Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?"

Transcription

1 Chapter 10 Strategic Behaviour Exercise 10.1 Table 10.1 is the strategic form representation of a simultaneous move game in which strategies are actions. s b 1 s b 2 s b 3 s a 1 0, 2 3, 1 4, 3 s a 2 2, 4 0, 3 3, 2 s a 3 1, 1 2, 0 2, 1 Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents? 2. Which strategies can always be eliminated because they are dominated? 3. Which strategies can be eliminated if it is common knowledge that both players are rational? 4. What are the Nash equilibria in pure strategies? Outline Answer: 1. No player has a dominant strategy. 2. Both s a 3 and s b 2 can be eliminated as individually irrational. 3. With common knowledge of rationality we can eliminate the dominated strategies: s a 3 and s b The Nash Equilibria in pure strategies are (s a 2, s b 1) and (s a 1, s b 3) 153

2 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise 10.2 Table 10.2 again represents a simultaneous move game in which strategies are actions. s b 1 s b 2 s b 3 s a 1 0, 2 2, 0 3, 1 s a 2 2, 0 0, 2 3, 1 s a 3 1, 3 1, 3 4, 4 Table 10.2: Pure-strategy Nash equilibria 1. Identify the best responses for each of the players a, b. 2. Is there a Nash equilibrium in pure strategies? Outline Answer 1. For player A the best reply is s a 2 if player B plays s b 1, s a 1if B plays s b 2, s a 3 if B plays s b 3.For player B the best reply is s b 1 if A plays s a 1, s b 2 if A plays s a 2, s b 3 if A plays s a 3 2. The unique Nash Equilibrium is (s a 3, s b 3) c Frank Cowell

3 Microeconomics Exercise 10.3 A taxpayer has income y that should be reported in full to the tax authority. There is a flat (proportional) tax rate γ on income. The reporting technology means that that taxpayer must report income in full or zero income. The tax authority can choose whether or not to audit the taxpayer. Each audit costs an amount ϕ and if the audit uncovers under-reporting then the taxpayer is required to pay the full amount of tax owed plus a fine F. 1. Set the problem out as a game in strategic form where each agent (taxpayer, tax-authority) has two pure strategies. 2. Explain why there is no simultaneous-move equilibrium in pure strategies. 3. Find the mixed-strategy equilibrium. How will the equilibrium respond to changes in the parameters γ, ϕ and F? Outline Answer 1. See Table Taxpayer Tax-Authority s b 1 s b 2 Audit Not audit s a 1 conceal [1 γ] y F, γy + F ϕ y, 0 s a 2 report [1 γ] y, γy ϕ [1 γ] y, γy Table 10.3: The tax audit game 2. Consider the best responses: Tax-Authority s best response to conceal is audit Taxpayer s best response to audit is report Tax-Authority s best response to report is not audit Taxpayer s best response to not audit is conceal 3. Suppose the taxpayer conceals with probability π a and the tax authority audits with probability π b. (a) Expected payoff to the taxpayer is υ a = π a [ π b [[1 γ] y F ] + [ 1 π b] y ] which, on simplifying, gives + [1 π a ] [ π b [1 γ] y + [ 1 π b] [1 γ] y ], υ a = [1 γ] y + π a [ 1 π b] γy π a π b F. So we have dυ a dπ a = [ 1 π b] γy π b F c Frank Cowell

4 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR π b 1 π *b taxpayer reaction tax authority reaction 0 π *a 1 π a Figure 10.1: The tax audit game It is clear that dυa dπ 0 as π b π b where a π b := γy γy + F. (10.1) So the taxpayer s optimal strategy is to conceal with probability 1 if the probability of audit is too low (π b < π b ) and to conceal with probability zero if the probability of audit is high. (b) Expected payoff to the tax-authority is υ b = π b [π a [γy + F ϕ] + [1 π a ] [γy ϕ]] which, on simplifying, gives So we have + [ 1 π b] [π a [0] + [1 π a ] [γy]] υ b = [1 π a ] γy + π a π b [γy + F ] π b ϕ dυ b dπ b = πa [γy + F ] ϕ It is clear that dυb 0 as π a π a where dπ b π a := ϕ γy + F. (10.2) So the tax authority s optimal strategy is to audit with probability 0 if the probability of the taxpayer concealing is low (π a < π a ) and to audit with probability 1 if the probability of concealment is high. (c) This yields a unique mixed-strategy equilibrium ( π a, π b) as illustrated in Figure c Frank Cowell

5 Microeconomics (d) The effect of a change in any of the model parameters on the equilibrium can be found by differentiating the expressions (10.1) and (10.2). we have π a γ = ϕy [γy + F ] 2 > 0; π b ϕ = F y [γy + F ] 2 > 0. π a ϕ = 1 γy + F > 0; π a F = ϕ [γy + F ] 2 < 0; π b ϕ = 0. π b F = γy [γy + F ] 2 < 0. c Frank Cowell

6 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise 10.4 Take the battle-of-the-sexes game in Table s b 1 s b 2 [West] [East] s a 1 [West] 2,1 0,0 s a 2 [East] 0,0 1,2 Table 10.4: Battle of the sexes strategic form 1. Show that, in addition to the pure strategy Nash equilibria there is also a mixed strategy equilibrium. 2. Construct the payoff-possibility frontier. Why is the interpretation of this frontier in the battle-of-the-sexes context rather unusual in comparison with the Cournot-oligopoly case? 3. Show that the mixed-strategy equilibrium lies strictly inside the frontier. 4. Suppose the two players adopt the same randomisation device, observable by both of them: they know that the specified random variable takes the value [ 1] with probability π and 2[ with probability ] 1 π; they agree to play s a 1, s b 1 with probability π and s a 2, s b 2 with probability 1 π; show that this correlated mixed strategy always produces a payoff on the frontier. Outline Answer 1. Suppose a plays [West] with probability π a and b plays [West] with probability π b. The expected payoff to a is υ a = π a [ π b [2] + [ 1 π b] [0] ] + [1 π a ] [ π b [0] + [ 1 π b] [1] ] So we have = 2π a π b + [1 π a ] [ 1 π b] = 1 π a π b + 3π a π b (10.3) dυ a = 1 + 3πb dπa It is clear that dυa dπ 0 as π b 1 a 3. The expected payoff to b is And so υ b = π b [π a [1] + [1 π a ] [0]] + [ 1 π b] [π a [0] + [1 π a ] [2]] = π a π b + 2 [1 π a ] [ 1 π b] = 2 2π a 2π b + 3π a π b. (10.4) dυ b = 2 + 3πa dπb It is clear that dυb 0 as π a 2 dπ b 3. So there is a mixed-strategy equilibrium where ( π a, π b) = ( 2 3, 3) 1. c Frank Cowell

7 Microeconomics 2. See Figure Note that, unlike oligopoly where the payoff (profit) is transferable, in this interpretation the payoff (utility) is not so the frontier has not been extended beyond the points (2,1) and (1,2). The lightly shaded area depicts all the points in the attainable set of utility can be thrown away. The heavily shaded area in Figure 10.2 shows the expected-utility outcomes achievable by randomisation. The frontier is given by the broken line joining the points (2,1) and (1,2). Figure 10.2: Battle-of-sexes: payoffs 3. The utility associated with the mixed-strategy equilibrium is ( 2 3, 2 3) and clearly lies inside the frontier in Figure Given that the probability of playing [West] is π, the expected utility for each player is υ a = 2π + [1 π] = 1 + π υ b = π + 2 [1 π] = 2 π If we allow π to take any value in [0, 1] this picks out the points on the broken line in Figure c Frank Cowell

8 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise 10.5 Rework Exercise 10.4 for the case of the Chicken game in Table s b 1 s b 2 s a 1 2, 2 1, 3 s a 2 3, 1 0, 0 Table 10.5: Chicken strategic form Outline Answer υ b (1½, 1½) υ a Figure 10.3: Chicken: payoffs 1. Suppose a plays s a 1 with probability π a and b plays s b 1 with probability π b. The expected payoff to a is υ a = π a [ π b [2] + [ 1 π b] [1] ] + [1 π a ] [ π b [3] + [ 1 π b] [0] ] So we have = π a + 3π b 2π a π b (10.5) dυ a dπ a = 1 2πb It is clear that dυa dπ 0 as π b 1 a 2. The expected payoff to b is And so υ b = π b [π a [2] + [1 π a ] [1]] + [ 1 π b] [π a [3] + [1 π a ] [0]] = π b + 3π a 2π a π b (10.6) dυ b dπ b = 1 2πa It is clear that dυb 0 as π a 1 dπ b 2. So there is a mixed-strategy equilibrium where ( π a, π b) = ( 1 2, 2) 1. c Frank Cowell

9 Microeconomics 2. See Figure The lightly shaded area depicts all the points in the attainable set of utility can be thrown away. The heavily shaded area shows the expected-utility outcomes achievable by randomisation 3. The utility associated with the mixed-strategy equilibrium is ( 1 1 2, 1 1 2) and clearly lies inside the frontier. 4. Once again a correlated strategy would produce an outcome on the broken line. c Frank Cowell

10 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR [LEFT] Alf [RIGHT] Bill [left] [right] [left] [right] Charlie [L] [M] [R] [L] [M] [R] [L] [M] [R] [L] [M] [R] Figure 10.4: Benefits of restricting information s a 1 :[LEFT] s a 2 :[RIGHT] s c 1 s c 2 s c 3 s c 1 s c 2 s c 3 L M R L M R s b 1 [left] 0, 1, 3 2, 2, 2 0, 1.0 1, 1, 1 2, 2, 0 1, 1, 0 s b 2 [right] 0, 0, 0 0, 0, 0 0, 0, 0 1, 0, 0 2, 2, 2 1, 0, 3 Table 10.6: Alf, Bill, Charlie Simultaneous move Exercise 10.6 Consider the three-person game depicted in Figure 10.4 where strategies are actions. For each strategy combination, the column of figures in parentheses denotes the payoff s to Alf, Bill and Charlie, respectively. 1. For the simultaneous-move game shown in Figure 10.4 show that there is a unique pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. 2. Suppose the game is changed. Alf and Bill agree to coordinate their actions by tossing a coin and playing [LEFT],[left] if heads comes up and [RIGHT],[right] if tails comes up. Charlie is not told the outcome of the spin of the coin before making his move. What is Charlie s best response? Compare your answer to part Now take the version of part 2 but suppose that Charlie knows the outcome of the coin toss before making his choice. What is his best response? Compare your answer to parts 1 and 2. Does this mean that restricting information can be socially beneficial? Outline Answer c Frank Cowell

11 Microeconomics s c 1 s c 2 s c 3 L M R Heads [left,left] 0, 1, 3 2, 2, 2 0, 1.0 Tails [right,right] 1, 0, 0 2, 2, 2 1, 0, 3 Table 10.7: Alf, Bill correlate their play 1. The strategic form of the game can be represented as in Table 10.6 from which it is clear that the best responses for the three players are as follows: BR a (left, L) = RIGHT BR a (left, M) = {LEFT, RIGHT} BR a (left, R) = {LEFT, RIGHT} BR a (right, L) = RIGHT BR a (right, M) = RIGHT BR a (right, R) = RIGHT BR b (LEFT, L) = left BR b (LEFT, M) = left BR b (LEFT, R) = left BR b (RIGHT, L) = left BR b (RIGHT, M) = {left, right} BR b (RIGHT, R) = left BR c (LEFT, left) = L BR c (LEFT, right) = {L, M, R} BR c (RIGHT, left) = L BR c (RIGHT, right) = R it is clear that (RIGHT, left, L) is the unique Nash equilibrium. Everyone gets a payoff of 1 at the Nash equilibrium: total payoff is Charlie knows the coordination rule but not the outcome of the coin toss. The payoffs are now as in Table Note that neither of the possible action combinations by Alf and Bill would have emerged under the Nash equilibrium in part 1. It is clear that now the expected payoff to Charlie of playing L is 1.5; the expected payoff of playing R is also 1.5. But the expected payoff of playing M is 2. So Charlie s best response is M Everybody gets a payoff of 2 with certainty: total payoff is Charlie now knows both the coordination rule and the outcome of the coin toss. From Table 10.7 it is clear that his best response is L if it is heads and R if it is tails. Now he gets a payoff of 3 and the others get an equal chance of 0 or 1: total payoff is 4, less than that under part 2 but more than under part 1. c Frank Cowell

12 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise 10.7 Consider a duopoly with identical firms. The cost function for firm f is C 0 + cq f, f = 1, 2. The inverse demand function is β 0 βq where C 0, c, β 0 and β are all positive numbers and total output is given by q = q 1 + q Find the isoprofit contour and the reaction function for firm Find the Cournot-Nash equilibrium for the industry and illustrate it in ( q 1, q 2) -space. 3. Find the joint-profit maximising solution for the industry and illustrate it on the same diagram. 4. If firm 1 acts as leader and firm 2 as a follower find the Stackelberg solution. 5. Draw the set of payoff possibilities and plot the payoffs for cases 2-4 and for the case where there is a monopoly. Outline Answer 1. Firm 2 s profits are given by Π 2 = pq 2 [ C 0 + cq 2] = [ β 0 β [ q 1 + q 2]] q 2 [ C 0 + cq 2] So it is clear that a typical isoprofit contour is given by the locus of ( q 1, q 2) satisfying [ β0 c β [ q 1 + q 2]] q 2 = constant see Figure The FOC for a maximum of Π 2 with respect to q 2 keeping q 1 constant is β 0 β [ q 1 + 2q 2] c = 0 which yields the Cournot reaction function for firm 2 q 2 = χ 2 ( q 1) = β 0 c 2β 1 2 q1 (10.7) a straight line. Note that this relationship holds wherever firm 2 can make positive profits. See Figure 10.6 which shows the locus of points that maximise Π 2 for various given values of q By symmetry the reaction function for firm 1 is q 1 = β 0 c 2β c Frank Cowell q2 (10.8)

13 Microeconomics q 2 profit q 1 Figure 10.5: Iso-profit curves for firm 2 q 2 χ 2 ( ) q 1 Figure 10.6: Reaction function for firm 2 c Frank Cowell

14 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR The Cournot-Nash solution is where (10.7) and (10.8) hold simultaneously, i.e. where q 1 = β 0 c 1 [ β0 c 1 ] 2β 2 2β 2 q1 (10.9) The solution is at q 1 = q 2 = q C where q C = β 0 c 3β (10.10) see Figure The price is 2 3 β c. q 2 χ 1 ( ) q C χ 2 ( ) q 1 Figure 10.7: Cournot-Nash equilibrium 3. Writing q = q 1 + q 2, the two firms joint profits are given by The FOC for a maximum is Π 2 = pq [2C 0 + cq] = [β 0 βq] q [2C 0 + cq] β 0 c 2βq = 0 which gives the collusive monopoly solution as q M = β 0 c 2β. (10.11) with the corresponding price 1 2 [β 0 + c]. However, the break-down into outputs q 1 and q 2 is in principle undefined. Examine Figure The points (q M, 0) and (0, q M ) are the endpoints of the two reaction functions (each indicates the amount that one firm would produce if it knew that the c Frank Cowell

15 Microeconomics other was producing zero). The solution lies somewhere on the line joining these two points. In particular the symmetric joint-profit maximising outcome (q J, q J ) lies exactly at the midpoint where the isoprofit contour of firm 1 is tangent to the isoprofit contour of firm 2. q 2 χ 1 ( ) (0,q M ) q J q C χ 2 ( ) (q M,0) q 1 Figure 10.8: Joint-profit maximisation 4. If firm 1 is the leader and firm 2 is the follower then firm 1 can predict firm 2 s output using the reaction function (10.7) and build this into its optimisation problem. The leader s profits are therefore given as [ β0 β [ q 1 + χ 2 ( q 1)]] q 1 [ C 0 + cq 1] which, using (10.7), becomes [ β 0 β [ q 1 + β 0 c 2β 1 2 q1 ]] q 1 [ C 0 + cq 1] = 1 [ β0 c βq 1] q 1 C 0 (10.12) 2 The FOC for the leader s problem is 1 2 [β 0 c] βq 1 = 0 so that the leader s output is q 1 S = β 0 c 2β and, using (10.7), the follower s output must be q 2 S = β 0 c 4β see Figure The price is 1 4 β c. c Frank Cowell

16 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR q 2 q C q S χ 2 ( ) (q M,0) q 1 Figure 10.9: Firm 1 as Stackelberg leader Cournot Joint profit max Stackelberg leader Stackelberg follower output price profit β 0 c 1 3β 3 β c. [β 0 c] 2 9β C 0 β 0 c 1 4β 2 [β [β 0 + c] 0 c] 2 8β C 0 β 0 c 1 2β 4 β c [β 0 c] 2 8β C 0 β 0 c 1 4β 4 β c [β 0 c] 2 16β C 0 Table 10.8: Outcomes of quantity competition linear model 5. The outcomes of the various models are given in Table 10.8.and the possible payoffs are illustrated in Figure Note that maximum total profit on the boundary of the triangle is exactly twice the entry in the Joint profit max row, namely 1 4 [β 0 c] 2 /β 2C 0. This holds as long as there are two firms present i.e. right up to a point arbitraily close to either of the end-points. But if one firm is closed down (so that the other becomes a monopolist) then its fixed costs are no longer incurred and the monopolist makes profit Π M := 1 4 [β 0 c] 2 /β C 0. In Figure the point marked is where both firms are in operation but firm 1 is getting all of the joint profit and the point (Π M, 0) is the situation where firm 1 is operating on its own. c Frank Cowell

17 Microeconomics Π 2 (0, Π M ) (Π J,Π J ) (Π C,Π C ) (Π S,Π S ) C 0 Π 1 { (Π M,0) Figure 10.10: Possible payoffs c Frank Cowell

18 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise 10.8 An oligopoly contains N identical firms. The cost function is convex in output. Show that if the firms act as Cournot competitors then as N increases the market price will approach the competitive price. Outline Answer The assumption of convex costs will ensure that there is no minimum viable size of firm. Profits for a typical firm are given by where p ( q f + K ) q f C ( q f ) (10.13) K := N j=1 j f is the total output of all the other firms, which of course firm f takes to be constant under the Cournot assumption. Maximising this by choice of q f gives the FOC for an interior solution q j p q ( q f + K ) q f + p ( q f + K ) C q ( q f ) = 0 (10.14) Given that all the firms are identical we may rewrite condition (10.14) as p q (q) q N + p (q) C q = 0 (10.15) where q is industry output. This in turn can be rewritten as p (q) = C q ηn (10.16) where η := p (q) qp q (q) is the elasticity of demand. The result follows immediately: as N becomes large (10.16) approaches p (q) = C q (10.17). c Frank Cowell

19 Microeconomics Exercise 10.9 Two identical firms consider entering a new market; setting up in the new market incurs a once-for-all cost K > 0; production involves constant marginal cost c. If both firms enter the market Bertrand competition then takes place afterwards. If the firms make their entry decision sequentially, what is the equilibrium? Outline Answer 1. The firms first decide whether to enter (and hence incur the fixed cost K), then they play the Bertrand pricing game. K is thus considered a sunk cost when the second-stage game is played. When both firms decide to enter, the unique Nash equilibrium of the Bertrand pricing game is to set prices equal to marginal cost, (p 1, p 2 ) = (c, c). This yields overall profits for the two firms (Π 1, Π 2 ) = ( K, K). 2. The extensive form is shown in Figure Figure 10.11: The entry game 3. To find the Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium, solve the game by backwards induction. If firm 1 decides to enter, firm 2 s optimal strategy is not to enter (profit of 0 compared to K). If firm one decides not to enter, then firm 2 should enter. Firm two can observe the action of firm 1, thus it can form history-dependent strategies. The optimal strategy is not to enter if firm 1 entered, and to enter if firm 1 did not enter the market, (,enter). Thus, the decision for firm 1 is between entering and receiving profits of Π M K, or not entering and receiving 0. For K small, firm 1 will decide to enter. The unique Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium in strategies is thus (, (not enter,enter)), (10.18) yielding the equilibrium outcome (,not enter). c Frank Cowell

20 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR 4. Clearly, there is a first-mover advantage, since even a small fixed cost leads to the monopoly outcome and hence strictly positive profits for the first mover. c Frank Cowell

21 Microeconomics Exercise Two firms have inherited capacity from the past so that production must take place subject to the constraint q f q f, f = 1, 2 There are zero marginal costs. Let χ ( ) be the Cournot (quantity-competition) reaction function for each firm. If the firms compete on prices show that the following must be true in a pure-strategy equilibrium: 1. Both firms will charge the same price p. 2. p = p ( q 1 + q 2). 3. p p ( χ 1 ( q 2) + q 2). 4. q 1 χ 1 ( q 2). Outline Answer 1. If p 1 < p 2 then, if q 1 = q 1 firm 1 could make higher profits by raising its price. Otherwise firm 1 would be undercutting firm 2 so that firm 2 would be forced to reduce its price or lose all its sales to firm 1. Hence we must have p 1 = p 2 = p in equilibrium. 2. Consider two cases: (a) If p > p ( q 1 + q 2).then for one or both firms it must be the case that q f < q f the price is too high to exhaust capacity. In which case one of the firms could reduce the price slightly, capture sales from the other firm and increase profits. (b) If p < p ( q 1 + q 2).then both firms are producing to capacity. Each could increase profits just by raising prices to its (rationed) customers. Therefore p = p ( q 1 + q 2) (10.19) 3. If p < p ( χ 1 ( q 2) + q 2).one of the firms must be capacity constrained: (a) If firm 1 is capacity constrained it could raise its price by p and make additional profits p q 1. (b) Otherwise, if firm 2 is capacity constrained then firm 1 s profits are q 1 p ( q 1 + q 2) (10.20) If firm 1 is also capacity constrained then it could increase profits by raising its price. So we may take firm 1 as not being capacity constrained. Given the definition of χ 1 ( ) as firm 1 s best response function (10.20) can be written: c Frank Cowell χ 1 ( q 2) p ( χ 1 ( q 2) + q 2)

22 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR with and the price must be q 1 = χ 1 ( q 2) (10.21) p = p ( χ 1 ( q 2) + q 2) (10.22) 4. Suppose q 1 > χ 1 ( q 2). If there is a pure strategy equilibrium then, by (10.19) p = p ( q 1 + q 2) < p ( χ 1 ( q 2) + q 2) (10.23) which contradicts (10.22) c Frank Cowell

23 Microeconomics Exercise In winter two identical ice-cream firms have to choose the capacity that they plan to use in the summer. To install capacity q costs an amount k q where k is a positive constant. Production in the summer takes place subject to q f q f, f = 1, 2 where q f is the capacity that was chosen in the previous winter. Once capacity is installed there is zero marginal cost. The market for ice-cream is characterised by the inverse demand function p ( q 1 + q 2). There are thus two views: the before problem when the decision on capacity has not yet been taken; the after problem (in the summer) once capacity has been installed. 1. Let χ ( ) be the Cournot reaction function for either firm in the after problem (as in Exercise 10.10). In the context of a diagram such as Figure 10.6 explain why this must lie strictly above the Cournot reaction function for the before problem. 2. Let q C be the Cournot-equilibrium quantity for the before problem. Write down the definition of this in terms of the present model. 3. Suppose that in the summer competition between the firms takes place in terms of prices (as in Exercise 10.10). Show that a pure-strategy Bertrand equilibrium for the overall problem is where both firms produce q C. Outline Answer q 2 low cost high cost q 1 Figure 10.12: Low-cost and high-cost reaction functions for firm 2 1. First consider how the reaction function of firm 2 would differ if the constant marginal cost were lower than its current value. Given a linear inverse demand function β 0 βq and constant marginal costs c, the reaction function for firm 2 is q 2 = β 0 c 2β c Frank Cowell q1 (10.24)

24 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR q 2 after before after before q 1 Figure 10.13: Reaction functions before and after capacity costs are sunk see Exercise So for high and low values of c we have the situation depicted in Figure Before installation capacity costs are proportional to the amount of capacity (marginal cost of capacity is k). But once the capacity has been installed it represents sunk costs so, from the firm s point of view it is as though the marginal cost of production has been cut. So the after-installation reaction functions must be as in Figure q 2 χ(q 2 ) ½k/β q C χ(q 1 ) ½k/β q 1 Figure 10.14: Equilibrium capacity 2. Clearly if (10.24) is the after reaction function for firm 2, so that q 2 = χ ( q 1) once capacity cost is sunk, the before reaction functions for firms c Frank Cowell

25 Microeconomics 1 and 2 are, respectively q 2 = β 0 c k 2β q 1 = β 0 c k 2β so that the before reaction function for each firm is χ ( ) k 2β. 1 2 q1 (10.25) 1 2 q2 (10.26) The value q C is found from setting q 1 = q 2 = q C in (10.25) and (10.26) to give q C = β 0 c k. (10.27) 3β This gives the solution to the amount of capacity q 1, q 2 to install in the first period 3. If there is price competition in the second period then, from the solution to Exercise p = p ( q 1 + q 2), we have the solution to the ice-cream sellers Summer price problem as p = p (2q C ). c Frank Cowell

26 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise There is a cake of size 1 to be divided between Alf and Bill. In period t = 1 Alf offers Bill a share: Bill may accept now (in which case the game ends), or reject. If Bill rejects then, in period t = 2 Alf again makes an offer, which Bill can accept (game ends) or reject. If Bill rejects, the game ends one period later with exogenously fixed payoffs of γ to Alf and 1 γ to Bill. Assume that Alf and Bill s payoffs are linear in cake and that both persons have the same, time-invariant discount factor δ < What is the backwards induction outcome in the two-period model? 2. How does the answer change if the time horizon increases but is finite? 3. What would happen if the horizon were infinite? Alf period 1 [offer 1 γ 1 ] Bill [accept] (γ 1, 1 γ 1 ) period 2 [reject] Alf [offer 1 γ 2 ] [accept] Bill [reject] (δγ 2, δ[1 γ 2 ]) period 3 (δ 2 γ, δ 2 [1 γ ]) Figure 10.15: One-sided bargaining game 1. Begin by drawing the extensive form game tree for this bargaining game. Note that payoffs can accrue either in period 1 (if Bill accepts immediately), in period 2 (if Bill accepts the second offer), or in period 3 (Bill rejects both offers). Using this time frame to discount all payoffs back to period 1 we find the game tree shown in Figure We can solve this game using backwards induction. Assume the game has reached period 2 where Alf makes an offer of 1 γ 2 to Bill (keeping γ 2 for himself). Bill can decide whether to accept or reject the offer made by Alf.: the best-response function for Bill is { [accept] if 1 γ2 δ [1 γ] [reject] otherwise c Frank Cowell

27 Microeconomics Since Alf wants to maximize his own payoff, he would not offer more than δ [1 γ] to Bill, leaving him (Alf) with γ 2 =1 δ + δγ. The other option is to offer less today and receive γ tomorrow, discounted back to date 2. But since δ < 1, 1 δ + δγ > δγ and hence Alf would offer 1 γ 2 = δ [1 γ] to Bill, which is accepted. Thus, going back to date 1, where Alf would offer Bill 1 γ 1 (keeping γ 1 for himself), the best-response function for Bill is now { [accept] if 1 γ1 δ 2 [1 γ] [reject] otherwise By a similar argument as before, Alf would not offer more than δ 2 [1 γ] in period 1, and thus has the choice between receiving γ 1 = 1 δ 2 + δ 2 γ in period 1, or receiving 1 δ + δγ in period 2. But again, since δ < 1, we find 1 δ 2 + δ 2 γ > δ [1 δ + δγ] and hence Alf will offer 1 γ 1 = δ 2 [1 γ] to Bill in period 1, which is accepted; Alf s equilibirum share is γ 1 = 1 δ 2 [1 γ]. 2. Now consider a longer, but finite time horizon. The structure of the backwards induction solution outlined above shows that as the time horizon increases from T = 2 bargaining rounds to T = T, the offer made by Alf reduces to 1 γ 1 = δ T [1 γ] which is accepted immediately by Bill; Alf s share is γ 1 = 1 δ T [1 γ]. 3. Now consider an infinite time horizon. The solution for the finite case would suggest that as T, (γ 1, 1 γ 1 ) (1, 0). However, this reasoning is inappropriate for the infinite case, since there is no last period from which a backwards induction outcome can be obtained. Instead, we use the crucial insight that the continuation game after each period, i.e. the game played if Bill rejects the offer made by Alf, looks identical to the game just played. In both games, there is a potentially infinite number of future periods. This insight enables us to find the equilibrium outcome of this game. Assume that the continuation game that follows if Bill rejects has a solution with allocation (γ, 1 γ). Then, in the current period, Bill will accept Alf s offer 1 γ 1 if 1 γ 1 δ [1 γ], as before. Thus, given a solution (γ, 1 γ), Alf would offer 1 γ 1 = δ [1 γ]. But if 1 γ is a solution to the continuation game, it has to be a solution to the current game as well, and hence 1 γ 1 = 1 γ. It follows that 1 γ = δ [1 γ] γ = 1 Alf will offer 1 γ = 0 to Bill, and Bill accepts immediately. c Frank Cowell

28 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise Take the game that begins at the node marked * in Figure [NOT INVEST] [INVEST] * 2 2 ** [In] [Out] [In] [Out] [FIGHT`] 1 1 [CONCEDE] (Π M, Π) _ [FIGHT`] [CONCEDE] (Π M k, Π) _ (Π F,0) (Π J, Π J ) (Π F,0) (Π J k, Π J ) Figure 10.16: Entry deterrence 1. Show that if Π M > Π J > Π F then the incumbent firm will always concede to a challenger. 2. Now suppose that the incumbent operates a chain of N stores, each in a separate location. It faces a challenge to each of the N stores: in each location there is a firm that would like to enter the local market). The challenges take place sequentially, location by location; at each point the potential entrant knows the outcomes of all previous challenges. The payoffs in each location are as in part 1 and the incumbent s overall payoff is the undiscounted sum of the payoff s over all locations. Show that, however large N is, all the challengers will enter and the incumbent never fights. Outline Answer 1. Consider the concept of an equilibrium here. (a) First note that there are several Nash equilibria as we can see from the strategic form in Table 10.9, where the first part of the monopolist s strategy specifies the action after the entrant played [in], while the second specifies the action after [out]. We find immediately that there are four Nash equilibria: c Frank Cowell ([concede], [concede]), [in] ([concede], [fight]), [in] ([fight], [concede]), [out] ([fight], [fight]), [out]

29 Microeconomics 2 (Entrant) [in] [out] ([concede], [concede]) Π J, Π J Π M, Π 1 (incumbent) ([concede], [fight]) Π J, Π J Π M, Π ([fight], [concede]) Π F, 0 Π M, Π ([fight], [fight]) Π F, 0 Π M, Π Table 10.9: Weak monopolist: strategic form Note that the outcome ([fight], [in]), where the entrant enters and the incumbent fights, is not an equilibrium outcome. E i [In] [Out] [FIGHT`] I i [CONCEDE] (Π M, Π) _ (Π F,0) (Π J, Π J ) Figure 10.17: Challenge i (b) To find the Subgame Perfect Nash equilibrium, we have to find the strategy combinations that are Nash equilibria in every subgame. There are two subgames here at firm 1 s decision nodes. In the case that the entrant (firm 2) chose [in], the best response is to choose [concede], while if the entrant chose [out], the best response is to choose either [concede] or [fight]. But the best response of the entrant to those best responses is to choose [in]. Thus, the Subgame-Perfect Nash Equilibria are and (([concede], [concede]), [in]) (([concede], [fight]), [in]) which both yield the backwards induction outcome. Hence, we find that the threat to fight after entry is not a credible strategy. However, if there were a precommitment device, such that the threat of fighting became credible, then it would be better for the entrant not to enter, so the equilibrium outcome would be ([fight], [out]) or ([concede], [out]), which imply Subgame-Perfect Nash equilibrium strategies (([fight], [concede]), [out]) or (([fight], [fight]), [out]). c Frank Cowell

30 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR 2. We may now consider an extension of essentially the same model. The incumbent has stores I 1, I 2,..., I N in local markets 1, 2,..., N. There is sequence of challenges in each market from potential entrants E 1, E 2,..., E N A typical encounter is depicted in Figure The outcome in this market is independent of actions in markets 1, 2,..., i 1. So the equilibrium behaviour of I i and E i is determined by the situation in local market i alone. By the result in part 1 the outcome is ([concede], [in]). c Frank Cowell

31 q 2 = χ(q 1 ;0) Microeconomics Exercise In a monopolistic industry firm 1, the incumbent, is considering whether to install extra capacity in order to deter the potential entry of firm 2. Marginal capacity installation costs, and marginal production costs (for production in excess of capacity) are equal and constant. Excess capacity cannot be sold. The potential entrant incurs a fixed cost k in the event of entry. 1. Let qs 1 be firm 1 s output level at the Stackelberg solution if firm 2 enters. Suppose qs 1 q M, where q M is firm 1 s output if its monopolistic position is unassailable (i.e. if entry-deterrence is inevitable). Show that this implies that market demand must be nonlinear. 2. Let q 1 be the incumbent s output level for which the potential entrant s best response yields zero profits for the entrant. In the case where entry deterrence is possible but not inevitable, show that if qs 1 > q1, then it is more profitable for firm 1 to deter entry than to accommodate the challenger. Outline Answer 1. We begin by modelling the use of capacity as deterrence. q 2 q 1 = χ(q 2 ;0) q 1 = χ(q 2 ;c) q C q M, q 1 Figure 10.18: Quantity and capacity choices (a) Suppose the two firms were to choose capacity z 1 and z 2 simultaneously a minor variation on the standard Cournot model. Firm 1 s problem is max q 1,z Π1 = p ( q 1 + q 2) q 1 cz 1 (10.28) 1 subject to c Frank Cowell q 1 z 1 (10.29)

32 q 2 = χ(q 1 ;0) Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR with solution q 1 = z 1 = χ ( q 2 ; c ) (10.30) where the dependence of the reaction function χ on the marginal cost parameter is made explicit see Figure Note that it never pays to leave capacity unused in this version of the story. Also note that if Firm 1 s marginal cost were cut from c to 0 then the χ schedule would be shifted to the right in Figure compare the schedule χ ( ; 0) with χ ( ; c) and also Figure in the answer to Exercise (b) Firm 2 s problem is similar: subject to max = p ( q 1 + q 2) cz 2 k (10.31) q 2,z 2Π1 q 2 z 2 (10.32) Note that the term k in (10.31), being a fixed entry cost, will not affect the first order condition that characterises firm 2 s best-response output, given that it enters the market. So its behaviour conditional on entry is also given by the reaction function χ: q 2 = z 2 = χ ( q 1 ; c ). (10.33) Taking (10.30) and (10.33) together we get the symmetric Cournot- Nash solution (q C, q C ) see point q C.in Figure q 2 z q 1 Figure 10.19: Incumbent s best response with precommitted capacity (c) But if firm 1 s capacity were fixed in advance (and cannot be sold off) then the term cz 1 in.(10.28) would be treated as a sunk cost, irrelevant to the optimisation problem. The optimisation problem for firm 1 would effectively become that of (10.28, 10.29) with c = 0. So its behaviour would be characterised by c Frank Cowell q 1 = χ 1 ( q 2 ; 0 ). (10.34)

33 Microeconomics Suppose firm 1 s advance capacity is fixed at z. Then, there are in principle two regimes that can apply when at the output-choice stage of the game: q 1 z. Output can be met from pre-existing capacity and so the best response of firm 1 (the incumbent) is given by (10.34) in this region. q 1 > z. Extra capacity will have to be installed at marginal cost c; the best response of firm 1 is given by (10.30) in this region. So the combined best responses will look like Figure q 2 q 2 z_z_ q 1 z _ q 1 Figure 10.20: Limits on incumbent s capacity precommitment (d) Now consider firm 1 s choice when determining advance capacity to be installed in advance as a possible deterrent. Let z be the capacity level corresponding to q C the solution to (10.30) and (10.33). The incumbent would not precommit to an amount less than z because it is pointless both firm 1 and firm 2 can always install extra capacity during the output-choice stage. Let z be the capacity level corresponding to the solution to (10.34) and (10.33) see the right-hand intersection in Figure The incumbent could not credibly precommit to an amount greater than z because this would imply that it would have capacity that would never be used in the output-choice stage. So the capacity precommitment must be in the range [z, z] see Figure (e) Choice of z within the range [z, z] depends on the size of the entry cost for firm 2. Note that, in the usual interpretation of a Cournot diagram firm 2 s profits rise as one moves North-west along firm 2.s reaction function see Figure 10.5 in the answer to Exercise Now consider the implications of the size of q 1, the output level of firm1 for which the firm 2 s best response yields it zero profits. q 1 z. Firm 2 can always make a profit for any any capacity choice made by firm 1 such that z [z, z]. The best that firm 1 can do is to accommodate firm 1 s entry and will act as a Stackelberg leader. c Frank Cowell

34 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR q 1 [z, z]. Firm 2 will make a loss for any capacity choice by firm 1 such that q 1 < z z. Here firm 1 may either (a) be assured of deterring firm 2 s entry and and choose monopoly output or (b) choose capacity z so as to deter entry or (c) accommodate entry as above q 2 q S χ 2 ( ) z_z_ q M _q 1 z _ z _ q 1 Figure 10.21: Capacity choice of incumbent (f) Compare the Stackelberg and monopoly solutions in the case where there is a linear demand curve β 0 βq In the case where firm 1 can blockade entry and act as a monopoly case profits are [ β0 βq 1] q 1 cq 1 and the solution as q 1 = q M = β 0 c 2β (10.35) see equation (10.11) in the outline answer to Exercise Take the case where firm 1 accommodates and acts as a Stackelberg leader. Firm 2 s reaction as follower is given by q 2 = χ 2 ( q 1) = β 0 c 2β 1 2 q1 (10.36) see equation (10.7) in Exercise Firm 1 s profits as leader are 1 [ β0 c βq 1] q 1 (10.37) 2 c Frank Cowell

35 Microeconomics see equation (10.12) in Exercise 10.7 and the profit-maximising output is q 1 = q 1 S = β 0 c 2β. So, if the demand function were linear we must have q 1 S = q M which contradicts what is stated in the question. Therefore the demand function must be nonlinear. 2. See Figure If q 1 q M then firm 1 sets q 1 = q M sells q M and the potential entrant does not enter: blockading of entry is inevitable. By assumption entry deterrence is not inevitable so q 1 > q M. If q 1 > z then q 1 = q 1 is not credible, it is outside the range [z, z] of credible precommitments. Since the profits of firm 2 increase as one moves Northwest along firm 2 s reaction function it follows that it is not possible to deter entry. So, by assumption, q 1 z. Also, qs 1 > q1 by assumption. Hence qs 1, z > q1 > q M. In Figure it has been assumed that qs 1 < z. We have entry accommodation if q 1 < q 1 and entry deterrence if q 1 q 1. In this case set q 1 = q 1 to get on to the lowest (and so higher profits) isoprofit contour possible. Of course this isoprofit contour is below the one through ( qs 1, S) q2 which, in turn, is below the one which is applicable if q 1 < q 1. This establishes the conclusion. Note that if qs 1 > z then q1 can be larger or smaller than z. If it is smaller, we get the same solution as above. If it is larger then entry deterrence is not possible for q 1 = q 1 is outside the range of credible pre-commitments. So now firm 1 sets q 1 = z and concedes entry. c Frank Cowell

36 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise Two firms in a duopolistic industry have constant and equal marginal costs c and face market demand schedule given by p = k q where k > c and q is total output.. 1. What would be the solution to the Bertrand price setting game? 2. Compute the joint-profit maximising solution for this industry. 3. Consider an infinitely repeated game based on the Bertrand stage game when both firms have the discount factor δ < 1. What trigger strategy, based on punishment levels p = c, will generate the outcome in part 2? For what values of δ do these trigger strategies constitute a subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium? Outline Answer 1. Suppose firm 2 sets a price p 2 > c. Firm 1 then has three options: It can set a price p 1 >p 2, it can match the price of firm 2, p 1 = p 2, or it can undercut, since there exists an ɛ > 0 such that p 1 = p 2 ɛ > c. The profits for firm 1 in the three cases are: 0 if p 1 > p Π 1 [ 2 = p 2 c ] k p 2 [ 2 if p 1 = p 2 p 2 ɛ c ] [ k p 2] if p 1 = p 2 ɛ For ɛ suffi ciently small profits in the last case exceed those in the other two, and hence firm 1 will choose to undercut firm two by a small ɛ and capture the whole market. The firms will choose to share the market if they are playing a one-shot simultaneous move game, where they will set p 1 = p 2 = c 2. If the firms maximise joint profits the problem becomes choose k to max [k q] q cq The FOC is k 2q c = 0 which implies that profit-maximising output is q M = k c 2 so that the price and the (joint) profit are, respectively p M = k + c 2 Π M = 1 [k c]2 4 c Frank Cowell

37 Microeconomics 3. The trigger strategy is to play p = p M at each stage of the game if the other firm does not deviate before this stage. But if the other firm does deviate then in all subsequent stages set p = c. In the accompanying table firm 2 deviates at t = 3 by setting p = p M ε < p M so that firm 1 responds with p = c to which the best response by firm 2 is also p = c t firm 1: p M p M p M c c firm 2: p M p M p c c If ε is small then for that one period firm 2 would get the whole market so Π 2 = Π M. Thereafter Π 2 = 0. If the firm had cooperated it would have got Π 2 = 1 2 Π M. The present discounted value of the net gain from defecting is 1 2 Π M 1 2 Π [ M δ + δ 2 + δ ] = 1 2 Π 1 2δ M 1 δ 0 if and only if 1 2 δ 1. c Frank Cowell

38 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise Consider a market with a very large number of consumers in which a firm faces a fixed cost of entry F. In period 0, N firms enter and in period 1 each firm chooses the quality of its product to be H, which costs c > 0, or L, which costs 0. Consumers choose which firms to buy from, choosing randomly if they are indiff erent. Only after purchasing the commodity can consumers observe the quality. In subsequent time periods the stage game just described is repeated indefinitely. The market demand function is given by ϕ(p) if quality is believed to be H q = 0 otherwise where ϕ ( ) is a strictly decreasing function and p is the price of the commodity. The discount rate is zero. 1. Specify a trigger strategy for consumers which induces firms always to choose H quality. Hence determine the subgame-perfect equilibrium. What price will be charged in equilibrium? 2. What is the equilibrium number of firms, and each firm s output level in a long-run equilibrium with free entry and exit? 3. What would happen if F = 0? Outline Answer 1. For a given price p profits for i are given by [ ] 1 Π = q i [p c] 1 + r + 1 [1 + r] F = q i [p c] F (10.38) r if it produces H quality for ever and q i p 1 + r F if it produces low quality in one period and then never sells any product thereafter. The trigger strategy is to stay with the firm unless it is observed to have changed its quality to L, in which case the firm will never again have customers. This punishment ensures SPNE (Note the zero demand for L quality.) To ensure that this strategy is incentive-compatible, and thus consistent with SPNE, we need Hence q i p q i [p c] [ r + 1 [1 + r] = 1 + r q i [p c] (10.39) r p [1 + r] c (10.40) in equilibrium. The equilibrium price is suffi ciently high that the firm is unwilling to sacrifice its future profits for a one-off gain from producing L quality and selling it at a high price. c Frank Cowell ]

39 Microeconomics 2. From (10.38) the long-run zero-profit condition implies q(p) [p c] r We have the market-clearing condition F (10.41) Nq i = q(p) (10.42) This (10.42) determines the equilibrium number of firms ( N = int q(p) p c ) rf (10.43) From (10.40) and (10.41) we get q i = 1 N rf p c (10.44) 3. Without entry cost, but with demand elastic, q(p) is determined, but q i and N are indeterminate. c Frank Cowell

40 Microeconomics CHAPTER 10. STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Exercise In a duopoly both firms have constant marginal cost. It is common knowledge that this is 1 for firm 1 and that for firm 2 it is either 3 4 or It is common knowledge that firm 1 believes that firm 2 is low cost with probability 1 2. The inverse demand function is 2 q where q is total output. The firms choose output simultaneously. What is the equilibrium in pure strategies? Outline Answer Let marginal cost be denoted by c. Firm 1 s and firm 2 s profits are given by, respectively: Π 1 := [ 2 q 1 q 2] q 1 C 1 q 1 (10.45) Π 2 := [ 2 q 1 q 2] q 2 C 2 cq 2 (10.46) Maximising (10.46) with respect to q 2, given q 1 we have the FOC 2 q 1 2q 2 c = 0 which yields the Cournot reaction function for firm 2 q 2 = χ 2 ( q 1 ; c ) = c 1 2 q1 (10.47) (compare the answer for Exercise 10.7). The two cases (low-cost and high-cost) for firm 2 are therefore q 2 L = q1 (10.48) q 2 H = q1 (10.49) compare this with Figure in Exercise In the light of the above the expected profits for firm 1 are 1 [[ 2 q 1 q 2 ] L q 1 C 1 q 1] + 1 [[ 2 q 1 q H] q 1 C 1 q 1] [ 2 q q2 L 1 ] 2 q2 H q 1 C 1 q 1 Under the Cournot assumption firm 1 takes ql 2 and q2 H for firm 1 is [ 2 2q q2 L 1 ] 2 q2 H 1 = 0 as given. So the FOC which implies q 1 = [ q 2 L + q 2 H] (10.50) as the best response of firm 1 to firm 2. Substituting from (10.48) and (10.49) into (10.50) we have q 1 = [ q ] 2 q1 (10.51) c Frank Cowell

41 Microeconomics which simplifies to q 1 = [ 1 q 1 ] 4 (10.52) = q1 (10.53) From which we find the solution as q 1 = 1 3 q 2 L = = q 2 H = = c Frank Cowell

GAME THEORY: DYNAMIC. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Dynamic Game Theory

GAME THEORY: DYNAMIC. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Dynamic Game Theory Prerequisites Almost essential Game Theory: Strategy and Equilibrium GAME THEORY: DYNAMIC MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 1 Overview Game Theory: Dynamic Mapping the temporal

More information

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly Prerequisites Almost essential Monopoly Useful, but optional Game Theory: Strategy and Equilibrium DUOPOLY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell 1 Overview Duopoly Background How the basic

More information

REPEATED GAMES. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Repeated Games. Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic.

REPEATED GAMES. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. Frank Cowell: Repeated Games. Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic. Prerequisites Almost essential Game Theory: Dynamic REPEATED GAMES MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 1 Overview Repeated Games Basic structure Embedding the game in context

More information

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9 CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO May 22, 2015 Announcements HW #3 is due next week. Ch. 6.1: Ultimatum Game This is a simple game that can model a very simplified

More information

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics November 16, 2012 Prof. Dr. Sebastian Rausch Centre for Energy Policy and Economics Department of Management, Technology and Economics ETH Zürich

More information

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015 CUR 41: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 015 Instructions: Please write your name in English. This exam is closed-book. Total time: 10 minutes. There are 4 questions,

More information

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions ECO 300 Fall 2005 November 22 OLIGOPOLY PART 2 PRISONER S DILEMMA Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, 481-2 Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions X = 12 2 P + P, X = 12 2 P + P 1 1 2 2 2 1

More information

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercise - Quantity competition 1 Take firm 1 s perspective Total revenue is R(q 1 = (4 q 1 q q 1 and, hence, marginal revenue is MR 1 (q 1 = 4 q 1 q Marginal cost is MC

More information

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Noncooperative Oligopoly Noncooperative Oligopoly Oligopoly: interaction among small number of firms Conflict of interest: Each firm maximizes its own profits, but... Firm j s actions affect firm i s profits Example: price war

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1 M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term.. Private Provision of Public Good. Consider the following public good game:

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 2. Dynamic games of complete information Chapter 1. Dynamic games of complete and perfect information Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics (for MBA students) 44111 (1393-94 1 st term) - Group 2 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Game Theory Game:

More information

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE Answers to Problem Set 2 [1] (a) This is standard (we have even done it in class). The one-shot Cournot outputs can be computed to be A/3, while the payoff to each firm can

More information

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation Reputations arise in situations where there is an element of repetition, and also where coordination between players is possible. One definition of leadership is that

More information

Strategic Production Game 1

Strategic Production Game 1 Lec5-6.doc Strategic Production Game Consider two firms, which have to make production decisions without knowing what the other is doing. For simplicity we shall suppose that the product is essentially

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Answers to Problem Set [] In part (i), proceed as follows. Suppose that we are doing 2 s best response to. Let p be probability that player plays U. Now if player 2 chooses

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Answer Key: Problem Set 4 Econ 409 018 Fall A reminder: An equilibrium is characterized by a set of strategies. As emphasized in the class, a strategy is a complete contingency plan (for every hypothetical

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati. Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati. Module No. # 06 Illustrations of Extensive Games and Nash Equilibrium

More information

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Recap Last class (September 20, 2016) Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma Today (October 13, 2016) Finitely

More information

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals. Chapter 3 Oligopoly Oligopoly is an industry where there are relatively few sellers. The product may be standardized (steel) or differentiated (automobiles). The firms have a high degree of interdependence.

More information

Economics 171: Final Exam

Economics 171: Final Exam Question 1: Basic Concepts (20 points) Economics 171: Final Exam 1. Is it true that every strategy is either strictly dominated or is a dominant strategy? Explain. (5) No, some strategies are neither dominated

More information

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games Game Theory Wolfgang Frimmel Repeated Games 1 / 41 Recap: SPNE The solution concept for dynamic games with complete information is the subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) Selten (1965): A strategy

More information

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games Repeated Games Frédéric KOESSLER September 3, 2007 1/ Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality Finitely Repeated Games Infinitely Repeated Games Automaton Representation of Strategies The One-Shot

More information

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1 . Economic Applications of Game Theory Fall 00 TA: Youngjin Hwang Problem 3 Solutions. (a) There are three subgames: [A] the subgame starting from Player s decision node after Player s choice of P; [B]

More information

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017 G5212: Game Theory Mark Dean Spring 2017 Bargaining We will now apply the concept of SPNE to bargaining A bit of background Bargaining is hugely interesting but complicated to model It turns out that the

More information

Outline for Dynamic Games of Complete Information

Outline for Dynamic Games of Complete Information Outline for Dynamic Games of Complete Information I. Examples of dynamic games of complete info: A. equential version of attle of the exes. equential version of Matching Pennies II. Definition of subgame-perfect

More information

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy Yangbo Song Economics Department, UCLA June 30, 2014 Yangbo Song UCLA June 30, 2014 1 / 31 Game theory Game theory is a methodology used to analyze strategic situations in

More information

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE Problem Set 1 These questions will go over basic game-theoretic concepts and some applications. homework is due during class on week 4. This [1] In this problem (see Fudenberg-Tirole

More information

Game Theory: Additional Exercises

Game Theory: Additional Exercises Game Theory: Additional Exercises Problem 1. Consider the following scenario. Players 1 and 2 compete in an auction for a valuable object, for example a painting. Each player writes a bid in a sealed envelope,

More information

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers Chapter : Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers Learning Objectives Students should learn to:. Extend the reaction function ideas developed in the Cournot duopoly model to a model of sequential behavior

More information

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit Homework #5 - Econ 57 (Due on /30) Answer Key. Consider a Cournot duopoly with linear inverse demand curve p(q) = a q, where q denotes aggregate output. Both firms have a common constant marginal cost

More information

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory Exercises Solutions: Game Theory Exercise. (U, R).. (U, L) and (D, R). 3. (D, R). 4. (U, L) and (D, R). 5. First, eliminate R as it is strictly dominated by M for player. Second, eliminate M as it is strictly

More information

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4) Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4) Outline: Modeling by means of games Normal form games Dominant strategies; dominated strategies,

More information

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017 G5212: Game Theory Mark Dean Spring 2017 Modelling Dynamics Up until now, our games have lacked any sort of dynamic aspect We have assumed that all players make decisions at the same time Or at least no

More information

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0) LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY September 11, 01 Introduction: So far we have considered models of perfect competition and monopoly which are the two polar extreme cases of market outcome. In models of monopoly,

More information

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few 27 Oligopoly Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few firms. Particularly, l each

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 11, 2017 Auctions results Histogram of

More information

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours YORK UNIVERSITY Faculty of Graduate Studies Final Examination December 14, 2010 Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics S. Bucovetsky time=2.5 hours Do any 6 of the following 10 questions. All count

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 017 1. Sheila moves first and chooses either H or L. Bruce receives a signal, h or l, about Sheila s behavior. The distribution

More information

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. (a) The monopolist solves: The first order condition is max Π(Q) = Q(a bq) cq. Q a Q c = 0, or equivalently, Q = a c, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated

More information

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2 Econ 37 Solution: Problem Set # Fall 00 Page Oligopoly Market demand is p a bq Q q + q.. Cournot General description of this game: Players: firm and firm. Firm and firm are identical. Firm s strategies:

More information

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya Microeconomics III Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 01) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya Oligopoly is a market in which only a few firms compete with one another,

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 07. (40 points) Consider a Cournot duopoly. The market price is given by q q, where q and q are the quantities of output produced

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 3 1. Consider the following strategic

More information

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

MKTG 555: Marketing Models MKTG 555: Marketing Models A Brief Introduction to Game Theory for Marketing February 14-21, 2017 1 Basic Definitions Game: A situation or context in which players (e.g., consumers, firms) make strategic

More information

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information Backward Induction in dynamic games of imperfect information We start at the end of the trees first find the Nash equilibrium (NE) of the last subgame

More information

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies:

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies: Problem Set 4 1. (a). Consider the infinitely repeated game with discount rate δ, where the strategic fm below is the stage game: B L R U 1, 1 2, 5 A D 2, 0 0, 0 Sketch a graph of the players payoffs.

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Almost essential MICROECONOMICS

Almost essential MICROECONOMICS Prerequisites Almost essential Games: Mixed Strategies GAMES: UNCERTAINTY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell April 2018 1 Overview Games: Uncertainty Basic structure Introduction to the

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY ECONS 44 STRATEGY AND GAE THEORY IDTER EXA # ANSWER KEY Exercise #1. Hawk-Dove game. Consider the following payoff matrix representing the Hawk-Dove game. Intuitively, Players 1 and compete for a resource,

More information

By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should:

By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should: Important note This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 013 14. The format and structure of the examination may change in future years,

More information

Answers to Problem Set 4

Answers to Problem Set 4 Answers to Problem Set 4 Economics 703 Spring 016 1. a) The monopolist facing no threat of entry will pick the first cost function. To see this, calculate profits with each one. With the first cost function,

More information

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing May 22, 2017 May 22, 2017 1 / 19 Bertrand Duopoly: Undifferentiated Products Game (Bertrand) Firm and Firm produce identical products. Each firm simultaneously

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions Microeconomics: Pricing 3E00 Fall 06. True or false: Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions (a) Since a durable goods monopolist prices at the monopoly price in her last period of operation, the prices must

More information

Economic Management Strategy: Hwrk 1. 1 Simultaneous-Move Game Theory Questions.

Economic Management Strategy: Hwrk 1. 1 Simultaneous-Move Game Theory Questions. Economic Management Strategy: Hwrk 1 1 Simultaneous-Move Game Theory Questions. 1.1 Chicken Lee and Spike want to see who is the bravest. To do so, they play a game called chicken. (Readers, don t try

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition Kai Hao Yang /2/207 In this lecture, we will apply the concepts in game theory to study oligopoly. In short, unlike

More information

Dynamic Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Dynamic Games 1 / 18

Dynamic Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Dynamic Games 1 / 18 Dynamic Games Econ 400 University of Notre Dame Econ 400 (ND) Dynamic Games 1 / 18 Dynamic Games A dynamic game of complete information is: A set of players, i = 1,2,...,N A payoff function for each player

More information

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly Chapter 13 Application: Implicit Cartels This chapter discusses many important subgame-perfect equilibrium strategies in optimal cartel, using the linear Cournot oligopoly as the stage game. For game theory

More information

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally. AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July 2017 time : 1 hour Do all 4 questions. All count equally. Q1. Monopoly is inefficient because the monopoly s owner makes high profits, and the monopoly s

More information

Problem Set 2 Answers

Problem Set 2 Answers Problem Set 2 Answers BPH8- February, 27. Note that the unique Nash Equilibrium of the simultaneous Bertrand duopoly model with a continuous price space has each rm playing a wealy dominated strategy.

More information

1 Solutions to Homework 3

1 Solutions to Homework 3 1 Solutions to Homework 3 1.1 163.1 (Nash equilibria of extensive games) 1. 164. (Subgames) Karl R E B H B H B H B H B H B H There are 6 proper subgames, beginning at every node where or chooses an action.

More information

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001 MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U813 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 001 Imperfect Competition Wednesday, March 1 st Reading: Pindyck/Rubinfeld Chapter 1 Strategic Interaction figure

More information

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5 Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO Oct. 23, 2015 Administrative Stuff Homework 2 is due next week. Due to the change in material covered, I have decided to change the grading system

More information

Finitely repeated simultaneous move game.

Finitely repeated simultaneous move game. Finitely repeated simultaneous move game. Consider a normal form game (simultaneous move game) Γ N which is played repeatedly for a finite (T )number of times. The normal form game which is played repeatedly

More information

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27 Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 7 February 11, 010 Oligopoly Considerations: Do firms compete on price or quantity? Do firms act sequentially (leader/followers) or simultaneously (equilibrium) Stackelberg models:

More information

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010 Answer Key Problem Set 1 Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010 Please give your answers to your class teacher by Friday of week 6 LT. If you not to hand in at your class, make

More information

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization An Application in Industrial Organization February 23, 2015 One form of collusive behavior among firms is to restrict output in order to keep the price of the product high. This is a goal of the OPEC oil

More information

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002 Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002 P1. Consider the following game. There are two piles of matches and two players. The game starts with Player 1 and thereafter the players

More information

Notes for Section: Week 4

Notes for Section: Week 4 Economics 160 Professor Steven Tadelis Stanford University Spring Quarter, 2004 Notes for Section: Week 4 Notes prepared by Paul Riskind (pnr@stanford.edu). spot errors or have questions about these notes.

More information

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization 12 December 2006. 0.1 (p. 26), 0.2 (p. 41), 1.2 (p. 67) and 1.3 (p.68) 0.1** (p. 26) In the text, it is assumed

More information

Exercise Chapter 10

Exercise Chapter 10 Exercise 10.8.1 Where the isoprofit curves touch the gradients of the profits of Alice and Bob point in the opposite directions. Thus, increasing one agent s profit will necessarily decrease the other

More information

Economics 431 Infinitely repeated games

Economics 431 Infinitely repeated games Economics 431 Infinitely repeated games Letuscomparetheprofit incentives to defect from the cartel in the short run (when the firm is the only defector) versus the long run (when the game is repeated)

More information

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z),

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z), ECO 305 Fall 003 Precept Week 9 Question Strategic Commitment in Oligopoly In quantity-setting duopoly, a firm will make more profit if it can seize the first move (become a Stackelberg leader) than in

More information

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I Homework 1, due in recitation on 10/18/2018. 1. Consider the following strategic game: player 1/player 2 L R U 1,1 0,0 D 0,0 3,2 Any NE can be

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 5 [1] Consider an infinitely repeated game with a finite number of actions for each player and a common discount factor δ. Prove that if δ is close enough to zero then

More information

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization ECON/MGMT 115 Industrial Organization 1. Cournot Model, reprised 2. Bertrand Model of Oligopoly 3. Cournot & Bertrand First Hour Reviewing the Cournot Duopoloy Equilibria Cournot vs. competitive markets

More information

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2013 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 01A) Fall 01 Oligopolistic markets (PR 1.-1.5) Lectures 11-1 Sep., 01 Oligopoly (preface to game theory) Another form

More information

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, 009 - Suggested Solution Problem 1: (Bertrand competition). Total cost function of two firms selling computers is T C 1 = T C = 15q. If these two firms compete

More information

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key EconS 44 Strategy and Game Theory Homework #5 Answer Key Exercise #1 Collusion among N doctors Consider an infinitely repeated game, in which there are nn 3 doctors, who have created a partnership. In

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

HW Consider the following game:

HW Consider the following game: HW 1 1. Consider the following game: 2. HW 2 Suppose a parent and child play the following game, first analyzed by Becker (1974). First child takes the action, A 0, that produces income for the child,

More information

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS ECO410H: Practice Questions SOLUTIONS 1. (a) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (M, M). (b) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (R4, C3). (c) The two Nash equilibria are

More information

ECON402: Practice Final Exam Solutions

ECON402: Practice Final Exam Solutions CO42: Practice Final xam Solutions Summer 22 Instructions There is a total of four problems. You must answer any three of them. You get % for writing your name and 3% for each of the three best problems

More information

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. You have 3 hours to answer the questions in the final exam. We will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, and good luck! Problem 1. Utility Maximization.

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 2 1. Consider a zero-sum game, where

More information

14.12 Game Theory Midterm II 11/15/ Compute all the subgame perfect equilibria in pure strategies for the following game:

14.12 Game Theory Midterm II 11/15/ Compute all the subgame perfect equilibria in pure strategies for the following game: 4. Game Theory Midterm II /5/7 Prof. Muhamet Yildiz Instructions. This is an open book exam; you can use any written material. You have one hour and minutes. Each question is 5 points. Good luck!. Compute

More information

Follow the Leader I has three pure strategy Nash equilibria of which only one is reasonable.

Follow the Leader I has three pure strategy Nash equilibria of which only one is reasonable. February 3, 2014 Eric Rasmusen, Erasmuse@indiana.edu. Http://www.rasmusen.org Follow the Leader I has three pure strategy Nash equilibria of which only one is reasonable. Equilibrium Strategies Outcome

More information

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 DUOPOLY MODELS Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 Contents 1. Collusion in Duopoly 2. Cournot Competition 3. Cournot Competition when One Firm is Subsidized 4. Stackelberg

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 03

More information

In reality; some cases of prisoner s dilemma end in cooperation. Game Theory Dr. F. Fatemi Page 219

In reality; some cases of prisoner s dilemma end in cooperation. Game Theory Dr. F. Fatemi Page 219 Repeated Games Basic lesson of prisoner s dilemma: In one-shot interaction, individual s have incentive to behave opportunistically Leads to socially inefficient outcomes In reality; some cases of prisoner

More information

that internalizes the constraint by solving to remove the y variable. 1. Using the substitution method, determine the utility function U( x)

that internalizes the constraint by solving to remove the y variable. 1. Using the substitution method, determine the utility function U( x) For the next two questions, the consumer s utility U( x, y) 3x y 4xy depends on the consumption of two goods x and y. Assume the consumer selects x and y to maximize utility subject to the budget constraint

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

University of Hong Kong ECON6036 Stephen Chiu. Extensive Games with Perfect Information II. Outline

University of Hong Kong ECON6036 Stephen Chiu. Extensive Games with Perfect Information II. Outline University of Hong Kong ECON6036 Stephen Chiu Extensive Games with Perfect Information II 1 Outline Interpretation of strategy Backward induction One stage deviation principle Rubinstein alternative bargaining

More information

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition Static Games and Cournot Competition Lecture 3: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors oligopoly market Each firm has to consider

More information