and makes its production decision. There is then a third stage at which firm 1 can change its mind about how much to produce and makes a final decision. Find the equilibrium quantities produced by the two firms under this three-stage game. M,K& R Chapter 15; subject guide Chapter 10 (Oligopoly and strategic behaviour). 6 (a) Firm 1 maximises: π 1 = (30 (q 1 + q ))q 1 6q 1.

10 The first order condition is 4 4q 1 q = 0, which gives us the best response function of firm 1: q 1 = 6 q. Similarly, the best response function of firm is: q = 6 q 1. Solving, q 1 = q = 4. The market price is then P = 30 8 = 14. (b) Firm s best response is as above. Firm 1 maximises in stage 1 knowing that will use this best response function at stage. Therefore firm 1 s problem is: max q 1 (30 (q q 1 ))q 1 6q 1. This simplifies to: max q 1 (1 q 1 )q 1. This gives us q 1 = 6. It follows that q = 3. The market price is P = 30 9 = 1. (c) Using the picture below, the deadweight loss under Cournot competition is: DWL C = 1 (14 6)(1 8) = 16. The deadweight loss under the Stackelberg market structure is: DWL S = 1 (1 6)(1 9) = 9. It follows that the Stackelberg market structure is more efficient. 7

11 (d) This is a little tricky. Try to see why a Stackelberg leader gets an advantage. This is because the first mover can choose an output it is committed to, and the second mover just plays a best response to that. It is the fact that the first mover can commit to an output before the follower has a chance to choose output is the source of the first mover advantage. Here, in contrast, firm 1 can change its mind about how much to produce and makes a final decision after decides. Therefore the initial stage has no commitment value. But can commit to an output at stage knowing that 1 will readjust and choose a best response at stage 3. It follows that Firm can now act like the Stackelberg leader, and 1 becomes the follower. Therefore, now q 1 = 3 and q = 6. Question 10 (a) Consider the following simultaneous-move game with two players, 1 and. Let p denote the probability with which player 1 plays A 1, where 0 p 1. B 1 is played with the residual probability. Next, let q denote the probability with which player plays A, where 0 q 1. B is played with the residual probability. Draw a picture with p along the horizontal axis and q along the vertical axis and draw the best response functions of players 1 and. Clearly label any equilibrium points in the picture. Player A B Player 1 A 1, 3,0 B 1 3,5 1,6 (6 marks) (b) Consider the following extensive-form game with two players. Player 1 can end the game by choosing Out. If player 1 chooses In, Player then chooses between L and R. The payoffs are written as (Payoff to 1, Payoff to ). Identify any subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. (6 marks) 8 (c) Suppose the following game is repeated infinitely. Players discount the future, so that, for each player, a payoff of x received t periods from today is worth δ t x today, where 0 < δ < 1. Show that it is possible to sustain cooperation (which in this case involves each player playing C every period) in the infinitely repeated game for high enough values of δ. (8 marks)

12 Player C D Player 1 C, 0,3 D 3,0 1,1 The coverage of game theory in M,K& R (Chapter 16) is not ideal. See Chapter 9 (Game theory: an introduction) of the subject guide for a detailed discussion. (a) There are no pure NE. The mixed Nash equilibrium is p = 1/3 and q = /3. The best response function of player 1 is given by: 0 if q > /3 p = [0, 1] if q = /3 1 if q < /3 The best response function of player is given by: 0 if p < 1/3 q = [0, 1] if p = 1/3 1 if p > 1/3 The picture below draws the best response functions and shows the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. 9

13 (b) To solve for the subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium in this game, we can simply solve backwards. At s decision node, would choose R (which gives a payoff of 3 compared to a payoff of from L). Knowing this, 1 s best choice is to stay out (which gives a payoff of 0 compared to a payoff of -1 from choosing In. ). It follows that the SPNE is (Out, R). Some of you prefer to write s strategy as R if 1 plays In. That is fine as well, although since there is exactly one node at which chooses a move, the qualifier is unnecessary here. (c) Cooperation can be sustained in equilibrium if players are patient enough, i.e. δ close enough to 1. This can be seen as follows. Suppose each player follows the following strategy: play C to start with, and continue to play C so long as there is no deviation. After any deviation, play D always. Let us compare the payoff from conforming to the payoff from deviating. Consider a deviation in period t by player 1. Note that the payoff until t 1 plays no role in comparing deviation payoff with the payoff from conforming. The payoffs only differ staring at t, so we might as well just consider the payoff starting at period t. Since this is an infinitely repeated game, the players face an infinite future starting at any period t, and the nature of calculations is exactly the same no matter when you start the calculations. Given the strategy of each player specified above, the payoff from always cooperating (starting at t) is as follows. A player gets at t, at t + 1 which is worth δ at t and so on. So the payoff starting at period t from conforming is: + δ + δ + = 1 δ By deviating at period t, 1 gets 3 in period t, but then from t + 1 onwards each player plays D and so 1 gets a payoff of 1 every period. Therefore, the payoff at t from deviating at t is: 3 + δ + δ + = 3 + δ 1 δ Cooperation can be sustained if such a deviation is not profitable. Therefore to sustain cooperation we need 1 δ δ δ which implies δ 1/. Question 11 A monopolist can vary the quality of a good he produces. The cost of producing quality q is C(q) = q There are two types of consumers. From consuming a good of quality q 1 at price p 1, type 1 consumers get a utility of u 1 (q 1, p 1 ) = q 1 p 1 Type consumers get a higher marginal benefit from quality. From consuming a good of quality q at price p, type consumers get a utility of u (q, p ) = q p Consumers buy the good so long as they get at least 0 utility. The profit of the monopolist from a quality-price pair of (q i, p i ) where i {1, } is then given by π(q i, p i ) = p i q i (a) Suppose the monopolist knows the type of any consumer. In this case the monopolist produces a quality q 1 for a type 1 consumer and charges a price p 1. Similarly, type consumers are offered quality q at price p. For any i {1, }, the optimal pair (q i, p i ) maximizes π(q i, p i ) subject to u i (q i, p i ) = 0. Find the optimal quality-price pairs (q 1, p 1 ) and (q, p ). 10

14 (b) Suppose a consumer s own type is known only to the consumer. The monopolist cannot identify the type of any consumer. In this case, suppose the monopolist still offers the quality-price pairs (q1, p 1 ) and (q, p ) from part (a). Which quality-price pair would a type 1 consumer choose? Which pair would a type consumer choose? (c) Suppose the monopolist sets q 1 = 1/, p 1 = 1/ and q =. The monopolist wants to set p such that type consumers would have the incentive to choose (q, p ) rather than (q 1, p 1 ). What is the highest value of p that satisfies the monopolist s objective? (d) Given the values of q 1, q, p 1 and p from part (c), would a type 1 consumer have the incentive to choose (q 1, p 1 ) rather than (q, p )? M,K& R Chapter 17; subject guide Chapter 1 (Asymmetric information). Before trying to answer the question, it is useful to have a general understanding of its structure. Once you understand the idea behind the questions, it is very easy to do the calculations. In questions on asymmetric information, it is typical to first set the full information benchmark. We then compare the outcome under asymmetric information to the benchmark, allowing us to quantify the impact of asymmetric information. The first part of the question asks you to solve the monopolist s profit maximisation problem when there is no asymmetric information. The next part demonstrates that asymmetric information is a non-trivial problem: the price-quantity pairs offered under full information fail to be incentive compatible under asymmetric information. As the calculations below show, if the monopolist simply offers the full-information contracts under asymmetric information, type consumers gain by pretending to be type 1 consumers. If the monopolist wants to induce different types to accept different contracts, he must design these contracts so that no type has an incentive to accept the contract designed for the other type. In other words, contracts must be incentive compatible. Parts (c) and (d) are simple exercises based on this idea. (a) Maximise p 1 q 1 / subject to q 1 p 1 = 0. Using the constraint to substitute the value of p 1, the maximisation problem becomes: max q 1 q 1 q 1 which implies q 1 = 1 which in turn implies p 1 = 1. Similarly, maximise p q / subject to q p = 0. Using the constraint to substitute the value of p, the maximisation problem becomes: max q q q which implies q = which in turn implies p = 4. (b) A type 1 consumer gets 0 from (q1, p 1 ). The utility from (q, p ) is 4 < 0. Therefore a type 1 consumer chooses (q1, p 1 ). A type consumer gets 0 from (q, p ). The utility from choosing (q 1, p 1 ). is 1 > 0. Therefore a type consumer would switch to buying the quality q1 at price p 1 rather than choose the quality-price pair (q, p ). In other words, if the monopolist cannot observe the type of a consumer, but still offers the same price-quality pairs as in part (a), both types will choose (q 1, p 1 ). 11

15 (c) We need: Using the values given: q p q 1 p 1. 4 p 1 1 which implies: p 7. So the maximum value of p for which type would choose (q, p ) rather than (q 1, p 1 ) is given by 7/. (d) A type 1 consumer gets a utility of 0 from (q 1 = 1/, p 1 = 1/). The utility from (q =, p = 7/) is 7/ < 0. Therefore a type 1 consumer would indeed choose (q 1, p 1 ) rather than (q, p ). Question 1 Maya spends her income on chocolate (X) and a composite of all other goods (Y). Her preferences are represented by the utility function u(x, Y) = X + Y The price of the composite good is 1, and the price of chocolate is p. Let M denote Maya s income. (a) Derive Maya s demand for X and Y. (b) Suppose M = 10. Suppose initially the price of X is 1/, and then the price falls to 1/5. How much does Maya s demand for X change? How much of this change in demand can be attributed to income effect and how much to substitution effect? (c) Consider the change in price of X from 1/ to 1/5. Calculate the compensating variation of the price change. (d) For the change in price noted in part (c), is the equivalent variation greater than, equal to or less than the compensating variation? M,K& R Chapters 3 and 4; subject guide Chapter 3 (Consumer theory). (a) Here MU X = 1 X, and MU Y = 1. So at the optimum: 1 X = p which gives us: X = 1 p. 1

16 From the budget constraint, Y + px = M, so: Y = M 1 p. Clearly, X is independent of M. This is quasi-linear utility. There is no income effect on the demand for X. (b) Initially price is 1/ and X = 1 (1/) = 4. When price falls to 1/5, demand for X rises to 1 (1/5) = 5. As noted above, in this case there is no income effect on the demand for X. The entire price effect of 1 constitutes simply of substitution effect. (c) Given the optimal demands, the utility is u = /p + M 1/p = M + 1/p. At M = 10, p = 1/, u0 = 1. With a price fall, u 1 = = 15. If we now take away 3, utility falls back to u0. So CV is 3. (d) As noted above, there is no income effect. It follows that CV and EV are equal. You can also check this directly. If the price is not allowed to fall, utility is M + 1/p = 10 + = 1. If we now increase M by 3, we get 15, which is the utility after the price fall. Therefore EV = 3. Question 13 You are advising the minister responsible for housing. The minister is concerned that rents are too high and wants to reduce the rent payments by tenants without causing too much inefficiency. (a) Using appropriate diagrams explain the circumstances under which you would advise the minister to impose rent control. (7 marks) (b) Using appropriate diagrams explain the circumstances under which you would advise the minister to give a rent subsidy to tenants. (7 marks) (c) Using appropriate diagrams describe a case in which issuing more building permits would not be an effective policy. (6 marks) M,K& R Chapter 11; subject guide Chapter 8 (Competition and Monopoly). 13

17 (a) If supply is inelastic, rent control works well. As you can see from the picture, in this case the deadweight loss is small. 14

18 (b) If supply is elastic and demand is not very elastic, any subsidy would mostly go to tenants and the deadweight loss would be relatively small. 15

19 (c) If demand is very elastic (indicating consumers already have a lot of choice), raising supply would not reduce rents much. 16 Question 14 Consider a society with agents. Agent 1 takes an action a where Action a generates an utility of 0 < a 1 u 1 (a) = 1 a for agent 1. The action also affects agent. The utility of agent if 1 takes action a is given by u (a) = 4 a (a) Let a denote the individually optimal level of a for agent 1. Calculate a. (b) Let a 0 denote the socially optimal level of a. Calculate a 0 and compare to a from part (a). (c) Suppose the government imposes a proportional tax of t on a on agent 1. The utility function of agent 1 is now u 1 (a, t) = 1 a t a Let a t denote the after-tax individually optimal choice of a by 1. Calculate the value of t for which a t is equal to a 0. (d) Suppose the utility functions of both agents are known to each agent, but the government does not know the utility functions. In this case the tax policy of part (c) will not work. Can you suggest an alternative policy that the government can adopt that will result in a 0 being chosen by agent 1? (You only need to suggest an appropriate policy informally no calculations are needed.)

20 M,K& R Chapter 18; subject guide Chapter 13 (Externalities and public goods). (a) Note that u (a) = 1/(a ) > 0, i.e. u(a) is increasing in a. Therefore agent 1 s optimal choice is to choose the highest possible level of a. Thus a = 1. (b) Let a 0 denote the socially optimal level. To get the value of a 0, you need to maximise the u 1 (a) + u (a) = (1/a) 4a. The first order condition for maximum is 1/(a ) = 8a, and thus a 0 = 1/. (You can check that the second order condition is satisfied at this point.) Clearly, a 0 < a. You should, of course, expect this even before you do any calculations. Since agent s utility is decreasing in a, it is clear that 1 exerts a negative externality on. Therefore, the individual optimum calculated in part (a) must be higher than the social optimum. The calculations in parts (a) and (b) simply reflect this. (c) Agent 1 now maximises (1/a) ta. The first order condition is 1/(a ) = t. You need to set t so that this first order condition is satisfied at a = a 0. In other words, t must be such that 1/(a 0 ) = t. It follows that the optimal choice of t, denoted by t 0, is given by t 0 = 4. (d) The magic phrase here is Coase theorem. Hopefully, as soon as you read the question, this is the phrase that pops up in your mind. To answer the question, say that the government should ensure that property rights are well defined. From the Coase theorem, we know that once property rights are well defined, so long as there are no transactions costs, bargaining would lead to the socially optimal outcome. In this case, once property rights are defined, bargaining among the two agents would result in a 0 being chosen. This completes the answer. Note that it does not matter whether 1 or is given the property right. Agent 1 might have the right to choose a, or might have the right to prevent 1 from taking action a. In either case, the outcome would be a 0. The question does not ask you to show this formally, but let us do it here. First, suppose 1 has the right to choose a. In this case, if there is no bargaining between 1 and, 1 chooses a = 1. If wants 1 to lower the level of a, must pay 1. How much can 1 extract from? Suppose 1 charges T 1, and agrees to choose a. Then s utility is u (a) T 1. In the absence of any agreement, gets u (1). Therefore, the maximum value of T 1 is given by: u (a) T 1 = u (1). Now 1 maximises u 1 (a) + T 1 with respect to a subject to the above constraint. Substituting the value of T 1, 1 s problem is: max u 1 (a) + u (a) u (1). a Now, u (1) is just a constant. So we are simply maximising the sum of utilities. From part (b), you already know that the above maximisation problem leads to the socially optimal level a 0 being chosen. Next, suppose has the right to choose a. The question simply states a 1 > 0. But to do the calculations here, we need to define a minimum feasible level of a. Suppose the minimum feasible level of a is given by some ε > 0. In this case, in the absence of bargaining, would prevent 1 from the externality-generating activity by choosing a = ε. So the maximum payment T that can extract from 1 under bargaining is given by: u 1 (a) T = u 1 (ε). Agent maximises u (a) + T with respect to a subject to the above constraint. Substituting the value of T, s problem is: max u (a) + u 1 (a) u 1 (ε). a Now, u 1 (ε) is just a constant. As before, from part (b) you already know that the above maximisation problem leads to the socially optimal level a 0 being chosen. 17

21 Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year The format and structure of the examination may change in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning environment (VLE). Information about the subject guide Unless otherwise stated, all cross-references will be to the latest version of the subject guide (011). You should always attempt to use the most recent edition of any Essential reading textbook, even if the commentary and/or online reading list and/or subject guide refers to an earlier edition. If different editions of Essential reading are listed, please check the VLE for reading supplements if none are available, please use the contents list and index of the new edition to find the relevant section. Comments on specific questions Zone B Text: We use the following abbreviations: M,K& R - Wyn Morgan, Michael Katz and Harvey Rosen, Microeconomics, McGraw-Hill, second edition, 009, ISBN: For each question, we point out the relevant sections from the main text (M,K & R) as well as the subject guide. Candidates should answer ELEVEN of the following FOURTEEN questions: all EIGHT of Section A (5 marks each) and THREE from Section B (0 marks each). Candidates are strongly advised to divide their time accordingly. If more questions are answered than requested, only the first answers attempted will be counted. 1

22 Section A Answer all eight questions in this section (5 marks each). Question 1 Consider the following simultaneous-move game with two players, 1 and. If 1 and/or have any dominated strategies, eliminate them. Once you have done this, consider the remaining game. In this remaining game, eliminate any dominated strategies of 1 and/or and so on. This method is called iterated elimination of dominated strategies. Find the equilibrium using this method. Your answer must show each round of elimination clearly. Player A B C A 1, 4, 0,4 Player 1 B 1 4,0 6,8, C 1 6,4 4,0 0,6 The coverage of game theory in M,K& R (Chapter 16) is not ideal. See Chapter 9 (Game theory: an introduction) of the subject guide for a detailed discussion. If you know what a dominated strategy is, this is easy. However, many candidates seem to confuse dominated strategy calculation with best response calculation. When you say for player 1 strategy B 1 dominates strategy A 1 that means the payoff of 1 from playing B 1 is better than that from playing A 1 no matter what player does. In other words, for every box in the row B 1, the first number (1 s payoff) must be higher than the first number in the box above. As you can see, this is true here. So we can conclude that B 1 dominates A 1. A best response, on the other hand, refers to the best response against a specific strategy. For player 1, the best response to A is C 1. This sort of calculation is not useful here we want to compare all possible payoffs of one strategy against all possible payoffs of another to determine whether one of these dominates the other. Once you understand the above, the answer is straightforward. Here B 1 dominates A 1, and C dominates A. So eliminate A 1 and A. After eliminating A 1 and A, we have the following reduced game: Player B C Player 1 B 1 6,8, C 1 4,0 0,6 In this game, B 1 dominates C 1. Eliminate C 1. We now have the further reduced game: Player B C Player 1 B 1 6,8, In the game above, B dominates C. Eliminate C. We are then left with B 1, B. Therefore, using the method of iterated elimination of dominated strategies, we get the equilibrium B 1, B.

23 Question Consider an exchange economy with two goods (milk and honey) and two consumers (A and B). There are 10 units available of each of the two goods. Consumer A is endowed with 6 units of milk and 4 units of honey. Consumer B is endowed with 4 units of milk and 6 units of honey. Let M denote units of milk and H denote units of honey. Consumer A has the following utility function: U A (M, H) = min[m, H] Consumer B has the following utility function: U B (M, H) = M + H Draw an Edgeworth box and show the area of mutually beneficial trades between the two consumers. M,K& R Chapter 1; subject guide Chapter 11 (General equilibrium and welfare economics). Milk and honey are perfect substitutes for consumer A and perfect complements for consumer B. You should know how to draw indifference curves for these preferences. The area of mutually beneficial trades is given by the shaded area EYZ. The question does not ask you this, but let us also understand where the equilibrium trades would lie in this box. Any equilibrium must be on the contract curve. So equilibrium trades lie somewhere on the part of the contract curve contained in the area EYZ. This is shown in the picture as the line ZA. 3

24 Question 3 A monopolist has a well-defined supply function. Is this true or false? Explain your answer. M,K& R Chapter 13; subject guide Chapter 8 (Competition and monopoly). Many candidates answered this question by saying that the statement is false because profit maximisation by the monopolist gives rise to a deadweight loss. You should understand that the presence or absence of deadweight loss has nothing to do with presence or absence of a supply function. Consider, for example, a firm in a competitive market. We know that a competitive firm has a well-defined supply function. Of course, we also know that there is no deadweight loss in the market. But now suppose the government imposes a per-unit tax. You know that this would distort the market equilibrium and give rise to a deadweight loss. But the supply function is still well-defined. So what is the answer? The crucial point is that a monopolist s optimisation is not independent of the market demand curve. Given a market demand (which is the average revenue curve), the monopolist chooses the best point on this curve (the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost). So if demand changes, the monopolist s optimal price-quantity bundle changes. Therefore, for a monopolist, there is no unique relationship between price and quantity supplied. Therefore a monopolist does not have a well-defined supply function. The statement is false. Question 4 A bond pays a fixed sum of 100 per year for ever (i.e. the bond is a perpetuity). The annual interest rate is 5%. What is the maximum amount an agent should pay to buy this bond? M,K& R Chapter 5.3; subject guide Chapter 5 (Saving, investment and choice over time). The discount factor is δ = 1 where r is the interest rate. The maximum price P should equal 1 + r the present value of payments received from next period onwards: P = δ100 + δ = δ 1 δ 100. Using the value of δ, P = 100/r. Since r = 0.05 = 1/0, P = 000. Question 5 Growth in the economy leads to a rise in the demand for labour. It follows that the equilibrium quantity of labour (measured in the number of hours worked) must rise. Is this true or false? Explain your answer. 4 M,K& R Chapter 5.1; subject guide Chapter 4 (Labour supply and the effect of taxes).

25 The important question is how you connect demand for labour to the equilibrium quantity of labour. You need to understand that the equilibrium quantity arises from the intersection of supply and demand. Therefore the change in equilibrium wage and quantity of labour as demand shifts up depends on the nature of the supply curve. If we are shifting demand along a positively sloped supply curve, clearly quantity and wage would rise. But as you know, the supply of labour is somewhat different from supply of standard goods, and could be backward bending. So we might be operating on a negatively sloped part of the labour supply curve. In this case, as demand shifts up, we would have a lower quantity of labour and a higher wage. Therefore, the statement is false. Question 6 Suppose the inverse demand curve is given by P = 10 Q. This is shown in the picture below. At the point A shown in the picture, is the demand elastic or inelastic (with respect to price change)? Explain your answer. M,K& R Chapter 3; subject guide Chapter 3 (Consumer theory). At point A, demand is elastic. To see this, note that the price elasticity of demand is: ε = dq P dp Q. Since P = 10 Q, the slope dq dp is -1 at all points, so we simply have: ε = P Q. It is clear from the picture that at point A, P > Q. It follows that at point A, ε > 1. 5

26 Question 7 The short run supply function of a competitive firm is given by { 0 if P < 10 Q = 3P 30 if P 10 where Q is the quantity supplied and P is the price of output. Derive the equation for the firm s marginal cost curve. M,K& R Chapter 10.1; subject guide Chapter 8 (Competition and monopoly). From the supply function: P = Q Since the supply function is P = MC, the marginal cost is given by: MC = Q Question 8 Too few people use public transport in London relative to the social optimum. Provide an economic argument in support of this statement. M,K& R Chapter 18; subject guide Chapter 13 (Externalities and public goods). This tests whether you understand the basic problem of externalities. When an activity generates negative externalities (e.g. activities that lead to pollution, congestion, noise, environmental degradation), the unregulated market outcome is too high relative to the social optimum. For example, everyone driving a car only takes into account own costs and benefits but does not take into account social costs of pollution, and so the aggregate amount of car use is higher than the social optimum. Similarly, when an activity generates positive externalities, individuals do not take into account the benefit of others when deciding on the level of the activity. Therefore the unregulated market outcome is too low compared to the social optimum. Here, the words too few people... relative to the social optimum should immediately trigger the phrase positive externality in your mind. Now try to think of some benefit that people using public transport confer on society. For example, assuming that commuters must travel to work, they could use public transport or drive private vehicles. The latter, of course, is worse for the environment. The presence of any such positive externality would tend to make the market outcome on public transport use too small relative to the social optimum. It should be clear to you that to provide an economic argument in support of the given statement, you simply need to suggest some positive externality from using public transport. 6

27 Section B Answer three questions from this section (0 marks each). Question 9 Suppose there are two identical firms in an industry. The output of firm 1 is denoted by q 1 and that of firm is denoted by q. Each firm can produce output at a constant marginal cost of 6. There are no fixed costs. Let Q denote total output, i.e. Q = q 1 + q. The inverse demand curve in the market is given by P = 30 Q (a) Find the Cournot-Nash equilibrium quantity produced by each firm and the market price. (b) What would be the quantities produced by each firm and market price under Stackelberg duopoly if firm 1 moves first? (c) Calculate the deadweight loss arising from Cournot-Nash and Stackelberg duopoly. Which market structure is more efficient? (d) Suppose, as in part (b), firm 1 moves first and decides how much to produce. Firm moves second and makes its production decision. There is then a third stage at which firm 1 can change its mind about how much to produce and makes a final decision. Find the equilibrium quantities produced by the two firms under this three-stage game. M,K& R Chapter 15; subject guide Chapter 10 (Oligopoly and strategic behaviour). (a) Firm 1 maximises: π 1 = (30 (q 1 + q ))q 1 6q 1. The first order condition is 4 4q 1 q = 0, which gives us the best response function of firm 1: q 1 = 6 q. Similarly, the best response function of firm is: q = 6 q 1. Solving, q 1 = q = 4. The market price is then P = 30 8 = 14. (b) Firm s best response is as above. Firm 1 maximises in stage 1 knowing that will use this best response function at stage. Therefore firm 1 s problem is: max q 1 (30 (q q 1 ))q 1 6q 1. This simplifies to: max q 1 (1 q 1 )q 1. This gives us q 1 = 6. It follows that q = 3. The market price is P = 30 9 = 1. 7

28 (c) Using the picture below, the deadweight loss under Cournot competition is: DWL C = 1 (14 6)(1 8) = 16. The deadweight loss under the Stackelberg market structure is: DWL S = 1 (1 6)(1 9) = 9. It follows that the Stackelberg market structure is more efficient. (d) This is a little tricky. Try to see why a Stackelberg leader gets an advantage. This is because the first mover can choose an output it is committed to, and the second mover just plays a best response to that. It is the fact that the first mover can commit to an output before the follower has a chance to choose output is the source of the first mover advantage. Here, in contrast, firm 1 can change its mind about how much to produce and makes a final decision after decides. Therefore the initial stage has no commitment value. But can commit to an output at stage knowing that 1 will readjust and choose a best response at stage 3. It follows that Firm can now act like the Stackelberg leader, and 1 becomes the follower. Therefore, now q 1 = 3 and q = 6. 8 Question 10 (a) Consider the following simultaneous-move game with two players, 1 and. Let p denote the probability with which player 1 plays A 1, where 0 p 1. B 1 is played with the residual probability. Next, let q denote the probability with which player plays A, where 0 q 1. B is played with the residual probability.

29 Draw a picture with p along the horizontal axis and q along the vertical axis and draw the best response functions of players 1 and. Clearly label any equilibrium points in the picture. Player A B Player 1 A 1, 3,0 B 1 3,5 1,6 (6 marks) (b) Consider the following extensive-form game with two players. Player 1 can end the game by choosing Out. If player 1 chooses In, Player then chooses between L and R. The payoffs are written as (Payoff to 1, Payoff to ). Identify any subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. (6 marks) (c) Suppose the following game is repeated infinitely. Players discount the future, so that, for each player, a payoff of x received t periods from today is worth δ t x today, where 0 < δ < 1. Show that it is possible to sustain cooperation (which in this case involves each player playing C every period) in the infinitely repeated game for high enough values of δ. Player C D Player 1 C, 0,3 D 3,0 1,1 (8 marks) The coverage of game theory in M,K& R (Chapter 16) is not ideal. See Chapter 9 (Game theory: an introduction) of the subject guide for a detailed discussion. (a) There are no pure NE. The mixed Nash equilibrium is p = 1/3 and q = /3. The best response function of player 1 is given by: 0 if q > /3 p = [0, 1] if q = /3 1 if q < /3. 9

30 The best response function of player is given by: 0 if p < 1/3 q = [0, 1] if p = 1/3 1 if p > 1/3. The picture below draws the best response functions and shows the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. 10 (b) To solve for the subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium in this game, we can simply solve backwards. At s decision node, would choose R (which gives a payoff of 3 compared to a payoff of from L). Knowing this, 1 s best choice is to stay out (which gives a payoff of 0 compared to a payoff of -1 from choosing In. ). It follows that the SPNE is (Out, R). Some of you prefer to write s strategy as R if 1 plays In. That is fine as well, although since there is exactly one node at which chooses a move, the qualifier is unnecessary here. (c) Cooperation can be sustained in equilibrium if players are patient enough, i.e. δ close enough to 1. This can be seen as follows. Suppose each player follows the following strategy: play C to start with, and continue to play C so long as there is no deviation. After any deviation, play D always. Let us compare the payoff from conforming to the payoff from deviating. Consider a deviation in period t by player 1. Note that the payoff until t 1 plays no role in comparing deviation payoff with the payoff from conforming. The payoffs only differ staring at t, so we might as well just consider the payoff starting at period t. Since this is an infinitely repeated game, the players face an infinite future starting at any period t, and the nature of calculations is exactly the same no matter when you start the calculations. Given the strategy of each player specified above, the payoff from always cooperating (starting at t) is as follows. A player gets at t, at t + 1 which is worth δ at t and so on. So

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9 CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO May 22, 2015 Announcements HW #3 is due next week. Ch. 6.1: Ultimatum Game This is a simple game that can model a very simplified

More information

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015 CUR 41: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 015 Instructions: Please write your name in English. This exam is closed-book. Total time: 10 minutes. There are 4 questions,

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati. Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati. Module No. # 06 Illustrations of Extensive Games and Nash Equilibrium

More information

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercise - Quantity competition 1 Take firm 1 s perspective Total revenue is R(q 1 = (4 q 1 q q 1 and, hence, marginal revenue is MR 1 (q 1 = 4 q 1 q Marginal cost is MC

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly Prerequisites Almost essential Monopoly Useful, but optional Game Theory: Strategy and Equilibrium DUOPOLY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell 1 Overview Duopoly Background How the basic

More information

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS University of Victoria Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS Martin Farnham Problem Set #5 Note: Answer each question as clearly and concisely as possible. Use of diagrams, where appropriate, is strongly

More information

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 DUOPOLY MODELS Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 Contents 1. Collusion in Duopoly 2. Cournot Competition 3. Cournot Competition when One Firm is Subsidized 4. Stackelberg

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 2. Dynamic games of complete information Chapter 1. Dynamic games of complete and perfect information Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas

More information

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours YORK UNIVERSITY Faculty of Graduate Studies Final Examination December 14, 2010 Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics S. Bucovetsky time=2.5 hours Do any 6 of the following 10 questions. All count

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4) Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4) Outline: Modeling by means of games Normal form games Dominant strategies; dominated strategies,

More information

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals. Chapter 3 Oligopoly Oligopoly is an industry where there are relatively few sellers. The product may be standardized (steel) or differentiated (automobiles). The firms have a high degree of interdependence.

More information

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization ECON/MGMT 115 Industrial Organization 1. Cournot Model, reprised 2. Bertrand Model of Oligopoly 3. Cournot & Bertrand First Hour Reviewing the Cournot Duopoloy Equilibria Cournot vs. competitive markets

More information

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics November 16, 2012 Prof. Dr. Sebastian Rausch Centre for Energy Policy and Economics Department of Management, Technology and Economics ETH Zürich

More information

REPEATED GAMES. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Repeated Games. Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic.

REPEATED GAMES. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Repeated Games. Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic. Prerequisites Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic REPEATED GAMES MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 1 Overview Repeated Games Basic structure Embedding the game in context

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104 Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104 Problem Set 1 1. Each of n farmers can costlessly produce as much wheat as she chooses. Suppose that the kth farmer produces W k, so that the total amount of what produced

More information

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible. Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible. 1) [36 points] Suppose that, within the state of Wisconsin, market demand for cigarettes

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics (for MBA students) 44111 (1393-94 1 st term) - Group 2 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Game Theory Game:

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. 1 Oligopoly The key feature of the oligopoly (and to some extent, the monopolistically competitive market) market structure is that one rm

More information

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001 AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001 1. Yes, the allocation will be efficient, since the tax in this question is a tax on the value of people s endowments. This is a lump sum tax. In an

More information

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION A10282W1 FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION Preliminary Examination for Philosophy, Politics and Economics Preliminary Examination for Economics and Management Preliminary Examination for History and Economics SECOND

More information

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley Theoretical Tools of Public Finance 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley 1 THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL TOOLS Theoretical tools: The set of tools designed to understand the mechanics

More information

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing BEE12 Basic Mathematical Economics Week 1, Lecture Tuesday 9.12.3 Profit maximization / Elasticity Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter 1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs

More information

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers Chapter : Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers Learning Objectives Students should learn to:. Extend the reaction function ideas developed in the Cournot duopoly model to a model of sequential behavior

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2018

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2018 Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2018 This exam is designed to test your broad knowledge of microeconomics. There are three sections: one required and two choice sections. You must complete both problems

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 07. (40 points) Consider a Cournot duopoly. The market price is given by q q, where q and q are the quantities of output produced

More information

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET Chapter 2 Theory y of Consumer Behaviour In this chapter, we will study the behaviour of an individual consumer in a market for final goods. The consumer has to decide on how much of each of the different

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing BEE14 { Basic Mathematics for Economists BEE15 { Introduction to Mathematical Economics Week 1, Lecture 1, Notes: Optimization II 3/12/21 Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter

More information

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally. AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July 2017 time : 1 hour Do all 4 questions. All count equally. Q1. Monopoly is inefficient because the monopoly s owner makes high profits, and the monopoly s

More information

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1 Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak Lecture 1 Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility Maximization Problem Expenditure Minimization Problem Mathematical Theory of Production Profit Maximization

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Econ 409 018 Fall A reminder: An equilibrium is characterized by a set of strategies. As emphasized in the class, a strategy is a complete contingency plan (for every hypothetical

More information

HW Consider the following game:

HW Consider the following game: HW 1 1. Consider the following game: 2. HW 2 Suppose a parent and child play the following game, first analyzed by Becker (1974). First child takes the action, A 0, that produces income for the child,

More information

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005 GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment November 005 Q1. What are the market price, and aggregate quantity sold, in long run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market for which the demand function has the

More information

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya Microeconomics III Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 01) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya Oligopoly is a market in which only a few firms compete with one another,

More information

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS ECO410H: Practice Questions SOLUTIONS 1. (a) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (M, M). (b) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (R4, C3). (c) The two Nash equilibria are

More information

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

In Class Exercises. Problem 1 In Class Exercises Problem 1 A group of n students go to a restaurant. Each person will simultaneously choose his own meal but the total bill will be shared amongst all the students. If a student chooses

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C Monday 11.15 am 1.15 pm wnowak@prawo.uni.wroc.pl http://prawo.uni.wroc.pl/user/12141/students-resources Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility

More information

Chapter 33: Public Goods

Chapter 33: Public Goods Chapter 33: Public Goods 33.1: Introduction Some people regard the message of this chapter that there are problems with the private provision of public goods as surprising or depressing. But the message

More information

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2013 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0) LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY September 11, 01 Introduction: So far we have considered models of perfect competition and monopoly which are the two polar extreme cases of market outcome. In models of monopoly,

More information

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS Learning Outcomes At the end of the presentation, participants should be able to: 1. Explain the concept of utility and welfare economics 2. Describe the measurement

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Kai Hao Yang /2/207 In this lecture, we will apply the concepts in game theory to study oligopoly. In short, unlike

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli 7 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1 Contract Theory has become only recently a subfield of Economics. As the name suggest the main object of the analysis is a contract. Therefore

More information

Economics 171: Final Exam

Economics 171: Final Exam Question 1: Basic Concepts (20 points) Economics 171: Final Exam 1. Is it true that every strategy is either strictly dominated or is a dominant strategy? Explain. (5) No, some strategies are neither dominated

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 01A) Fall 01 Oligopolistic markets (PR 1.-1.5) Lectures 11-1 Sep., 01 Oligopoly (preface to game theory) Another form

More information

On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule

On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule WP 2018/4 ISSN: 2464-4005 www.nhh.no WORKING PAPER On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule Kenneth Fjell og Debashis Pal Department of Accounting, Auditing and Law Institutt for regnskap,

More information

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1 Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory Practice Exam 2 with Solutions Chapter 10, Question 1 Which of the following is not a condition for perfect competition? Firms a. take prices as given b. sell a standardized

More information

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

MKTG 555: Marketing Models MKTG 555: Marketing Models A Brief Introduction to Game Theory for Marketing February 14-21, 2017 1 Basic Definitions Game: A situation or context in which players (e.g., consumers, firms) make strategic

More information

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Recap Last class (September 20, 2016) Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Today (October 13, 2016) Finitely

More information

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions ECO 300 Fall 2005 November 22 OLIGOPOLY PART 2 PRISONER S DILEMMA Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, 481-2 Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions X = 12 2 P + P, X = 12 2 P + P 1 1 2 2 2 1

More information

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1 . Economic Applications of Game Theory Fall 00 TA: Youngjin Hwang Problem 3 Solutions. (a) There are three subgames: [A] the subgame starting from Player s decision node after Player s choice of P; [B]

More information

Final Solutions ECON 301 May 13, 2012

Final Solutions ECON 301 May 13, 2012 Final Solutions ECON May, Problem a) Because it is easier and more familiar, we will work with the monotonic transformation (and thus equivalent) utility function: U(x, x ) = log x + log x. MRS = MUx MU

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Repeated Games 1 / 41 Recap: SPNE The solution concept for dynamic games with complete information is the subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) Selten (1965): A strategy

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Ram Singh October 4, 015 This Write-up is available at photocopy shop. Not for circulation. In this write-up we provide intuition behind the two fundamental theorems

More information

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare Price Changes and Consumer Welfare While the basic theory previously considered is extremely useful as a tool for analysis, it is also somewhat restrictive. The theory of consumer choice is often referred

More information

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition Static Games and Cournot Competition Lecture 3: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors oligopoly market Each firm has to consider

More information

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics Microeconomics I Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics Academic year 2011-2012 Second test 1st Semester January 11, 2012 Fernando Branco (fbranco@ucp.pt) Fernando Machado (fsm@ucp.pt)

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Journal of Economics and Management, 2018, Vol. 14, No. 1, 1-31 License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Masahiko Hattori Faculty

More information

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium Below are two different games. The first game has a dominant strategy equilibrium. The second game has two Nash

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory Practice Exam 2 with Solutions Chapter 10, Question 1 Which of the following is not a condition for perfect competition? Firms a. take prices as given b. sell a standardized

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to. 1 Econ 101A Final Exam Th 15 December. Please solve Problem 1, 2, and 3 in the first blue book and Problems 4 and 5 in the

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information Backward Induction in dynamic games of imperfect information We start at the end of the trees first find the Nash equilibrium (NE) of the last subgame

More information

Efficient provision of a public good

Efficient provision of a public good Public Goods Once a pure public good is provided, the additional resource cost of another person consuming the good is zero. The public good is nonrival in consumption. Examples: lighthouse national defense

More information

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. (a) The monopolist solves: The first order condition is max Π(Q) = Q(a bq) cq. Q a Q c = 0, or equivalently, Q = a c, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated

More information

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 2: Household ehaviour Introductory Microeconomics (ES11) Topic 2: Consumer Theory Exercise 4: Suggested Solutions 1. Which of the following statements is not valid? utility maximising consumer chooses

More information

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Noncooperative Oligopoly Noncooperative Oligopoly Oligopoly: interaction among small number of firms Conflict of interest: Each firm maximizes its own profits, but... Firm j s actions affect firm i s profits Example: price war

More information

Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?

Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents? Chapter 10 Strategic Behaviour Exercise 10.1 Table 10.1 is the strategic form representation of a simultaneous move game in which strategies are actions. s b 1 s b 2 s b 3 s a 1 0, 2 3, 1 4, 3 s a 2 2,

More information

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers Econ 5001 Spring 2018 Prof. James Peck The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers Note: There were 4 versions of the test: A, B, C, and D, based on player 1 s

More information

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010 Answer Key Problem Set 1 Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010 Please give your answers to your class teacher by Friday of week 6 LT. If you not to hand in at your class, make

More information

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery Answer all questions. 100 points possible. 1. [20 points] Policymakers are concerned that Americans save too little. To encourage more saving, some policymakers

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Problem Set 1 These questions will go over basic game-theoretic concepts and some applications. homework is due during class on week 4. This [1] In this problem (see Fudenberg-Tirole

More information

PBAF 516 YA Prof. Mark Long Practice Midterm Questions

PBAF 516 YA Prof. Mark Long Practice Midterm Questions PBAF 516 YA Prof. Mark Long Practice Midterm Questions Note: these 10 questions were drawn from questions that I have given in prior years (in a similar class). These questions should not be considered

More information

Problem Set 2 Answers

Problem Set 2 Answers Problem Set 2 Answers BPH8- February, 27. Note that the unique Nash Equilibrium of the simultaneous Bertrand duopoly model with a continuous price space has each rm playing a wealy dominated strategy.

More information

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Reputations arise in situations where there is an element of repetition, and also where coordination between players is possible. One definition of leadership is that

More information

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2 Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2 Question 1 (Microeconomics, 30 points). A ticket to a newly staged opera is on sale through sealed-bid auction. There are three bidders,

More information

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30)

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30) Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30) Problem (1) (8 points) Consider the following lobbying game between two firms. Each firm may lobby

More information

ECONOMICS 336Y5Y Fall/Spring 2014/15. PUBLIC ECONOMICS Spring Term Test February 26, 2015

ECONOMICS 336Y5Y Fall/Spring 2014/15. PUBLIC ECONOMICS Spring Term Test February 26, 2015 UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO MISSISSAUGA DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 336Y5Y Fall/Spring 2014/15 PUBLIC ECONOMICS Spring Term Test February 26, 2015 Please fill in your full name and student number in the

More information

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE Answers to Problem Set 2 [1] (a) This is standard (we have even done it in class). The one-shot Cournot outputs can be computed to be A/3, while the payoff to each firm can

More information

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours Microeconomics, IB and IBP Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours There are two pages in this exam. In total, there are six questions in the exam. The questions are organized into four sections.

More information

Microeconomics. Please remember Spring 2018

Microeconomics. Please remember Spring 2018 Microeconomics Please remember Spring 2018 "The time has come," the Walrus said, "To talk of many things: Of shoes - and ships - and sealing-wax - Of cabbages - and kings And why the sea is boiling hot

More information

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets Chapter 5 Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors In determining strategy each firm has to consider rival s reactions strategic

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 02

More information

Mathematical Economics

Mathematical Economics Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C wioletta.nowak@uwr.edu.pl http://prawo.uni.wroc.pl/user/12141/students-resources Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility Maximization Problem

More information

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013 Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar. 2017 Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 201 1. The inverse demand function for apples is defined by the equation p = 214 5q, where

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 03

More information

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Some Notes on Timing in Games Some Notes on Timing in Games John Morgan University of California, Berkeley The Main Result If given the chance, it is better to move rst than to move at the same time as others; that is IGOUGO > WEGO

More information

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2 Solutions to Spring 014 ECON 301 Final Group A Problem 1. (Quasilinear income effect) (5 points) Mirabella consumes chocolate candy bars x 1 and fruits x. The prices of the two goods are = 4 and p = 4

More information

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets 経済研究 ( 明治学院大学 ) 第 155 号 2018 年 Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets Jinryo TAKASAKI I Introduction Many governments have been attempting to make public sectors more efficient. Some socialistic

More information

University of Toronto June 22, 2004 ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #1

University of Toronto June 22, 2004 ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #1 Department of Economics Prof. Gustavo Indart University of Toronto June 22, 2004 SOLUTIONS ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test #1 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER INSTRUCTIONS: 1.

More information