Reverse return-volatility asymmetry, and short sale constraints: Evidence from the Chinese markets

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Reverse return-volatility asymmetry, and short sale constraints: Evidence from the Chinese markets"

Transcription

1 Reverse return-volatility asymmetry, and short sale constraints: Evidence from the Chinese markets Liang Wu The School of Economics, Sichuan University, Chengdu,China Abstract Reverse return-volatility asymmetry (i.e. positive returns induce higher price volatilities than negative ones) is documented in the Chinese markets in contrast to the widely accepted negative return-volatility correlation. Using a theoretic model with short sale and borrowing constraints, we show that the asymmetry response of investors to news is one cause of the reverse return-volatility asymmetry. Lifting of short sale constraints can decrease the return-volatility correlation while margin trading increases the correlation. In the context of slow adoption of margin trading and security lending policy, we conduct empirical analysis and verify that the lifting of short sale constraints leads to significantly less reverse return-volatility asymmetry. Keywords: reverse return-volatility asymmetry, anti-leverage, short sale constraints, margin trading 1. Introduction Risk and return are fundamental concepts in finance. For example, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) provides for an explicit relationship between risk and return by saying that the expected return of an asset is positively related to its undiversified risk. Accordingly, investors taking on additional risks should be compensated with higher expected returns. If the variance and covariance are time-varying, the dynamic nature between risk and volatility can be complex. Theories such as leverage effect (Christie (1982)) and volatility-feeback theory (Pindyck (1983); Campbell address: liangwu@scu.edu.cn (Liang Wu) Preprint submitted to EFMA Annual Meeting 2017 January 15, 2017

2 and Hentschel (1992)) are developed to explain the asymmetric volatility property of individual stock returns in the United States (U.S.) which says that the stock return volatility is negatively correlated with stock returns (see e.g., Bekaert and Wu (2000)). The leverage effect hypothesis suggests that a drop in the value of a stock increases the debt-to-equity ratio, this in turn makes the stock riskier and causes future volatility to rise. Volatility-feedback theory suggests that a volatility increase raises the expected return, leading to an immediate stock price decline after investors revalue the equity. The causalities of the two theories are different: the leverage effect suggests that return shocks lead to the change of future volatility, while volatility-feedback suggests that current or future returns are caused by current or lagged volatility shocks. Since the two effects could happen at intra-day sub-timescales, the observation of contemporaneous return-volatility correlation at a daily level could thus be caused by either effect or by both effects regardless of any differences in order of occurrence of return shocks and volatility shocks. Negative correlation of return and volatility has been observed in most of the financial markets in developed countries (Bollerslev et al. (2008) (U.S. stock markets), Qiu et al. (2006) (German stock markets), Bekaert and Wu (2000) (Japanese stock markets) and Lee (2012) (Korea stock markets)). Other researchers such as Harrison and Zhang (1999); Ghysels et al. (2005); Ludvigson and Ng (2007) find a positive relation. Nelson (1991) and Glosten et al. (1993) argue that either a positive or a negative relationship is possible. While some researchers are discussing whether the correlation of return and volatility is negative or which theory seems to offer the best explanations, other studies focusing upon the Chinese markets reveals the existence of positive return-volatility correlation. Based upon daily raw returns from four market indices of the Shanghai and Shenzhen markets (taking from May, 1992 to August, 1996 for two composite indices and from October, 1992 to August, 1996 for two B-share indices), Yeh and Lee (2001) find that good news has a larger impact upon future volatility than bad news. Menggen (2007) examines the log returns of both Shanghai and Shenzhen Composite Index. He finds a positive and statistically significant risk-return relationship for the daily returns of stock indices composed of stocks traded on the Shenzhen Stock Exchange while the relationship is negative but insignificant for those referencing the Shanghai Stock Exchange. Qiu et al. (2006) discover the positive return-volatility correlation in Chinese stock indices using both daily and 5-min data of Chinese stock indices, compared with the neg- 2

3 ative correlation founded on German DAX Index. They refer to this as the anti-leverage effect, and their result is echoed by Shen and Zheng (2009), who use a retarded volatility model and further argue that leverage effect and the anti-leverage effect are independent of the probability distribution of returns and long-range time correlation of volatilities. Zheng et al. (2014) review this effect together with other features of the Chinese stock markets including the volatility auto-correlation, the return-volatility correlation and the spatial structure at the firm level. Wan et al. (2014) confirm the positive correlation using 5-minute data of 10 individual stocks with high capitalization and high liquidity selected from different industries in the Hushen 300 Index and finds a positive return-volatility correlation for most of the individual stocks in the sample. Possible explanations of the reverse return-volatility asymmetry effect in the Chinese markets given by previous researchers are based on indigenous trading mechanisms. Wan et al. (2014) postulate that the Chinese markets protect investors against daily loss by limiting a stock s daily range to ±10% of the previous day s closing price, which reduces the risk averse of investors. Few or even no dividends cut down their motivations for value investment. The majority of the participants are retail investors who behave like shortterm speculators. They surge for a price rising trend. Klößner et al. (2012) develop a statistical approach to detect intra-day overreaction. They find that Chinese investors over-react to good news with greater emphasis than to bad news, when they are compared with investors in the U.S. and German markets who over-react with greater emphasis to bad news than to good news. However, among all of the empirical studies, few notice the linkage between short sale constraints and the anti-leverage effect observed in Chinese markets. It is worth noting that it is difficult to directly examine the effect of short sales on return-volatility correlation, since short sales have long been practiced in developed markets. To this end, many researchers use proxies such as relative short interest, breadth of ownership, institutional ownership for the level of short sale constraints (see Figlewski (1981); Chen et al. (2002); Nagel (2005)). The 2008 financial crisis, during which short sales were banned to different extents among different countries, provides researchers with the opportunity to test the effects of short sale constraints on pricing efficiency and market stability. Nevertheless, the credence and stability of their results are dampened by the brief periods of the bans and the limited number of affected stocks (e.g. the short ban lasted for only 3 weeks in the U.S.). In this respect, the Chinese stock market is ideal for 3

4 empirical testing: the launches of margin financing and security lending for selected stocks naturally divides the time horizon into two time periods (i.e., before and after the stocks can be sold short). The fact that stocks can be added to the short sale list only if they meet certain requirements provides us with a treatment group as well as a control group composed of shortable and non-shortable stocks, respectively. Based on the margin financing and security lending policy, two previous papers (Chang et al. (2014),Zhao et al. (2014)) studying the effect of short sales focus mainly on market efficiency. The authors find that after the ban is lifted, price efficiency increases and stock return volatility decreases. The first motive of this paper is to test whether return-volatility correlation are positive for daily firm-level returns in the Chinese markets. Most previous studies of the Chinese markets focus on stock indices (see Yeh and Lee (2001); Menggen (2007); Qiu et al. (2006)). One contribution of our study to the literature is that we have a thorough test of the statistics based on raw returns, excess returns and normalized returns of individual stocks. The excess returns retain the idiosyncratic aspects of each stock while the market aspect is removed. The normalized excess returns, on the other hand, remove the effect of time-varying volatility and possible leverage (or anti-leverage) effect through dividing the excess returns by the conditional volatility obtained from the EGARCH model. The second contribution of our study is that we have empirically shown that short sale constraints are responsible for the existence of reverse returnvolatility asymmetry in the Chinese markets, based on a panel regression on a wide range of daily return data covering both shortable and non-shortable stocks spanning from 2006 to 2014 (4 years before and 4 years after the first launch of security lending policy). Some researchers believe that these statistical anomalies are caused by the fact that investors in the Chinese markets tend to be speculators and rush for a price rising (see e.g.qiu et al. (2006); Wan et al. (2014)). It is unlikely that Chinese investors are significantly different from other investors throughout the world. There should be some mechanisms built into the markets which offer the Chinese market investors the motivation to behave differently. In this paper, we present evidence that one possible mechanism to explain the statistical anomalies resides within the policy of the short sale constraints. When the short sales are constrained, investors tend to rush for a price rising hoping to make profits since they can only buy low and sell high. As a result, we can observe that the market reacts more to a positive signal than to a negative signal, and hence the presence 4

5 of reverse return-volatility asymmetry. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: part 2 gives a theoretic discussion of the effect of short sale constraints on return-volatility correlation especially when margin trading is adopted simultaneously; part 3 gives a brief description of the data set; part 4 presents the data processing method and empirical results; part 4 is the conclusion and discussion. 2. Model In this section, we build a model to study the impact of the short sale and borrowing constraints on return-volatility correlation. Positive returnvolatility correlation means that investors react more intensively to positive returns than their reaction to negative returns. It has been shown in Xu (2007) that the price is convex function of information if the short sales are constrained. One might postulate that the positive return-volatility is also caused by the short sale constraints. The original model framework in Xu (2007) was developed to show that positive skewness is a result from the asymmetric response of the price to information when short sale is strictly constrained. On the other hand, the margin trading policy is adopted simultaneously with the security lending in China. In order to understand how the return-volatility correlation is impacted when both short sale and margin trading are practiced. We extend the theoretical analysis as in Xu (2007) to meet the reality of the Chinese stock markets: the short sale constraints are not strictly imposed; we introduce borrowing constraints to study the effect of margin trading. We will calculate the return-volatility correlation of an asset as we vary the degree of short sales and borrowing constraints. As in Xu (2007), we consider a one period model and assume an economy consisting of two assets, a risky asset with a random payoff of X and a risk-free asset with gross interest rate R. Assume that X follows a normal distribution with mean µ X and precision (the reciprocal of variance) τ X. The public information S = X + ɛ contains a noise ɛ with expected value 0 and precision τ ɛ. All investors can observe the same information S while they hold different opinions towards the precision of noise. There are two representative types of investors who consider τ L and τ H to be the precision of noise, respectively. In addition, τ L < τ H. The two types of investors take proportions of λ and 1 λ respectively in the market. Suppose that information S = s is announced at time 1 and two types of investors trade in the market based on their opinions of error precision. First, 5

6 for θ (θ = L, H) type investors, we calculate the conditional expectation and variance of the risky assets payoff X given the information S = s, E θ [X s] ˆµ θ = τ X µ X + τ θ s (1) τ θ + τ x τ θ + τ X Va θ (X s) ˆτ 1 θ = (τ X + τ θ ) 1 (2) Assume θ type investors have initial wealth of W θ, they maximize their utility function of final wealth W θ by choosing their demand for the risky assets at time 1. The utility function is chosen to be the same constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) utility function U(W θ ) = e aw θ for both types of investors. Since information is a normally distributed random variable, the maximization of the utility function equals the maximization of the mean-variance utility function. max y 1,θ {E θ [ e aw θ ]} max y 1,θ {E θ [W 2,θ s] a 2 Var θ(w θ s)} (3) s.t. W θ = (W θ y 1,θ P 1 )R + y 1,θ X where y θ is the quantity of risky asset demanded by type θ, P 1 is the price of risky asset and a measures absolute risk aversion. Solving the utility maximization, we have the demand function for each type of investors, y θ = (ˆµ θ RP )ˆτ θ a (4) After we set the market clearing condition λy 1,L + (1 λ)y 1,H = 1. This implies the equilibrium price of the risky asset P 1 = 1 R ( µ ā τ ) (5) where τ = λˆτ L + (1 λ)ˆτ H is the average precision, µ = [λˆµ Lˆτ L + (1 λ)ˆµ H ˆτ H ]/ τ is the expected payoff by an average investor (i.e., E[X L, H, λ] after integrating the beliefs from both L and H investors according to their population weights). As seen in Eq. (5), the asset price is a linear function of information s. In the absence of short sale and borrowing constraints, price reacts symmetrically to information. 6

7 2.1. short sale and borrowing constraints If there is a strict short sale constraint (investors are completely forbidden from short selling), the equilibrium solution has been given in Xu (2007). In this paper, we loose the short sale constraints to assume that there is a maximum amount N 0 investors are allowed to short sell the risky asset, i.e., λy L N, (1 λ)y H N. When N = 0, short selling is completely prohibited in the market and we get back to the case discussed in Xu (2007). Note that, as a requirement for the market to clear, two types of investors cannot sell short at the same time. Therefore, at most one type of investors are binding to the short sale constraint, i.e., λy L = N or (1 λ)y H = N. In this paper, we also consider borrowing constraint, which means that there is a limited amount of money investors can borrow. We express the borrowing constraint as the total initial wealth (investors own wealth plus the amount they can borrow) that can be used to invest in the risky asset is less than a limit W. We assume that the borrowing constraints are only applicable to H investors, i.e., W H W, because borrowing constraints on L investors have little impact on skewness based on the following analysis. As shown in Xu (2007), the short constraints lend to asymmetric response of investors because H investors crowd out L investors when the market information s is very bullish. As a consequence, the price only reflects H investors overreaction to market s bullish information. If the initial wealth of H investors is inadequate due to borrowing constraints, the overreaction of H investors to bullish information will largely be damped. At this time, L investors have left the market and has no need for borrowing. Although it is true when s is rather bearish, only L investors will buy the risky asset when H investors overconfidently regard the market signal as bearish and leave the market under short sale constraints, however, at this time, the riksy asset prices is rather cheap, and the amount of capital needed by L investors is much smaller than what is needed by H investors in a bullish market. The following proposition provides the details of the equilibrium solution under short sale and borrowing constraints (see Appendix for proof). Proposition 1. (a) Under condition ˆµ H ˆµ L > a(1+n) (1 λ)ˆτ H + an λˆτ L (or s > µ x + a(1+n)ˆτ L (1 λ)(τ H τ L )τ x + ), the equilibrium price becomes: an ˆτ H λ(τ H τ L )τ x (i) when W (1 + N)P H, P = P H ; (ii) when (1 + N)P s < W < (1 + N)P H, P = W/(1 + N); (iii) when W (1 + N)P s, P = P M ; 7

8 Under (i) and (ii), the demand of L investors is λy L = N, and that of investor H is (1 λ)y H = 1+N; under (iii), λy L = λ(ˆµ L RP M )ˆτ L, (1 a λ)y H = 1 λy L. (b) Under condition ˆµ L ˆµ H > a(1+n) an ˆτ L λˆτ L + an (1 λ)ˆτ H (or s < µ x a(1+n)ˆτ H λ(τ H τ L )τ x λ(τ H τ L )τ x ), the demand of investor H is (1 λ)y H = N while the demand of investor S is λy L = 1 + N; the equilibrium price P = P L ; (c) While neither condition (a) nor (b) is satisfied, short sale constraints no longer affect the equilibrium solution. Then the following two borrowing constraints should be considered: (i) when W (1 λ)p 0 y 0,H, P = P 0 ; (ii) when W < (1 λ)p 0 y 0,H, P = P M ; On condition (i), investor demands are as in Equation (8) and (9), and on condition (ii), investor demands are as in (iii) of (a). Among which P H is the price corresponding to the demand (1 λ)y H = 1 + N of investor H, P L is the price corresponding to the demand λy L = 1 + N of investor L, P M is the equilibrium price when market clears out on condition that investors H are not subject to borrowing constraint W H = W while investors L are not subject to any constraint. Their expressions are given as, P H = 1 R (ˆµ H a(1+n) (1 λ)ˆτ H ) P L = 1 R (ˆµ L a(1+n) λˆτ L ) P M = 1 2λRˆτ L (λˆτ Lˆµ L a + 3. Numerical simulations (a λˆτ Lˆµ L ) 2 + 4aRW λˆτ L ) Under short sale constraint and borrowing constraint, the price of the risky asset is a piecewise function of information s, while s itself is subject to normal distribution and it can be difficult to calculate the return-volatility correlation of the prices, here we adopt the method of Monto Carlo Simulation and generate random samples of x and ɛ. After generating x and ɛ, we calculate the price of risky asset based on each sample and then we calculate return-volatility correlation. As long as the sample space is chosen large enough, for example in this paper we take 1,000,000 samplings, we 8

9 can get a rather smooth curve. In the example of our Monto Carlo Simulation, µ x = 1.5, τ x = 1, R = 1.2, τ L = 0.5, τ H = 1.5, λ = 0.5, a = 0.5, the interval of W is [0.5,5], and N is taken from three dispersed values N = 0, N = 0.1, N = 1. In order to understand the relative magnitudes of different values of W, we need to calculate the market value of the risky asset. Since the total volume of risky asset is 1, the market value is the same as the asset price. When s = µ x, the market provides accurate information of the risky asset and we can obtain P 0 = 1.04, which means the fair value of the asset is We further look at the situation where the information signal is two standard deviations away from its expectation s = µ x + 2 1/τ ɛ + 1/τ x = 4.32, at this time we have P 0 = 2.22, P H = 2.33(N = 0), which means that the market value of risky asset is 2.22 under no short sale constraint and 2.33 when short sale is prohibited. That is to say, with a probability of 97.5%, the market value of risky value will be smaller than From the analysis of the market value we can see that, if the capital of the investor is below 1, the capital is not sufficient for the market to be cleared at its fair value. On the other hand, W = 5 means almost no constraints to the investment capital, since with more than 97.5%, the market value is below For a reasonable range of W to study the effect of borrowing constraints, we use the interval W [0.5, 5]. Under most occasions the interval that would have a real influence on investors borrowing is W [1, 3]. Figure 1 presents the return-volatility correlation under different choices of N and W. We can see that, within the interval W [0.5, 5], the returnvolatility correlation increases as W increases. In addition, if short sale is allowed, the return-volatility correlation would decrease under all levels of borrowing constraints W [0.5, 5]. If some degree of short sale is allowed while the constraint is still strong (for example N = 0.1 which means only 10% of the risky asset can be sold short), the return-volatility correlation of risky asset is still above 0. At this time, the skewness of risky asset is still positively biased. But if the short constraint is very mild (for example N = 1 which means 100% of risky asset can be sold short), while there is borrowing constraint at the same time (for example W < 5), the returnvolatility correlation is negative. 9

10 Correlation N=0,W=+ N=0 N=0.1 N= W Figure 1: Return-volatility correlation of risky asset price under various levels of short sale and borrowing constraint 4. Data We collect Chinese stock data and the designated short sale list from the GuoTaiAn database. We only keep data on A-share stocks traded on the Chinese main board. We exclude the stocks traded in the China Growth Enterprise Market which begin its trading activities on October 23, 2009, significantly after the moment of our earliest data selection. Turnover rate data and the FAMA three-factor data are obtained from the Wind Investor Terminal (WIT). Short sale practices started on March 31, 2010 in China. Only a list of designated securities that meet certain requirements can be sold short. Up to December 31, 2015, there are 756 securities allowed for short sale through the margin trading and security lending policy, including 742 stocks and 14 ETFs listed on the Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Exchanges. There are a total of 2,674 A-share stocks traded on the Chinese main board up to December 31, Among them, 742 stocks are on the designated list, and 1,932 stocks are not. There are 2,674 A-share stocks in total in our samples as of December 31, Starting from January 1, 2002, four years of data are rolled to estimate the FAMA three-factor model to obtain excess returns. Thus the 10

11 actual effective period is January, 2006 to December, 2015, 10 years in total; four years before the launch of margin financing and security lending, and six years after that. Only those stocks with more than sixty days of data are kept after the calculation of excess returns. Thus, we end up with 2,010 stocks in our samples (865 are on the designated list and 1,145 are not). 5. Empirical study In this section, we want to show empirically that the reverse returnvolatility asymmetry in the Chinese financial markets are all caused at least partially by short sale constraints. First, we present the data processing method Data processing In order to confirm the existence and the robustness of positive risk-return correlation in the Chinese markets, we conduct our experiment on the raw stock returns, excess returns, and normalized excess returns. Excess return is obtained from the FAMA three-factor model for each individual stock. ɛ t = y t (α + β 1 r t1 + β 2 r t2 + β 3 r t3 ) (6) where ɛ t is the excess return (or innovation), r 1, r 2 and r 3 respectively, represent one of the FAMA three factors, namely market return, market capitalization, and price-to-book ratio. The parameters α and βs are estimated from a four-year rolling time window and the excess return is computed for the next one quarter. In this way, the parameters are gradually adapted and do not cause large disruption to ɛ t. We then normalize the excess return by dividing its conditional standard deviation obtained from the EGARCH model. We assume that ɛ t is sampled from a normal distribution N (0, σt 2 ). For the evolution equation of σt 2, as has been documented by many researchers to be suitable for the financial time series in the Chinese markets, the EGARCH (1, 1) model is deployed here to estimate the variances of residuals. log σ 2 t = κ + γ 1 log σ 2 t 1 + η 1 [ ɛ t 1 σ t 1 2 π ] + ξ 1( ɛ t 1 σ t 1 ) (7) By using the conditional volatility estimated from EGARCH model, we can get the normalized excess return ɛ t = ɛ t /σ t. 11

12 The excess return ɛ t keeps the idiosyncratic innovations of each stock while the market part is removed. The normalization of excess return removes the effect of time-varying volatility by dividing the conditional volatility estimated from the EGARCH model. The other advantage of the normalization is that the leverage effect has also been removed after the excess return is normalized by the EGARCH model, which has a leverage term. By the assumption of the EGARCH model, we know that even if a leverage or an anti-leverage effect is present, ɛ t is still symmetrically distributed if it is sampled from N (0, σt 2 ). Therefore, if we can still observe asymmetry in the normalized excess returns, the asymmetry is not due to the leverage or anti-leverage effect described in the EGARCH model Effects of short sales and margin trading on return-volatility relationship The usual way to study the effect of short sale constraints is to take only a few dozen days around the events and thus the time effect and other market events may not be distracting issues. In our study, the time span is rather long (i.e., four years before the first launch of security lending policy and four years after). In order to exclude the possibility that positive return-volatility correlation is caused by factors other than the short sale constraints, we include those stocks which are not yet eligible for short sales for comparison (thanks to the slow adjustment of the security lending policy). Therefore, we divide the stocks into two groups, namely, treatment group which includes stocks that are selected for short sales practice at least once as of March 31, 2014, and control group which includes stocks that are never eligible for short sales. The dependent variables are the three return-volatility correlations measured using the raw returns, excess returns and normalized excess returns. The raw returns is noisy with the market component in it. The excess returns are cleaned and more suitable to examine the return-volatility correlation after we remove the impact from the market. The normalized excess returns are even better after we remove the time-varying volatility. We estimate the variables in non-overlapping time windows spanning from January 1, 2006 to December 31, As a robustness check, we use two time windows to prepare the samples (i.e., quarterly and half-year time windows). If the samples are calculated for every quarter, there are 40 samples for each stock, denoting 40 quarters from January 1, 2006 to December 31, If we prepare the samples for every half-year, then there are 20 samples. 12

13 5.3. Univariate analysis First, we present the average return-volatility correlation for the control group and treatment group. The results are reported in Table.? and Table. 2 for the quarterly samples and semi-annual samples, respectively. We can see that all return-volatility correlations are positive on a 1% significance level. The return-volatility correlations of the excess returns and normalized excess returns are particularly larger than 0 after we remove the market part from the firm-level returns. These results confirm the reverse return-volatility asymmetry in the Chinese markets documented in previous literature. Then, we check the change in the return-volatility correlations before and after the short sale practice. For the control group, we simply divide the samples according to the starting date of the margin trading and security lending policy. The change for correlation measured using the normalized excess return in the control group is nearly 0, while the change of the correlation measured using excess returns is also very small (the statistical significance at 5% level is largely due to the time-varying of the volatility). In contrast, in the treatment group, the return-volatility correlations have significantly reduced when measured using both the excess returns and normalized excess returns. From these comparison, we can see that the short sale policy has substantially reduced the return-volatility correlations. However, the short sale and margin trading are simultaneously implemented in the Chinese markets. We do not know from the univariate analysis which one contributes to the reduction in the return-volatility correlations. In addition, the reduction may be caused by other reasons or by mere time effect. We will conduct a panel regression for a rigorous analysis in the next subsection. 13

14 14 Table 1: Results for univariate analysis conducted on quarterly samples. Raw returns Excess returns Normalized excess returns control group before the policy 0.041*** (15.0) 0.254*** (91.8) 0.31*** (105) control group after the policy 0.022*** (9.06) 0.247*** (104) 0.31*** (122.8) control group change *** (-5.08) ** (-2.06) (-0.027) treatment group before short sale 0.052*** (24.27) 0.24*** (109) 0.29*** (123.5) treatment group after short sale 0.089*** (22.76) 0.21*** (51.8) 0.25*** (57.6) treatment group change 0.037*** (8.25) *** (-7.81) *** (-8.51) Note:Triple asterisks(***)denote significance at 1% critical level, double asterisks(**) at 5% level, and single asterisks(*) at 10% level respectively.

15 15 Table 2: Results for univariate analysis conducted on semi-annual samples. Raw returns Excess returns Normalized excess returns control group before the policy 0.050*** (15.1) 0.28*** (82.1) 0.33*** (91.4) control group after the policy 0.034*** (128.4) 0.27*** (110) 0.33*** (128) control group change *** (-3.95) (-1.17) (1.34) treatment group before short sale 0.064*** (25.6) 0.27*** (106) 0.31*** (117) treatment group after short sale 0.13*** (28.8) 0.23*** (50.6) 0.27*** (55.5) treatment group change 0.062*** (12.3) *** (-6.73) *** (-6.56)

16 5.4. Panal regression results The stocks are different in the treatment group and control group. We use the FAMA three factors as control variables (beta 1, beta 2 and beta 3) to account for the different characteristics between the two groups. We formalize the empirical study in the framework of panel regression. We use the three correlation as explained above as the dependent variables. Explanatory variables include turnover rate (which is the ratio of daily volume to shares outstanding) to proxy for the difference of opinions, return and volatility for each stock, a dummy variable v to represent treatment group vs control group and a dummy variable u to represent short sale practiced. The other two sets of dummy variables account for the fixed effects of industry and time. There are 18 industry categories in total according to the China Securities Regulatory Commission). The designated list is frequently adjusted. Remember that treatment group refers to stocks that are selected for short sales practice at least once as of December 31, There are stocks in treatment group which are not practiced for short sales yet in a time window 1. Since a stock can be allowed for short sale within a time window, we disregard those samples if only a faction of the time a stock is practiced for short sales 2. The regression results are reported in Table 4 and Table 5 for quarterly and semi-annul sampling periods, respectively. The results are similar despite the sampling windows. For each dependent variable, we have two regression equations, Eq. 1 uses the dummy for short sale practice only, and Eq. 2 uses the short sale practice plus the margin rate and short sale rate. As we predict in the theoretic session that margin trading can increase the return-volatility correlation. The impact of short sale and margin trading on return-volatility correlation is opposite. If we observe the reduction of return-volatility correlation, it must be caused by the lifting of short sale constraints. As shown in the Tables, the return-volatility correlation measured using normalized excess returns decreased significantly at a 1% level after short sale is practiced when it is regressed alone. While we include the margin rate and short sale rate in the regression, short sale is still significant less than 0 at 10% level. As predicted, the margin rate has a positive contribution, and the short rate 1 For those stocks in the control group, short sales are never practiced. 2 We also conducted the test by treating a sample with short sale practiced if there are more than half of the days in the given time window the stock is allowed for short selling. The results are not reported in this paper but they do not show big difference. 16

17 Table 3: Descriptive statistics of some of the explanatory and control variables. semi-annual quarterly mean (std.) mean (std.) beta (0.23) (0.24) beta (0.55) (0.571) beta (0.58) (0.60) turnover 3.38 (3.575) 3.36 (3.52) excess return (0.41) (0.29) volatility (0.0298) (0.030) dummy for short sale 0.24 (0.429) 0.26 (0.44) margin rate 1.37% (0.032%) 1.47% (0.033%) short rate % ( %) 0.009% (0.0057%) dummy for shortable (0.499) (0.499) is negative. These results give the direct evidence to support our hypothesis that the short sale constraints are responsible for the reverse return-volatility asymmetry we have observed in the Chinese markets. 17

18 18 Table 4: The table reports the regression conducted on quarterly samples. Dependent variables are the return-volatility correlations measured using raw returns, excess returns, and normalized excess returns, respectively. Explanatory variables include, average daily turnover in a quarter, cumulative return and standard deviation of daily returns in a quarter, a dummy variable for designated list, and a dummy variable for short sale practice, margin rate, and short sale rate. All regressions include dummies (unreported) for each quarter and industry. Raw Returns Excess Returns Normalized Excess Returns Eq. 1 Eq. 2 Eq. 1 Eq. 2 Eq. 1 Eq. 2 beta *** -0.13*** * * (-25.6) (-28.74) (-1.23) (-1.23) (-1.83) (-1.77) beta *** *** *** *** 0.013*** 0.015*** (-19.11) (-20.26) (3.02) (3.22) (4.51) (5.04) beta *** *** * * (-5.27) (-5.14) (0.86) (0.84) (-1.74) (-1.8) turnover *** *** (30.29) (30.01) (0.63) (0.66) (0.82) (0.99) excess return 0.44*** 0.44*** (98.34) (98.62) (1.63) (1.59) (0.42) (0.3) volatility -1.47*** -1.48*** (-27.28) (-27.52) (0.4) (0.43) (-0.049) (0.069) dummy for shortable 0.043*** 0.042*** *** * *** *** (18.02) (17.58) (4.23) (-1.75) (-5.33) (-5.09) dummy for short sale * *** *** *** * *** (-1.85) (-7.03) (-3.72) (-4.99) (-1.76) (-4.665) margin rate -0.38*** *** (-5.29) (0.65) (2.67) shortrate 8.3*** -7.7** -6.9* (3.14) (-2.19) (-1.88) Obj No. of Stocks R-square adjusted F-statistics Time fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES Industry fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES Note:Triple asterisks(***)denote significance at 1% critical level, double asterisks(**) at 5% level, and single asterisks(*) at 10% level respectively.

19 19 Table 5: The table reports the regression conducted on semi-annual samples. Dependent variables are the return-volatility correlations measured using raw returns, excess returns, and normalized excess returns, respectively. Explanatory variables include, average daily turnover in a half year, cumulative return and standard deviation of daily returns in a half year, a dummy variable for designated list, and a dummy variable for short sale practice, margin rate, and short sale rate. All regressions include dummies (unreported) for each half year and industry. Raw Returns Excess Returns Normalized Excess Returns Eq. 1 Eq. 2 Eq. 1 Eq. 2 Eq. 1 Eq. 2 beta *** -0.12*** (-22.73) (-22.85) (-0.003) (0.12) (-0.4) (-0.31) beta 2-0,045*** *** *** 0.011*** 0.025*** *** (-18.38) (-19.44) (2.69) (3.44) (7.23) (7.64) beta * * (-1.52) (-1.38) (1.129) (1.0) (1.89) (1.82) turnover *** *** (17.38) (17.15) (1.28) (1.52) (-0.35) (-0.22) excess return 0.19*** 0.19*** *** (56.49) (56.72) (-0.021) (-0.39) (1.46) (1.38) volatility (0.49) (1.28) (0.31) (0.51) (0.087) (0.18) dummy for shortable 0.039*** 0.038*** * *** *** (14.66) (14.28) (-1.94) (-1.55) (-3.89) (-3.72) dummy for short sale *** *** -0.04*** * *** (-1.29) (-6.15) (-5.23) (-3.28) (-4.24) (-3.76) margin rate -0.4*** 0.48*** 0.25** (-4.61) (4.26) (2.1) short rate 5.2* (1.71) (-0.25) (1.56) Obj No. of Stocks R-square adjusted F-statistics Time fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES Industry fixed effect YES YES YES YES YES YES Note:Triple asterisks(***)denote significance at 1% critical level, double asterisks(**) at 5% level, and single asterisks(*) at 10% level respectively.

20 6. Discussion and conclusion Reverse return-volatility asymmetry (i.e., positive return-volatility correlation) has been documented in the Chinese stock markets in contrast to the widely accepted theory of negative return-volatility correlation. Investors react more intensively on the upside than the downside. One might postulate that the short sale constraints are behind this anomaly since it has shown in Xu (2007) that the price is convex function of information if the short sales are constrained. However, In order to understand how the return-volatility correlation is impacted when both short sale and margin trading are practiced. We extend the theoretical analysis as in Xu (2007) to meet the reality of the Chinese stock markets: the short sale constraints are not strictly imposed; we introduce borrowing constraints to study the effect of margin trading. We calculate the return-volatility correlation of an asset as we vary the degree of short sales and borrowing constraints. The theoretical analysis shows that lifting of short sale constraints can decrease the return-volatility correlation while margin trading increases the correlation. Empirically, we examine the return-volatility correlation of daily firmlevel returns in the Chinese stock market. Three return-volatility correlations are measured using raw returns, excess returns and normalized excess returns. They are all statistically significantly positive. The normalized excess returns are cleaned and more suitable to examine the return-volatility correlation after we remove the impact from the market and time-varying volatility. The return-volatility correlations of the normalized excess returns is significantly positive after the market part is removed. Starting from March, 2010, China adopts the margin finance and security lending policy. The policy provides for a designated list of stocks for short sale practice. The adoption of the security lending policy takes place over time and it is still in process. This affords us sufficient time space from which to collect data to examine the effects of the policy. We divide the Chinese stocks into two groups, namely treatment group and control group. Treatment group includes stocks that are selected for short sales practice at least once as of December 31, 2014; Control group includes stocks that are never eligible for short sales. The univariate analysis indicates that after the margin trading and security lending policy on March 31, 2010, both the return-volatility correlations for the excess returns and normalized excess returns are statistically and economically significantly reduced. However, the 20

21 reduction is nearly zero for the return-volatility correlation of the normalized excess returns for the control group. We then conduct panel regression using daily return data of stocks allowed for short sale after they are added to a designated list and of other stocks never added to the list. Our results show that (i) the lifting of short sale constraints largely decreases the return-volatility correlation of the excess returns and normalized excess returns; Appendix A. Proof of the Proposition 1 Proof. Under condition (a), the market is relatively bullish, H investors overestimate the asset price while L investors are subject to short sale constraints. According to Eq. (4) we have λy 0,L < N, L investors can only sell N thus λy L = N. Market clearing condition requires (1 λ)y H = 1 + N. Under (i), investors H are not subject to the borrowing constraint, then the equilibrium price is determined by investor H s excessive demand alone for risky asset. Substitute y H into Eq. (4) and we get P H ; Under (ii), investors H are subject to the borrowing constraint, then the capital endowment of investor H does not allow the risky asset to be cleared out at price P H which corresponds to its demand, but equilibrium price will still be maintained above P s, the price corresponding to the demand N of investor L. At this time investor L is still affected by short sale constraints and can only sale a maximum amount of N, and the price of risky asset is determined by the initial wealth W instead of the demand 1+N of investor H, consequently the market price under borrowing constraints becomes P = W/(1 + N); Under (iii), the borrowing constraint is so strong that investor H does not have enough capital to support its demand meanwhile even a rather low price P s that corresponds to the negative demand of investor L can not be reached, the asset price would fall until investor L does not need to sort N. Now investors L are not subject to any constraint, and market price P = P M can be solved from the three simultaneous equations as below, (1 λ)y H P = W y L = ˆµ L RP a λy L + (1 λ)y H = 1 (A.1) P M is the non-negative solution to above equations, it can be proved that P M < P s, thus it is true that investor L does not need to short N. 21

22 Under condition (b), the market is relatively bearish, investors H underestimate the asset price due to overconfidence but the amount of asset they can short is limited by short sale constraint, at the same time investor L still has positive demand for risky asset and is not affected by borrowing constraint since the price is already low as explained earlier. According to 4 we have λy 0,H < N, investor H can only short a maximum of N, and the demand of investor L that is not limited by short sale constraint becomes λy L = 1 + N, consequently, the equilibrium price P = P L can be obtained according to the relationship between price and demand as in Eq. (4). Under condition (c), neither of the two investors are subject to short sale constraints, and if W P 0 y 0,H, then investor H will not be affected by borrowing constraints, and the equilibrium solution would be the same as the solution without any constraints i.e. P = P 0 ; if W < P 0 y 0,H then investors H are subject to borrowing constraints, as in (a) P = P M can be obtained by three simultaneous equations mentioned in (a). 22

23 References Bekaert, G., Wu, G., Asymmetric volatility and risk in equity markets. Review of Financial Studies 13 (1), Bollerslev, T., Law, T. H., Tauchen, G., Risk, jumps, and diversification. Journal of Econometrics 144 (1), Campbell, J. Y., Hentschel, L., No news is good news: An asymmetric model of changing volatility in stock returns. Journal of financial Economics 31 (3), Chang, E. C., Luo, Y., Ren, J., Short-selling, margin-trading, and price efficiency: Evidence from the chinese market. Journal of Banking & Finance 48, Chen, J., Hong, H., Stein, J. C., Breadth of ownership and stock returns. Journal of financial Economics 66 (2), Christie, A. A., The stochastic behavior of common stock variances: Value, leverage and interest rate effects. Journal of financial Economics 10 (4), Figlewski, S., The informational effects of restrictions on short sales: some empirical evidence. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 16 (04), Ghysels, E., Santa-Clara, P., Valkanov, R., There is a risk-return tradeoff after all. Journal of Financial Economics 76 (3), Glosten, L. R., Jagannathan, R., Runkle, D. E., On the relation between the expected value and the volatility of the nominal excess return on stocks. The journal of finance 48 (5), Harrison, P., Zhang, H. H., An investigation of the risk and return relation at long horizons. Review of Economics and Statistics 81 (3), Hong, H., Stein, J. C., Differences of opinion, short-sales constraints, and market crashes. Review of financial studies 16 (2),

24 Klößner, S., Becker, M., Friedmann, R., Modeling and measuring intraday overreaction of stock prices. Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (4), Lee, C.-Y., Leverage effect and its causality in the korea composite stock price index. Journal of the Korean Physical Society 60 (3), Ludvigson, S. C., Ng, S., The empirical risk return relation: a factor analysis approach. Journal of Financial Economics 83 (1), Menggen, C., The risk-return trade off in emerging stock market: Evidence from china. In: A Seminar Paper. Nagel, S., Short sales, institutional investors and the cross-section of stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 78 (2), Nelson, D. B., Conditional heteroskedasticity in asset returns: A new approach. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, Pindyck, R. S., Risk, inflation, and the stock market. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research. Qiu, T., Zheng, B., Ren, F., Trimper, S., Return-volatility correlation in financial dynamics. Physical Review E 73 (6), Shen, J., Zheng, B., On return-volatility correlation in financial dynamics. EPL (Europhysics Letters) 88 (2), Wan, D., Cheng, K., Yang, X., The reverse volatility asymmetry in chinese financial market. Applied Financial Economics 24 (24), Xu, J., Price convexity and skewness. The Journal of Finance 62 (5), Yeh, Y.-H., Lee, T.-S., The interaction and volatility asymmetry of unexpected returns in the greater china stock markets. Global Finance Journal 11 (1), Zhao, Z., Li, S., Xiong, H., Short sale constraints, disperse pessimistic beliefs and market efficiencyevidence from the chinese stock market. Economic Modelling 42,

25 Zheng, B., Jiang, X.-F., Ni, P.-Y., A mini-review on econophysics: Comparative study of chinese and western financial markets. Chinese Physics B 23 (7),

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 5 Nov 2015

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 5 Nov 2015 arxiv:1511.01824v1 [q-fin.gn] 5 Nov 2015 Positive skewness, anti-leverage, reverse volatility asymmetry, and short sale constraints: Evidence from the Chinese markets Abstract Liang Wu, Jingyi Luo The

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 12 Nov 2015

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 12 Nov 2015 Deleveraging, short sale constraints and market crash arxiv:1511.03777v1 [q-fin.gn] 12 Nov 2015 Abstract Liang Wu, Lei Zhang and Zhiming Fu The School of Economics, Sichuan University, Chengdu, PR. China,

More information

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs John L. Glascock 1 University of Connecticut Ran Lu-Andrews 2 California Lutheran University (This version: August 2016) Abstract The traditional

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Volume 2009, Article ID 743685, 9 pages doi:10.1155/2009/743685 Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and

More information

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012 Speculative Betas Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University September 30, 2012 Introduction Model 1 factor static Shorting OLG Exenstion Calibration High Risk, Low Return Puzzle Cumulative Returns

More information

The Analysis of ICBC Stock Based on ARMA-GARCH Model

The Analysis of ICBC Stock Based on ARMA-GARCH Model Volume 04 - Issue 08 August 2018 PP. 11-16 The Analysis of ICBC Stock Based on ARMA-GARCH Model Si-qin LIU 1 Hong-guo SUN 1* 1 (Department of Mathematics and Finance Hunan University of Humanities Science

More information

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Eric Zivot April 29, 2013 Lecture Outline The Leverage Effect Asymmetric GARCH Models Forecasts from Asymmetric GARCH Models GARCH Models with

More information

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed Snehal Banerjee (Northwestern) Brett Green (UC-Berkeley) AFA 2014 Meetings July 2013 Learning about other traders Trade motives

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Itamar Drechsler Alan Moreira Alexi Savov New York University and NBER University of Rochester March, 2018 Motivation 1. A key function of the financial sector is

More information

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Itamar Drechsler, NYU and NBER Alan Moreira, Rochester Alexi Savov, NYU and NBER JHU Carey Finance Conference June, 2018 1 Liquidity and Volatility 1. Liquidity creation

More information

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM Samit Majumdar Virginia Commonwealth University majumdars@vcu.edu Frank W. Bacon Longwood University baconfw@longwood.edu ABSTRACT: This study

More information

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market Meng-Wei Chen Department of Economics, Indiana University at Bloomington April 21, 2011 Abstract This paper studies the information transmission

More information

Forecasting Volatility in the Chinese Stock Market under Model Uncertainty 1

Forecasting Volatility in the Chinese Stock Market under Model Uncertainty 1 Forecasting Volatility in the Chinese Stock Market under Model Uncertainty 1 Yong Li 1, Wei-Ping Huang, Jie Zhang 3 (1,. Sun Yat-Sen University Business, Sun Yat-Sen University, Guangzhou, 51075,China)

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

A Study on Asymmetric Preference in Foreign Exchange Market Intervention in Emerging Asia Yanzhen Wang 1,a, Xiumin Li 1, Yutan Li 1, Mingming Liu 1

A Study on Asymmetric Preference in Foreign Exchange Market Intervention in Emerging Asia Yanzhen Wang 1,a, Xiumin Li 1, Yutan Li 1, Mingming Liu 1 A Study on Asymmetric Preference in Foreign Exchange Market Intervention in Emerging Asia Yanzhen Wang 1,a, Xiumin Li 1, Yutan Li 1, Mingming Liu 1 1 School of Economics, Northeast Normal University, Changchun,

More information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring Holmstrom and Tirole (JPE, 1993) The main idea A firm would like to issue shares in the capital market because once these shares are publicly traded, speculators

More information

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models Indian Institute of Management Calcutta Working Paper Series WPS No. 797 March 2017 Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models Vivek Rajvanshi Assistant Professor, Indian Institute of Management

More information

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions Cynthia Royal Tori, PhD Valdosta State University Langdale College of Business 1500 N. Patterson Street, Valdosta, GA USA 31698

More information

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis WenShwo Fang Department of Economics Feng Chia University 100 WenHwa Road, Taichung, TAIWAN Stephen M. Miller* College of Business University

More information

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Financial Mathematics III Theory summary Table of Contents Lecture 1... 7 1. State the objective of modern portfolio theory... 7 2. Define the return of an asset... 7 3. How is expected return defined?...

More information

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern. , JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 13, 2009 Outline 1 Motivation Production-Based Asset Pricing Framework 2 Assumptions Firm s Problem Equilibrium 3 Main Findings Mechanism Testable

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Alberto Bisin Corporate Finance: Lecture Notes Class 1: Valuation updated November 17th, 2002 1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Consider an economy with two states of nature {s 1, s 2 } and with

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 There are two questions on the exam, representing Asset Pricing (236D = 234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) Yigit Bora Senyigit *, Yusuf Ag

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) Yigit Bora Senyigit *, Yusuf Ag Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) 327 332 2 nd World Conference on Business, Economics and Management WCBEM 2013 Explaining

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2013 GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 1 / 37 Squared log returns for CRSP daily GPD (TCD) Volatility 01/13 2 / 37 Absolute value

More information

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Log-Robust Portfolio Management Log-Robust Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Elcin Cetinkaya and Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983 Dr.

More information

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Jin Yong Jung We analyze how the wealth of an agent and its distribution affect the profit of the principal by considering the simple

More information

Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Final Exam Suggested Solutions University of Washington Fall 003 Department of Economics Eric Zivot Economics 483 Final Exam Suggested Solutions This is a closed book and closed note exam. However, you are allowed one page of handwritten

More information

Volatility Index and the Return-Volatility Relation: Intraday Evidence from China

Volatility Index and the Return-Volatility Relation: Intraday Evidence from China Volatility Index and the Return-Volatility Relation: Intraday Evidence from China Jupeng Li a, Xingguo Luo b* and Xiaoli Yu c a Shanghai Stock Exchange, Shanghai 200120, China. b School of Economics and

More information

Study on Dynamic Risk Measurement Based on ARMA-GJR-AL Model

Study on Dynamic Risk Measurement Based on ARMA-GJR-AL Model Applied and Computational Mathematics 5; 4(3): 6- Published online April 3, 5 (http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/acm) doi:.648/j.acm.543.3 ISSN: 38-565 (Print); ISSN: 38-563 (Online) Study on Dynamic

More information

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 10-, 351 365 (009) Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information Chanwoo Noh Department of Mathematics, Pohang University of Science

More information

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements Table of List of figures List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements page xii xv xvii xix xxi xxv 1 Introduction 1 1.1 What is econometrics? 2 1.2 Is

More information

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology FE570 Financial Markets and Trading Lecture 6. Volatility Models and (Ref. Joel Hasbrouck - Empirical Market Microstructure ) Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 10/02/2012 Outline 1 Volatility

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1334ec e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2011 INFORMS Electronic Companion Trust in Forecast Information Sharing by Özalp Özer, Yanchong Zheng,

More information

The Impact of Macroeconomic Uncertainty on Commercial Bank Lending Behavior in Barbados. Ryan Bynoe. Draft. Abstract

The Impact of Macroeconomic Uncertainty on Commercial Bank Lending Behavior in Barbados. Ryan Bynoe. Draft. Abstract The Impact of Macroeconomic Uncertainty on Commercial Bank Lending Behavior in Barbados Ryan Bynoe Draft Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between macroeconomic uncertainty and the allocation

More information

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Badrinath Kottimukkalur * January 2018 Abstract This paper provides an arbitrage based explanation for the puzzling negative

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk Itamar Drechsler Alan Moreira Alexi Savov Wharton Rochester NYU Chicago November 2018 1 Liquidity and Volatility 1. Liquidity creation - makes it cheaper to pledge

More information

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M VIALE I Markowitz-Tobin Mean-Variance Portfolio Analysis Assumption Mean-Variance preferences Markowitz 95 Quadratic utility function E [ w b w ] { = E [ w] b V ar w + E [ w] }

More information

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers Final Exam Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, 2004 Answers This exam consists of two parts. The first part is a long analytical question. The second part is a set of short discussion questions.

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation Tao Wang Queens College and the Graduate Center of the City University of New York Abstract Stock return volatilities are related to firms' financial

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell Trinity College and Darwin College University of Cambridge 1 / 32 Problem Definition We revisit last year s smart beta work of Ed Fishwick. The CAPM predicts that higher risk portfolios earn a higher return

More information

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea Hangyong Lee Korea development Institute December 2005 Abstract This paper investigates the empirical relationship

More information

MAGNT Research Report (ISSN ) Vol.6(1). PP , 2019

MAGNT Research Report (ISSN ) Vol.6(1). PP , 2019 Does the Overconfidence Bias Explain the Return Volatility in the Saudi Arabia Stock Market? Majid Ibrahim AlSaggaf Department of Finance and Insurance, College of Business, University of Jeddah, Saudi

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

Principles of Finance

Principles of Finance Principles of Finance Grzegorz Trojanowski Lecture 7: Arbitrage Pricing Theory Principles of Finance - Lecture 7 1 Lecture 7 material Required reading: Elton et al., Chapter 16 Supplementary reading: Luenberger,

More information

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 ortfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach Validity of the Mean-Variance Approach Constant absolute risk aversion (CARA): u(w ) = exp(

More information

Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model

Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model Estimating time-varying risk prices with a multivariate GARCH model Chikashi TSUJI December 30, 2007 Abstract This paper examines the pricing of month-by-month time-varying risks on the Japanese stock

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models Preliminary Lecture Notes Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University November 2014 Contents 1 Static Moral Hazard

More information

Heterogeneous Beliefs, Short-Sale Constraints and the Closed-End Fund Puzzle. Zhiguang Cao Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China

Heterogeneous Beliefs, Short-Sale Constraints and the Closed-End Fund Puzzle. Zhiguang Cao Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China Heterogeneous Beliefs, Short-Sale Constraints and the Closed-End Fund Puzzle Zhiguang Cao Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China Richard D. F. Harris* University of Exeter, UK Junmin Yang

More information

Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior

Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior Yan-liang Zhang*, Zi-wei Yang Shandong University of Finance and Economics. Jinan P.R.China E-mail:zhyanliang@sina.com

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES KRISTOFFER P. NIMARK Lucas Island Model The Lucas Island model appeared in a series of papers in the early 970s

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Yosuke Kimura Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo March 20, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the relationship between stock

More information

Financial Times Series. Lecture 6

Financial Times Series. Lecture 6 Financial Times Series Lecture 6 Extensions of the GARCH There are numerous extensions of the GARCH Among the more well known are EGARCH (Nelson 1991) and GJR (Glosten et al 1993) Both models allow for

More information

Keywords: China; Globalization; Rate of Return; Stock Markets; Time-varying parameter regression.

Keywords: China; Globalization; Rate of Return; Stock Markets; Time-varying parameter regression. Co-movements of Shanghai and New York Stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Peter L. Swan ACE Conference, July 13, 2018, Canberra UNSW Business School, Sydney Australia July 13, 2018 UNSW Australia, Sydney, Australia 1 /

More information

Relationship Between Voluntary Disclosure, Stock Price Synchronicity and Financial Status: Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies

Relationship Between Voluntary Disclosure, Stock Price Synchronicity and Financial Status: Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies American Journal of Operations Management and Information Systems 018; 3(4): 74-80 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/ajomis doi: 10.11648/j.ajomis.0180304.11 ISSN: 578-830 (Print); ISSN: 578-8310

More information

Asset Allocation Model with Tail Risk Parity

Asset Allocation Model with Tail Risk Parity Proceedings of the Asia Pacific Industrial Engineering & Management Systems Conference 2017 Asset Allocation Model with Tail Risk Parity Hirotaka Kato Graduate School of Science and Technology Keio University,

More information

An Empirical Research on Chinese Stock Market Volatility Based. on Garch

An Empirical Research on Chinese Stock Market Volatility Based. on Garch Volume 04 - Issue 07 July 2018 PP. 15-23 An Empirical Research on Chinese Stock Market Volatility Based on Garch Ya Qian Zhu 1, Wen huili* 1 (Department of Mathematics and Finance, Hunan University of

More information

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index Management Science and Engineering Vol. 11, No. 1, 2017, pp. 67-75 DOI:10.3968/9412 ISSN 1913-0341 [Print] ISSN 1913-035X [Online] www.cscanada.net www.cscanada.org Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR

More information

Managerial Power, Capital Structure and Firm Value

Managerial Power, Capital Structure and Firm Value Open Journal of Social Sciences, 2014, 2, 138-142 Published Online December 2014 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/journal/jss http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jss.2014.212019 Managerial Power, Capital Structure

More information

Analysis of accounting risk based on derivative financial instruments. Gao Lin

Analysis of accounting risk based on derivative financial instruments. Gao Lin International Conference on Education Technology and Social Science (ICETSS 2014) Analysis of accounting risk based on derivative financial instruments 1,a Gao Lin 1 Qingdao Vocational and Technical College

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

Liquidity Regulation and Credit Booms: Theory and Evidence from China. JRCPPF Sixth Annual Conference February 16-17, 2017

Liquidity Regulation and Credit Booms: Theory and Evidence from China. JRCPPF Sixth Annual Conference February 16-17, 2017 Liquidity Regulation and Credit Booms: Theory and Evidence from China Kinda Hachem Chicago Booth and NBER Zheng Michael Song Chinese University of Hong Kong JRCPPF Sixth Annual Conference February 16-17,

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Is the Potential for International Diversification Disappearing? A Dynamic Copula Approach

Is the Potential for International Diversification Disappearing? A Dynamic Copula Approach Is the Potential for International Diversification Disappearing? A Dynamic Copula Approach Peter Christoffersen University of Toronto Vihang Errunza McGill University Kris Jacobs University of Houston

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. Market Reactions to Different Types of Information

Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. Market Reactions to Different Types of Information Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. This document contains the unpublished appendices for Daniel and Titman (006), Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data Nicolas Parent, Financial Markets Department It is now widely recognized that greater transparency facilitates the

More information

. Large-dimensional and multi-scale effects in stocks volatility m

. Large-dimensional and multi-scale effects in stocks volatility m Large-dimensional and multi-scale effects in stocks volatility modeling Swissquote bank, Quant Asset Management work done at: Chaire de finance quantitative, École Centrale Paris Capital Fund Management,

More information

Analyzing volatility shocks to Eurozone CDS spreads with a multicountry GMM model in Stata

Analyzing volatility shocks to Eurozone CDS spreads with a multicountry GMM model in Stata Analyzing volatility shocks to Eurozone CDS spreads with a multicountry GMM model in Stata Christopher F Baum and Paola Zerilli Boston College / DIW Berlin and University of York SUGUK 2016, London Christopher

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Black s Leverage Effect Is Not Due To Leverage

Black s Leverage Effect Is Not Due To Leverage Black s Leverage Effect Is Not Due To Leverage Jasmina Hasanhodzic and Andrew W. Lo This Draft: February 15, 2011 Abstract One of the most enduring empirical regularities in equity markets is the inverse

More information

Asymmetric and negative return-volatility relationship: The case of the VKOSPI. Qian Han, Biao Guo, Doojin Ryu and Robert I. Webb*

Asymmetric and negative return-volatility relationship: The case of the VKOSPI. Qian Han, Biao Guo, Doojin Ryu and Robert I. Webb* Asymmetric and negative return-volatility relationship: The case of the VKOSPI Qian Han, Biao Guo, Doojin Ryu and Robert I. Webb* *Xiamen University (Wang Yanan Institute for Studies in Economics), University

More information

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2 Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO September 25, 2015 A Brief Look at General Equilibrium Asset Pricing Last week, we saw a general equilibrium model in which banks were irrelevant.

More information

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2014 Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Courtney D. Winn Utah State University Follow this

More information

WHERE HAS ALL THE BIG DATA GONE?

WHERE HAS ALL THE BIG DATA GONE? WHERE HAS ALL THE BIG DATA GONE? Maryam Farboodi Princeton Adrien Matray Princeton Laura Veldkamp NYU Stern School of Business 2018 MOTIVATION Increase in big data in financial sector 1. data processing

More information

Quantitative Risk Management

Quantitative Risk Management Quantitative Risk Management Asset Allocation and Risk Management Martin B. Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Outline Review of Mean-Variance Analysis

More information

Short-selling constraints and stock-return volatility: empirical evidence from the German stock market

Short-selling constraints and stock-return volatility: empirical evidence from the German stock market Short-selling constraints and stock-return volatility: empirical evidence from the German stock market Martin Bohl, Gerrit Reher, Bernd Wilfling Westfälische Wilhelms-Universität Münster Contents 1. Introduction

More information

The Conditional Relationship between Risk and Return: Evidence from an Emerging Market

The Conditional Relationship between Risk and Return: Evidence from an Emerging Market Pak. j. eng. technol. sci. Volume 4, No 1, 2014, 13-27 ISSN: 2222-9930 print ISSN: 2224-2333 online The Conditional Relationship between Risk and Return: Evidence from an Emerging Market Sara Azher* Received

More information

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note* Yin-Wong Cheung University of California, U.S.A. Frank Westermann University of Munich, Germany Daily data from the German and

More information

Evaluating Combined Forecasts for Realized Volatility Using Asymmetric Loss Functions

Evaluating Combined Forecasts for Realized Volatility Using Asymmetric Loss Functions Econometric Research in Finance Vol. 2 99 Evaluating Combined Forecasts for Realized Volatility Using Asymmetric Loss Functions Giovanni De Luca, Giampiero M. Gallo, and Danilo Carità Università degli

More information

Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models for Strategic Asset Allocation

Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models for Strategic Asset Allocation Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models for Strategic Asset Allocation Jared Fisher Carlos Carvalho, The University of Texas Davide Pettenuzzo, Brandeis University April 18, 2016 Fisher (UT) Bayesian Risk Prediction

More information

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market Bin Liu School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT University, Australia Amalia Di Iorio Faculty of Business,

More information

Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach

Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach 1 Faculty of Economics, Chuo University, Tokyo, Japan Chikashi Tsuji 1 Correspondence: Chikashi Tsuji, Professor, Faculty

More information