Central Bankers Preferences and Attitudes Towards Uncertainty: Identification by Means of Asset Prices

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Central Bankers Preferences and Attitudes Towards Uncertainty: Identification by Means of Asset Prices"

Transcription

1 Central Bankers Preferences and Attitudes Towards Uncertainty: Identification by Means of Asset Prices Anna Orlik February 1, 2018 Abstract Can we identify preferences of a central bank and her attitude towards model uncertainty? Not if we restrict our attention to commonly used observable macro time series (no matter how many; in the context of monetary models, say, interest rates set by the central bank, inflation and unemployment (or growth)). Yes, if we make an informed use of asset prices. This paper constructs an observational equivalence result between standard optimal control problems based on rational expectations paradigm and robust control theory in which a decision maker is assumed to be faced with model uncertainty: According to the finding, the same optimal policy rule will be chosen by a central banker with rational expectations who fully trusts his model as well as by a robust policy maker who acknowledges model uncertainty and whose preferences are appropriately augmented to offset his fears about model misspecification. In an example application of our result, the introduction of model uncertainty is shown to bridge the difference between empirical values of central bank preferences for inflation Preliminary and incomplete. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve or the Federal Reserve System. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Anna.A.Orlik@frb.gov 1

2 stabilization and its theoretical values derived in a microfounded New Keynesian model as it is shown to be explicitly equivalent to augmenting central bank s preference towards less favorable inflation - output gap trade-off (higher λ). Since for every preferencefor-robustness characteristic θ we can identify such λ that leaves the interest rate rule unaltered we conclude that it is impossible to pin down at the same time the central bank s intrinsic preference for inflation stabilization and its attitude towards model uncertainty from the observations of interest rates, inflation and growth, the time series typically used in estimations of New Keynesian model. What breaks the equivalence and restores identification is the use of asset prices as two economies with identical macro outcomes are shown to be associated with different underlying asset prices depending on central banker s attitude towards model uncertainty. This result reopens the discussion on the desirability of targeting asset prices when setting monetary policy as pioneered by Bernanke and Gertler (2000). Keywords: robust control, model misspecification, New Keynesian monetary policy JEL Classification: E52, E58, D81 1 Introduction Can we identify preferences of a central bank and her attitude towards model uncertainty? Not if we restrict our attention to commonly used observable macro time series (no matter how many; in the context of monetary models, say, interest rates set by the central bank, inflation and unemployment (or growth)) and have a very precise knowledge about central bank s attitude towards model uncertainty. Yes, if we make use of asset prices. Within only the last decade the issue of robustness in economic policy design has attracted a large amount of attention in economic theory and in policy-making circles. Two seemingly contradicting approaches - standard optimal control based on rational expectations paradigm and robust control - guide the decision maker faced with uncertainty concerning his model in

3 designing reliable policy rules. If an agent is set in the rational expectations scenario she is bound to have either a perfect knowledge of the modelling environment or probability distributions over all possible realizations of uncertain variables. Then, being a Bayesian, she is able to reduce all the uncertainty to calculated risk. Therefore, Hansen and Sargent (2000) suggest that the rational expectations hypothesis imposes a communism of models : standard optimal control theory tells the policy maker how to derive optimal decisions when his model is the correct one. Contrary to the latter approach robust control is set on the assumption that the model constructed by the decision maker only approximates the true model. In this sense a robust policy making can be viewed as a willingness to manage model uncertainty with the aim of making a policy as reliable as possible given the information provided. To acknowledge the possibility of model misspecification Hansen and Sargent (2000) design the following framework. There exists a set of available perturbated models around the true (reference) model. Being uncertain about her model a robust policy maker tries to design a rule that performs best for the worst possible scenario, i.e. for the situation in which the prior distribution would be the worst distribution among all possible distributions. On top of that, the decision maker s preferences are augmented by adding the preference-for-robustness parameter so as to enhance risk sensitivity. Then, computing the robust decision rules comes down to solving for an equilibrium of a zero-sum game between the policy maker and the evil agent as a dynamic version of max-min game of Milnor (1954). The first applications of robust control techniques bring a fresh look at the matter of the response of monetary authority to increased uncertainty. Contrary to Brainard (1967) who showed that under parameter uncertainty it would be optimal for the central bank to act less vigorously than it would under perfect foresight robust policy design literature concludes in favor of a more aggressive response as compared with the rational expectations benchmark (Hansen and Sargent (2001, 2004), Giannoni (2002), Giordani and Söderlind (2003)). In light of the above results the question posed in this paper may seem intriguing. Is it possible that the observed optimal policy is the same for rational and robust decision makers? Can it 3

4 be therefore independent of the central banker s attitude towards model uncertainty? To our knowledge the issue of the equivalence between standard optimal and robust control problems has been taken up in two studies. Hansen, Sargent and Tallarini (1999) show that the risk-sensitive version of the permanent income model may be observationally equivalent (with respect to the same consumption and savings allocation rules) to the rational expectations benchmark provided that the agents discount factor is appropriately smaller than in the benchmark. As an explanation for this phenomenon they suggest a type of precautionary savings interpretation: activating a concern about robustness induces an increase in savings in the same way as increasing the time discount factor would. We ask the reader to bear in mind that the robust permanent income model is a pure forecasting model with no control and one state variable only. Kasa (1999) constructs an observational equivalence result for the linear optimal regulator problem and its robust counterpart for the case of a single-state and single-control model where the analytical solution can be found in a very straightforward way. He shows that for a given H decision rule there is a strictly convex function relating values of the H -norm to the variable summarizing the relative cost of state versus control variability. He concludes by stating that even though his result is highly specific to the scalar case it is generally impossible to obtain the same feedback matrix for a standard and robust control in a multivariate case. Our results are generalization of the above result. First, we prove that for every rational agent who solves a standard optimal control problem there exists another robust decision maker who is uncertain about his model and yet chooses exactly the same optimal policy rule as his rational counterpart. This result is used to show that the same interest rate will be set by the rational and robust central bankers provided that the latter agent has appropriately stronger preferences towards inflation stabilisation (i.e lower weight attached to output stabilisation and/or interest rate smoothing) than her rational counterpart. The mechanism operating behind this finding is the following. Ceteris paribus, in the context of optimal monetary policymaking, an increased model uncertainty calls for more aggressive behavior. The paper shows 4

5 that this tendency can be completely offset by an appropriate increase in the costs of variation the control variable. This result help explain the difference between empirical values of central bank preferences for inflation stabilization and its theoretical values derived in a microfounded New Keynesian model as it is shown to be explicitly equivalent to augmenting central bank s preference towards less favorable inflation - output gap trade-off (higher λ). Since for every preference-for-robustness characteristic θ we can identify such λ that leaves the interest rate rule unaltered we conclude that it is impossible to pin down at the same time the central bank s intrinsic preference for inflation stabilization and its attitude towards model uncertainty from the observations of interest rates, inflation and growth, the time series typically used in estimations of New Keynesian model. What breaks the equivalence and restores identification is the use of asset prices as two economies with identical macro outcomes are shown to be associated with different underlying asset prices depending on central banker s attitude towards model uncertainty, ceteris paribus. This result reopens the discussion on the desirability of targetting asset prices when setting monetary policy as pioneered by Bernanke and Gertler (2000). The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we discuss the robust control terminology and derive the general observational equivalence result. As an application of our proposition Section 3 sets up the monetary policy problem in New Keynesian framework with the rational and robust central banker respectively. We show how the use of fundamental asset prices restores identification of central bank s intrinsic preference towards inflation stabilization and allows us to identify, on top of that, central bank s preference for robustness. The last section concludes and outlines the direction of further research that the author intends to pursue. 5

6 2 Robust Control as an Optimal Control Problem In what follows we study the optimum and equilibrium properties of linear-quadratic rational and robust expectations models, respectively. Therefore, let x t be a vector of state variables of dimension n 1 and u t a vector of controllers of dimension k 1. Furthermore let Q [k k] be a symmetric positive definite matrix and R [n n] be some symmetric positive semidefinite matrix. Then the benchmark model we study is cast in the following form Let the one-time period loss be r (x t, u t ) = (x trx t + u tqu t ) max E 0 β t r (x t, u t ) {u t} t=0 t=0 s.t. x t+1 = Ax t + Bu t + Cɛ t+1 and x 0 given where 0 < β < 1 and ɛ t+1 is an i.i.d Gaussian vector process with N (0, I). Provided that some regularity conditions are fullfilled (see e.g. Hansen and Sargent (2006)) the state feedback rule is u t = F x t with F given as F = β(q + βbp B) 1 BP A Matrix P denotes the stabilizing solution of the corresponding algebraic matrix Riccati equation P = T (P ) or P = R + βa P A β 2 A P B(Q + βb P B) 1 BP A To acknowledge the possibility of model misspecification Hansen and Sargent surround the unreliable underlying model with the set of available perturbated data generated processes that lie within a certain neighborhood of the approximated model. The law of motion for the state variables becomes x t+1 = Ax t + Bu t + C (ɛ t+1 + w t+1 ) 6

7 where w t+1 is the term reflecting dynamic misspecification chosen by the evil agent. Thus, the model uncertainty is reflected by augmenting the conditional mean of the exogenous shock to unknown value w t+1 rather than 0. Notice that the conditional volatility of the shock process, as parametrized by C, remains unchanged 1. If the planner was a Bayesian one she would form the probability distributions over all possible realizations of uncertain variables and, hence, reduce all the uncertainty to calculated risk. But once we abstract from priors and rational expectations paradigm we need other tools at hand. First of all, since the robust agent s criterion function cannot involve, by definition, any well defined probabilistic statements Hansen and Sargent (following Gilboa and Schmeidler (1989)) suggest adoption of the dynamic version of the so called max-min approach. In this seetting a policy maker tries to design a rule that performs best for the worst possible scenario, i.e. for the situation in which the prior distribution would be the worst distribution among all possible distributions. A very useful way of setting up and solving the max-min problems is by means of a zero-sum two-agents game: decision maker versus a fictious evil agent. While nature chooses the model from the available set of models so as to maximize the planner s loss the latter agent chooses an optimal robust policy function. Since the evil agent is just a metaphor of policy maker s worst fears about model misspecification the two players share the same reference model given by { max min E 0 β ( ) } t r (x t, u t ) + θw t+1w t+1 {u t} t=0{w t} t=0 t=0 s.t. x t+1 = Ax t + Bu t + C (ɛ t+1 + w t+1 ) and x 0 given max {u t} t=0{w t} t=0 min E 0 β { } t r (x t, u t ) + θw t+1w t+1 t=0 s.t. x t+1 = Ax t + Bu t + C (ɛ t+1 + w t+1 ) and x 0 given 1 This assumption is set for illustration purposes. Hansen and Sargent (2006) show that the worst-case value of w t+1 remains unchanged if we allow the volatility matrix to varry in the approximating and perturbated models. So will we in the analysis which follows. 7

8 The penalty parameter θ θ, ) (sometimes called a preference-for-robustness parameter) restrains the minimizing choice of the w t+1 sequence since it is associated with a Lagrange multiplier on the evil agent s budget constraint E 0 β t w t+1w t+1 η 0 t=0 In the above formulation η 0 can be defined as the set of alternative models (misspecifications) considered by the decision maker. The standard rational expectations solution is achieved by setting η 0 = 0 or, equivalently, by letting θ. Since the evil agent s constraint is always binding in a linear-quadratic framework choosing the degree of robustness is crucial. For calibrating θ Hansen and Sargent suggest a detection error probability procedure using a likelihood ratio test. Zero robustness corresponds to a detection error probability of 50 percent. By analogy to model (??) its robust version (??) has a solution in form of a robust decision rule for control u t = F x t while w t+1 = Kx t is the formula for the worst-case shock where the optimal feedback coefficients are F = β(q + βbd(p )B) 1 BD(P )A K = 1 ( I 1 1 θ θ C P C) C P (A BF ) and where D(P ) = P + P C(θI C P C) 1 C P. One can easily verify that, as mentioned above, with θ we have K = 0 and we are back to the rational expectations state feedback policy rule. The main question posed in this paper is whether it is possible to derive the robust optimal decision rule which will be equivalent to the standard rational expectations (non-robust) optimal control policy rule for any θ θ, ). To show this we first present an alternative way of solving the game defined in (??). Consider the standard (non-robust) optimal regulator problem (w t+1 = K x t ) with the current period criterion x trx t + u tqu t βθ (K x t ) (K x t ) 8

9 subject to the law of motion x t+1 x t+1 = A  0 A x t x t + B 0 u t where  = CK and A = A BF + CK. Hansen and Sargent (2006) prove that for this problem the optimal value function is given by x 0 P P x 0 P P x 0 x 0 where P = P P and P = P P with P and P being a stabilizing solution of the Riccati equation for the standard and robust optimal control problems respectively. The direct implication of the above follows. Lemma 1 Every robust control problem is an augmented regulator problem as defined by Anderson et. al. (1996). Therefore, it can be broken down into two subproblems the first of which is a non-robust version of the decision maker s problem with the optimal policy rule u t = F x t. The second subproblem contains the part directly responsible for promoting robustness F such that F = ( Q + βb P B ) 1 ( βb P A ) F = ( Q + βb P B ) ( ) 1 βb P  + βb P A where u t = F x t is the control law for the robust problem in which F = F + F. Proof. See Hansen and Sargent (2006), p (in the version of 12 September 2006). We will use the above lemma to prove the core result of our paper as given by the proposition below. Fix all parameters except for (R, Q, θ). Then, for the robust planner with 0 < θ < θ < whose preferences (R 1, Q 1 ) satisfy ( Q1 + βb P 1 (R 1 ) B ) 1 [ ] βb P (R 1 ) (A BF1 + CK ) + βb P 1 (R 1 ) BF1 = F 2 9

10 Proposition 1 the optimal feedback control law F 1 is the same as chosen by the rational decision maker with θ = and preferences given by (R 2, Q 2 ), i.e.f 1 = F 2. Proof. By contradiction. Assume that there exists a robust policy maker whose preferences (R 1, Q 1 ) obey eq. (??) but, contrary to the proposition result, there exists other candidate stabilizing robust controller of her problem F c. In other words, there exists such F c F 2 that ( Q1 + βb P 1 (R 1 ) B ) 1 [ ] βb P (R 1 ) (A BFc + CK ) + βb P 1 (R 1 ) BFc = F 2 If F c is the stabilizing controller of the robust control problem then by the Lemma we know that we can break down the problem such that F c = F c + F c where F c = ( Q + βb P (R 1 ) B ) 1 ( βb P (R 1 ) A ) and F c = ( Q + βb P (R 1 ) B ) 1 ( βb P (R 1 ) Â + βb P (R1 ) A ). Hence, the consecutive rearrangements of the equation F c = ( Q + βb P (R 1 ) B ) 1 [ βb P (R 1 ) A + βb P (R 1 ) Â + βb P (R1 ) A ] yield ( Q 1 + βb P 1 (R 1 ) B ) 1 [ βb P (R 1 ) (A BF c + CK ) + βb P 1 (R 1 ) BF c ] = F c. But at the same time by eq. (??) it must be that F c = F 2. QED. The above proposition states that ex post it is possible to interpret the decision taken by a robust policy maker who is uncertain about her model as a decision of a rational agent who fully trusts her model provided that the preferences of a former agent are designed according to eq. (??). Thus, the robust policy rule is observationally equivalent to standard optimal (rational) rule. The direct implication of our finding is that it is impossible to pin down at the same time the inherit preferences of the robust planner, (R 1, Q 1 ), and her need for robustness as measured by θ. We do realize that our proposition establishes a certain existence type of an argument. It does not, however, provide any intuition behind the equivalence result. In particular, we would be interested in the character of the trade-off between (R 1, Q 1 ) and θ. Therefore, in what follows we solve analytically the rational expectations and robust versions of the monetary New Keynesian model. 10

11 3 Application: New Keynesian Model of Monetary Policy The model is set in the New Keynesian (NK) framework for monetary analysis. The popularity of the NK models is due to the fact that they summarize the behavior of optimizing agents (households and firms) in two equations: New Keynesian Philips curve (NKPC) which represents the supply side of the economy and forward-looking (expectational) IS equation that corresponds to the demand side. We refer to the standard model by Clarida, Galí and Gertler (1999) as given by π t = κx t + βe t π t+1 + u t x t = E t x t+1 ϕ (i t E t π t+1 ) + g t where π t, x t and i t are the log-deviations of inflation, output gap and interest rate from their steady-state values, respectively. The disturbance terms, u t (inflation/cost-push shock) and g t (demand shock) evolve according to the following AR(1) specification u t = ρu t 1 + ε u,t g t = µg t 1 + ε g,t with 0 < ρ < 1, 0 < µ < 1 and ε i,t iid(0, σ 2 i ) for i = u, g. The first of the equations of the model may be interpreted as the NKPC which represents the supply side of the economy, whereas the expectational (forward-looking) IS curve (eq. (??)) corresponds to the demand side. Since both equations have been derived from private agents optimization problems together they constitute the equilibrium conditions for a well-specified general equilibrium model. Unlike the traditional Philips curve, the NKPC implies that the correct driving force for an inflation process is a real marginal cost. Deviations in real marginal cost are, in turn, due to changes in output gap and technology. The two objectives of monetary policy which are commonly assumed are: low and stable average rate of inflation and stabilizing output around the full employment. Therefore, we 11

12 assume a policy objective function that minimizes a weighted (by λ) sum of the unconditional variances of the inflation rate and of the output gap 2 [ E t β [ s (π t+s ) 2 + λ (x t+s ) 2]] s=0 Later on we will consider a more general form of the central bank s loss function which accounts for the costs associated with adjusting the interest rate. 3.1 Discretionary Monetary Policy Scenario I. Rational Expectations Since under discretionary monetary stance the period-t decisions of the central banker are not binding in any other period we take expectations as given in the optimization and the decision problem becomes a single-period problem of minimizing the social welfare loss function subject to NKPC equation. In the RE scenario this is equivalent to minimizing (??) subject to eq. (??). { } min π 2 t + λx 2 t x t s.t. NKPC From the FOC we derive the condition relating output gap and inflation x t = κ λ π t. Substituting it into NKPC one obtains π t = βe t π t+1 κ2 λ π t + u t Using the educative guess for the solution to the above expectational difference equation, π t = Mu t, and knowing that with rational expectations the following relation holds: u t+1 = ρu t, 2 For discussions concerning this type of monetary policy objective function see e.g. Clarida Gali and Gertler (1999) or Walsh (2003). 12

13 ( ) 1. we solve for underlying coefficient to be equal to M = 1 βρ + κ2 λ Hence, the optimal deviations in inflation and output gap are given by π t = ) 1 (1 βρ + κ2 u t λ x t = κ λ (1 βρ) + κ u 2 t Finally, to obtain the implied instrument rule for rational expectations scenario substitute the results obtained above into expectational IS curve equation to get i RE t = λρ + (1 ρ) κϕ 1 λ (1 βρ) + κ u 2 t + ϕ 1 g t = P u t + ϕ 1 g t Scenario II. Robust Control The robust decision maker fears that her model is misspecified and seeks robustness. The dynamic misspecification v t+1 = [v 1,t+1, v 2,t+1 ] manifests itself in augmenting the law of motion for the exogenous disturbances u t+1 = ρu t + ε 1,t+1 + v 1,t+1 g t+1 = µg t + ε 2,t+1 + v 2,t+1 In principle, we allow for different level of uncertainty across the model equation. However, as shown in Orlik (2006a) the optimal misspecification of the expectational IS curve in the New Keynesian model with the absence of costs associated with adjusting the interest rate is always equal to zero. To see how the model is misspecified rewrite the NKPC equation as π t = κx t + βe t π t+1 + ρ 1 (u t+1 ε 1,t+1 v 1,t+1 ) As mentioned, to solve for the robust optimal policy under discretion we bring to life another player - evil nature - and construct the following zero-sum game. 13

14 Definition 1 An equilibrium of the Markov perfect multiplier game is a pair of strategies ( ) x t, v1,t+1 such that (a) Given v 1,t+1, x t minimizes the robust agent s expected loss function as given by π 2 t + λx 2 t θβ (v 1,t+1 ) 2 s.t. π t = κx t + βe t π t+1 + ρ 1 (u t+1 ε 1,t+1 v 1,t+1 ). (a) Given x t, v 1,t+1 maximizes the robust agent s expected loss function s.t. the above eq. From the FOCs we obtain the following optimality conditions relating inflation, output gap and misspecification to each other x t = κ λ π t v 1,t+1 = (βθρ) 1 π t Eq. (??) relates the worst-case misspecification to the deviations in inflation through the agent s preference for robustness θ. One salient fact about robust control problems should be discussed before we proceed to find the closed-form solution to our problem, namely a modified certainty equivalence principle. Hansen and Sargent show that despite the fact that the state-control feedback matrix is a function of the shock volatility the solution to the problem remains the same if we set ε i,t+1 = 0. We guess that the equilibrium misspecification chosen by the evil agent evolves optimally with the exogenous predetermined variable, i.e. v 1,t+1 = F u t. At the same time we guess that, as in the rational expectations case, inflation reacts to changes in exogenous state variable accordingly, π t = Nu t, such that N M, (1 ρ) βθρ.hence, using eq. (??) F = N (βθρ) 1.To verify our guess we first take advantage of the modified certainty equivalence property and ) rewrite the disturbance process as u t+1 = u t (ρ + N. Furthermore substituting our guess βθρ into eq. the following condition holds at equilibrium ) N 2 (θρ) 1 N (1 βρ + κ2 λ + 1 = 0 14

15 Notice that the solution to the above equation with θ is N = M if λ = λ, i.e we reproduce the rational expectations solution. However, if the policy maker mistrusts his model, i.e. θ θ, ), and λ λ than the above quadratic equation has the following positive real roots given by N = θρ 2 N < (1 ρ) βθρ. Since N θ will be given by θ= ) (1 βρ + κ2 λ ( ) 2 1 βρ + κ2 λ 4 (θρ) 1 < 0 then the lower bound on preference-for-robustness parameter The last thing is to compute the robust implied interest rate rule from the expectational IS curve as i t = 1 κ ϕ λ N ( ρ + N ) βθρ u t + 1 κ ϕ λ Nu t + N The next proposition shows the conditions under which i t = i RE t. ( ρ + N ) u t + ϕ 1 g t βθρ Proposition 2 Observational equivalence result for rational and robust policies under discretionary monetary stance. Fix all parameters, excluding (λ, θ). Then there exists such λ that the same optimal implied interest rate rule is pursued by a rational monetary authority (λ, θ = ) and by a robust decision maker characterized by (λ, θ ) and where λ < λ is given by λ = κ 2 N N 2 θρ N (1 βρ) + 1 where N is the positive root real (satisfying the stability condition) of the following polynomial [ ] N θ 2 ρ 2 βϕκ + N 2 (1 βρ) (1 ρ) + + βθρ βθρϕκ θρϕκ [ (1 ρ) (1 βρ) +N ρ 1 ] + 1 ρ ϕκ βθρϕκ ϕκ P = 0 Proof. See Appendix A. The graphical illustration of the above proposition follows. 15

16 Figure 1. Socially optimal inflation-output gap trade-off. The value of λ has been set up to 0.5. The figure shows that, ceteris paribus, the higher the model uncertainty (i.e. the lower the θ) the higher λ should be in order for the rational and robust policy rules to be observationally equivalent. This is due to the fact that the higher the model uncertainty the more aggressive the response of the robust planner will be. This effect will be totally offset in case of the central banker who attaches an appropriately higher weight to output gap deviations. Notice that with θ all the model uncertainty disappears and λ λ = Optimal Unrestricted Commitment In what follows we present the situation in which the decision maker credibly commits to optimal policy rule Scenario I. Rational Expectations As before we start our analysis of misspecified monetary dynamics with commitment policy by solving for the rational expectations equilibrium. We assume an unrestricted commitment mechanism in the sense that we don t apply any specific form of it as it would be the case with, e.g., the Taylor-type rules. In this framework the policymaker s objective is to choose sequences of i t+i, π t+i and x t+i to minimize: [ 1 E t β i 2 (π t+i) ] 2 λ (x t+i) 2 i=0 κ 1,t+i (π t+i βπ t+i+1 κx t+i u t+i ) κ 2,t+i (x t+i x t+i+1 ϕπ t+i+1 + ϕi t+i g t ) The FOC with respect to i t is given by ϕe t (κ 2,t+i ) = 0 for i 0 16

17 This condition reflects the fact that the expectational IS curve equation imposes no real constraint on the central bank as long as there are no restrictions or costs associated with adjusting the nominal interest rate. Taking it into account, the further FOCs take the following form π t + κ 1,t = 0 E t (π t+i + κ 1,t+i κ 1,t+i 1 ) = 0 for i > 0 E t (λx t+i κκ 1,t+i ) = 0 for i > 0 The fully optimal commitment policy (see Walsh (2003)) does not honour any past commitment. If we set the Lagrangian multipliers the problem becomes equivalent to discretionary solution Scenario II. Robust Control with Commitment In what follows we assume that also the evil agent has access to a certain commitment mechanism. This assumption is very intuitive considering the fact that the evil agent is just a technical metaphor used for expressing the policymaker s fears about model misspecification. From this perspective the evil agent should reoptimize only once the central banker does so. Hence, the only difference with respect to the definition of the robust game presented in the previous section is in the definition of the strategies: at time zero the evil agent chooses and credibly commits to the sequence of perturbations {v t } t=0 the optimal policy forever 3. while the planner commits to implementing Definition 2 An equilibrium of the robust multiplier game in sequences is a pair of sequences {v t } t=0 and {x t } t=0 such that (a) Given {vt } t=0, {x t } t=0 minimizes the robust agent s expected loss function as given by [ 1 β i 2 (π t+i) λ (x t+i) 2 1 ] 2 βθ (v 1,t+i+1) 2 Et R i=0 3 Giordani and Söderlind (2004) show that if the evil agent commits to a non-stationary process of misspecification the policy maker s loss function becomes unbounded. 17

18 subject to NKPC and IS curve and where u t+i and g t+i are misspecified according to eq. u t+i+1 = ρu t+i + ε 1,t+i+1 + v 1,t+i+1 g t+i+1 = µg t+i + ε 2,t+i+1 + v 2,t+i+1 (b) Given {x t } t=0, {v t } t=0 above. maximizes the robust agent s expected loss function as given the Hence, the Lagrangian for the problem is given by maxmin v x E R t {[ 1 β i 2 (π t+i) ] 2 λ (x t+i) 2 1 } 2 βθ (v 1,t+i+1) 2 + i=0 +ψ 1,t+i (π t+i βπ t+i+1 κx t+i u t+i ) + +ψ 2,t+i (x t+i x t+i+1 ϕπ t+i+1 + ϕi t+i g t ) + +ψ 3,t+i (γg t+i + ɛ g,t+i+1 g t+i+1 ) + +ψ 4,t+i (ρu t+i + ɛ u,t+i+1 + v t+i+1 u t+i+1 ) (1) As in the RE scenario the FOC for interest rate again reflects the no real constraint property, since E t ( ψ2,t+i ) = 0 for i 0. Therefore, the remaining FOCs are given by π t + ψ 1,t = 0 (2) E R t ( πt+i + ψ 1,t+i ψ 1,t+i 1 ) = 0 for i 0 (3) E t ( λxt+i κψ 1,t+i ) = 0 (4) ψ 1,t+i + ρψ 4,t+i 1 β ψ 4,t+i 1 = 0 (5) βθv 1,t+i+1 + ψ 4,t+i = 0 (6) Again, assume that also evil agent ignores the past commitments. As before the robust solution with commitment follows as in the discretionary case. 18

19 3.3 General Case with Costs of Adjusting the Nominal Interest Rate Scenario I. Rational Expectations [ 1 E t β i 2 (π t+i) λ (x t+i) ] 2 λ i (i t+i ) 2 i=0 +κ 1,t+i (π t+i βπ t+i+1 κx t+i u t+i ) + +κ 2,t+i (x t+i x t+i+1 ϕπ t+i+1 + ϕi t+i g t ) The FOCs are E t (π t+i + κ 1,t+i κ 1,t+i 1 = 0 for i 0 E t (λx t+i κκ 1,t+i + κ 2,t+i 1 ) β κ 2,t+i 1 = 0 for i 0 The additional condition governing the costs of adjusting the nominal interest rate is given by E t (λ i i t+i + ϕκ 2,t+i ) = 0 for i 0 We combine the first-order conditions under the assumption of fully optimal commitment policy. Hence, λx t + κπ t λ i ϕ i t = 0 (7) To generate the candidate equilibrium guess that the solution to the problem takes the form: π t = Su t + Kg t. Details of the algorithm for computing the response coefficients S and K can be found in the appendix. Then, it can be shown that the implied interest rate rule takes the following form: i t = ϕ λ i (Au t + Bg t ) where A = λ (S βρs 1) + κs and B = κ λ (K βkγ) + κk. κ 19

20 3.3.2 Scenario II. Robust Control [ 1 maxminet R β (π i 2 t+i) 2 + 1λ (x 2 t+i) 2 + 1λ 2 i (i t+i ) 2] v i 1βθ (v 2 1,t+i+1) 2 1βθ (v 2 2,t+i+1) 2 i=0 +µ 1,t+i (π t+i βπ t+i+1 κx t+i u t+i ) + +µ 2,t+i (x t+i x t+i+1 ϕπ t+i+1 + ϕi t+i g t ) + +µ 3,t+i (ρu t+i + ɛ u,t+i+1 + v 1,t+i+1 u t+i+1 ) + +µ 4,t+i (γg t+i + ɛ g,t+i+1 + v 2,t+i+1 g t+i+1 ) + for i 0 E R t ( ) Et R πt+i + µ 1,t+i µ 1,t+i 1 = 0 ( λx t+i κµ 1,t+i + µ 2,t+i 1 ) β µ 2,t+i 1 = 0 E R t ( λi i t+i + ϕµ 2,t+i ) = 0 Optimal commitment policy is characterized by µ 1,t+i + ρµ 3,t+i + 1 β µ 3,t+i 1 = 0 µ 2,t+i + γµ 4,t+i + 1 β µ 4,t+i 1 = 0 θv 1,t+i+1 + µ 3,t+i = 0 θv 2,t+i+1 + µ 4,t+i = 0 λx t + κπ t λ i ϕ i t = 0 (8) v 1,t+1 = 1 βθρ π t (9) v 2,t+1 = λ i γβθϕ i t (10) This time we generate our candidate solutions as π t = Cu t + Dg t. Furthermore guess that v 1,t+1 = F 1 u t + F 2 g t and v 2,t+1 = F 3 u t + F 4 g t. Then, the exogenous state variables evolution will be determined as u t+1 = (ρ + F 1 ) u t + F 2 g t and g t+1 = (γ + F 4 ) g t + F 3 u t. 20

21 4 Conclusion TBC Appendix A Observational equivalence result for discretionary monetary stance Proposition 1 Observational equivalence result for rational and robust policies under discretionary monetary stance. Fix all parameters, excluding (λ, θ). Then there exists such λ that the same optimal implied interest rate rule is pursued by a rational monetary authority (λ, θ = ) and by a robust decision maker characterized by (λ, θ ) and where λ < λ is given by N 2 θρ κ 2 N = λ N (1 βρ) + 1 where N is the positive root real of the following third-degree polynomial [ ] N θ 2 ρ 2 βϕκ +N 2 (1 βρ) (1 ρ) + + +N βθρ βθρϕκ θρϕκ and P = λρ+(1 ρ)κϕ 1 λ(1 βρ)+κ 2. [ (1 ρ) (1 βρ) ρ 1 ϕκ βθρϕκ ] + 1 ρ ϕκ P = 0 Proof. Rewrite consecutively the latter equation N 2 βθρ N [ ] N 2 N (1 βρ) [ ] N 2 N (1 βρ) Nρ ρ [ N 2 βθρϕκ θρ ϕκ θρ ϕκ θρ N 2 ( 1 1 ) ( κ 1 κ βθρ ϕ λ + N ϕ λ + ρ ρ 1 κ ϕ λ 1 ( κ ϕ λ N ρ + N ) u t + 1 ( κ βθρ ϕ λ Nu t + N ρ + N βθρ to obtain i t = i RE t. QED. ] N (1 βρ) + 1 P = ) P = ) u t + ϕ 1 g t = 21

22 B General Case with Costs of Adjustment of the Interest Rate TBC 22

23 References [1] Anderson E., Hansen L. P., McGrattan E. R., Sargent T. J. (1996). Mechanics of Forming and Estimating Dynamic Linear Economies. in Amman H., Kendrick D. A., Rust J. (eds.), Handbook of Computational Economics, vol.1 [2] Bernanke B., Gertler M. (2000). Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility, NBER working paper no 7559 [3] Blanchard O. J., Kahn C. M., 1980, The Solution of Linear Difference Models Under Rational Expectations, Econometrica, 48(5), [4] Brainard W., 1967, Uncertainty and Effectiveness of Policy, American Economic Review, 57(2), pp [5] Giannoni M. P.,, 2002, Does Model Uncertainty Justify Caution? Robust Optimal Monetary Policy in a Forward Looking Model, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 6(1), pp [6] Giordani P., Söderlind P., 2003, Inflation Forecast Uncertainty, European Economic Review, vol. 47(6), pp [7] Hansen L. P., Sargent T. J., 2000, Wanting Robustness in Macroeconomics, manuscript, University of Chicago, Stanford University and Hoover Institution [8] Hansen L. P., Sargent T., 2001, Acknowledging Misspecification in Macroeconomic Theory, Review of Economic Dynamics, 4, pp [9] Hansen L. P., Sargent T. J, Tallarini T. J., 1999, Robust Permanent Income and Pricing, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 66(4), pp [10] Hansen L. P., Sargent T. J., 2006, [11] Kasa K., 1999, An observational equivalence among H - control policies, Economic Letters, 64, pp [12] Milnor J., 1954, Games Against Nature, in Decission Processes, pp

24 [13] Leitemo K., Söderström U., 2004, Robust Monetary Policy in New-Keynesian framework [14] Walsh C. E., 2003, Monetary Theory and Policy, second edition, The MIT Press [15] Woodford M.,2001, Inflation Stabilization and Welfare, NBER Working Paper No

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1 Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1 Carl E. Walsh UC Santa Cruz August 18-22, 2014 1 c Carl E. Walsh, 2014. Carl E. Walsh (UC Santa Cruz) Gerzensee Study Center August 18-22, 2014 1 / 38 Uncertainty

More information

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312/702 Basic New Keynesian Model of Transmission Can be derived from primitives:

More information

Robust Discretionary Monetary Policy under Cost- Push Shock Uncertainty of Iran s Economy

Robust Discretionary Monetary Policy under Cost- Push Shock Uncertainty of Iran s Economy Iran. Econ. Rev. Vol. 22, No. 2, 218. pp. 53-526 Robust Discretionary Monetary Policy under Cost- Push Shock Uncertainty of Iran s Economy Fatemeh Labafi Feriz 1, Saeed Samadi *2 Khadijeh Nasrullahi 3,

More information

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont) Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont) 1 New Keynesian Model Demand is an Euler equation x t = E t x t+1 ( ) 1 σ (i t E t π t+1 ) + u t Supply is New Keynesian Phillips Curve π

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates Bank of Japan Working Paper Series Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates Tomohiro Sugo * sugo@troi.cc.rochester.edu Yuki Teranishi ** yuuki.teranishi

More information

Parameter Uncertainty and Non-Linear Monetary Policy Rules

Parameter Uncertainty and Non-Linear Monetary Policy Rules Parameter Uncertainty and Non-Linear Monetary Policy Rules Peter Tillmann 1 University of Bonn February 26, 2008 Abstract: Empirical evidence suggests that the instrument rule describing the interest rate

More information

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero Kai Leitemo The Norwegian School of Management (BI) and Bank of Finland March 2006 Abstract This paper shows that in an economy with inflation persistence,

More information

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound Robert G. King Boston University and NBER 1. Introduction What should the monetary authority do when prices are

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MONETARY STABILIZATION POLICY. Michael Woodford. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MONETARY STABILIZATION POLICY. Michael Woodford. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MONETARY STABILIZATION POLICY Michael Woodford Working Paper 16095 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16095 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank

Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank Kai Leitemo The Norwegian School of Management BI and Norges Bank March 2003 Abstract Delegating monetary policy to a

More information

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Jinill Kim, Korea University Sunghyun Kim, Sungkyunkwan University March 015 Abstract This paper provides two illustrative examples

More information

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II ECON 815 A Basic New Keynesian Model II Winter 2015 Queen s University ECON 815 1 Unemployment vs. Inflation 12 10 Unemployment 8 6 4 2 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Core Inflation 14 12 10 Unemployment

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999)

Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999) Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999) Satya P. Das @ NIPFP Satya P. Das (@ NIPFP) Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999) 1 / 14 1 Model Structure 2 Time Inconsistency and Commitment 3 Discretion Satya

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

The science of monetary policy

The science of monetary policy Macroeconomic dynamics PhD School of Economics, Lectures 2018/19 The science of monetary policy Giovanni Di Bartolomeo giovanni.dibartolomeo@uniroma1.it Doctoral School of Economics Sapienza University

More information

Optimal Interest-Rate Rules: I. General Theory

Optimal Interest-Rate Rules: I. General Theory Optimal Interest-Rate Rules: I. General Theory Marc P. Giannoni Columbia University Michael Woodford Princeton University September 9, 2002 Abstract This paper proposes a general method for deriving an

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016 BOOK REVIEW: Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian... 167 UDK: 338.23:336.74 DOI: 10.1515/jcbtp-2017-0009 Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice,

More information

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve by George Alogoskoufis* March 2016 Abstract This paper puts forward an alternative new Keynesian

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy with a Preference for Robustness

Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy with a Preference for Robustness Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy with a Preference for Robustness Richard Dennis Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kai Leitemo Norwegian School of Management (BI) Ulf Söderström Bocconi University

More information

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Michael Woodford Columbia University New Approaches to Fiscal Policy FRB Atlanta, January 8-9, 2010 Woodford (Columbia) Analytics of Multiplier

More information

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules WILLIAM A. BRANCH TROY DAVIG BRUCE MCGOUGH Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules This paper examines the implications of forward- and backward-looking monetary policy

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model Jordi Gali Monetary Policy, inflation, and the business cycle Lian Allub 15/12/2009 In The Classical Monetary economy we have perfect competition and fully flexible prices in all markets. Here there is

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Price-level or Inflation-targeting under Model Uncertainty

Price-level or Inflation-targeting under Model Uncertainty Price-level or Inflation-targeting under Model Uncertainty Gino Cateau Bank of Canada, Research Department. November 5, 27 Abstract The purpose of this paper is to make a quantitative contribution to the

More information

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18 Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model Satya P. Das @ NIPFP Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18 1 CGG (2001) 2 CGG (2002)

More information

The New Keynesian Model

The New Keynesian Model The New Keynesian Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 1 / 37 Research strategy policy as systematic and predictable...the central bank s stabilization

More information

Monetary policy regime formalization: instrumental rules

Monetary policy regime formalization: instrumental rules Monetary policy regime formalization: instrumental rules PhD program in economics 2009/10 University of Rome La Sapienza Course in monetary policy (with G. Ciccarone) University of Teramo The monetary

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) MACRO-LINKAGES, OIL PRICES AND DEFLATION WORKSHOP JANUARY 6 9, 2009 Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University) Credit Frictions and

More information

Thom Thurston Queens College and The Graduate Center, CUNY

Thom Thurston Queens College and The Graduate Center, CUNY How the Taylor Rule works in the Baseline New Keynesian Model Thom Thurston Queens College and The Graduate Center, CUNY Revised July 2012 Abstract This paper shows how to derive a Taylor rule for the

More information

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function Eurilton Araújo Insper Working Paper WPE: 23/2008 Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução

More information

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting) Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development H. Uzawa Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting) In this paper, we prove in terms of the prototype model of

More information

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability Hilde C. Bjørnland Vegard H. Larsen Centre for Applied Macro- and Petroleum Economics (CAMP) BI Norwegian Business School CFE-ERCIM December 07, 2014 Bjørnland and Larsen

More information

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods. Introduction In ECON 50, we discussed the structure of two-period dynamic general equilibrium models, some solution methods, and their

More information

EC3115 Monetary Economics

EC3115 Monetary Economics EC3115 :: L.12 : Time inconsistency and inflation bias Almaty, KZ :: 20 January 2016 EC3115 Monetary Economics Lecture 12: Time inconsistency and inflation bias Anuar D. Ushbayev International School of

More information

Monetary Policy under Behavioral Expectations: Theory and Experiment

Monetary Policy under Behavioral Expectations: Theory and Experiment Monetary Policy under Behavioral Expectations: Theory and Experiment Matthias Weber (joint work with Cars Hommes and Domenico Massaro) Bank of Lithuania & Vilnius University January 5, 2018 Disclaimer:

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014 Macroeconomics Basic New Keynesian Model Nicola Viegi April 29, 2014 The Problem I Short run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks I I I persistent e ects on real variables slow adjustment of aggregate price

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Information Processing and Limited Liability Information Processing and Limited Liability Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University January 2012 Abstract Decision-makers often face limited liability

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44 TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Marija Vukotić Banque de France NBS, April 27, 2012 NBS, April 27, 2012 1 / 44 Motivation 1 Well Known Facts about the

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

Monetary Policy Frameworks and the Effective Lower Bound on Interest Rates

Monetary Policy Frameworks and the Effective Lower Bound on Interest Rates Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Monetary Policy Frameworks and the Effective Lower Bound on Interest Rates Thomas Mertens John C. Williams Staff Report No. 877 January 2019 This paper presents

More information

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results Volume 35, Issue 4 Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results Richard T Froyen University of North Carolina Alfred V Guender University of Canterbury Abstract

More information

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance (J.Gali et al., JME 2003) Miguel Angel Alcobendas, Laura Desplans, Dong Hee Joe March 5, 2010 M.A.Alcobendas, L. Desplans, D.H.Joe

More information

Inflation Target Uncertainty and Monetary Policy

Inflation Target Uncertainty and Monetary Policy Inflation Target Uncertainty and Monetary Policy Job Market Paper Yevgeniy Teryoshin Stanford University http://www.stanford.edu/~yteryosh This version: January 4, 208 Latest version: http://www.stanford.edu/~yteryosh/yevgeniy_teryoshin_jmp.pdf

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Ricardo Reyes-Heroles Federal Reserve Board Gabriel Tenorio The Boston Consulting Group IEA World Congress 2017 Mexico City, Mexico June 20, 2017

More information

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities Wojciech Kopczuk Address: Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, #997-1873 East Mall, Vancouver BC V6T1Z1, Canada and NBER

More information

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl) University of California, Davis Date: September 1, 2011 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Macroeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Directions: Answer all

More information

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model Burkhard Heer Alfred Maussner CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 3311 CATEGORY 12: EMPIRICAL AND THEORETICAL METHODS DECEMBER 2010 An electronic

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Price level targeting versus inflation targeting in a forward looking model

Price level targeting versus inflation targeting in a forward looking model Price level targeting versus inflation targeting in a forward looking model David Vestin IIES, Stockholm University First draft: June 1999 This draft: January 2000 Preliminary - Comments Welcome Abstract

More information

Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy

Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy Eric M. Leeper & Xuan Zhou Indiana University 5 August 2013 KDI Journal of Economic Policy Conference Policy Institution Arrangements Advanced economies

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

Overshooting Meets Inflation Targeting. José De Gregorio and Eric Parrado. Central Bank of Chile

Overshooting Meets Inflation Targeting. José De Gregorio and Eric Parrado. Central Bank of Chile Overshooting Meets Inflation Targeting José De Gregorio and Eric Parrado Central Bank of Chile October 2, 25 Preliminary and Incomplete When deciding on writing a paper to honor Rudi Dornbusch we were

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 5 - Money Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 February A brief history of money in macro 1. 1. Hume: money has a wealth effect more money increase in aggregate demand Y 2. Friedman

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh * Journal of Monetary Economics Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for monetary policy in Japan Carl E. Walsh * Department of Economics, University of California,

More information

Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment

Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment Ragna Alstadheim Norges Bank 1. Introduction The topic of Coenen and Warne (this issue) is of

More information

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model R. Barrell S.G.Hall 3 And I. Hurst Abstract This paper argues that the dominant practise of evaluating the properties

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

Learning about Monetary Policy Rules when the Cost Channel Matters

Learning about Monetary Policy Rules when the Cost Channel Matters Learning about Monetary Policy Rules when the Cost Channel Matters Luis-Gonzalo Llosa,a, Vicente Tuesta c,b a Economics Department, University of California, Los Angeles, CA, USA. b Emerging Markets Research,

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Carl E. Walsh March 8, 017 Contents 1 Policy Coordination 1 1.1 The Basic Model..................................... 1. Equilibrium with Coordination.............................

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Escaping the Great Recession 1

Escaping the Great Recession 1 Escaping the Great Recession 1 Francesco Bianchi Duke University Leonardo Melosi FRB Chicago ECB workshop on Non-Standard Monetary Policy Measures 1 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Growth model with Epstein-Zin preferences and stochastic volatility

Growth model with Epstein-Zin preferences and stochastic volatility Growth model with Epstein-Zin preferences and stochastic volatility Håkon Tretvoll July 8, 2011 1 Introduction This document goes through a method of solving a growth model with Epstein-Zin preferences

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy

Optimal Monetary Policy Optimal Monetary Policy Graduate Macro II, Spring 200 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Here I consider how a welfare-maximizing central bank can and should implement monetary policy in the standard

More information

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Time-Series Time-series is a sequence fx 1, x 2,..., x T g or fx t g, t = 1,..., T, where t is an index denoting

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Changes in the Inflation Target and the Comovement between Inflation and the Nominal Interest Rate

Changes in the Inflation Target and the Comovement between Inflation and the Nominal Interest Rate Economics Working Paper Series 2018-2 Changes in the Inflation Target and the Comovement between Inflation and the Nominal Interest Rate Yunjong Eo and Denny Lie July 2018 Changes in the Inflation Target

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

3 Optimal Inflation-Targeting Rules

3 Optimal Inflation-Targeting Rules 3 Optimal Inflation-Targeting Rules Marc P. Giannoni and Michael Woodford Citation: Giannoni Marc P., and Michael Woodford (2005), Optimal Inflation Targeting Rules, in Ben S. Bernanke and Michael Woodford,

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

Monetary Policy and Model Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Monetary Policy and Model Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy Monetary Policy and Model Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy Richard Dennis Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kai Leitemo Norwegian School of Management BI Ulf Söderström Bocconi

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Conditional Versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Conditional Versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Comput Econ (018) 51:719 730 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-016-9635-7 Conditional Versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Jinill Kim 1 Sunghyun Kim Accepted: 11 November 016 /

More information