ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS I

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS I"

Transcription

1 Lecture 3 Stochastic Processes & Stochastic Calculus September 24, 2018

2 STOCHASTIC PROCESSES Asset prices, asset payoffs, investor wealth, and portfolio strategies can all be viewed as stochastic processes. Definition: A stochastic process is a time-indexed sequence of random variables. Stochastic Processes vs. Random Variables (paths) (real numbers) A stochastic process must be regarded as a single unit. It is a random variable, but it belongs to a different space, i.e., a function space, and we write it using two arguments: X(t, ω).

3 A realization is an entire path, not a number, and the Population is the set of all possible realizations. Price ω1 ω2 ω3 Time Note, in economics we observe only one realization. Law of Large Numbers and Central Limit Theorem arguments are still applicable if observations over time provide enough new information about ensemble averages.

4 Stationary Stochastic Process: All joint distributions are independent of time (e.g., initial conditions have worn off ) f(x t, x t+1, x t+j ) indpt. of t j Markov Process: A restriction on the conditional distribution function: f(future present, past) = f(future present) or Prob(x t+1 x t, x t 1, x t k ) = prob(x t+1 x t ) k 1 (i.e., no path dependence). Whether a process is Markov depends on the dimensionality of the state. Example: S t = α 1 S t 1 + α 2 S t 2 appears non-markov. However, if we define Z t = (S t, S t 1 ), then Z t is Markov. A process can be Markov but nonstationary. Example: x t = λx t 1 + ε t with λ 1 (Why?) If a process is stationary and (low-dimensional) Markov, then conventional statistical methods can be applied.

5 MARTINGALES The preeminent stochastic process in finance is a martingale. A martingale satisfies the following restriction: E[X t+1 F t ] = X t where F t = Information available at time-t. Hence, a martingale is nonstationary. There are 2 key ingredients to any martingale: 1 A family of information sets, F t (called a filtration ). A process may be a martingale w.r.t. one filtration but not another. 2 A probability measure, used to define conditional expectations. A process may be a martingale w.r.t. one measure but not another. We exploit this often later on. A martingale is a mathematical formalization of a fair game. Betting on the outcomes of an unbiased coin generates a martingale wealth process.

6 A martingale only restricts the first moment. It should be distinguished from a random walk. A random walk is a martingale, but not vice versa. (Exercise: Provide an example of a martingale that is not a random walk). If E[X t+1 F t ] > X t the process is called a submartingale. If E[X t+1 F t ] < X t it is a supermartingale. Note that if we define prices to include dividends we can write the Fund. Eq. as follows: M t P t = E t [M t+ P t+ ] where with time-additive utility M t+ /M t = e ρ U (C t+ )/U (C t) This says that SDF-scaled prices follow a martingale. We are interested in what happens when 0 and trading becomes continuous. The continuous-time limit of a (continuous) martingale is a Brownian motion process.

7 CONTINUOUS- VS. DISCRETE-TIME The time index in a stochastic process can either be discrete (integers) or continuous (real numbers). Is time really discrete or continuous? [Who knows, ask a physicist]. In economics, the choice between them should be based solely on mathematical and computational convenience. Use whichever is easier for the problem at hand! The fact is, in many asset pricing problems, continuous-time is easier. This is especially true in option pricing. Besides, in today s world of computerized, algorithmic trading, continuous-time is becoming increasingly accurate even from a descriptive standpoint! The easiest way to think about a continuous-time stochastic process is as a limit of a discrete-time process. However, there are dangers in doing this, and we must be careful in how we take limits.

8 WIENER PROCESS (BROWNIAN MOTION) Defining a discrete-time process is simple - Just cumulate i.i.d. shocks. The Wold Representation Theorem tells us this is a completely general way to define a (linear) discrete-time process. Example: x t = ρx t 1 + ε t ρ < 1 ε t i.i.d. x t = j=0 ρj ε t j Likewise, defining a deterministic continuous-time process is also simple - Just write down a differential equation Example: dx dt = a x Here s the question - Can we define a stochastic continuous-time process by just adding on an i.i.d. shock to a differential equation, as we did in the discrete-time case? Does the following eq. make sense? dx dt = a x + ε Answer: Not really, but in a way yes.

9 It turns out that defining a continuous-time i.i.d. process is a bit tricky, and leads to some surprising results. We will see that the mathematically correct way to define a stochastic differential equation is in terms of the following integral equation: x t = x 0 + t 0 ax s ds + t 0 dw s where W t is a Wiener Process, and the 2nd integral is a new type of integral, called an Ito Integral. The Wiener process can be viewed as a continuous-time limit of the following random walk process x t = x t 1 + ε t ε t i.i.d. N(0, 1) x t+t = x t + T j=1 ε t+j where the step-size shrinks to zero in a very particular way as the time between steps shrinks to zero.

10 Note 3 features of the above random walk: 1 E(x t+t x t) = x t T or equivalently, E( x t+k x t) = 0 (Markov, with indpt., zero mean increments). 2 Var(x t+t x t) = T (Variance increases linearly with number of periods). 3 Although the unconditional distribution is undefined (since the process is nonstationary), all conditional distributions are Gaussian. We want to derive a continuous-time process with these same properties. In particular, we want the variance to depend on the sample length, T, but not on the number of steps. Unless the step-sizes go to zero slower than the step-lengths, the law of large numbers would cause the variance to shrink to zero. In analogy to the Wold Representation Theorem, all continuous sample path continuous-time processes can be constructed as functions of the Wiener process. (If you want to allow jumps, then you must consider a wider class of innovations, called Levy Processes).

11 BINOMIAL TREE Let s consider a slight generalization of a random walk, which allows the process to drift up or down on average over time. To visualize the path of this process, consider the following binomial tree: X0 + 2Δh P 2 X0 + Δh P X0 2pq X0 -- Δh q X0 -- 2Δh q 2 t=0 Type equation he t = Δt t = 2Δt This depicts the path of the following r.w. (with drift) process: x t+ t = x t + ε t+ t ε t = h with prob. p = h with prob. q

12 This is called a binomial tree because each step is the outcome of a Bernoulli trial, so the path of the process (sum of the steps) is a binomial r.v. By definition, t 0 when defining a continuous-time process. The question is, What happens to h as t 0? Clearly, if the process is to be continuous, then h 0 as t 0. But how fast? Moments: E( x) = (p q) h E[( x) 2 ] = p( h) 2 + q( h) 2 = ( h) 2 var( x) = E[( x) 2 ] [E( x)] 2 = [1 (p q) 2 ]( h) 2 = 4pq( h) 2

13 A continuous-time interval of length T can be divided into n = T t discrete time-steps. Since each step is independent, we have E(x T x 0 ) = T (p q) h = T (p q) h t t var(x T x 0 ) = T t 4pq( h)2 = T 4pq ( h)2 t (1) (2) Suppose h t ( h goes to 0 at the same rate as t). Then notice from (2) that var(x T x 0 ) 0. This is just the Law of Large Numbers. However, we want var(x T x 0 ) T. To get this, we assume h = σ t This implies ( h)2 t σ 2. If we also let p = 1 2 [ 1 + α ] t σ q = 1 2 [ 1 α ] t σ then, as t 0, the above binomial dist. converges to a Normal dist. (ie, Central Limit Theorem) and we find This is what we want! x T x 0 N(αT, σ 2 T ) Note, pq = 1 α2 (1 4 σ 2 t) 1 4

14 Comments & Questions: 1 Notice that x t h t t 1 as t 0 t t 2 This means that the continuous-time limit process, x(t), is not differentiable. However, it is continuous. (Can you visualize a continuous, but nowhere differentiable process?) 3 Divide the continuous interval [0, T ] into discrete subintervals t 0 = 0 < t 1 < < t n = T. Define the pth-variation of the Wiener process as n V p = lim X tk X tk 1 p t k 0 k=1 Using the above results, one can show V 1 =, V 2 = T, and V p = 0 for p 3. 4 Thus, the total variation or length of the Wiener process is infinite, even over arbitrarily short time intervals. However, its quadratic variation is finite, and equal to the length of the time interval. This reflects a trade-off between the number of steps, and the size of each step. As the number of steps goes to, the size of each step doesn t go to zero fast enough to keep the sum of the products finite, but the squared step sizes do. 5 The fact that variations beyond order 2 equal 0 will be important when developing our new stochastic calculus rules. 6 It turns out that the Wiener process is not special in this regard. All continuous martingales have V 1 = and V 2 = T (except for the degenerate case of a constant).

15 What exactly does it mean for a discrete-time process to converge to a continuous-time process. (They live in different spaces!). We just showed their means and variances converged. What about their sample paths? How do we know a random process is continuous? (It s random!) If W t is not differentiable, in what sense (if any) can we use its innovations as the underlying i.i.d. shocks driving a stochastic analog of a differential equation? In discrete-time, we move interchangebly between sums and differences: x t = x t 1 + ε t {discrete differential eq. x t = t ε j {discrete integral eq. j=0 This correspondence is like a discrete version of the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus: F (b) F (a) = b a F (x)dx. Does a similar result apply to stochastic continuous-time processes? It s not obvious, since dw does not exist. dt

16 SUMMARY SO FAR A Wiener process (or standard Brownian motion) is a continuous-time process having the following 3 properties: 1 Continuous sample paths 2 Stationary i.i.d. increments 3 W t N(0, t) t [W 0 = 0] Therefore, over any discrete time interval, t, we can write W t = ε t t εt N(0, 1) Notation: As t 0, we write dw = ε dt E[dW ] = E[ε dt] = 0 E[(dW ) 2 ] = E[ε 2 dt] = dt More generally, we can define a Brownian motion with drift, µ, and volatility, σ, as follows x t = x 0 + µ t + σw t

17 Upon first encountering this material, one sometimes gets the impression that Wiener processes and Brownian motion are different objects, i.e., that Wiener processes are in some sense more general. A famous theorem of P. Levy shows that this is not the case, and that we can think of them as being synonymous. Theorem: If a continuous-time process, x t, has continuous sample paths with stationary i.i.d. increments, then it must be a Brownian motion. That is, continuity + stationary i.i.d. increments Normality Hence, the 3rd part of the previous definition was not really required. Implication: If the data indicate a process is non-gaussian, then it cannot be a Wiener process. (However, you might be able to convert it into one with a suitable transformation).

18 A Caveat Before proceeding, we need to be aware of an important caveat to all our results. Consider the following silly (but useful) example: Example: Let U by a r.v. which is uniformly distributed on [0, 1], and consider the following 2 random processes on the continuous time interval [0, 1]: { 1 if t = U X t = 0 for all t [0, 1] Y t = 0 otherwise Since Pr(U = t) = 0 t, X t and Y t have the same distributions. However, X t and Y t are different processes. In particular, Pr(X t = 0 t) = 1 and Pr(Y t = 0 t) = 0. Implications: 1 Since we are dealing with random things, there are no guarantees. 2 All our statements about the properties of a random process mean they hold almost everywhere or almost surely. 3 In this way, we can say the above 2 processes are equal. (They only differ on a set of measure zero). 4 This qualifies our earlier claim about the continuity of a Wiener process - More precisely, The sample paths of a Wiener process are almost surely continuous

19 W EAK C ONVERGENCE /D ONSKER S T HEOREM In what sense do the sample paths of a discrete-time random walk converge to those of a Wiener process? In statistics, you learn that there are many ways we can define the convergence of a random variable. One of them is: K ASA ECON F INANCIAL E CONOMICS I

20 Convergence in Distribution: Let X n be a sequence of random variables with CDF F n(x n). We say that X n converges in distribution to a r.v. X with CDF F (X) if lim n F n(x n) F (X) = 0 at all continuity points of F (X). This is a statement about the prob. dists. of X n and X, not the values of X n and X Weak convergence can be interpreted as a function space analog of convergence in distribution (ie, it applies to stochastic processes rather than random variables). Definition: Let (Ω, F) be a measure space, where Ω is a set of continuous functions, F be a σ-algebra of its subsets, and µ n be a sequence of prob. measures on (Ω, F). Then µ n converges weakly to µ (denoted µ n µ) if for each continuous, bounded function f we have f(x)µn(dx) f(x)µ(dx) Equivalently, if we let X n be the random process associated with µ n (ie, µ n(a) = P r(x n A)), then weak convergence implies Ef(X n) Ef(x). Theorem (Donsker): Let ε t i.i.d. with E t = 0 and Eε 2 t = 1. Let X T = ε 1 + ε ε T be the T th partial sum. Form the following linear continuous-time interpolation of X T on the interval [0, 1] W n t = { 1 n X m if t = m n (0 m n) linear if t [ m n, m+1 n ) Then, as n, W n t W t, where W t is a Wiener process.

21 Comments: Note that no assumption was made about the distribution of ε t. Believe it or not, this is really a useful and practical result. Why? Because the function f can be used to define many useful properties of a path (e.g., the maximum value reached before time T ). Donsker s Theorem then tells us that the sample path properties of a random walk can be approximated by those of a Wiener process (and vice versa). This means computer programs can be used to approximate the path properties of W t (or, going the other way) analytically derived results for W t approximate those for X t.

22 BACKWARD & FORWARD EQUATIONS Markov processes are fully characterized by their transition probabilities (and an initial condition). Example: A discrete-state/discrete-time process (called a Markov Chain) is characterized by its transition probability matrix, P ij. A standard Wiener process is Markov, and from our results so far, its transition probabilities are given by: { 1 (y x) 2 } f(y, t x, s) = exp 2π(t s) 2(t s) = prob. W t will be at y at t given it starts at x at s < t Taking derivatives, one can verify that f is the solution of the following 2 (partial) differential equations: f s f t = 1 2 f 2 x 2 = 1 2 f 2 y 2 }Backward Eq. }Forward Eq.

23 The backward eq. conditions on a future time and value, and describes how the expectation of this value changes with different initial conditions. It is solved backwards. Option pricing uses the backward eq., since we know the value at expiration if we know the terminal price of the underlying asset. The forward eq. conditions on an initial distribution, and describes how this distribution evolves over time. It is solved forwards. It can be used to find the long-run stationary distribution of a stochastic process. Mathematically, the backward and forward eqs. are duals (adjoints) of each other. The forward eq. describes the diffusion of particles subject to random molecular motion. It is sometimes called the heat eq.. The backward eq. is just the heat eq. with time running backwards. Later we derive more general versions of these equations using a different method, based on Ito s Lemma.

24 WHITE NOISE & STOCHASTIC DIFF. EQS. Discrete-time processes are built from discrete-time i.i.d. random variables, ε t X t = propagation mech. impulse {}}{{}}{ α 1 X t 1 + α 2 X t 2 + ε t It would be nice if the same were true for cont.-time processes The sum of a cont.-time i.i.d. process makes sense. That s what a Wiener process is: W t = t 0 εsds. Problem: We can t differentiate this to get: dw = ε. W dt t is too eratic. The stochastic analog of the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus breaks down. We need to develop new calculus rules (known as stochastic calculus ). For now, I will just alert you to the fact that there is a mathematically sophisticated way of defining the above derivative by appealing to the notion of generalized functions, which are motivated by the Dirac δ-function δ(x) = { + x = 0 0 x 0 f(x)δ(x)dx = f(0) δ(x)dx = 1 Engineers & physicists use these all the time. Using δ-functions we can say that dw dt exists, and engineers call it white noise.

25 STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Since dw does not exist (in a conventional sense), we approach dt SDEs via the following integral eq. X t = X 0 + t 0 µ(x s )ds + t 0 σ(x s )dw s The first integral is a conventional Riemann integral. The 2nd integral requires special treatment due to the erratic behavior of W t. If the integrand σ( ) is well behaved (eg, independent of W ) then the 2nd integral can be evaluated as usual. For example, if σ is constant, we have t 0 σdw s = σw t (since W 0 = 0). However, if the integrand is random (as if often is in finance) then we must be careful. Note, since dw is random, we must remember that the integral is a random variable, so when discussing convergence of discrete sums we must adopt a probabilistic notion of convergence.

26 THE ITO INTEGRAL Let s start with an example. Suppose we want to evaluate t 0 W s dw s Consider the following two Riemann sum approximations I 1 = lim I 2 = lim n 1 t k 0 k=0 n 1 t k 0 k=0 W tk [W tk+1 W tk ] W tk+1 [W tk+1 W tk ] The only difference here is that I 1 evaluates the integrand at the left-hand endpoint of each interval whereas I 2 evaluates at the right endpoint. If W were a deterministic function of time, both would converge to the same result: 1 2 W t 2 (since W 0 = 0). [To show this use the result nk=1 k = (1/2)n(n + 1)]

27 When W t is random, however, it matters where we evaluate the integrand. Using the fact that W t has independent mean zero increments and the law of iterated expectations, we can see that E(I 1 ) = 0. At the same time, we can easily see that E(I 2 ) = t. The Ito integral is defined by the assumption that we evaluate at the left endpoint. As long as the integrand is nonanticipating (ie, measurable w.r.t. info available at the left endpoint) and square integrable (to make sure sums converge) this will ensure that the Ito integral is a martingale. Evaluating at the left endpoint also makes sense economically. It allows us to use integrals to sum up continuous-time trading profits when agents must choose portfolios before future prices are known. In this simple example, we could actually evaluate the limit of the Riemann sum by brute force. However, it is easier to use the fact that by construction the Ito integral is a martingale. Since E(W 2 t ) = t, we can infer that t 0 WsdWs = 1 2 (W 2 t t). More precisely, remembering that the integral is random, one can show that I 1 converges in mean-square to 1 2 (W t 2 t). (That is, the expected squared deviations between the two goes to zero as the intervals go to zero).

28 ITO S LEMMA As in regular calculus, one rarely evaluates stochastic integrals using Riemann sums. Instead, we look for an anti-derivative. Not surprisingly, taking derivatives of a random process also produces some differences from classical calculus. Ito s lemma shows us how to take derivatives of functions of a Wiener process. It can be interpreted as a stochastic analog of the Chain Rule. It has 3 main uses in financial economics 1 It allows us to calculate expected continuation values, E[dV ], in continuous-time dynamic programming problems. We use DP to study optimal consumption/portfolio problems in various settings. 2 In asset pricing problems, the SDF process is a function of underlying macro variables that follow Ito processes [eg., M t = e δt U (C t)]. Ito s lemma enables us to infer the stochastic properties of the SDF, given the stochastic properties of the underlying macro variables. 3 Derivatives prices are functions the underlying price, C(S, t), where S follows an Ito process. To calculate its value we use Ito s lemma.

29 Rather than proceed in the abstract, let s consider an example. Suppose X t follows the Brownian motion with drift process dx = µ dt + σdw Remember, we cannot write: dx dt = µ + σ dw dt simply shorthand notation for the integral. The above equation is X t = X 0 + µ t 0 ds + σ t 0 dw s (Since σ is constant here, no special treatment of the integral is required). Suppose we have some function, F (t, X), which depends on X (and t), and we want to approximate df = total differential. Normally, a 1st-order approximation would be: df F F dx + x t dt

30 However, since dx dt, we must go out to 2nd order in the Taylor series to pick-up all the first-order terms in dt df F F dx + x t dt F X 2 (dx) F t 2 (dt)2 + F dx dt X t Note that the final two terms are of order higher than dt, and so can be dropped. However, note that (dx) 2 = µ 2 (dt) 2 + 2µσdt dw + σ 2 (dw ) 2 σ 2 dt This gives us Ito s Lemma: df = F X = dx + F t dt σ2 2 F X 2 dt ( µ F X σ2 2 F X 2 + F t ) dt + σ F X dw

31 The extra 1 2 σ2 2 F X 2 dt term in Ito s Lemma can be interpreted as a Jensen s inequality correction, reflecting the fact that the expectation of a nonlinear function the nonlinear function of the expectation. As always, its importance is increasing in the variance. Note that if F is concave, the Ito/Jensen correction reduces the drift of the process, while if F is convex, it increases the drift. Examples: 1 Suppose dx = µ dt + σdw and define Z = F (X) = e X. Note, Plugging into Ito s lemma we get F x = e X = Z F xx = e X = Z F t = 0 dz = df = F x dx σ2 F xxdt = Z(µdt + σdw ) σ2 Zdt = (µ σ2 )Z dt + σzdw This example is used all the time in financial economics. [Z is called geometric Brownian motion] 2 Suppose dx = µx dt + σx dw and define Z = F (X) = log(x). Note, F x = 1/X F xx = 1/X 2 F t = 0

32 Plugging into Ito s lemma we get dz = df = F x dx σ2 X 2 ( 1/X 2 )dt = 1 X (µxdt + σxdw ) 1 2 σ2 dt = (µ 1 2 σ2 ) dt + σdw This example is also used all the time in financial economics. Suppose dc = µdt + σdw, and consider the SDF process C M = F (t, C) = e δt U (C). Ito s lemma allows us to infer the following process for the SDF dm = F t dt + F cdc σ2 C 2 F ccdt = δe δt U (C)dt + e δt U (C)[µCdt + σcdw ] σ2 C 2 e δt U (C)dt ( ) ( )] ( ) [ δ dm M = + CU U µ + 1 C 2 σ2 2 U U dt + σ CU U dw Once again, this result is used often in financial economics.

33 SOLUTIONS OF SDES Consider the SDE dx = µ(t, X)dt + σ(t, X)dW (3) What does it mean to solve this equation? Unlike solving a deterministic ODE, we cannot expect to find a unique path that satisfies the equation. Instead, we look for a stochastic process whose statistical properties replicate those of equation (3). One possible strategy is to express it in its more appropriate integral form: X t = X 0 + t 0 µ(s, X s)ds + t 0 σ(s, X s)dw s and attempt to evaluate the integrals. In practice, it is more common to search for a function, X t = F (t, X), such that when Ito s Lemma is applied to it, we get back the same drift, µ(t, X), and diffusion, σ(t, X), coefficients as in eq. (3).

34 Since the drift and diffusion coefficients fully characterize the statistical properties of a process, doing this will solve the equation. However, there is a subtlety here that goes back to our discussion of martingales. We know that Ito integrals are martingales, and that martingales are always defined relative to an information set. Let F t be the filtration generated by the Brownian motion in eq. (3). Then if our solution is F t-adapted, we have what is called a strong solution. If it is adapted to some other information set, we have a weak solution. The statistical properties are the same either way, but our assumptions about the available information could be different. Example: Suppose we want to solve for the geometric Brownian motion process dx X = µdt + σdw (4) where µ and σ are constants. It s not clear how we should evaluate the Ito integral X sdw s, since we don t know what X is yet! So let s use the indirect/ito s lemma approach. Let s posit the form X t = X 0 e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t (5) Applying Ito s lemma to this, one can verify that the resulting drift is µx and the resulting diffusion coefficient is σx. Hence, eq. (5) solves eq. (4). If the W t process in (5) is the same as in (4), then we have a strong solution.

35 AN EXISTENCE THEOREM In the case of deterministic ODEs there are well known conditions that ensure existence (and uniqueness) of solutions. (Before looking for something, it s useful to know that it exists) The following theorem provides conditions for the existence and uniqueness of solutions to SDEs. Theorem: Assume the drift and diffusion coefficients are measureable functions satisfying the following two conditions µ(t, X) + σ(t, X) C 1 (1 + X ) X, t [0, T ] µ(t, X) µ(t, Y ) + σ(t, X) σ(t, Y ) C 2 X Y X, Y, t [0, T ] where C 1 and C 2 are given constants. Then the SDE has a unique square-integrable solution. dx = µ(t, X)dt + σ(t, X)dW The 1st condition is called a linear growth condition. The 2nd condition is called a Lipschitz condition. These are sufficient conditions, and are often too strict for finance applications. However, one case is noteworthy - if the drift and diffusion coefficients are indpt. of t and affine functions of X, then this theorem tells us a unique solution exists.

36 LOCAL MARTINGALES Earlier I claimed that Ito integrals produce martingales. That is, M t = M 0 + t 0 θ s dw s is a martingale as long as θ t is adapted to the filtration generated by W t, (F t ). According to the Martingale Representation Theorem, this is a completely general way to define martingales, i.e., all (continuous) martingales adapted to F t are Ito integrals for some θ t process. However, it turns out this is not quite correct. Ito integrals only define local martingales. Without further restrictions on θ t, there is no guarantee they are global martingales. A sufficient condition that ensures a local martingale is a global martingale is the following [ ] T E θ 2 s ds < 0

37 DOUBLING STRATEGIES A good way to see the relevance of this distinction is to consider the following doubling strategy: Consider an infinite sequence of discrete dates within some interval [0, T ]. For example, 0 = t 0 < t 1 < < T with t n = nt /(n + 1) as n. Suppose you can bet on the toss of a fair coin at each t n, winning if it shows heads. Suppose your initial bet is $1, and you double your bet each time until you win. If you win, you quit. From the Law of Large Numbers, you win with probability 1, and E[W T ] = W W 0. Hence, your wealth is not a martingale, even though each bet is fair and the expected (local) change in your wealth is 0. What s going on here? How can the sum of a bunch of zeros add up to 1? Three things are crucial: (1) You can place an infinite number of bets, (2) Your wealth is allowed to become unboundedly negative, and (3) You are allowed to place an infinitely large bet. Relax any of these and your strategy is a loser: E(W T ) < W 0. The only way you can generate a positive global mean from a sequence mean zero bets is if there is some probability of an infinite loss. Lesson: In continuous-time finance, ruling out arbitrage requires placing (weak) restrictions on an agent s portfolio or wealth.

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk Continuous Time Finance Tomas Björk 1 II Stochastic Calculus Tomas Björk 2 Typical Setup Take as given the market price process, S(t), of some underlying asset. S(t) = price, at t, per unit of underlying

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12 Lecture 11: Ito Calculus Continuous time models We start with the model from Chapter 3 log S j log S j 1 = µ t + p tz j Sum it over j: log S N log S 0 = NX µ t + NX p tzj j=1 j=1 Can we take the limit

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction M. Kazim Khan Kent State University. UET, Taxila August 15-16, 17 Outline 1 From R.W. to B.M. B.M. 3 Stochastic Integration 4 Ito s Formula 5 Recap Random Walk Consider

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13. FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Asset Price Dynamics Introduction These notes give assumptions of asset price returns that are derived from the efficient markets hypothesis. Although a hypothesis,

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s An Informal Introduction Olav Kallenberg Graduate Student Seminar, April 18, 2012 1 / 33 2 / 33 Simple recursion: Deterministic system, discrete time x n+1 = f (x

More information

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance , Application of Real Analysis in Finance Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea Seungkyu Lee Pohang University of Science and Technology August 4th, 2010 Contents 1 BINOMIAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Contents

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun Michael Perlmutter Department of Mathematics Purdue University 1 M. Perlmutter(Purdue) Brownian Motion and Martingales Outline Review of Basic Probability

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon basso@unive.it, mnardon@unive.it Department of Applied Mathematics University Ca Foscari Venice Brownian motion p. 1 Brownian motion Brownian motion plays

More information

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar BROWNIAN MOTION II D.Majumdar DEFINITION Let (Ω, F, P) be a probability space. For each ω Ω, suppose there is a continuous function W(t) of t 0 that satisfies W(0) = 0 and that depends on ω. Then W(t),

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables Lecture 3 Log Normal Distribution 3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables Mathematical Finance is about pricing (or valuing) financial contracts, and in particular those contracts which depend

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch chris bemis November 27, 2006 0-0 Goal: Derive the Black-Scholes PDE To do this, we will need to: Come up with some dynamics for the stock returns Discuss Brownian motion

More information

S t d with probability (1 p), where

S t d with probability (1 p), where Stochastic Calculus Week 3 Topics: Towards Black-Scholes Stochastic Processes Brownian Motion Conditional Expectations Continuous-time Martingales Towards Black Scholes Suppose again that S t+δt equals

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Numerical schemes for SDEs Lecture 5 Numerical schemes for SDEs Lecture Notes by Jan Palczewski Computational Finance p. 1 A Stochastic Differential Equation (SDE) is an object of the following type dx t = a(t,x t )dt + b(t,x t

More information

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes Bluff our Way Through Black-Scholes Saurav Sen December 000 Contents What is Black-Scholes?.............................. 1 The Classical Black-Scholes Model....................... 1 Some Useful Background

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance Stochastic Finance C. Azizieh VUB C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance 1/91 Agenda of the course Stochastic calculus : introduction Black-Scholes model Interest rates models C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets (Hull chapter: 12, 13, 14) Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 17 The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model Black and Scholes

More information

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Dr. Maddah ENMG 65 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Chapter 11 Models of Asset Dynamics () Random Walk A random process, z, is an additive process defined over times t 0, t 1,, t k, t k+1,, such that z( t )

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Merton-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 18 The Black-Merton-Scholes-Merton (BMS) model Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton

More information

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations IEOR E4603: Monte-Carlo Simulation c 2017 by Martin Haugh Columbia University Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations In these lecture notes we discuss the simulation of stochastic differential equations

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Binomial model: numerical algorithm Binomial model: numerical algorithm S / 0 C \ 0 S0 u / C \ 1,1 S0 d / S u 0 /, S u 3 0 / 3,3 C \ S0 u d /,1 S u 5 0 4 0 / C 5 5,5 max X S0 u,0 S u C \ 4 4,4 C \ 3 S u d / 0 3, C \ S u d 0 S u d 0 / C 4

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

Lecture 23: April 10

Lecture 23: April 10 CS271 Randomness & Computation Spring 2018 Instructor: Alistair Sinclair Lecture 23: April 10 Disclaimer: These notes have not been subjected to the usual scrutiny accorded to formal publications. They

More information

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009 Martingales by D. Cox December 2, 2009 1 Stochastic Processes. Definition 1.1 Let T be an arbitrary index set. A stochastic process indexed by T is a family of random variables (X t : t T) defined on a

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 13 Haijun Li Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Week 13 1 / 28 Outline 1 Simulation

More information

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus Continuous Processes Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus Continuous Processes The binomial models are the building block for our realistic models. Three small-scale principles in continuous

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

Using of stochastic Ito and Stratonovich integrals derived security pricing

Using of stochastic Ito and Stratonovich integrals derived security pricing Using of stochastic Ito and Stratonovich integrals derived security pricing Laura Pânzar and Elena Corina Cipu Abstract We seek for good numerical approximations of solutions for stochastic differential

More information

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5. MATH136/STAT219 Lecture 21, November 12, 2008 p. 1/11 Last Time Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.3 MATH136/STAT219

More information

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS Stat 391/FinMath 346 Lecture 8 STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS X t = CONTINUOUS PROCESS θ t = PORTFOLIO: #X t HELD AT t { St : STOCK PRICE M t : MG W t : BROWNIAN MOTION DISCRETE TIME: = t < t 1

More information

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation 3.1 Itô Integral 3.1.1 Convergence in the Mean and Stieltjes Integral Definition 3.1 (Convergence in the Mean) A sequence {X n } n ln of random

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 21th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 3 1 / 51 Outline 1 Some model independent definitions and principals

More information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Magnus Wiktorsson September 27, 2018 Magnus Wiktorsson L8 September 27, 2018 1 / 14 The risk neutral valuation formula Let X be contingent claim with maturity T.

More information

Martingale representation theorem

Martingale representation theorem Martingale representation theorem Ω = C[, T ], F T = smallest σ-field with respect to which B s are all measurable, s T, P the Wiener measure, B t = Brownian motion M t square integrable martingale with

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane. Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane c Sateesh R. Mane 2017 14 Lecture 14 November 15, 2017 Derivation of the

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t Economathematics Problem Sheet 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 1. Calculate Ee X where X is a gaussian random variable with mean µ and volatility σ >.. Verify that where W is a Wiener process. Ws dw s = 1 3 W t 3

More information

Monte Carlo Simulations

Monte Carlo Simulations Monte Carlo Simulations Lecture 1 December 7, 2014 Outline Monte Carlo Methods Monte Carlo methods simulate the random behavior underlying the financial models Remember: When pricing you must simulate

More information

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs. Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs Andrea Cosso LPMA, Université Paris Diderot joint work with Francesco Russo ENSTA,

More information

Lévy models in finance

Lévy models in finance Lévy models in finance Ernesto Mordecki Universidad de la República, Montevideo, Uruguay PASI - Guanajuato - June 2010 Summary General aim: describe jummp modelling in finace through some relevant issues.

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 MSc Financial Engineering 2012-13 CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 Department EMS, Birkbeck Introduction The assignment consists of Reading

More information

Interest rate models in continuous time

Interest rate models in continuous time slides for the course Interest rate theory, University of Ljubljana, 2012-13/I, part IV József Gáll University of Debrecen Nov. 2012 Jan. 2013, Ljubljana Continuous time markets General assumptions, notations

More information

Numerical Simulation of Stochastic Differential Equations: Lecture 1, Part 2. Integration For deterministic h : R R,

Numerical Simulation of Stochastic Differential Equations: Lecture 1, Part 2. Integration For deterministic h : R R, Numerical Simulation of Stochastic Differential Equations: Lecture, Part Des Higham Department of Mathematics University of Strathclyde Lecture, part : SDEs Ito stochastic integrals Ito SDEs Examples of

More information

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics Chapter 12 American Put Option Recall that the American option has strike K and maturity T and gives the holder the right to exercise at any time in [0, T ]. The American option is not straightforward

More information

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time Nico van der Wijst 1 Finance: A Quantitative Introduction c Cambridge University Press 1 Modelling stock returns in continuous

More information

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory). 5. Itô Calculus Types of derivatives Consider a function F (S t,t) depending on two variables S t (say, price) time t, where variable S t itself varies with time t. In stard calculus there are three types

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem) Change of Measure Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem Radon-Nikodym derivative: Taking again our intuition from the discrete world, we know that, in the context of option pricing, we need to price the claim

More information

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance Dimbinirina Ramarimbahoaka Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Calgary AMAT 621 - Fall 2012 October 15, 2012 Question: What are appropriate

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion A stochastic process Stochastic Processes X = { X(t) } Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion is a time series of random variables. X(t) (or X t ) is a random variable for each time t and is usually

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as: Continuous Time Finance Notes, Spring 2004 Section 1. 1/21/04 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences. For use in connection with the NYU course Continuous Time Finance. This

More information

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models Matematiikan päivät, Tampere, 4-5. January 2006 Tommi Sottinen University of Helsinki 4.1.2006 Outline 1. The classical pricing model:

More information

CS134: Networks Spring Random Variables and Independence. 1.2 Probability Distribution Function (PDF) Number of heads Probability 2 0.

CS134: Networks Spring Random Variables and Independence. 1.2 Probability Distribution Function (PDF) Number of heads Probability 2 0. CS134: Networks Spring 2017 Prof. Yaron Singer Section 0 1 Probability 1.1 Random Variables and Independence A real-valued random variable is a variable that can take each of a set of possible values in

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1 Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1 1B, p. 72: (60%)(0.39) + (40%)(0.75) = 0.534. 1D, page 131, solution to the first Exercise: 2.5 2.5 λ(t) dt = 3t 2 dt 2 2 = t 3 ]

More information

X i = 124 MARTINGALES

X i = 124 MARTINGALES 124 MARTINGALES 5.4. Optimal Sampling Theorem (OST). First I stated it a little vaguely: Theorem 5.12. Suppose that (1) T is a stopping time (2) M n is a martingale wrt the filtration F n (3) certain other

More information

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October

More information

Probability in Options Pricing

Probability in Options Pricing Probability in Options Pricing Mark Cohen and Luke Skon Kenyon College cohenmj@kenyon.edu December 14, 2012 Mark Cohen and Luke Skon (Kenyon college) Probability Presentation December 14, 2012 1 / 16 What

More information

(Informal) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

(Informal) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus (Informal) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Paola Mosconi Banca IMI Bocconi University, 19/02/2018 Paola Mosconi 20541 Lecture 2-3 1 / 68 Disclaimer The opinion expressed here are solely those of the

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t - 1 - **** These answers indicate the solutions to the 2014 exam questions. Obviously you should plot graphs where I have simply described the key features. It is important when plotting graphs to label

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2 Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1. 1 Introduction This plug-in implements different binomial trees approximations for pricing contingent claims and allows Fairmat to use some of the most popular binomial

More information

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Advanced Stochastic Processes. Advanced Stochastic Processes. David Gamarnik LECTURE 16 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Lecture outline Trading strategies Black Scholes option pricing formula 16.1. Security price processes,

More information

6. Martingales. = Zn. Think of Z n+1 as being a gambler s earnings after n+1 games. If the game if fair, then E [ Z n+1 Z n

6. Martingales. = Zn. Think of Z n+1 as being a gambler s earnings after n+1 games. If the game if fair, then E [ Z n+1 Z n 6. Martingales For casino gamblers, a martingale is a betting strategy where (at even odds) the stake doubled each time the player loses. Players follow this strategy because, since they will eventually

More information

King s College London

King s College London King s College London University Of London This paper is part of an examination of the College counting towards the award of a degree. Examinations are governed by the College Regulations under the authority

More information

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6 Lecture 3 Sergei Fedotov 091 - Introduction to Financial Mathematics Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) 091 010 1 / 6 Lecture 3 1 Distribution for lns(t) Solution to Stochastic Differential Equation

More information

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 2-3 Haijun Li An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus Week 2-3 1 / 24 Outline

More information

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems M.I.T. 15.450-Fall 2010 Sloan School of Management Professor Leonid Kogan Practice Problems 1. Consider a 3-period model with t = 0, 1, 2, 3. There are a stock and a risk-free asset. The initial stock

More information

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Dr. Roman V Belavkin MSO4112 Contents 1 Geometric Brownian motion 1 2 The Black-Scholes pricing 2 3 The Black-Scholes equation 3 References 5 1 Geometric Brownian motion

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS May/June 2006 Time allowed: 2 HOURS. Examiner: Dr N.P. Byott This is a CLOSED

More information

1 Geometric Brownian motion

1 Geometric Brownian motion Copyright c 05 by Karl Sigman Geometric Brownian motion Note that since BM can take on negative values, using it directly for modeling stock prices is questionable. There are other reasons too why BM is

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information