On the Calibration of Mortality Forward Curves

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On the Calibration of Mortality Forward Curves"

Transcription

1 On the Calibration of Mortality Forward Curves Wai-Sum Chan, Johnny Siu-Hang Li and Andrew Cheuk-Yin Ng Abstract In 2007, a major investment bank launched a product called q-forward, which may be regarded as a forward contract on a mortality rate. The pricing of mortality forwards is similar to the pricing of other forward-rate contracts, such as interest-rate forwards or foreign exchange forwards. In particular, since investors require compensation to take on longevity risk, the forward mortality rate at which q-forward contracts will trade will be smaller than the expected mortality rate. The relationship between the forward rate and the time to maturity is called a mortality forward curve. In this paper, we contribute a method for calibrating mortality forward curves. This method consists of two parts, one of which is the generation of a distribution of future mortality rates, and the other of which is the transformation of the distribution into its risk-neutral counterpart, using the idea of canonical valuation developed by Stutzer (1996, The Journal of Finance, 51, ). To illustrate the method, mortality forward curves for English and Welsh males are calibrated. Keywords: Canonical valuation; Maximum entropy measure; Mortality derivatives; The Cairns-Blake-Dowd model Presenting author, chanws@cuhk.edu.hk. Wai-Sum Chan is Professor of Finance in the Department of Finance at The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, PR China. Johnny Siu-Hang Li is Fairfax Chair in Risk Management in the Department of Statistics at the University of Waterloo, Waterloo, Ontario, Canada. Andrew Cheuk-Yin Ng is Associate Professor in the Department of Finance at The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, PR China. 1

2 1 Introduction The trading of longevity risk, that is, the risk that people live longer than expected, has recently become a hot topic in finance. 1 Through trading in the capital markets, pension plan providers and annuity writers can lay off their longevity risk exposures that introduce uncertainty about the period of time over which benefits must be paid. They view capital market solutions as a plausible alternative to reinsurance, where capacity is often limited, and a good opportunity to enhance their credit profiles. On the other hand, some investors including hedge funds are interested in acquiring an exposure to longevity risk, provided that expected returns are reasonable. This is because longevity securities have a very low correlation to virtually every other asset class in the market, be it inflation, foreign exchange, commodities, equities or credit. 2 The Life and Longevity Markets Association (LLMA) estimates that the potential size of the longevity securities market exceeds 2 trillion in the UK alone, and exceeds $25 trillion worldwide. 3 The first generation of longevity securities is largely bond-based (see, e.g., Blake and Burrows (2001); Blake et al. (2006b)). In November 2004, a longevity bond to be issued by the European Investment Bank (EIB) was announced by BNP Paribas. The bond, with a maturity of 25 years, was intended for UK life insurance companies and pension funds with exposure to longevity risk. Coupon payments from the bond were linked to a survivor index, which was based on the realized mortality rates of a certain cohort of English and Welsh males. The issue, however, was withdrawn in late A possible reason for its failure is that the amount of capital required is high relative to the reduction in risk exposure, making the bond capital-expensive as a risk management tool. The second generation is derivatives-based, usually in the form of a swap or forward (see, e.g., Dowd (2003); Dowd et al. (2006)). Derivative structures are often considered more favorable than bonds because the requirement to invest a large amount of capital up front in purchasing the bond is eliminated. To date we have 1 Discussions on this topic can be found in the following articles: Longevity and Mortality Risk Market Takes Shape, Financial Times, August ; Newcomers Pile into Longevity Risk Market, Financial Times, May ; Lifeline for Longevity Risk Trading, Financial Times, December The low correlation between longevity risk and the risks associated with other asset classes is further discussed by Blake et al. (2006a) and analyzed statistically by Ribeiro and di Pietro (2009). 3 See Coughlan (2010) and LLMA s website ( 2

3 Notional 100 fixed mortality rate FIXED RATE PAYER (Investor) FIXED RATE RECIEVER (Hedger) Notional 100 realized mortality rate Figure 1: Settlement of a q-forward contract at maturity. seen a number of mortality swap transactions. A recent example is the longevity swap agreed between Babcock International and Credit Suisse in Under the terms of the contract, Babcock s pension plan will swap pre-agreed monthly payments to Credit Suisse in return for monthly payments dependent on the longevity of the plan s 4,500 retired members. We call this contract a bespoke longevity swap, by which we mean the arrangement is based on the actual number of survivors in the hedger s portfolio. While hedgers may prefer a bespoke security that is based on the concept of survival rates, investors and intermediaries favor more standardized instruments which are easier to analyze and more conductive to the development of liquidity. Moreover, derivatives that are linked to survival rates (or the number of survivors in the reference population) may be considered path dependent, because a survival rate is essentially a function of several mortality rates at different ages and different times. Investors may find it difficult to evaluate the underlying risk. The perceived complexity would certainly limit investors appetite, posing barriers to market growth. As a precursor to a liquid longevity market, in July 2007, JPMorgan launched a product called q-forward, a forward contract on a mortality rate at a certain age. 4 The derivative involves an exchange of the realized mortality rate at some future date, in return for a pre-agreed fixed mortality rate (see Fig. 1). Provided that it is fairly priced, there is no payment changes hands at the inception of the trade. A pension plan wishing to hedge longevity risk could execute q-forwards in which it receives fixed mortality rates and pays realized mortality rates. At maturity, the forward contracts will pay out to the pension plan a net amount that increases as mortality rates fall to offset the correspondingly higher value of pension liabilities. 4 It is so named because the letter q is the notation used by actuaries to denote mortality rates. 3

4 Mortality forwards are simpler than longevity bonds and swaps, because they are based on a single mortality rate rather than a survival rate that depends on a series of mortality rates. Another advantage of q-forward is that it is more transparent to investors. In particular, its floating leg is linked to a broad-based index (the LifeMetrics index), which is derived from national population statistics. Relevant data are available in the public domain for investors reference. In the early stages of the market s development, transactions are restricted to a limited number of standardized contracts, with a range of maturities and reference ages, in which liquidity can be concentrated. Pension plans and annuity writers can use the available q-forwards to build a longevity hedge with a reasonable effectiveness (see, e.g., Cairns et al. (2008); Coughlan (2009); Li and Hardy (2009)). In a fair market, the fixed mortality rate agreed at inception defines the forward mortality rate for the population in question. Because the investors (the fixed rate payers) require compensation to take on longevity risk, the forward mortality rate will lie below the corresponding expected mortality rate. In this way, on average (i.e., if mortality is realized as expected), a net payment will be made from the hedgers to the investors. Therefore, the difference between the expected and forward mortality rates can be regarded as the expected risk premium to the investors who acquire a longevity risk exposure. The relationship between the forward mortality rate and the maturity date is called a mortality forward curve (see Fig. 2). This curve, which contains all information about the prices of q-forwards with different times to maturity, is the main focus of this study. It is not straightforward to identify fair mortality forward curves in an incomplete market. In this paper, we contribute a method that allows us to calibrate mortality forward curves. Specifically, the method is derived from the idea of canonical valuation, developed by Stutzer (1996). This approach does not strictly require the use of security prices to predict other security prices, making it particularly useful in today s market where we have only a handful of mortality-linked securities available. Although we may calibrate the forward curves by actuarial approaches that are based on a distortion operator, such as the Wang transform (Wang, 1996), there is usually no strong case for the choice of the distortion operator. On top of that, additional subjective decisions are needed if a more sophisticated model is assumed for the evolution of mortality rates (see, e.g., Chen and Cox, 2009). Such subjectivity can be avoided when canonical valuation is used. 4

5 Expected Forward Mortality rate Risk premium Time to maturity (in years) Figure 2: Illustrative expected and forward mortality curves. Empirical findings indicate that canonical valuation performs well in pricing options on equity indexes. Stutzer (1996) reports that, in a simulated market governed by the Black-Scholes assumptions, canonical valuation produces prices close to Black- Scholes prices, even without using any of the simulated market prices in the valuation process. Gray and Newman (2005) show that, in a stochastic volatility environment, canonical valuation clearly outperforms the historic-volatility-based Black-Scholes estimator for most combinations of moneyness and maturity. Canonical valuation has also been applied to different derivative securities including soybean futures options (Foster and Whiteman, 1999) and bond futures options (Stutzer and Chowdhury, 1999). Results suggest that canonical valuation has merits in both applications. Further extensions of canonical valuation has been considered by Alcock and Carmichael (2008), Alcock and Auerswald (2010), Haley and Walker (2010) and Liu (2010). The rest of this article is organized as follows: Section 2 presents a general set-up of canonical valuation, with an explanation to the intuitions behind; Section 3 presents a stochastic mortality model that is fitted to historic data for the population in question, and describes how an empirical distribution of mortality scenarios can be generated from the model; Section 4 explains how we may transform the empirical distribution to its risk-neutral counterpart with canonical valuation; Section 5 calibrates mortality 5

6 forward curves on the basis of the estimated risk-neutral density; finally, Section 6 concludes the paper. 2 Canonical Valuation: A General Set-up Let us consider a market in which there are m distinct primary securities, whose values evolve according to the state of nature ω. We assume that the ith security, where i = 1, 2,..., m, has a time-zero price of F i and, at the risk-free interest rate, a random discounted payoff of f i (ω). Let P be the real-world probability measure and Q be the set of all measures equivalent to P and satisfying E Q [f i (ω)] = F i, i = 1, 2,..., m, (1) for any Q in Q. That is, Q is the set of all equivalent martingale measures. Assume further that there are a finite number N of states of nature. If m = N, then we say the market is complete. In a complete market, the equivalent martingale measure is unique. However, if m < N, which happens when there are only a few securities trading in the market, then we say the market is incomplete. Market incompleteness implies there are infinitely many equivalent martingale measures. To price a derivative in an incomplete market, we need to choose an equivalent martingale measure that is justifiable. canonical valuation. This important step may be accomplished by using the principle of The principle of canonical valuation is heavily based on the Kullback-Leibler information criterion (Kullback and Leibler, 1951). Denote by [ ] dq D(Q, P ) = E P dq ln dp dp the Kullback-Leibler information criterion of measure Q from measure P. Under the principle of canonical valuation, we should choose the equivalent martingale measure Q 0 that minimizes the Kullback-Leibler information criterion, that is, Q 0 = arg min Q Q D(Q, P ), subject to the constraints specified in equation (1). We call Q 0 the canonical measure. When measure P is discrete uniform, the set-up above is equivalent to the maximization of the Shannon entropy in physics. Therefore, this principle is sometimes 6

7 referred to as the principle of maximum entropy. Interested readers are referred to Jaynes (1957) and Kapur (1989) for applications of this principle in physical science. In statistics, the Kullback-Leibler information criterion D(Q, P ) represents the information gained by moving from measure P to measure Q. From a Bayesian viewpoint, we may regard the real-world probability measure P as the prior distribution. In the absence of any information about market prices, the real-world probability measure P is the only measure we can use. Given the prices of the m primary securities, we can update the prior assessment by incorporating the information contained in equation (1). However, no information other than equation (1) should be incorporated in the update. As a result, we choose the measure that minimizes D(Q, P ), the resulting gain in information, subject to the price constraints in equation (1). Generally speaking, there are two widely used approaches to price contingent claims: Replication: When the market is complete, then every contingent claim can be replicated perfectly, and the price of the contingent claim is just the cost of the hedging strategy. Expected utility maximization: Alternatively, risk-neutral valuation can also be derived from general market equilibrium. By assuming no arbitrage and some mild conditions on the underlying utility function, one can use an expected utility maximization argument to derive a risk-neutral measure based on marginal utility. Risk-neutral valuation can thus be understood as a method to utilityweight the probabilities rather than utility-weight the random cashflows. See, for example, Appendix 11B in McDonald (2006) for a one-period binomial tree setting and Corollary 3.10 in Föllmer and Schied (2004) for a general setting in discrete-time. In our pricing problem, the market is incomplete. Mortality forwards (and any mortality derivative in general) cannot be replicated perfectly. However, one can consider expected utility maximization. The method of canonical valuation can be justified from this viewpoint. Specifically, as stated in proposition 3.1 in Frittelli (2000), when one assumes exponential utility, minimizing the Kullback-Leibler information criterion is equivalent to maximizing utility. As a result, the price obtained from the canonical measure fits into the framework of utility maximization. 7

8 To implement canonical valuation, we are required to generate a number of scenarios with equal probability. This step can be accomplished either non-parametrically or semi-parametrically. In the non-parametric approach, which is used in the original work of Stutzer (1996), we generate realizations of the random variable in question by drawing with replacement directly from the associated data sample. In contrast, in the semi-parametric approach, we first fit a parametric model to the associated data sample, and then we generate realizations of the random variable in question from the fitted model. In this study we use the semi-parametric approach to generate scenarios of future mortality. The scenarios generated may be regarded as a collection of all states of nature. As a result, if N scenarios are generated, then the probability mass function for the state of nature ω under the real-world probability measure P is given by Pr(ω = ω j ) = π j = 1, j = 1, 2,..., N. N The above is often called the empirical probability distribution or the ungrouped histogram of ω. Let π j, j = 1, 2,..., N, be the probability distribution of ω under an equivalent martingale measure Q. We can rewrite the constraints in equation (1) as N f i (ω j )πj = F i, i = 1, 2,..., m, (2) j=1 and the Kullback-Leibler information criterion as N j=1 π j ln π j π j. As such, to find the canonical measure Q 0, we solve the following constrained minimization problem: Q 0 = arg min π j N j=1 π j ln π j π j such that N j=1 π j = 1 and (2) holds. Given Q 0, it is straightforward to place a value on a derivative security. Let us consider a security that has a payoff, discounted to time-zero at the risk-free interest rate, of g(ω j ) in scenario j. The price of this security is simply N j=1 g(ω j) π j, where π j, j = 1, 2,..., N, is the probability distribution of ω under Q 0. 3 Modeling Mortality Dynamics When we calibrate mortality forward curves, the random variable in question is the mortality rate q x,t. This is the probability that an individual aged exactly x at exact 8

9 time t will die between t and t + 1. Due to longevity improvement, for any given age x, the value of q x,t is different at different times. Our goal is to model the evolution of the vector q t = (q x1,t, q x2,t,..., q xn,t) over time. In this study we set x 1 = 60 and x n = 90, as hedgers (pension plans and annuity writers) are most interested in this age range. In subsequent sections, the longevity securities presented are linked to the future mortality rates for English and Welsh males. Here we estimate a stochastic mortality process from the associated data sample, which is obtained from the Human Mortality Database (2010). 5 Specifically, we consider a generalized version of the celebrated Cairns-Blake-Dowd model (Cairns et al., 2006). Blake-Dowd model can be expressed as ( ) qx,t ln = κ (1) t + κ (2) t (x x), 1 q x,t In its original form, the Cairns- where x is the average age over the age range we consider, and κ (1) t and κ (2) t are period indexes. The model assumes that, at a fixed time t, ln(q x,t /(1 q x,t )) is a linear function of the mean corrected age x x, with κ (1) t κ (2) t being the slope. Intuitively, we may interpret κ (1) t mortality level at time t and κ (2) t curve (in logit 6 scale) at time t. being the y-intercept and as an indicator of the overall as an indicator of the steepness of the mortality The original Cairns-Blake-Dowd model has two limitations. First, it fails to capture any potential curvature in the mortality curve (in logit scale). Second, it does not incorporate any cohort effect, which refers to the observed phenomenon that people born in certain years have experienced more rapid improvement than people born in other years. The Continuous Mortality Investigation (CMI) Bureau (2002) noted that cohort effects are highly significant in the mortality experience of UK male pensioners and insured lives. Their findings suggest that a model that permits cohort effects should be considered in this study. For the reasons above, we base our calibration work on the following generalization of the Cairns-Blake-Dowd model: ( ) qx,t ln = κ (1) t + κ (2) t (x x) + κ (3) t ((x x) 2 ˆσ 1 q x) 2 + γ t x, (4) (3) x,t 5 Alternatively, the data may be obtained from the United Kingdom s Office for National Statistics or LifeMetrics ( 6 We call the transformation ln(y/(1 y)) a logit transformation. 9

10 where κ (1) t, κ (2) t, and κ (3) t are period risk factors, γ (4) t x is a cohort risk factor, and ˆσ 2 x is the mean of (x x) 2 over the age range we consider. This model is called Model M7 in Cairns et al. (2009). The generalized version contains a cohort risk factor γ (4) t x that is explicitly linked to the year of birth, t x. Parameter γ (4) t x captures the cohort (year-of-birth) effect by taking different values for different years of birth. The generalized version also includes a quadratic term κ (3) t ((x x) 2 ˆσ x) 2 to capture the potential curvature in the relationship between ln(q x,t /(1 q x,t )) and x. As with many other stochastic mortality models, this model has an identifiability problem. In more detail, if κ (1) t, κ (2) t, κ (3) t, and γ (4) t x are model parameters, then it can be shown that κ (1) t = κ (1) t + ψ 1 + ψ 2 t + ψ 3 t 2 + ψ 3ˆσ 2 x, and κ (2) t = κ (2) t ψ 2 2ψ 3 t, κ (3) t = κ (3) t + ψ 3, γ (4) t x = γ (4) t x ψ 1 ψ 2 (t x x) ψ 3 (t x x) 2 are also parameters of the model. following constraints : x,t γ (4) t x = 0, (t x)γ (4) t x = 0, x,t (t x) 2 γ (4) t x = 0. x,t To stipulate parameter uniqueness, we use the The use of these constraints is equivalent to setting ψ 1, ψ 2, and ψ 3 to 0, thereby ensuring the fitted γ (4) t x will fluctuate around zero and will have no discernible linear trend or quadratic curvature. Note that we place no restriction on the signs of the model parameters. We can estimate the model parameters by the method of maximum likelihood. The details regarding parameter estimation are provided in the Appendix. 10

11 Having fitted equation (3) to historic data, the period indexes are modeled by a trivariate random walk with drift: κ t+1 = κ t + µ + CW t+1, (4) where κ t = (κ (1) t, κ (2) t, κ (3) t ), µ is a constant 3 1 vector, C is a constant 3 3 upper triangular matrix, and W t is a 3-dimensional standard normal random vector. The cohort index γ t x, (4) which has no long-term trend, is modeled by an AR(1) process: γ (4) c = φ 0 + φ 1 γ (4) c 1 + a t, where c = t x, φ 0 and φ 1 are constants, and {a t } is a sequence of iid normal random variables with zero mean and constant variance. Although early 20th century data are available, it may not be desirable to use all available data to estimate the model. This is because in doing so, the period indexes may significantly depart from linearity, violating the assumption behind equation (4). The assumption of linearity can be better met by appropriately restricting the fitting period, as Booth et al. (2002) suggest. According to the decision rule suggested by Booth et al. (2002), we find that it is most appropriate to begin the fitting period in year The estimated parameters are show diagrammatically in Figure 3. As expected, the estimated values of γ (4) t x fluctuate around zero and have no discernible linear trend. The spike of γ (4) t x at t x = 1918 has captured the effect of the Spanish flu epidemic, which might have affected people who were born in 1918 (see, e.g., Holmes, 2004). We use the Bayes Information Criterion (BIC; Schwarz, 1978) to evaluate the estimated model. In general terms, the BIC for a fitted model is defined by BIC = ˆl 0.5j ln(n), where ˆl is the maximized log-likelihood, j is the number of effective parameters, and n is the number of observations. The BIC merits goodness-of-fit (measured by the log-likelihood) but penalizes for the use of additional parameters. A model with a higher BIC value is preferred. In Table 1 we show the BIC values for the estimated Cairns-Blake-Dowd model, both in its original and generalized form. The values indicate the need for using the generalized version rather than the simpler original version. 11

12 κ (1) t t κ (2) t t κ (3) t 0 x t γ (4) t x t x Figure 3: Parameter estimates for the generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd model. The need for a cohort index and a quadratic term in the model can also be seen from the standardized residuals, which can be expressed as Z x,t = D x,t ˆD x,t, ˆDx,t where D x,t is the actual death count at age x from time t to t + 1, and ˆD x,t is the corresponding death count estimated from the model. If the model is appropriate, Z x,t will be approximately iid standard normal random variables, and the pattern of Z x,t should be random and have little clustering. In Figure 4 we show the contour plots of Z x,t for both versions of the Cairns-Blake-Dowd model. We observe large clusters in the plot for the original version, indicating that it fails to give an adequate fit. In sharp contrast, the pattern for the generalized version looks a lot more random and contains much less clustering. The variance of Z x,t (see Table 1) also points to the same conclusion. The generalized version gives a variance of Z x,t that is significantly smaller and closer to 1. 12

13 Model BIC Var(Z x,t ) Original Cairns-Blake-Dowd Generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd Table 1: Values of BIC and Var(Z x,t ). 90 The Original Cairns Blake Dowd 90 The Generalized Cairns Blake Dowd x 75 x t t Figure 4: Contour plots of the standardized residuals, Z x,t, from the original and generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd models. It is noteworthy that in the contour plots, diagonals from bottom left to top right correspond to different years of birth. For the simpler model, the contour plot contains obvious diagonal bands, indicating that there are some year-of-birth specific effects that cannot be captured by the model. On the other hand, for the model with a cohort effect term (γ (4) t x), the contour plot contains no apparent diagonal bands, indicating that γ (4) t x has successfully captured the year-of-birth specific effects. We acknowledge that the generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd model is not the only model that can model cohort effects. For instance, Richards et al. (2006) model cohort effects with a P-splines regression. However, this approach is not applicable here, because we cannot generate from a P-splines regression sample paths of future mortality, which are necessary for implementing canonical valuation. Another 13

14 alternative model is the age-period-cohort log-bilinear model proposed by Renshaw and Haberman (2006). Although this model can generate sample paths, it is not considered in this study because the algorithm for estimating its parameters has a slow rate of convergence. When fitted to the data we consider, this model would contain 36 more parameters than the model we use in our calculations. Further, on the basis of several selection criteria, Cairns et al. (2009) conclude that the generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd model is more preferred when considering English and Welsh males data. 4 Deriving the Canonical Measure To carry out canonical valuation, we need to generate a large number of mortality scenarios. Given the generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd model, we generate mortality scenarios by simulating future values of the period indexes, κ (1) t, κ (2) t, and κ (3) t, and the cohort index, γ t x. (4) Given a realization of κ (1) t, κ (2) t, κ (3) t, and γ t x, (4) we can obtain a scenario of future mortality rates by substituting the values into equation (3). Note that the generated mortality scenarios are equally probable. Suppose that N scenarios are generated. Under the real-world probability measure, the probability of having a mortality rate of q x,t (ω j ) (i.e., being in the state of nature ω j ), for j = 1, 2,..., N, is simply 1/N. Other than the simulated mortality scenarios, we need at least one price constraint in order to implement canonical valuation. BNP/EIB longevity bond announced in 2004 to illustrate. In this paper we use the price of the The BNP/EIB longevity bond is a 25-year amortising bond (i.e., a bond without principal repayment) with coupon payments that are linked to a survivor index, which is based on the realized mortality rates of English and Welsh males aged 65 in The index I(t) on which the coupon payments are based is defined as follows: I(t) = I(t 1)(1 m 64+t,2002+t ), t = 1, 2,..., 25, where I(0) = 1, and m x,t = ln(1 q x,t ) is the central death rate at age x and in year t. In each year t, t = 1, 2,..., 25, from inception, the bond pays a coupon of 50 I(t) million. According to EIB, the issue price was determined by discounting the expected coupon payments (in the real-world probability measure) at LIBOR minus 35 basis 14

15 points. Cairns et al. (2006) observed that the EIB curve typically stands about 15 basis points below the LIBOR curve. The difference (20 basis points) can be regarded as the longevity risk premium. Cairns et al. (2006) further assume that the EIB curve is flat at the level of 4% per annum. Discounting the expected coupon payments at 4% less the risk premium of 20 basis points, they obtain an estimated time-0 price of ( ) million. For each simulated mortality scenario, we have an array of future mortality rates from which we can calculate I(t) at t = 1, 2,..., 25. Let I(t, ω j ) be the value of the longevity index at time t in the jth scenario. Then in the jth scenario, the payoffs, discounted to time zero at the risk-free interest rate, from the longevity bond is given by 25 v(ω j ) = 50 B(0, t)i(t, ω j ), t=1 where B(0, t) is the price at time 0 of a risk-free zero-coupon bond maturing for 1 at time t. 7 Under the real-world probability measure P, the probability of having a discounted payoff of v(ω j ) from the longevity bond is π j = 1/N, for j = 1, 2,..., N. We now transform this probability distribution into its risk-neutral counterpart. We let πj be the probability associated with v(ω j ) (i.e., the jth scenario) under an equivalent martingale measure Q. Under Q, the expectation of v(ω) must be the same as the market price of the longevity bond at time zero. In other words, the following constraint must be satisfied: N v(ω j )πj = (5) j=1 The canonical measure is then found by minimizing the Kullback-Leibler information criterion, subject to N j=1 π j = 1 and equation (5). We solve this problem with the method of Lagrange multipliers, which says the constrained minimization is 7 We define here a risk-free bond by a bond that is free of longevity risk; that is, its payoff is the same regardless of what mortality scenario it turns out to be. On this basis of our definition, a risk-free bond may be subject to other types of risk, for example, counterparty default risk. Such a bond could be one that is issued by EIB (or an institution with a similar credit rating) and is not mortality-linked. In the rest of this article, the risk-free rate refers to the interest rate on such a bond. 15

16 equivalent to minimizing ( N N ) L = πj ln πj λ 0 πj 1 λ 1 j=1 j=1 N j=1 ( v(ωj )π j ). Let π j, j = 1, 2,..., N, be the solution, that is, the canonical measure Q 0. We require it to satisfy the first-order conditions: ln π j + 1 λ 0 λ 1 v(ω j ) = 0, j = 1, 2,..., N, or equivalently, π j = exp(λ 0 + λ 1 v(ω j ) 1), j = 1, 2,..., N, which means π j is proportional to exp(λ 1 v(ω j )). It follows from N j=1 π j = 1 that π j = exp(λ 1 v(ω j )) N j=1 exp(λ, j = 1, 2,..., N. (6) 1v(ω j )) What remains is the Lagrange multiplier λ 1, which can be determined by substituting equation (6) into equation (5) or by the following expression: λ 1 = arg min γ N exp(γ(v(ω j ) 572.1)). j=1 Figure 5 shows the resulting canonical measure, which is obtained from N = 5000 mortality scenarios. Given π j, for j = 1,..., N, we can price another mortality-linked security easily. Suppose that, in the jth scenario, a mortality-linked security has a payoff, discounted to time-0 at the risk-free rate, of h(ω j ). The time-0 price of such a security is simply given by N j=1 h(ω j) π j. We acknowledge that basing the price constraint on the BNP/EIB longevity bond is subject to the following limitations: 1. Information contained in this price, which was announced in 2004, might have become obsolete. 2. The bond did not actually trade, and therefore its price may not truly reflect market participants aversion to longevity risk. 16

17 π * j j Figure 5: The canonical measure. However, as of when the article is written, the BNP/EIB longevity bond seems to be the only suitable security with pricing information available in the public domain. Other mortality-linked securities, such as the 3-year bond sold by Swiss Re in 2003, are short-term securities for hedging the risk of catastrophic events. They are therefore not suitable for deriving the canonical measure which will then be used to price mortality forward contracts for hedging the uncertainty in long-term longevity improvement. 5 Mortality Forward Curves Let us recall how a mortality forward contract is structured. Suppose that the contract is linked to the mortality rate at age x and at a future time T. Then at maturity, which is usually a few months after time T due to the lag in the availability of official data, the fixed rate payer (the investor) pays to the fixed rate receiver (the hedger) an amount proportional to the forward mortality rate, q f x,t, which is agreed at inception. In return, the hedger pays to the investor an amount proportional to the realized value of the reference mortality rate, q x,t. The settlement that takes place at maturity is 17

18 based on the net amount payable and is proportional to the difference between the transacted forward mortality rate and the realized reference mortality rate. Since there is no price paid to enter into a forward contract, we have B(0, T + δ)e Q [q x,t q f x,t F 0] = 0, where T + δ is the maturity date, δ is the lag in the availability of official data, and F t is the filtration generated by the development of the mortality curve up to time t. As a result, we can calculate the forward mortality rate at which the contract will transact by the following equation: q f x,t = EQ [q x,t F 0 ]. All that then remains is to obtain E Q [q x,t F 0 ], the risk-neutral expectation of q x,t. When we use canonical valuation, the expectation can be calculated as follows: N q x,t (ω j )πj, j=1 where q x,t (ω j ) is the value of q x,t in the jth mortality scenario, and πj is the probability associated with the jth scenario under the canonical measure Q 0, which we identified in Section 4. In Figure 6 we show the calibrated mortality forward curves, that is, the relationships between q f x,t and T, for some selected ages. As expected, the expected and forward mortality curve diverge as T increases, since the uncertainty associated with the underlying mortality rate increases as we project the rate further into the future. We also observe that the spread is significantly larger at higher ages, for which mortality rates are more volatile and more difficult to predict. The relationship between the expected risk premium (i.e., the difference between the expected and forward mortality rates) and age can be seen more easily from Figure 7, in which we show the expected and forward mortality rates at a given time to maturity T = 20. The increasing divergence with age indicates that investors demand a higher risk premium when taking on longevity risk associated with more advanced ages. For the reader s reference, we summarize in Table 2 the expected risk premia for different combinations of reference age and time to maturity. On top of the limitations we mentioned in Section 4, the time-0 price ( million) of the BNP/EIB longevity bond is just an estimate, which is calculated 18

19 Age 65 Age 70 Mortality rate Expected Forward Mortality rate Expected Forward Mortality rate Maturity (years) Age 75 Expected Forward Mortality rate Maturity (years) Age 80 Expected Forward Mortality rate Maturity (years) Age 85 Expected Forward Mortality rate Maturity (years) Age 90 Expected Forward Maturity (years) Maturity (years) Figure 6: Calibrated mortality forward curves for English and Welsh males at representative ages. 19

20 Expected Forward 0.12 Mortality rate Age Figure 7: Expected and forward mortality rates at T = 20, English and Welsh males. under the assumption of a flat EIB curve and a risk premium of 20 basis points. It is worthwhile to perform a sensitivity analysis to understand how the forward mortality rates may change when the estimated price is varied. The sensitivity test is performed by considering two other risk premia: 10 basis points and 30 basis points. For each of these risk premia, the time-0 price of the BNP/EIB longevity bond is estimated by discounting the expected coupon payments at 4% less the assumed risk premium. The estimated time-0 prices are million and million, respectively. We then use each of these two prices as a price constraint to recalibrate the mortality forward curves. The resulting risk premia on mortality forwards with different reference ages and times to maturity are summarized in Tables 3 and 4. 6 Concluding Remarks This study presents a method for calibrating mortality forward curves. The method presented is derived from a semi-parametric implementation of canonical valuation. 20

21 Age / Maturity (years) Table 2: Expected risk premia on mortality forwards with different reference ages and times to maturity. The price constraint is formulated with an assumed price of million. Age / Maturity (years) Table 3: Expected risk premia on mortality forwards with different reference ages and times to maturity. The price constraint is formulated with an assumed price of million. In particular, we utilize a generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd model to form an empirical distribution of future mortality rates, and then we transform the empirical distribution to its risk-neutral counterpart by maximizing the associated Shannon entropy. As an illustration, we calibrate mortality forward curves for English and Welsh males. From these curves hedgers and investors can access the expected risk premium associated with a specific mortality forward contract. Over the past few years, the advancement of the longevity market has been supported by the development of various tools that are designed to improve the degree of transparency, education and standardization. These tools include mortality forecasting software provided by the CMI Bureau and the LifeMetrics, historic mortality data supplied by organizations such as the Max Planck Institute for Demographic 21

22 Age / Maturity (years) Table 4: Expected risk premia on mortality forwards with different reference ages and times to maturity. The price constraint is formulated with an assumed price of million. Research and the CMI Bureau, and standardized longevity indexes offered by, for example, Credit Suisse, Deutsche Börse, Goldman Sachs and JPMorgan. However, there is still a lack of valuation methods that are applicable to the current market situation. This study partially fills in this gap, and we believe that significant further research on the topic of pricing is necessary. Standardized longevity securities such as mortality forwards have both pros and cons. While investors and intermediaries often view standardized securities more favorably as a means of trading longevity risk, they cannot take away all of the longevity risk involved in the hedger s portfolio. In particular, a hedge formed by standardized securities will always leave a residual exposure to population basis risk, which refers to the mismatch between the longevity experience of individuals associated with the hedger s portfolio and that associated with the index to which the security is linked. We may minimize population basis risk by constructing the hedge carefully. By sensitivity matching, Coughlan (2009) demonstrates that a hedge effectiveness of 86% can be achieved. With more advanced hedging strategies, we can even obtain an over 90% hedge effectiveness (see Li and Hardy, 2009). Given a hedging strategy and the calibrated mortality forward curves, a hedger such as a pension plan can cost out the longevity hedge formed by mortality forward contracts. The pension plan can compare this cost against the costs associated with other options, which include bespoke longevity swaps and buy-ins, that is, the seeking a financial institution to insure (lock-in) its pension liabilities. A financially optimal decision can then be made. 22

23 In the original work of Stutzer (1996), canonical valuation is implemented nonparametrically. A non-parametric approach is not used here, in large part because it is unclear about how to incorporate cohort effects if mortality scenarios are bootstrapped directly from the data. We acknowledge that, by using a semi-parametric approach, the calibration work is subject to parameter risk, that is, the uncertainty involved in estimating the model parameters. Such uncertainty may be taken into account by using the parametric bootstrap, which is based on a sequence of generated pseudo samples. In using the parametric bootstrap, we estimate one set of model parameters from each of the pseudo samples, yielding a distribution, rather than just a single point estimate, of model parameters. Each mortality scenario is derived from a specific set of parameter estimates, and therefore, parameter uncertainty is incorporated in the resulting empirical distribution on which canonical valuation is based. On the basis of this method, Li (2010) found that longevity bond prices that are calculated with the incorporation of parameter uncertainty can be significantly higher than those without. It is expected that the forward mortality rates will be lower if parameter risk is included in our calculations. This issue deserves further investigation in future research. References Alcock, J. and Auerswald, D. (2010). Empirical Tests of Canonical Nonparametric American Option-Pricing Methods. Journal of Futures Markets, 30, Alcock, J. and Carmichael, T. (2008). Nonparametric American Option Pricing. Journal of Futures Markets, Blake, D. and Burrows, W. (2001). Survivor Bonds: Helping to Hedge Mortality Risk. Journal of Risk and Insurance, Blake, D., Cairns, A.J.G., and Dowd, K. (2006a). Living with Mortality: Longevity Bonds and Other Mortality-Linked Securities. British Actuarial Journal, 12, Blake, D., Cairns, A.J.C., Dowd, K. and MacMinn, R. (2006b). Longevity Bonds: Financial Engineering, Valuation and Hedging. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 73,

24 Booth, H., Maindonald, J. and Smith, L. (2002). Applying Lee-Carter under Conditions of Variable Mortality Decline. Population Studies, 56, Cairns, A.J.G., Blake, D., and Dowd, K. (2006). A Two-Factor Model for Stochastic Mortality with Parameter Uncertainty: Theory and Calibration. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 73, Cairns, A.J.G., Blake, D. and Dowd, K. (2008). Modelling and Management of Mortality Risk: A Review. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 108, Cairns, A.J.G., Blake, D., Dowd, K., Coughlan, G.D., Epstein, D., Ong, A., and Balevich, I. (2009). A Quantitative Comparison of Stochastic Mortality Models Using Data from England and Wales and the United States. North American Actuarial Journal, 13, Chen, H., and Cox. S.H. (2009). Modeling Mortality With Jumps: Applications to Mortality Securitization. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 76, Continuous Mortality Investigation Bureau (2002). An Interim Basis for Adjusting the 92 Series Mortality Projections for Cohort Effects. CMI Working Paper 1. London: Institute of Actuaries and Faculty of Actuaries. Coughlan, G. (2010). Life and Longevity Markets Association: The Development of a Longevity and Mortality Trading Market. Presentation in the Sixth International Longevity Risk and Capital Markets Solutions Conference, Sydney, Australia, September Coughlan, G. (2009). Longevity Risk Transfer: Indices and Capital Market Solutions. In Barrieu, P. and Albertini, L. (eds.), The Handbook of Insurance-Linked Securities. West Sussex: John Wiley & Sons. Dowd. K. (2003). Survivor Bonds: A Comment on Blake and Burrows. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 70, Dowd, K., Blake, D., Cairns, A.J.G. and Dawson, P. (2006). Survivor swaps. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 73, Föllmer, H., and A. Schied. (2004). Stochastic Finance An Introduction in Discrete Time, 2nd ed. Number 27 in de Gruyter Studies in Mathematics. Walter de Gruyter. Foster, F.D. and C.H. Whiteman. (1999). An Application of Bayesian Option Pricing to the Soybean Market. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81,

25 Frittelli, M. (2000). The Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure and the Valuation Problem in Incomplete Market. Mathematical Finance, 10, Gray, P. and Newman, S. (2005). Canonical Valuation of Options in the Presence of Stochastic Volatility. Journal of Futures Markets, 25, Haley, M.R. and Walker, T.B. (2010). Alternative Tilts for Nonparametric Option Pricing. Journal of Futures Markets, in press. Holmes, E.C. (2004). Enhanced: 1918 and All That. Science, 303, Human Mortality Database. University of California, Berkeley (USA), and Max Planck Institute of Demographic Research (Germany). Available at or (data downloaded on 1 Jan 2010). Jaynes, E.T. (1957). Information Theory and Statistical Mechanics. Physical Review, 106, Kapur, K. N. (1989). Maximum-Entropy Models in Science and Engineering. New York: Wiley Eastern, Ltd. Kullback, S. and Leibler, R. A. (1951). On Information and Sufficiency. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 22, Li, J.S.-H. (2010). Pricing Longevity Risk with the Parametric Bootstrap: A Maximum Entropy Approach. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 47, Li, J.S.-H. and Hardy, M.R. (2009). Measuring Basis Risk Involved in Longevity Hedges. Paper presented in the Fifth International Longevity Risk and Capital Markets Solutions Conference, New York, USA, September Liu, Q. (2010). Pricing American Options by Canonical Least-Squares Monte Carlo. Journal of Futures Markets, 30, McDonald, R.L. (2006). Derivatives Markets, 2nd ed. Boston: Addison-Wesley. Renshaw, A.E. and Haberman, S. (2006). A Cohort-based Extension to the Lee-Carter Model for Mortality Reduction Factors. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 38, Richards, S.J., Kirkby, J.G., and Currie, I.D. (2006). The Importance of Year of Birth in Two-Dimensional Mortality Data. British Actuarial Journal, Ribeiro, R. and di Pietro, V. (2009). Longevity Risk and Portfolio Allocation. Available at 25

26 Stutzer, M. (1996). A Simple Nonparametric Approach to Derivative Security Valuation. Journal of Finance, 51, Stutzer, M. and Chowdhury, M. (1999). A Simple Nonparametric Approach to Bond Futures Option Pricing. Journal of Fixed Income, 8, Schwarz, G. (1978). Estimating the Dimension of a Model. Annals of Statistics, 6, Wang, S. (1996). Premium Calculation by Transforming the Layer Premium Density. ASTIN Bulletin, 26(1), Appendix Maximum Likelihood Estimation for the Generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd Model Let us define D x,t by the number of deaths at age x from time t to t + 1, and E x,t by the corresponding exposures to the risk of death. To construct the likelihood function, we treat D x,t as independent Poisson responses, that is, D x,t Poisson(E x,t m x,t ), where m x,t is the central death rate. The product E x,t m x,t is the expected number of deaths at age x and in year t. This gives the following log-likelihood: l = (D x,t ln(e x,t m x,t ) E x,t m x,t ln(d x,t!)), (7) x,t where D x,t! stands for D x,t factorial. The generalized Cairns-Blake-Dowd model is based on death probability q x,t rather than the central death rate m x,t. To relate these two quantities, we use the following relation: m x,t = ln(1 q x,t ), (8) which holds if we assume that the force of mortality is constant over each year of integer age and over each calendar year. So the required likelihood function can be obtained by substituting equation (3) into equation (8) and then into equation (7). 26

27 Parameter estimates can be obtained by maximizing the corresponding likelihood function. The maximization can be accomplished by an iterative Newton-Raphson method, in which parameters are updated one at a time. The updating of a typical parameter θ proceeds according to u(θ) = θ l/ θ 2 l/ θ 2, where u(θ) is the updated value of θ in the iteration. The parameter constraints are applied at the end of each iteration. 27

Time-Simultaneous Fan Charts: Applications to Stochastic Life Table Forecasting

Time-Simultaneous Fan Charts: Applications to Stochastic Life Table Forecasting 19th International Congress on Modelling and Simulation, Perth, Australia, 12 16 December 211 http://mssanz.org.au/modsim211 Time-Simultaneous Fan Charts: Applications to Stochastic Life Table Forecasting

More information

Canonical Valuation of Mortality-linked Securities

Canonical Valuation of Mortality-linked Securities Canonical Valuation of Mortality-linked Securities Johnny S.H. Li Abstract A fundamental question in the study of mortality-linked securities is how to place a value on them. This is still an open question,

More information

Comparison of Pricing Approaches for Longevity Markets

Comparison of Pricing Approaches for Longevity Markets Comparison of Pricing Approaches for Longevity Markets Melvern Leung Simon Fung & Colin O hare Longevity 12 Conference, Chicago, The Drake Hotel, September 30 th 2016 1 / 29 Overview Introduction 1 Introduction

More information

Evaluating Hedge Effectiveness for Longevity Annuities

Evaluating Hedge Effectiveness for Longevity Annuities Outline Evaluating Hedge Effectiveness for Longevity Annuities Min Ji, Ph.D., FIA, FSA Towson University, Maryland, USA Rui Zhou, Ph.D., FSA University of Manitoba, Canada Longevity 12, Chicago September

More information

A Simple Stochastic Model for Longevity Risk revisited through Bootstrap

A Simple Stochastic Model for Longevity Risk revisited through Bootstrap A Simple Stochastic Model for Longevity Risk revisited through Bootstrap Xu Shi Bridget Browne Xu Shi, Bridget Browne This presentation has been prepared for the Actuaries Institute 2015 Actuaries Summit.

More information

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation Entropic Derivative Security Valuation Michael Stutzer 1 Professor of Finance and Director Burridge Center for Securities Analysis and Valuation University of Colorado, Boulder, CO 80309 1 Mathematical

More information

MODELLING AND MANAGEMENT OF LONGEVITY RISK. Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh

MODELLING AND MANAGEMENT OF LONGEVITY RISK. Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh 1 MODELLING AND MANAGEMENT OF LONGEVITY RISK Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh Philadelphia, 2013 Acknowledgements: David Blake, Kevin Dowd, Guy Coughlan 2 Plan

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

A comparative study of two-population models for the assessment of basis risk in longevity hedges

A comparative study of two-population models for the assessment of basis risk in longevity hedges A comparative study of two-population models for the assessment of basis risk in longevity hedges Steven Haberman, Vladimir Kaishev, Pietro Millossovich, Andres Villegas Faculty of Actuarial Science and

More information

Pricing death. or Modelling the Mortality Term Structure. Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh. Joint work with David Blake & Kevin Dowd

Pricing death. or Modelling the Mortality Term Structure. Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh. Joint work with David Blake & Kevin Dowd 1 Pricing death or Modelling the Mortality Term Structure Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh Joint work with David Blake & Kevin Dowd 2 Background Life insurers and pension funds exposed to

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER PI-1109

DISCUSSION PAPER PI-1109 DISCUSSION PAPER PI-1109 Key q-duration: A Framework for Hedging Longevity Risk Johnny Siu-Hang Li, and Ancheng Luo July 2011 ISSN 1367-580X The Pensions Institute Cass Business School City University

More information

HEDGING LONGEVITY RISK: A FORENSIC, MODEL-BASED ANALYSIS AND DECOMPOSITION OF BASIS RISK

HEDGING LONGEVITY RISK: A FORENSIC, MODEL-BASED ANALYSIS AND DECOMPOSITION OF BASIS RISK 1 HEDGING LONGEVITY RISK: A FORENSIC, MODEL-BASED ANALYSIS AND DECOMPOSITION OF BASIS RISK Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh Longevity 6, Sydney, 9-10 September

More information

Longevity risk and stochastic models

Longevity risk and stochastic models Part 1 Longevity risk and stochastic models Wenyu Bai Quantitative Analyst, Redington Partners LLP Rodrigo Leon-Morales Investment Consultant, Redington Partners LLP Muqiu Liu Quantitative Analyst, Redington

More information

Pricing q-forward Contracts: An evaluation of estimation window and pricing method under different mortality models

Pricing q-forward Contracts: An evaluation of estimation window and pricing method under different mortality models Pricing q-forward Contracts: An evaluation of estimation window and pricing method under different mortality models Pauline M. Barrieu London School of Economics and Political Science Luitgard A. M. Veraart

More information

Modelling, Estimation and Hedging of Longevity Risk

Modelling, Estimation and Hedging of Longevity Risk IA BE Summer School 2016, K. Antonio, UvA 1 / 50 Modelling, Estimation and Hedging of Longevity Risk Katrien Antonio KU Leuven and University of Amsterdam IA BE Summer School 2016, Leuven Module II: Fitting

More information

MODELLING AND MANAGEMENT OF MORTALITY RISK

MODELLING AND MANAGEMENT OF MORTALITY RISK 1 MODELLING AND MANAGEMENT OF MORTALITY RISK Stochastic models for modelling mortality risk ANDREW CAIRNS Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh and Director of the Actuarial Research Centre Institute and Faculty

More information

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm Chapter 8 Utility Indifference ricing and Dynamic rogramming Algorithm In the Black-Scholes framework, we can perfectly replicate an option s payoff. However, it may not be true beyond the Black-Scholes

More information

Hedging Longevity Risk using Longevity Swaps: A Case Study of the Social Security and National Insurance Trust (SSNIT), Ghana

Hedging Longevity Risk using Longevity Swaps: A Case Study of the Social Security and National Insurance Trust (SSNIT), Ghana International Journal of Finance and Accounting 2016, 5(4): 165-170 DOI: 10.5923/j.ijfa.20160504.01 Hedging Longevity Risk using Longevity Swaps: A Case Study of the Social Security and National Insurance

More information

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis 1/18 : estimation and model analysis, EDHEC Business School (joint work with Rama COT) Modeling and managing financial risks Paris, 10 13 January 2011 2/18 Outline 1 2 of multi-asset models Solution to

More information

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling Interest rate modeling Abstract In this paper, three models were used to forecast short term interest rates for the 3 month LIBOR. Each of the models, regression time series, GARCH, and Cox, Ingersoll,

More information

September 7th, 2009 Dr. Guido Grützner 1

September 7th, 2009 Dr. Guido Grützner 1 September 7th, 2009 Dr. Guido Grützner 1 Cautionary remarks about conclusions from the observation of record-life expectancy IAA Life Colloquium 2009 Guido Grützner München, September 7 th, 2009 Cautionary

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER PI-0801

DISCUSSION PAPER PI-0801 DISCUSSION PAPER PI-0801 Mortality Density Forecasts: An Analysis of Six Stochastic Mortality Models Andrew J.G. Cairns, David Blake, Kevin Dowd Guy D. Coughlan, David Epstein, and Marwa Khalaf Allah April

More information

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Market Risk Analysis Volume I Market Risk Analysis Volume I Quantitative Methods in Finance Carol Alexander John Wiley & Sons, Ltd List of Figures List of Tables List of Examples Foreword Preface to Volume I xiii xvi xvii xix xxiii

More information

Robust Longevity Risk Management

Robust Longevity Risk Management Robust Longevity Risk Management Hong Li a,, Anja De Waegenaere a,b, Bertrand Melenberg a,b a Department of Econometrics and Operations Research, Tilburg University b Netspar Longevity 10 3-4, September,

More information

Managing Systematic Mortality Risk in Life Annuities: An Application of Longevity Derivatives

Managing Systematic Mortality Risk in Life Annuities: An Application of Longevity Derivatives Managing Systematic Mortality Risk in Life Annuities: An Application of Longevity Derivatives Simon Man Chung Fung, Katja Ignatieva and Michael Sherris School of Risk & Actuarial Studies University of

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Lecture 17: More on Markov Decision Processes. Reinforcement learning

Lecture 17: More on Markov Decision Processes. Reinforcement learning Lecture 17: More on Markov Decision Processes. Reinforcement learning Learning a model: maximum likelihood Learning a value function directly Monte Carlo Temporal-difference (TD) learning COMP-424, Lecture

More information

MORTALITY RISK ASSESSMENT UNDER IFRS 17

MORTALITY RISK ASSESSMENT UNDER IFRS 17 MORTALITY RISK ASSESSMENT UNDER IFRS 17 PETR SOTONA University of Economics, Prague, Faculty of Informatics and Statistics, Department of Statistics and Probability, W. Churchill Square 4, Prague, Czech

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

Mortality Density Forecasts: An Analysis of Six Stochastic Mortality Models

Mortality Density Forecasts: An Analysis of Six Stochastic Mortality Models Mortality Density Forecasts: An Analysis of Six Stochastic Mortality Models Andrew J.G. Cairns ab, David Blake c, Kevin Dowd c, Guy D. Coughlan de, David Epstein d, and Marwa Khalaf-Allah d January 6,

More information

Modeling and Managing Longevity Risk: Models and Applications

Modeling and Managing Longevity Risk: Models and Applications Modeling and Managing Longevity Risk: Models and Applications by Yanxin Liu A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfillment of the thesis requirement for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

More information

Cohort and Value-Based Multi-Country Longevity Risk Management

Cohort and Value-Based Multi-Country Longevity Risk Management Cohort and Value-Based Multi-Country Longevity Risk Management Michael Sherris, Yajing Xu and Jonathan Ziveyi School of Risk & Actuarial Studies Centre of Excellence in Population Ageing Research UNSW

More information

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Appendix A Financial Calculations Derivatives Demystified: A Step-by-Step Guide to Forwards, Futures, Swaps and Options, Second Edition By Andrew M. Chisholm 010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appendix A Financial Calculations TIME VALUE OF MONEY

More information

Modelling Longevity Dynamics for Pensions and Annuity Business

Modelling Longevity Dynamics for Pensions and Annuity Business Modelling Longevity Dynamics for Pensions and Annuity Business Ermanno Pitacco University of Trieste (Italy) Michel Denuit UCL, Louvain-la-Neuve (Belgium) Steven Haberman City University, London (UK) Annamaria

More information

It Takes Two: Why Mortality Trend Modeling is more than modeling one Mortality Trend

It Takes Two: Why Mortality Trend Modeling is more than modeling one Mortality Trend It Takes Two: Why Mortality Trend Modeling is more than modeling one Mortality Trend Johannes Schupp Joint work with Matthias Börger and Jochen Russ IAA Life Section Colloquium, Barcelona, 23 th -24 th

More information

Market Price of Longevity Risk for A Multi-Cohort Mortality Model with Application to Longevity Bond Option Pricing

Market Price of Longevity Risk for A Multi-Cohort Mortality Model with Application to Longevity Bond Option Pricing 1/51 Market Price of Longevity Risk for A Multi-Cohort Mortality Model with Application to Longevity Bond Option Pricing Yajing Xu, Michael Sherris and Jonathan Ziveyi School of Risk & Actuarial Studies,

More information

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model Wai-Ki Ching Tak-Kuen Siu Li-min Li 26 Jan. 2007 Abstract In this paper, we consider the pricing of exotic options when the price dynamic

More information

UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS

UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS II. UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS A. Supporting Learning Areas 1. STATISTICS Aim: To enable students to apply core statistical techniques to actuarial applications in insurance, pensions and emerging

More information

HEDGING THE LONGEVITY RISK FOR THE PORTUGUESE POPULATION IN THE BOND MARKET

HEDGING THE LONGEVITY RISK FOR THE PORTUGUESE POPULATION IN THE BOND MARKET School of Economics and Management TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY OF LISBON HEDGING THE LONGEVITY RISK FOR THE PORTUGUESE POPULATION IN THE BOND MARKET Rúben Pereira Carlos Mercer Portugal Onofre Simões ISEG - Instituto

More information

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14 Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA March 1, 2012 1 Introduction Premia 14 Top-down" models for portfolio credit derivatives have been introduced as

More information

City, University of London Institutional Repository. This version of the publication may differ from the final published version.

City, University of London Institutional Repository. This version of the publication may differ from the final published version. City Research Online City, University of London Institutional Repository Citation: Hunt, A. & Blake, D. (2017). Modelling Mortality for Pension Schemes. ASTIN Bulletin, doi: 10.1017/asb.2016.40 This is

More information

IFRS Convergence: The Role of Stochastic Mortality Models in the Disclosure of Longevity Risk for Defined Benefit Plans

IFRS Convergence: The Role of Stochastic Mortality Models in the Disclosure of Longevity Risk for Defined Benefit Plans IFRS Convergence: The Role of Stochastic Mortality Models in the Disclosure of Longevity Risk for Defined Benefit Plans Yosuke Fujisawa (joint-work with Johnny Li) Dept. of Statistics & Actuarial Science

More information

Term Structure Lattice Models

Term Structure Lattice Models IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models These lecture notes introduce fixed income derivative securities and the modeling philosophy used to

More information

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs 1 Introduction Václav Kozmík 1 Abstract. This paper deals with asset allocation problems formulated as multistage stochastic programming models.

More information

A Markov Chain Monte Carlo Approach to Estimate the Risks of Extremely Large Insurance Claims

A Markov Chain Monte Carlo Approach to Estimate the Risks of Extremely Large Insurance Claims International Journal of Business and Economics, 007, Vol. 6, No. 3, 5-36 A Markov Chain Monte Carlo Approach to Estimate the Risks of Extremely Large Insurance Claims Wan-Kai Pang * Department of Applied

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

ROBUST HEDGING OF LONGEVITY RISK. Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh

ROBUST HEDGING OF LONGEVITY RISK. Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh 1 ROBUST HEDGING OF LONGEVITY RISK Andrew Cairns Heriot-Watt University, and The Maxwell Institute, Edinburgh June 2014 In Journal of Risk and Insurance (2013) 80: 621-648. 2 Plan Intro + model Recalibration

More information

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright Faculty and Institute of Actuaries Claims Reserving Manual v.2 (09/1997) Section D7 [D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright 1. Introduction

More information

Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs

Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs Ken Jackson Wanhe Zhang February 10, 2007 Abstract A forward starting CDO is a single tranche CDO with a specified premium starting at a specified future time. Pricing

More information

Simulating Continuous Time Rating Transitions

Simulating Continuous Time Rating Transitions Bus 864 1 Simulating Continuous Time Rating Transitions Robert A. Jones 17 March 2003 This note describes how to simulate state changes in continuous time Markov chains. An important application to credit

More information

Handbook of Financial Risk Management

Handbook of Financial Risk Management Handbook of Financial Risk Management Simulations and Case Studies N.H. Chan H.Y. Wong The Chinese University of Hong Kong WILEY Contents Preface xi 1 An Introduction to Excel VBA 1 1.1 How to Start Excel

More information

Research Article Optimal Hedging and Pricing of Equity-LinkedLife Insurance Contracts in a Discrete-Time Incomplete Market

Research Article Optimal Hedging and Pricing of Equity-LinkedLife Insurance Contracts in a Discrete-Time Incomplete Market Journal of Probability and Statistics Volume 2011, Article ID 850727, 23 pages doi:10.1155/2011/850727 Research Article Optimal Hedging and Pricing of Equity-LinkedLife Insurance Contracts in a Discrete-Time

More information

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios Matti Koivu Teemu Pennanen June 19, 2013 Abstract Bond returns are known to exhibit mean reversion, autocorrelation and other dynamic properties that differentiate

More information

Construction of a BRICS index and option price evaluation relative to constituent indexes

Construction of a BRICS index and option price evaluation relative to constituent indexes Construction of a BRICS index and option price evaluation relative to constituent indexes Abstract A BRICS index is proposed relative to given indexes on the stock exchanges of the BRICS countries. The

More information

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1. THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** Abstract The change of numeraire gives very important computational

More information

SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE

SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE C The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2006, Vol. 73, No. 1, 71-96 SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE Michael Sherris INTRODUCTION ABSTRACT In this article, we consider the

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) A stochastic discount factor is a stochastic process {M t,t+s } such that

More information

Pricing Pension Buy-ins and Buy-outs 1

Pricing Pension Buy-ins and Buy-outs 1 Pricing Pension Buy-ins and Buy-outs 1 Tianxiang Shi Department of Finance College of Business Administration University of Nebraska-Lincoln Longevity 10, Santiago, Chile September 3-4, 2014 1 Joint work

More information

Overnight Index Rate: Model, calibration and simulation

Overnight Index Rate: Model, calibration and simulation Research Article Overnight Index Rate: Model, calibration and simulation Olga Yashkir and Yuri Yashkir Cogent Economics & Finance (2014), 2: 936955 Page 1 of 11 Research Article Overnight Index Rate: Model,

More information

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives John Crosby Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Presentation at Baruch College, in New York, 16th November 2010

More information

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model:

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model: Fall 2003 Society of Actuaries **BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** 1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model: (i) ρ 1 = 05. (ii) ρ 2 = 01. Determine φ 2. (A) 0.2 (B) 0.1 (C) 0.4

More information

Introduction to Real Options

Introduction to Real Options IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Introduction to Real Options We introduce real options and discuss some of the issues and solution methods that arise when tackling

More information

Forecasting Life Expectancy in an International Context

Forecasting Life Expectancy in an International Context Forecasting Life Expectancy in an International Context Tiziana Torri 1 Introduction Many factors influencing mortality are not limited to their country of discovery - both germs and medical advances can

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS Teor Imov r.tamatem.statist. Theor. Probability and Math. Statist. Vip. 73, 005 No. 73, 006, Pages 109 115 S 0094-90000700685-0 Article electronically published on January 17, 007 UDC 519.1 VALUATION OF

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Constructing Two-Dimensional Mortality Improvement Scales for Canadian Pension Plans and Insurers: A Stochastic Modelling Approach

Constructing Two-Dimensional Mortality Improvement Scales for Canadian Pension Plans and Insurers: A Stochastic Modelling Approach Research paper Constructing Two-Dimensional Mortality Improvement Scales for Canadian Pension Plans and Insurers: A Stochastic Modelling Approach Prepared by: Johnny Siu-Hang Li Department of Statistics

More information

Occupation Pension for Public Employees in China: A New Approach with DB Underpin Pension Plan

Occupation Pension for Public Employees in China: A New Approach with DB Underpin Pension Plan Occupation Pension for Public Employees in China: A New Approach with DB Underpin Pension Plan Kai Chen Julie Shi Yi Yao Abstract The population aging has already become a major concern in China s pension

More information

Markowitz portfolio theory

Markowitz portfolio theory Markowitz portfolio theory Farhad Amu, Marcus Millegård February 9, 2009 1 Introduction Optimizing a portfolio is a major area in nance. The objective is to maximize the yield and simultaneously minimize

More information

Mortality Improvement Rates: Modelling and Parameter Uncertainty

Mortality Improvement Rates: Modelling and Parameter Uncertainty Mortality Improvement Rates: Modelling and Parameter Uncertainty Andrew Hunt a, Andrés M. Villegas b a Pacific Life Re, London, UK b School of Risk and Actuarial Studies and ARC Centre of Excellence in

More information

Longevity Seminar. Forward Mortality Rates. Presenter(s): Andrew Hunt. Sponsored by

Longevity Seminar. Forward Mortality Rates. Presenter(s): Andrew Hunt. Sponsored by Longevity Seminar Sponsored by Forward Mortality Rates Presenter(s): Andrew Hunt Forward mortality rates SOA Longevity Seminar Chicago, USA 23 February 2015 Andrew Hunt andrew.hunt.1@cass.city.ac.uk Agenda

More information

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 1. Default dynamics of a single obligor. 2. Model the dependence structure of defaults

More information

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION SILAS A. IHEDIOHA 1, BRIGHT O. OSU 2 1 Department of Mathematics, Plateau State University, Bokkos, P. M. B. 2012, Jos,

More information

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options IEOR E476: Financial Engineering: Discrete-Time Asset Pricing c 21 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options We consider some further applications of

More information

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management Basic Concepts and Techniques of Risk Management Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Understanding Patterns of Mortality Homogeneity and Heterogeneity. across Countries and their Role in Modelling Mortality Dynamics and

Understanding Patterns of Mortality Homogeneity and Heterogeneity. across Countries and their Role in Modelling Mortality Dynamics and Understanding Patterns of Mortality Homogeneity and Heterogeneity across Countries and their Role in Modelling Mortality Dynamics and Hedging Longevity Risk Sharon S. Yang Professor, Department of Finance,

More information

Rapid computation of prices and deltas of nth to default swaps in the Li Model

Rapid computation of prices and deltas of nth to default swaps in the Li Model Rapid computation of prices and deltas of nth to default swaps in the Li Model Mark Joshi, Dherminder Kainth QUARC RBS Group Risk Management Summary Basic description of an nth to default swap Introduction

More information

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin Spot and forward dynamic utilities and their associated pricing systems Thaleia Zariphopoulou UT, Austin 1 Joint work with Marek Musiela (BNP Paribas, London) References A valuation algorithm for indifference

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Understanding, Measuring & Managing Longevity Risk. Longevity Modelling Technical Paper

Understanding, Measuring & Managing Longevity Risk. Longevity Modelling Technical Paper Longevity Modelling Technical Paper Table of Contents Table of Figures and Tables... 4 1.0 Introduction... 6 1.1 The Importance of Understanding Longevity Risk... 6 1.2 Deterministic vs. Stochastic Models...

More information

Coale & Kisker approach

Coale & Kisker approach Coale & Kisker approach Often actuaries need to extrapolate mortality at old ages. Many authors impose q120 =1but the latter constraint is not compatible with forces of mortality; here, we impose µ110

More information

Longevity hedge effectiveness Cairns, Andrew John George; Dowd, Kevin; Blake, David; Coughlan, Guy D

Longevity hedge effectiveness Cairns, Andrew John George; Dowd, Kevin; Blake, David; Coughlan, Guy D Heriot-Watt University Heriot-Watt University Research Gateway Longevity hedge effectiveness Cairns, Andrew John George; Dowd, Kevin; Blake, David; Coughlan, Guy D Published in: Quantitative Finance DOI:

More information

Pricing and Risk Management of guarantees in unit-linked life insurance

Pricing and Risk Management of guarantees in unit-linked life insurance Pricing and Risk Management of guarantees in unit-linked life insurance Xavier Chenut Secura Belgian Re xavier.chenut@secura-re.com SÉPIA, PARIS, DECEMBER 12, 2007 Pricing and Risk Management of guarantees

More information

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES Proceedings of ALGORITMY 01 pp. 95 104 A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES BEÁTA STEHLÍKOVÁ AND ZUZANA ZÍKOVÁ Abstract. A convergence model of interest rates explains the evolution of the

More information

Basis Risk and Optimal longevity hedging framework for Insurance Company

Basis Risk and Optimal longevity hedging framework for Insurance Company Basis Risk and Optimal longevity hedging framework for Insurance Company Sharon S. Yang National Central University, Taiwan Hong-Chih Huang National Cheng-Chi University, Taiwan Jin-Kuo Jung Actuarial

More information

Mathematics in Finance

Mathematics in Finance Mathematics in Finance Steven E. Shreve Department of Mathematical Sciences Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 USA shreve@andrew.cmu.edu A Talk in the Series Probability in Science and Industry

More information

Subject CS2A Risk Modelling and Survival Analysis Core Principles

Subject CS2A Risk Modelling and Survival Analysis Core Principles ` Subject CS2A Risk Modelling and Survival Analysis Core Principles Syllabus for the 2019 exams 1 June 2018 Copyright in this Core Reading is the property of the Institute and Faculty of Actuaries who

More information

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products June 2016 2 Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products Jungmin Choi Department of Mathematics East Carolina University Abstract In this study, a hybrid

More information

Anticipating the new life market:

Anticipating the new life market: Anticipating the new life market: Dependence-free bounds for longevity-linked derivatives Hamza Hanbali Daniël Linders Jan Dhaene Fourteenth International Longevity Risk and Capital Markets Solutions Conference

More information

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II Dynamic Portfolio Choice II Dynamic Programming Leonid Kogan MIT, Sloan 15.450, Fall 2010 c Leonid Kogan ( MIT, Sloan ) Dynamic Portfolio Choice II 15.450, Fall 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 Introduction to Dynamic

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Modelling and management of mortality risk: a review

Modelling and management of mortality risk: a review Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 2008, 23, 79113 Original Article Modelling and management of mortality risk: a review ANDREW J. G. CAIRNS*, DAVID BLAKE$ and KEVIN DOWD% *Maxwell Institute for Mathematical

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments Valuing fixed cash flows Two basic rules: - Value additivity: Find the portfolio of zero-coupon bonds which replicates the cash flows of the security, the price

More information

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products by David Epstein (LINK:www.maths.ox.ac.uk/users/epstein) Mathematical Institute (LINK:www.maths.ox.ac.uk) Oxford Paul Wilmott (LINK:www.oxfordfinancial.co.uk/pw)

More information

A user-friendly approach to stochastic mortality modelling

A user-friendly approach to stochastic mortality modelling A user-friendly approach to stochastic mortality modelling Helena Aro Teemu Pennanen Department of Mathematics and Systems Analysis Helsinki University of Technology PL, 25 TKK [haro,teemu]@math.hut.fi

More information