The effect of free trade agreements revisited: Does residual trade cost bias matter?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The effect of free trade agreements revisited: Does residual trade cost bias matter?"

Transcription

1 Received: 12 October 2017 Revised: 14 July 2018 DOI: /roie Accepted: 22 August 2018 ORIGINAL ARTICLE The effect of free trade agreements revisited: Does residual trade cost bias matter? Paras Kharel South Asia Watch on Trade, Economics and Environment (SAWTEE), Kathmandu, Nepal Correspondence Paras Kharel, South Asia Watch on Trade, Economics and Environment (SAWTEE), Baluwatar, Kathmandu, Nepal. JEL Classification C23, F13, F14, F15 Abstract This paper revisits a prominent gravity model based empirical literature on the effects of free trade agreements by accounting for a potential bias caused by unobservable trade costs that operate through general equilibrium constraints. It embeds state of the art panel estimation techniques in a recently proposed two step remedy that features a constrained ANOVA type estimation. Using a dataset on manufacturing trade flows in eight sectors in 40 countries and a rest of the world aggregate for the period , it finds evidence of significant residual trade cost bias. The direction and magnitude of bias vary across sectors, with the standard one step approach used in the literature overestimating or underestimating the partial effect of free trade agreements by up to 110 percent. Overall, coefficients on trade costs variables are jointly significantly different between the standard method and the twostep method. The biases in partial effect estimates translate into biases in general equilibrium effects. 1 INTRODUCTION There has long been an interest among economists and policymakers alike in the effect of regional trade agreements, or free trade agreements (FTAs), on trade. The proliferation of such agreements since the early 1990s gave an impetus to empirical investigations. 1 As trade agreements continue to be negotiated, interest in the subject is likely to sustain. The gravity model is the go to method for ex post quantification of FTAs. FTA membership is one of the very few available observable proxies for trade costs in a gravity equation that is naturally at the bilateral level, varies across bilateral pairs, exhibits some variation over time and, importantly, is reflective of trade policy. Rev Int Ecom. 2019;27: wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 367

2 368 KHAREL A key concern in estimating the trade effects of FTAs is endogeneity. A traditional source of endogeneity is selection: the existence of unobservables that influence both the signing of FTAs and trade flows, and the possibility of reverse causality (e.g., country pairs that have a high level of trade may be entering into FTAs). The literature on the determinants of FTA formation provides robust evidence of the endogeneity of FTAs to trade flows for example, Baier and Bergstrand (2004), Magee (2003), Baier, Bergstrand, and Mariutto (2014b) and Bergstrand, Egger, and Larch (2016). A number of methods have been employed in the literature to deal with such endogeneity concerns. One approach is to use instrumental variables (IVs). A challenge this approach faces is to find a valid instrument, that is, a variable that is not only strongly related to the FTA variable but affects the outcome of interest only through the FTA variable. To avoid relying solely on functional form for identification in their non linear model, Egger, Larch, Staub, and Winkelmann (2011), for example, use as instruments three dummies denoting whether a country pair has ever had a common colonizer, has ever been in a colonial relationship and has ever been part of the same country. Another route is to use matching econometrics, as used by, among others, Baier and Bergstrand (2009a) and Egger, Egger, and Greenaway (2008). Matching methods assume selection on observables. A third approach is the use of panel data econometrics. Exploiting panel data on trade flows and FTA formation, papers in this mold use country pair fixed effects to account for pair level selection into FTAs, assuming that time varying bilateral unobserved heterogeneity is orthogonal to the FTA variable. Since Baier and Bergstrand (2007), there has been a wave of empirical studies on the trade effects of FTAs using the panel estimation approach for example, Eicher and Henn (2011), Behar and Cirera i Crivillé (2013), Dahi and Demir (2013), Baier, Bergstrand, and Feng (2014a), Bergstrand, Larch, and Yotov (2015) and Anderson and Yotov (2016) making it the most established method in this line of literature. A common finding is that FTAs do increase trade substantially, albeit with heterogeneous effects. Although a variety of methods have been brought to bear on the selection issues around the age old topic of FTA trade relationship, an additional source of endogeneity remains ignored. It arises from the general equilibrium structure of the gravity model, as demonstrated in Egger and Nigai (2015). In this paper, I show that ignoring this endogeneity substantially biases the effect of FTAs on trade. To understand the source of this bias, first note that the error term in a panel gravity equation can be decomposed as a sum of (i) bilateral country pair fixed effects, which capture pair specific timeinvariant heterogeneity, including time invariant bilateral trade costs; (ii) importer year fixed effects; (iii) exporter year fixed effects; and (iv) residual or unobserved trade costs. The inclusion of pair fixed effects speaks to the traditional endogeneity of FTAs discussed earlier, while the use of exporter year and importer year fixed effects controls for multilateral resistance and other country time specific factors. 2 As Egger and Nigai (2015) show, the country time specific factors are themselves endogenous to residual trade costs. In a general gravity context, this endogeneity arises from the market clearing general equilibrium structure underlying a gravity equation. Just as general equilibrium linkages yield the now well appreciated importance of multilateral resistance, the same linkages also imply that the country time specific factors are a function of, inter alia, residual trade costs. Egger and Nigai (2015) demonstrate that this leads to biased estimates of total bilateral trade costs, country specific effects and the partial effects of observable trade cost measures, while also biasing general equilibrium consistent comparative statics. They suggest a two step remedy to this problem: first obtain unbiased measures of total trade costs from a constrained ANOVA type (CANOVA) estimation of the gravity model 3 and then decompose them into their individual observable components. To what extent residual trade cost bias is reflected in estimates of FTA effects arguably the most prominent policy effect analyzed with a gravity model is the primary empirical question that I attempt to answer. In their empirical illustration, Egger and Nigai (2015) take a balanced sample of manufacturing trade flows in 31 OECD countries for the year 2005 and compare the estimates from

3 KHAREL 369 a standard, single step gravity equation with those from the proposed two step method. They find differences between the two sets of point estimates but do not formally test for statistical significance. Crucially, they do not tackle the usual endogeneity concern associated with estimating FTA impacts, as it is not their focus. Therefore, the empirical relevance of residual trade cost bias emphasized in Egger and Nigai (2015) merits further investigation in the context of FTAs. To do so, I estimate the partial effects of FTAs using panel data techniques, as in Bergstrand et al. (2015), but embed them in the two step CANOVA approach of Egger and Nigai (2015). The dataset, from Bergstrand et al. (2015), covers manufactures trade in eight sectors in 40 countries (OECD and some developing countries) and a rest of the world (RoW) aggregate for the years 1990, 1994, 1998, and The CANOVA method of obtaining unbiased total trade costs in the first step can be readily applied as the data include intranational trade flows. The panel structure of the data, coupled with the availability of intranational trade flows, enabled Bergstrand et al. (2015) to additionally assess the effects of international borders (the border effect ) and bilateral distance (the distance elasticity puzzle ) over time. I assess these also using the CANOVA approach. Additionally, I quantify how differences in partial equilibrium effects of trade costs (including but not limited to FTA formation) between the two methods translate into differences in general equilibrium (GE) effects. Comparing the results of the two step CANOVA approach with the standard panel technique based approach as in Bergstrand et al. (2015), which I dub the one step approach, I find evidence that the one step approach overestimates the partial effects of FTAs that entered into force during in overall manufactures by 31.6 percentage points (or 57 percent). At the sectoral level, I uncover heterogeneity across sectors in terms of the importance of residual trade cost bias when estimating the total, partial effects of FTAs. 4 More broadly, coefficients on trade cost variables FTA dummies (current and lagged), time interacted standard gravity covariates, time interacted international border dummies and time invariant bilateral trade costs captured by pair fixed effects are jointly significantly different between the two methods. Correlations between unobservable trade costs and country specific fixed effects provide additional evidence of residual trade cost bias. The two step method also confirms Bergstrand et al. s (2015) finding, based on the one step method, of the decline in the effect of the international border and of distance. While the GE effects of changes in trade costs, which account for changes in multilateral resistance and endogenous changes in incomes, being muted relative to partial effects is well recognized in the literature (see, e.g., Head & Meyer, 2014), it is not a priori clear how the differences in the partial estimates obtained from the one step standard method and the two step CANOVA approach play out when fed into the system of non linear equations representing structural gravity. I find that differences in partial effect estimates translate into non trivial differences in GE effects. In a globalization experiment, the difference in magnitude is on the order of a third for the entire world. Interestingly, the sign of the difference depends on the type of globalization considered. CANOVA estimates deliver lower GE effects than one step estimates when only the effect of FTA formation during is considered, and higher GE effects when broader globalization, inclusive of the declining effect of the international border and standard gravity covariates, is considered. This paper contributes to the empirical literature on the quantification of the trade effects of FTAs by accounting for a recently highlighted endogeneity in structural gravity estimation. 5 In a focused policy relevant empirical application of the CANOVA method developed in Egger and Nigai (2015), my results indicate that residual trade cost bias may be important for particular sectors in quantifying the trade effects of FTAs. Methodologically, to my knowledge this is the first paper that combines well established panel estimation techniques with the two step CANOVA method. 6 Baier and Bergstrand (2007) made it de rigueur to use pair fixed effects to account for the endogeneity of FTAs in a panel setting. Bergstrand et al. (2015), using panel data inclusive of intranational trade flows,

4 370 KHAREL emphasize the importance of including (time interacted) international border dummies in addition to pair fixed effects to get more reliable estimates of FTA effects. My findings are supportive of a case for embedding state of the art panel gravity estimation techniques that include international border dummies and pair fixed effects in a two step CANOVA approach to improve the reliability of the estimates. Additionally, this paper shows that the residual trade cost bias in partial effect estimates extends to general equilibrium effects based on those partial estimates. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the methodology and the data. Section 3 presents the results. Section 4 concludes. 2 ESTIMATION TECHNIQUES AND ISSUES I embed the panel data gravity techniques used in Bergstrand et al. (2015) in the two step CANOVA approach of Egger and Nigai (2015). I first describe the panel techniques, and briefly discuss the data. I then explain residual trade cost bias, followed by an explanation of the CANOVA approach and a combination of the techniques. 2.1 Panel estimation techniques Bergstrand et al. (2015) estimate the following gravity equation: [ ] X = exp β 0 +FTA β 1 +INTER β 2 +GRAV β 3 +μ i,t +ζ j,t +φ ij +u (1) with i, j = 1, , t = 1990, 1994, 1998, where X is exports from country j to country i in year t; FTA is a vector of dummy variables capturing the current and lagged presence of an economic integration agreement between i and j in year t 7 ; INTER is a vector of the product of a year dummy (for 1994, 1998 or 2002, with 1990 as base year) and a time invariant binary variable, INTERNATIONAL ij, which takes the value 1 if i = j and 0 otherwise; GRAV is a vector of standard gravity variables (log of distance, contiguity, colonial relationship and common language) interacted with year dummies; μ i,t is an importer year fixed effect; ζ j,t is an exporter year fixed effect; φ ij is a bilateral (country pair) fixed effect 8 ; and u is an error. 9 Bergstrand et al. (2015) also interact the bilateral fixed effect, φ ij, with a time trend but find that the results are unaffected and hence focus their analysis on Equation (1). 10 Adding up the coefficients on all FTA dummies gives an estimate of the total partial effect of FTAs that came into effect during ,12 All data are from Bergstrand et al. (2015). 13 There are 40 countries and one RoW aggregate. Years span from 1990 through 2002, in four year intervals. Trade flows (international and intranational) are available for total manufactures and eight 2 digit ISIC sectors: food, textiles, wood, paper, chemicals, minerals, metals, and machinery. Table 1 provides some summary statistics of variables used in the estimation of Equation (1). A key reason for using this dataset is that it contains intranational trade flows in a sample that also includes non OECD countries. Data on intranational trade flows are a prerequisite to CANOVA estimation, while the presence of non OECD countries adds to the cross sectional and time variation in FTA, otherwise limited when using only an OECD sample. The sectoral disaggregation, albeit limited, is another attractive feature. In short, to my knowledge, this is the best available data for the research question at hand. 14

5 KHAREL 371 Equation (1) is estimated by Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood (PPML) with standard errors clustered by country pair. Variants of the equation are also estimated with different combinations of regressors. Bergstrand et al. (2015) also estimate the model with OLS, but they prefer PPML estimation as it accounts for heteroskedasticity bias (Santos Silva & Tenreyro, 2006, 2011). 15 Bergstrand et al. (2015) summarize the key features of their preferred specification thus: exporterand importer year fixed effects that account for multilateral resistance and other time varying importer and exporter unobservables; country pair fixed effects or country pair fixed effects interacted with a time trend to account for unobserved time invariant or time varying bilateral effects, including pair specific initial border effect levels; international border dummies that account for possible average declining international relative to intranational bilateral trade costs; and PPML estimation to account for heteroskedasticity bias and zero flows. 2.2 Residual trade cost bias Notice that in Equation (1), where the trade costs are parameterized, the unobservable trade costs are partly captured by the pair fixed effects (φ ij ) and international border dummies (INTER ij, t ), but other time varying unobserved trade costs remain unmeasured, residual trade costs, absorbed into the error term. The latter cannot be avoided even by interacting the pair fixed effect with a trend. The pair fixed effect does not capture year specific asymmetric bilateral trade costs, for example. Even if the time varying unobserved trade costs were uncorrelated with the observed trade cost proxies, the total TABLE 1 Summary statistics Mean SD Min Max Trade flows, in billion US$ Total manufactures , Food Textiles Wood Paper Chemicals Minerals Metals Machinery , FTA t FTA t FTA t FTA t FTA t DIST*Year CNTG*Year LANG*Year CLNY*Year INTER*Year Notes. No. of observations = 6724.

6 372 KHAREL trade cost estimates as well as the partial effect estimates would still be biased since the unmeasured trade costs would still be correlated with the exporter and importer specific variables (fixed effects) through general equilibrium constraints. 16 This is the key insight from Egger and Nigai (2015). Let s clarify it further, drawing on Egger and Nigai (2015). In a typical gravity framework, on which Equation (1) is based, bilateral imports of country i from j at time t can be expressed as: X = exp(ζ j,t +δ +μ it ), (2) where δ represents country pair time specific trade costs and ζ j,t and μ i,t are, respectively, exportertime and importer time specific variables. δ can be interpreted as δ σ ln τ where τ is ad valorem trade costs, and σ<0 is the partial effect of bilateral trade costs or trade elasticity. ζ j,t and μ i,t are implicit functions of bilateral trade costs through the resource constraint (with deficit parameter D j,t ): J J X = X ji,t +D j,t. i=1 i=1 (3) The structural country time parameters can be expressed as: exp ( ζ j,t ) = J i=1 exp ( ζ i,t +δ ji,t +μ j,t ) +Dj,t J i=1 exp(δ +μ i,t ), exp ( J ) j=1 μ exp ( ) ζi,t +δ ji,t +μ j,t Di,t i,t = J j=1 exp(δ +ζ j,t ). (4) Empirical specifications, such as Equation (1), typically decompose δ as: K δ = o +u = β k o k, +u, k=1 (5) where o is a parameterized observable component, u is an unobservable component, and K denotes the number of observables behind o. To illustrate, in Equation (1), o = FTA β 1 +INTER β 2 +GRAV β 3 +φ ij.17 Equation (2) is then expressed as: X = exp ( ζ j,t +o +μ i,t +u ). (6) This can be rewritten as: X = exp ( ζ j,t +o +μ i,t ) exp(u ), (7) and country specific terms are either solved iteratively as implicit functions of o or estimated as fixed effects. PPML estimation of Equation (6) is based on the assumption: E [ exp ( u ) ζj,t,o k,,μ i,t ] = 1, or E [ exp ( u ) 1 ζj,t,o k,,μ i,t ] = 0 As Egger and Nigai (2015) point out, it is clear from the GE constraints in (4) that the country specific terms are not independent of residual trade costs. Hence, E [ exp ( u ) 1 ζj,t ] 0 and

7 KHAREL 373 E[exp(u ) 1 μ i,t ] 0, thereby biasing the estimates of ζ j,t, μ i,t and δ. As a result, comparative static exercises are also biased (e.g., gauging the contribution of trade costs to changes in trade flows). They further show that estimates of the partial effects, β k, are biased. The independence of an observable trade cost measure from unobservable trade costs is not sufficient for estimating the partial effect of the measure without bias: it has to be independent also of the bias in the estimated country specific effects. The latter is not the case, due to the GE constraints in (4) (Egger and Nigai, 2015). 2.3 CANOVA approach I apply a remedy to the residual trade cost bias proposed by Egger and Nigai (2015) to the estimation of specification (1). The two step approach first involves obtaining unbiased estimates of trade costs δ through the CANOVA method. This method uses, for each period, J 2 observations on aggregate bilateral sales underlying Equation (2), of which 2J degrees of freedom are used by the constraints in Equation (4). As a result, J(J 2) values of δ ij are identifiable for each year. Intranational trade costs are normalized to zero (δ jj = 0) for each year. The δ ij s thus obtained are unbiased since all trade costs parameterized as well as residual are always treated jointly and properly accounted for (Egger and Nigai, 2015). 18 I obtain δ, separately for each t (1990, 1994, 1998, 2002), for aggregate manufacturing trade as well as for disaggregated manufacturing trade for eight 2 digit ISIC sectors. 19 The CANOVA method does not deliver finite values for δ when trade is zero. So I estimate a lower bound of trade costs for zero trade observations as the maximum (relative) level of trade costs obtained for country pairs with non zero trade flows. 20 Zero trade flows are not highly prevalent in the dataset: in total manufactures, the share of zero trade flows in the total number of observations is 1.3 percent, and at the sectoral level it is 5.8 percent (food), 4.5 percent (textile), 13 percent (wood), 12.4 percent (paper), 5.3 percent (chemicals), 11.5 percent (minerals), 13.4 percent (metals) and 3.2 percent (machinery). Reassuringly, excluding zero flows does not materially change the results of the paper, either at the aggregate level or the sectoral level. The second step decomposes δ into their individual components. In my application, I use exp(δ ) following Egger and Nigai (2015) in their empirical illustration as a dependent variable in Equation (1) and its variants, and estimate it by PPML. 21 The estimating equation in the CANOVA second step is thus: [ ] exp(δ ) = exp β 0 +FTA β 1 +INTER β 2 +GRAV β 3 +μ i,t +ζ j,t +φ ij +u. (8) I call direct estimation of (1) as done by Bergstrand et al. (2015) and which I also reproduce the one step approach, to contrast it with the CANOVA approach that involves two steps. Notice that while the use of the CANOVA based unbiased estimates of δ in the second step avoids the bias stemming from the correlation between observable trade costs and the bias in country specific structural parameters due to residual trade cost bias, the use of panel estimation techniques in the second step helps mitigate the usual endogeneity concerns applicable to FTAs; for example, selection of country pairs into FTAs. Table 2 provides summary statistics of the dependent variables used in the two approaches. Although the absolute levels of δ are not identified from the CANOVA approach, their relative level or variation is (Egger & Nigai, 2015). In a regression, it is the variation in δ that is exploited. If there were no residual trade cost bias, the two methods would yield similar estimates of the partial effects of observable trade costs. Estimation is done for total manufactures trade as well as for manufactures trade disaggregated into eight sectors. The difference between the coefficients from the two

8 374 KHAREL approaches is tested statistically in a seemingly unrelated estimation framework. This ensures that the test statistics have the correct size, by accounting for the possible dependence between the two sets of coefficients. 22 To understand why the coefficients from the second step in the CANOVA approach and from the one step approach can be compared although the dependent variables are different (exp ( ) δ vs X ), recall that δ σ ln τ, where τ is ad valorem trade costs. This implies that the dependent variable in the CANOVA second step is exp(δ ) = τ σ. For expositional purposes, let s consider a cross sectional setting and assume τ ij = d ρ ij bfta ij exp(uij ), where d ij is distance, u ij is unobserved trade costs, and ρ and b are parameters. It is standard to express a theory consistent multiplicative gravity equation as X ij = exp(σρln d ij +σ ln b FTA ij +μ i +ζ j +u ij ), (9) TABLE 2 Summary statistics of dependent variables Mean SD Min Max Total manufactures Trade , exp(δ) < Food Trade exp(δ) < Textiles Trade exp(δ) < Wood Trade exp(δ) < Paper Trade exp(δ) < Chemicals Trade exp(δ) < Minerals Trade exp(δ) < Metals Trade exp(δ) < Machinery Trade , exp(δ) < Notes. No. of observations = 6724; trade is in US$ billion. See section 2.3 for details about computation of δ.

9 KHAREL 375 to be estimated with PPML, where μ i and ζ j are importer and exporter specific fixed effects, measuring country specific factors influencing trade, including multilateral resistance. This is the estimating equation in the one step approach. To get the estimating equation for the CANOVA second step, first use the definition of the ad valorem trade cost: τ ij = d ρ ( ) ( ) ij bfta ij exp uij = exp [ln d ρ ij bfta ij exp ( ) ] u ij = exp(ρ ln d ij +ln b FTA ij +u ij ). τ σ = exp(σρln d ij +σ ln b FTA ij +u ij ), where, with a slight abuse of notation, u ij also absorbs the multiplicative elasticity parameter. We can decompose the unmeasured trade cost, u ij, as u ij = ũ i +ũ j +ũ ij, where ũ i and ũ j can be captured by importer and exporter specific fixed effects. We now have the estimating equation for the CANOVA second step: exp(δ ij ) τ σ = exp(σρln d ij +σ ln b FTA ij +ũ i +ũ j +ũ ij ), (10) Clearly, the coefficients on log of distance and FTA are measuring the same object in the two approaches (Equations (9) and (10)). Under both methods, they represent the elasticity of ad valorem trade costs with respect to observable trade costs multiplied by the elasticity of trade flows with respect to ad valorem trade costs. 3 RESULTS 3.1 Partial equilibrium Focusing on the partial estimates, I first present broad similarities between the findings from the single step method as used in Bergstrand et al. (2015) and the two step CANOVA method. Including time varying international border variables reduces the total partial effect of FTA by over a half. There is a declining effect of the international border between 1990 and In specifications that include interactions of year dummies with the log of distance, a common language dummy, a contiguity dummy and a colonial relationship dummy, in addition to the time varying international border variables, these standard gravity covariates have mostly no significant effect on trade flows. There is a decline in the trade reducing effect of distance over time in general mirroring a fall in bilateral fixed and variable costs. 23 Online Appendix Tables A1 A14 present detailed results from the two approaches. Now let s focus on the total, partial effects of FTA obtained from the two methods. Table 3 provides a summary by comparing the total, partial effects of FTA obtained from the two approaches across different specifications, along with statistical tests of difference. 24 In specifications that have neither the border variable nor standard gravity covariates (panel 1), the differences in the estimates from the two methods are statistically significant for total manufactures, textiles, wood, paper, minerals, and metals. The one step method overestimates in total manufactures (by 41 percentage points or 35 percent), textiles (226 percentage points or 119 percent), minerals (23 percentage points or 80 percent) and metals (65 percentage points or 61 percent), and underestimates in wood (36 percentage points or 65 percent) and paper (53 percentage points or 56 percent). When one throws in the border

10 376 KHAREL variables (panel 2), the statistical significance of the difference between the two sets of estimates of FTA effects disappears for all but two sectors: textiles and paper, with the direction of bias as before. Theoretically, the differences between the estimates from the one step approach and the CANOVA approach arise from the failure of the one step approach to account for all trade costs, a problem avoided by the CANOVA approach in the first stage estimation of trade costs where all trade costs are fully and jointly accounted for. The inclusion of the border variables, by capturing changes in international relative to intranational trade costs that are otherwise unobserved, seems to mitigate this problem for total manufactures and all sectors except textiles and paper. This suggests that the inclusion of border variables is not sufficient enough to address residual trade cost bias in the latter two sectors. In specifications that include both the border variables and standard gravity covariates (panel 3) that is, the full specification as used in Bergstrand et al. (2015) the total, partial FTA estimates from the two approaches are statistically different for in addition to textiles and paper total manufactures (overestimation), chemicals (overestimation) and machinery (overestimation). In specifications that exclude the border variables but include standard gravity covariates (panel 4), the differences are statistically significant for total manufactures and chemicals, besides textiles and paper. The estimates of the coefficient on INTER 2002 (see Appendix Tables A5 A12), which captures the changes in the effect of the international border between 1990 and 2002, are not robustly statistically different between the two methods across different specifications, suggesting residual trade cost bias may not be affecting estimates of the declining effect of the international border. 25 While both sets of results show a declining effect of distance (see Appendix Tables A13 A14), they are not statistically different for total manufactures and most sectors barring wood, minerals and metals. 26 In the wood sector, the one step method shows no decline in the negative distance effect whereas the two step method delivers a decline in the negative distance effect of 10.6 percent over 12 years, or 0.93 percent per year. In minerals, the two step method shows no decline, whereas the one step method indicates a decline of 5.2 percent over 12 years, or 0.44 percent per year. In metals, the two step method shows no decline, whereas the one step method delivers a decline of 11.4 percent over 12 years, or 1 percent per year. What do the residual trade costs represent? They capture, for example, bilateral asymmetric trade costs that vary over time, ranging from non tariff measures to transport costs, some of which may differ across sectors and also result from agreement specific features. Because residual trade cost bias arises from non linear general equilibrium constraints, which make exporter( time) and importer( time) specific factors functions of residual trade costs, it is not straightforward to pin down the direction of bias a priori. Investigating the exact forces that drive these biases, which differ in direction and magnitude across sectors, is left for future work. 3.2 Testing differences in multiple trade cost variables I also test whether the coefficient estimates on different trade cost measures are jointly significantly different between the two approaches. The rationale for the joint tests is that statistical (in)significance in the difference between the effects of individual trade cost measures need not imply statistical (in) significance in the difference between their joint effects. The idea, therefore, is to gauge whether various trade cost variables jointly exert statistically different effects on trade flows across the two methods. To illustrate, the null hypothesis for the joint tests is H o :TC One-step = TC CANOVA, where TC is a vector of estimated coefficients on trade cost measures considered. I consider the full specification that includes border variables as well as standard gravity covariates. The p values of the tests are presented in Table 4. The first panel refers to the joint test of FTA dummies. 27 The p values indicate that the FTA dummies are jointly significantly different between the

11 KHAREL 377 TABLE 3 Comparison of estimates of total, partial FTA effects from one step and CANOVA approaches Total Food Textiles Wood Paper Chem. Minerals Metals Machin. No border, no gravity vars One step CANOVA p val < Difference in % points Difference in percentage With border, no gravity vars One step CANOVA p val Difference in % points Difference in percentage With border, gravity vars One step CANOVA p val Difference in % points Difference in percentage (Continues)

12 378 KHAREL TABLE 3 (Continued) Total Food Textiles Wood Paper Chem. Minerals Metals Machin. With gravity vars, no border One step CANOVA p val Difference in % points Difference in percentage a Notes: One step and CANOVA are the sum of coefficients on current and lagged FTA dummies from respective estimations: Equations (1) and (8). Full estimation results are in the Appendix: Panel 1 is based on Tables A1 A4; Panel 2 on Tables A5 A8; Panel 3 on Tables A9 A12; Panel 4 on Tables A13 A14. b+ p value of test of difference of one step and CANOVA total, partial effect estimates. c++ [exp(one step) 1] 100 [exp(canova) 1] 100. d *[{[exp(one step) 1]/ [exp(canova) 1]} 1].

13 KHAREL 379 two approaches for total manufactures, wood, paper, chemicals, minerals, and machinery. The second panel indicates that the FTA dummies, border variables and all standard gravity covariates are jointly significantly different between the two methods for total manufactures as well as all sectors. The third panel refers to the joint test of total FTA effect (instead of individual FTA dummies), border variables and all standard gravity covariates. The differences are jointly statistically significant for all sectors but paper. The fourth panel tells us that the bilateral pair fixed effects, which capture time invariant bilateral trade costs, are jointly significantly different for total manufactures and all sectors between the two methods. The fifth panel indicates that, for total manufactures and all sectors, the pair fixed effects, FTA dummies, border variables and all standard gravity covariates are jointly significantly different between the two methods. The last panel suggests that, for total manufactures and all sectors, the pair fixed effects, total FTA effect, border variables, and all standard gravity covariates are jointly significantly different between the two methods. 3.3 Another test of importance of residual trade cost bias The analysis above operated on the logic that significant differences between the partial estimates obtained from the two methods indicate residual trade cost bias. Since, theoretically, residual trade cost bias in the usual one step method arises from the linkages between residual trade costs and countryspecific effects, another way to gauge this endogeneity is to look at the associations between residual trade costs and exporter year and importer year fixed effects. Recall the estimating equation from the one step method (Equation (7): X = exp ( ζ j,t +o +μ i,t ) exp(u ). In our sample, we test the following conditions: [ ( ) COV exp [ ( COV exp û CANOVA û CANOVA ] 1, ζ One-step = 0 and j,t ) ] 1,û One-step = 0. i,t (11) TABLE 4 P values of joint test of significance of differences between one step and CANOVA estimates Total Food Text. Wood Paper Chem. Minerals Metals Machin. FTA dummies < < FTA dummies, border variables, and all other gravity variables < <0.001 <0.001 < < <0.001 Total FTA effect, border variables, and all other gravity variables < <0.001 < <0.001 Pair fixed effects <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 Pair fixed effects, FTA dummies, border variables, and all other gravity variables <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 Pair fixed effects, total FTA effect, border variables, and all other gravity variables <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001

14 380 KHAREL A violation of any of these conditions implies that exp ( u ) 1 is not independent of ζj,t and μ i,t, which is the population moment condition discussed in Section 2.2. The conditions in (11) can be tested as we can obtain estimates of residual trade costs, u, from the CANOVA approach. More precisely, one can obtain estimates of residual trade costs using Equation (5): û CANOVA = δ CANOVA ô CANOVA, where ô CANOVA = FTA β CANOVA +INTER 1 β CANOVA +GRAV 2 β CANOVA + φ CANOVA 3 ij Note that δ CANOVA is obtained from CANOVA first stage and ô CANOVA from CANOVA second stage. Notice that φ CANOVA, the estimated pair fixed effects, are part and parcel of the observed trade ij costs in our model since they capture all time invariant symmetric bilateral trade costs, including initial border [ effects. ( ) ] [ ( ) ] COV exp û CANOVA 1, ζ One-step 0 and/or COV exp û CANOVA 1,û One-step 0 would imply j,t i,t that the fixed effects are endogenous to residual trade costs. Table 5 shows the coefficients of these correlations, as well as between û CANOVA and ζ One-step and between û CANOVA and μ One-step. Focusing on ( ) j,t i,t the correlation between exp û CANOVA 1 and the fixed effects, we see that it is highly statistically significant with respect to the exporter fixed effect ( ζ One-step ), with coefficients ranging from 0.12 for j,t wood to 0.26 for total manufacturing to 0.32 for food. The correlation with respect to the importer fixed effect ( μ One-step ) is negative and statistically significant for total manufacturing and all sectors, i,t but weaker compared to the correlation with respect to the exporter fixed effect. Overall, these correlations provide further evidence of residual trade cost bias in total manufacturing as well as in almost every sector. 3.4 General equilibrium Given that the coefficients on all trade cost variables are jointly significantly different between the two methods for total manufactures, it is interesting to investigate the implications of these differences in partial effect estimates for the general equilibrium (GE) effects of globalization. Partial estimates of trade cost effects do not incorporate the changes in multilateral resistance and endogenous changes in income triggered by a change in trade cost. The need to do so is increasingly recognized in the gravity literature (see Head & Mayer, 2014). The GE consistent counterfactual analysis in Egger and Nigai (2015) seeks to gauge the contribution of changes in total trade costs to changes in observed trade flows between two periods (t 1 and t 2 ), whereby the change in total trade costs is given by Δδ ij = δ 1 δ 2. In contrast, the aim here is to quantify the effect of a change in an observable trade cost variable (e.g., FTA formation) on trade flows, which necessitates the use of a parameterized trade cost function for counterfactual analysis. 28 The idea is to ascertain to what extent differences in the partial estimates obtained from the onestep standard method and the two step CANOVA method yield different GE effects when these estimates are fed into the system of non linear equations representing structural gravity. Consequently, I follow a standard approach based on an endowment economy trade model (as described in Head and Mayer, 2014) 29 in computing two measures of GE effects using one step and CANOVA estimates separately: the modular trade impact (MTI) that accounts for changes in multilateral resistance (MR) but ignores changes in incomes; and the general equilibrium trade impact (GETI) that accounts for changes in both MR and incomes. 30 While the details of MTI and GETI computation are described

15 KHAREL 381 TABLE 5 Correlations between residual trade costs and exporter, importer fixed effects Total Food Textiles ζ One-step j,t μ One-step i,t ζ One-step j,t μ One-step i,t û CANOVA exp(û CANOVA ) 1 û CANOVA exp(û CANOVA ) 1 û CANOVA Wood Paper Chemicals û CANOVA exp(û CANOVA ) 1 û CANOVA exp(û CANOVA ) 1 û CANOVA Minerals Metals Machinery exp(û CANOVA ) 1 exp(û CANOVA ) 1 ζ One-step j,t μ One-step i,t û CANOVA exp(û CANOVA ) 1 û CANOVA exp(û CANOVA ) 1 û CANOVA Notes. All correlations are significant at 1% level. See text for details. exp(û CANOVA ) 1 in Head and Mayer (2014), an intuitive way to understand these measures is that they are the partial effect estimate multiplied by a factor representing changes in, respectively, MR and MR cum incomes induced by changes in trade costs. For a comparison with the analysis in Bergstrand et al. (2015), I also compute the so called partial trade impact (PTI) that potentially varies across countries but ignores changes in MR and incomes. 31 Globalization is defined in two ways, in the spirit of Bergstrand et al. (2015). First, the formation of FTAs between 1990 and Second, as in Bergstrand et al. (2015), the formation of FTAs between 1990 and 2002 and the changes in the effects of international borders and standard gravity covariates (distance, colonial relationship, language, and contiguity) observed during the same period. Under both definitions, observed trade costs are those prevailing in Under the first definition, the FTA variables are switched off in the counterfactual equilibrium, while bilateral pair fixed effects and time interacted international borders and standard gravity covariates are common to both observed and counterfactual equilibria. Under the second definition, the FTA variables and time interacted international borders and standard gravity covariates are switched off in the counterfactual equilibrium, while bilateral pair fixed effects are common to both observed and counterfactual equilibria. Tables 6 and 7 show the PTI, MTI and GETI for individual countries and RoW as well as (weighted) averages for three groups: the world, country pairs that have entered into an FTA and country pairs that have never entered into an FTA. The MTI and GETI are substantially lower than the PTI with both CANOVA and one step estimates under both counterfactual exercises (Tables 6 and 7). This is not surprising. We know since Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and, more recently, from Behar and Nelson (2014) that multilateral resistance serves to mute the effects of trade liberalization when carried out on a global scale. Of more relevance to our context, there are differences in the MTI and GETI resulting from the two sets of estimates. Interestingly, the sign of the differences depends on the definition of globalization employed. When only the effects of the formation of FTAs are considered, the PTI, MTI, and GETI all are lower when CANOVA partial estimates are used instead of one step partial estimates (Table 6). For example, the PTI, MTI, and GETI of FTA formation are lower in magnitude by a quarter to a third in the aggregate, whether considering the world as a whole,

16 382 KHAREL or country pairs that entered into FTAs, or country pairs that did not enter into FTAs. At the country level, all three measures are lower for most countries when based on CANOVA estimates. In contrast, when the broader definition of globalization is used (Table 7), all three measures are higher, for almost all countries, when computed with CANOVA estimates. When using CANOVA estimates, the MTI and GETI are higher by a third for the world as a whole, and higher by 50 percent for country pairs that did not enter into FTAs, although higher by barely 7 percent for country pairs that formed FTAs. An explanation for the difference in the results between the two types of globalization experiments is as follows: In the broader globalization experiment, both (i) FTA formations and (ii) changes in the effects of international borders and gravity covariates are happening, such that CANOVA partial estimates of the latter set of effects appear to be more than offsetting the lower CANOVA partial estimates of FTA formations alone. 33 The method of GETI computation yields as a by product, for each country i, the change in its share of expenditure on domestically produced goods, π ii, resulting from the change in trade costs. This and the trade elasticity parameter, σ, have been shown to be sufficient statistics for the calculation of gains from trade in a fairly broad class of quantitative trade models utilizing the gravity equation (Arkolakis et al., 2012; Costinot & Rodríguez Clare, 2014). Welfare associated with the formation of FTAs or globalization (inclusive of FTAs) in a one sector model, such as ours when we consider only 1 σ total manufactures, is given by a simple formula: π. Unlike trade effects, stark differences are not ii found between the welfare numbers computed using one step and CANOVA estimates, under either definition of globalization. For example, when only the effect of FTA formation is considered, the median welfare change for the world is percent and percent, respectively, with CANOVA and one step estimates. 34 When broader globalization is considered, the median welfare change for the world is percent with CANOVA estimates and percent with one step estimates. 35 An explanation for the modest differences in welfare change despite non trivial differences in the change in cross border trade could be the presence of an offsetting difference in the change in internal trade flows. Note that although internal trade costs are assumed zero, international trade cost changes affect not just cross border trade but also internal trade by changing relative trade costs. One must not, however, read too much into these welfare numbers. Simple as the welfare formula is, it assumes trade costs to be exclusively of the non revenue generating iceberg type, whereby welfare change is a function of terms of trade alone and changes in tariff revenue are not accounted for. An adjusted formula incorporates changes in tariff revenue (Costinot & Rodríguez Clare, 2014, p. 227), but data limitations preclude its use here CONCLUSION This paper revisits a prominent gravity model based empirical literature on the effects of FTAs by accounting for residual trade cost bias that standard gravity equations with parameterized trade cost functions ignore, as shown in Egger and Nigai (2015). I estimate the partial effects of FTAs using panel estimation techniques, as in Bergstrand et al. (2015), but embed them in the two step CANOVA approach proposed by Egger and Nigai (2015) to address a bias that would otherwise arise from the correlation of observable trade cost measures with the bias in country specific structural parameters. I find that the conventional one step approach overestimates or underestimates the total, partial effects of FTAs during by up to 110 percent. The importance of such residual trade cost bias varies across sectors. There is also evidence that coefficients on trade costs variables are jointly significantly different between the two methods. Correlations between unobservable trade costs and country specific fixed effects provide additional evidence of residual trade cost bias.

17 KHAREL 383 TABLE 6 GE effects of FTA formation (% change) One step CANOVA PTI MTI GETI Welfare PTI MTI GETI Welfare World a FTA b No FTA c Asia AUS CHN ISR JPN KOR TUR Europe AUT Latin America BGR BLX CHE DEU DNK ESP FIN FRA GBR GRC HUN IRL ISL ITA NLD NOR POL PRT ROM SWE ARG BOL BRA CHL COL CRI ECU MEX URY (Continues)

Do Customs Union Members Engage in More Bilateral Trade than Free-Trade Agreement Members?

Do Customs Union Members Engage in More Bilateral Trade than Free-Trade Agreement Members? Archived version from NCDOCKS Institutional Repository http://libres.uncg.edu/ir/asu/ Roy, J. (2010). Do customs union members engage in more bilateral trade than free-trade agreement members? Review of

More information

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I) 14.581 Week 13 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 13) Trade Policy Theory (I) Spring 2013 1 / 29 Trade Policy Literature A Brief Overview Key questions:

More information

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports 1 Thierry Mayer (Science Po, Banque de France) and Walter Steingress (Bank of Canada) BIS Workshop 1 The views expressed in this paper are

More information

OECD Workshop on effective corporate taxation. Corporate taxation on FDI; Kwang-Yeol. YOO, Korean Ministry of Finance. July.

OECD Workshop on effective corporate taxation. Corporate taxation on FDI; Kwang-Yeol. YOO, Korean Ministry of Finance. July. OECD Workshop on effective corporate taxation Corporate taxation on FDI; 1991-001 Kwang-Yeol YOO, Korean Ministry of Finance July.4th, 006 Table of contents I. How to measure tax burden on FDI II. Tax

More information

WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD)

WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD) WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD) Motivation: the Inclusive growth puzzle the top percentile managed to capture a very large

More information

Conference Presentation

Conference Presentation Conference Presentation Trade and long-term unemployment: A quantitative assessment CARRERE, Céline, ROBERT-NICOUD, Frédéric, GRUJOVIC, Anja Abstract We develop a multi-country, multi-sector, gravity model

More information

World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division

World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division WTO Working Paper ERSD-2016-10 Date: 19 July 2016 World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division ESTIMATING TRADE POLICY EFFECTS WITH STRUCTURAL GRAVITY Roberta Piermartini and Yoto

More information

Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment

Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment Céline Carrère Université de Genève and CEPR Anja Grujovic Université de Genève Frédéric Robert-Nicoud Université de Genève, SERC and CEPR July

More information

CHAPTER 1: Partial equilibrium trade policy analysis with structural gravity 1

CHAPTER 1: Partial equilibrium trade policy analysis with structural gravity 1 CHAPTER 1: Partial equilibrium trade policy analysis with structural gravity 1 CHAPTER 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS A. Overview and learning objectives 11 B. Analytical tools 12 1. Structural gravity: from theory

More information

Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence

Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence Scott L. Baier, Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Ronald Mariutto December 20, 2011 Abstract One of the most notable

More information

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Arvind Magesan and Jordi Mondria January 31, 2011 Abstract In this paper we study the economic and strategic incentives for a country to financially liberalize

More information

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle Sophie Gruber Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle James E. Anderson and Eric van Wincoop American Economic Review, March 2003, Vol. 93(1), pp. 170-192 Outline 1. McCallum s Gravity Equation

More information

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot Online Theory Appendix Not for Publication) Equilibrium in the Complements-Pareto Case

More information

The WTO Is Not Passé

The WTO Is Not Passé The WTO Is Not Passé Pushan Dutt * INSEAD Abstract The empirical literature on the effect of trade agreements on trade flows has reached a consensus that WTO effects are insignificant or modest at best,

More information

Measuring the Effects of Endogenous Policies on Economic Integration

Measuring the Effects of Endogenous Policies on Economic Integration CESifo Economic Studies, Vol. 59, 2/2013, 199 222 doi:10.1093/cesifo/ift004 Measuring the Effects of Endogenous Policies on Economic Integration Jeffrey H. Bergstrand Department of Finance, Mendoza College

More information

Gravity Redux: Structural Estimation of Gravity Equations with Asymmetric Bilateral Trade Costs

Gravity Redux: Structural Estimation of Gravity Equations with Asymmetric Bilateral Trade Costs Gravity Redux: Structural Estimation of Gravity Equations with Asymmetric Bilateral Trade Costs Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Peter Egger, and Mario Larch December 20, 2007 Abstract Theoretical foundations for

More information

Costs of Business Cycles Empirical Evidence

Costs of Business Cycles Empirical Evidence Costs of Business Cycles Empirical Evidence Petr Sedláček Bonn University Summer Term 2014 1 / 48 Background and some empirical evidence Seminal contribution by, Lucas (2003) Empirical evidence on the

More information

The Trade Effects of Endogenous Preferential Trade Agreements

The Trade Effects of Endogenous Preferential Trade Agreements The Trade Effects of Endogenous Preferential Trade Agreements Peter Egger, Mario Larch, Kevin E. Staub, and Rainer Winkelmann 24th March 2009 Abstract Recent work by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) establishes

More information

The Composition of Exports and Gravity

The Composition of Exports and Gravity The Composition of Exports and Gravity Scott French December, 2012 Version 3.0 Abstract Gravity estimations using aggregate bilateral trade data implicitly assume that the effect of trade barriers on trade

More information

The Cost of Non-Europe Revisited

The Cost of Non-Europe Revisited T.Mayer 1,2,3,4 V.Vicard 3 S.Zignago 2 1 Sciences-Po 2 Banque de France 3 CEPII 4 CEPR Compnet, Bruxelles, 29-30 June 2017 Motivation Why re-evaluate Costs of Non-Europe nearly 30 years after the Cecchini

More information

Peter Egger, Mario Larch, Kevin E. Staub and Rainer Winkelmann

Peter Egger, Mario Larch, Kevin E. Staub and Rainer Winkelmann The Trade Effects of Endogenous Preferential Trade Agreements Peter Egger, Mario Larch, Kevin E. Staub and Rainer Winkelmann CESifo GmbH Phone: +49 (0) 89 9224-1410 Poschingerstr. 5 Fax: +49 (0) 89 9224-1409

More information

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries Natalie Chen University of Warwick and CEPR Dennis Novy University of Warwick and CESifo Motivations Trade costs are a key feature in today

More information

THE UNEVEN ROLES OF FTAS: SELECTION EFFECT OR LEARNING EFFECT? Faqin Lin *

THE UNEVEN ROLES OF FTAS: SELECTION EFFECT OR LEARNING EFFECT? Faqin Lin * RAE REVIEW OF APPLIED ECONOMICS Vol. 8, No. 1, (January-June 2012) THE UNEVEN ROLES OF FTAS: SELECTION EFFECT OR LEARNING EFFECT? Faqin Lin * Abstract: Previous studies on the role of FTAs in promoting

More information

Global Production with Export Platforms

Global Production with Export Platforms Global Production with Export Platforms Felix Tintelnot University of Chicago and Princeton University (IES) ECO 552 February 19, 2014 Standard trade models Most trade models you have seen fix the location

More information

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports * Financial and the relationship-specificity of exports * Fabrice Defever Jens Suedekum a) University of Nottingham Center of Economic Performance (LSE) GEP and CESifo Mercator School of Management University

More information

Understanding the Downward Trend in Labor Income Shares

Understanding the Downward Trend in Labor Income Shares Understanding the Downward Trend in Labor Income Shares Mai Dao, Mitali Das (team lead), Zsoka Koczan and Weicheng Lian, 1 with contributions from Jihad Dagher and support from Ben Hilgenstock and Hao

More information

University of Pennsylvania & NBER. This paper reflects only the authors views, and not those of the IMF

University of Pennsylvania & NBER. This paper reflects only the authors views, and not those of the IMF An Anatomy of Credit Booms and their Demise Enrique G. Mendoza University of Pennsylvania & NBER Marco E. Terrones IMF This paper reflects only the authors views, and not those of the IMF Motivation and

More information

The Effects of Common Currencies on Trade

The Effects of Common Currencies on Trade The Effects of Common Currencies on Trade Countries select particular exchange rate arrangements for a variety of reasons. The ability to conduct an independent monetary policy is often cited as the main

More information

Online Appendix for Explaining Educational Attainment across Countries and over Time

Online Appendix for Explaining Educational Attainment across Countries and over Time Online Appendix for Explaining Educational Attainment across Countries and over Time Diego Restuccia University of Toronto Guillaume Vandenbroucke University of Southern California March 2014 Contents

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

SERVICES TRADE, REGULATION AND GVCS

SERVICES TRADE, REGULATION AND GVCS UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT MULTI-YEAR EXPERT MEETING ON TRADE, SERVICES AND DEVELOPMENT Geneva, 11 13 May 2015 SERVICES TRADE, REGULATION AND GVCS SESSION 2 Ms. Dorothée Rouzet

More information

Do Customs Union Members Indulge In More Bilateral Trade Than Free Trade Agreement Members?

Do Customs Union Members Indulge In More Bilateral Trade Than Free Trade Agreement Members? Do Customs Union Members Indulge In More Bilateral Trade Than Free Trade Agreement Members? Jayjit Roy * Abstract Fiorentino et al. (2007) question the popularity of customs unions (CUs) relative to that

More information

A gravity equation of bank loans

A gravity equation of bank loans Workshop on The Costs and Benefits of International Banking Eltville, 18 October 2011 Bettina Brüggemann University of Frankfurt Jörn Kleinert University of Graz Esteban Prieto University of Tübingen A

More information

Incidence of Social Security Contributions: Evidence from France

Incidence of Social Security Contributions: Evidence from France Incidence of Social Security Contributions: Evidence from France Antoine Bozio, Thomas Breda et Julien Grenet Paris School of Economics PSE Public and Labour Economics Seminar Paris, 15 September 2016

More information

Why is Japan s inward FDI so low?

Why is Japan s inward FDI so low? Why is Japan s inward FDI so low? Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research August 8, 2017 Japan s low level of inward foreign direct investment stock In May, it was reported

More information

CORPORATE TAX STATISTICS

CORPORATE TAX STATISTICS CORPORATE TAX STATISTICS Corporate Effective Tax Rates: Explanatory Annex (Annex applicable for corporate effective tax rates 2017) 1 Annex A. Explanatory Remarks Methodology, Exogenous Variables and Data

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables 34 Figure A.1: First Page of the Standard Layout 35 Figure A.2: Second Page of the Credit Card Statement 36 Figure A.3: First

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013 OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 213 CANADA HIGHLIGHTS Canada experienced a decline in business spending on R&D between 21 and 211, despite generous public support, mainly through tax incentives

More information

Introduction Intuitive Gravity Structural Gravity Discrete Choice Gravity. The Gravity Model. James E. Anderson. Boston College and NBER.

Introduction Intuitive Gravity Structural Gravity Discrete Choice Gravity. The Gravity Model. James E. Anderson. Boston College and NBER. The Gravity Model James E. Anderson Boston College and NBER March 2011 Outline Introduction Intuitive Gravity Size Effects Structural Gravity Differentiated Demand Differentiated Productivity Discrete

More information

Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies

Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies By Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi, Luis Felipe Cespedes, Alessandro Rebucci Bank of Canada and European Central

More information

An Analysis of the CSI Effect on the U.S. Trade (Draft)

An Analysis of the CSI Effect on the U.S. Trade (Draft) An Analysis of the CSI Effect on the U.S. Trade (Draft) Yuliya Shakurova and Irina Velea August 2011 Abstract This paper studies the effect of Container Security Initiative (CSI), a maritime trade security

More information

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013 Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak November 2013 Well known that policymakers face important tradeoffs between equity and efficiency in the design of the tax system The issue we address in this paper informs

More information

Global value networks 1

Global value networks 1 Global value networks 1 Carlo Altomonte, Italo Colantone, Armando Rungi and Tommaso Sonno Bocconi University; IMT Institute for Advanced Studies; Université Catholique de Louvain and LSE We study, at the

More information

A note on tax base, public debt, and investors beliefs. May Abstract

A note on tax base, public debt, and investors beliefs. May Abstract A note on tax base, public debt, and investors beliefs May 2011 Abstract This paper provides a new evidence and theoretical support for the role of market expectation in the public debt markets. Dispersion

More information

North South FDI and Bilateral Investment Treaties Rod Falvey and Neil Foster McGregor

North South FDI and Bilateral Investment Treaties Rod Falvey and Neil Foster McGregor Working Paper Series #2015-010 North South FDI and Bilateral Investment Treaties Rod Falvey and Neil Foster McGregor Maastricht Economic and social Research institute on Innovation and Technology (UNU

More information

What is the economic outlook for OECD countries?

What is the economic outlook for OECD countries? The outlook What is the economic outlook for OECD countries? Paul van den Noord Counselor to the Chief Economist The outlook Real GDP growth, in per cent.....9. -..9 Japan. -... Total OECD.... Brazil....

More information

ENDOGENEITY AND DYNAMICS IN THE IMPACT OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ON TRADE AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CRISTINA LIRA A DISSERTATION

ENDOGENEITY AND DYNAMICS IN THE IMPACT OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ON TRADE AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CRISTINA LIRA A DISSERTATION ENDOGENEITY AND DYNAMICS IN THE IMPACT OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS ON TRADE AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT by CRISTINA LIRA A DISSERTATION Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

More information

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS Bielefeld University phemelo.tamasiga@uni-bielefeld.de 01-July-2013 Agenda 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 6 Motivation Samuelson (1939);there are gains from trade, consequently

More information

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point A Web-Appendix A.1 Information on data sources Individual level responses on benefit morale, tax morale, age, sex, marital status, children, education (captured by the school leaving age), household income

More information

Bilateral Free Trade Agreements. How do Countries Choose Partners?

Bilateral Free Trade Agreements. How do Countries Choose Partners? Bilateral Free Trade Agreements How do Countries Choose Partners? Suresh Singh * Abstract While the debate on whether countries should or should not sign trade agreements with selected partners continues,

More information

Income inequality, tax base and sovereign spreads by Joshua Aizenman and Yothin Jinjarak

Income inequality, tax base and sovereign spreads by Joshua Aizenman and Yothin Jinjarak Income inequality, tax base and sovereign spreads by Joshua Aizenman and Yothin Jinjarak October 2011 This note investigates the impact of greater income inequality on the tax base, on the defacto fiscal

More information

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets René Garcia Edhec Business School, Université de Montréal, CIRANO and CIREQ Georges Tsafack Suffolk University Measuring

More information

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel Anca Cristea University of Oregon December 2010 Abstract This appendix

More information

Deregulation and Firm Investment

Deregulation and Firm Investment Policy Research Working Paper 7884 WPS7884 Deregulation and Firm Investment Evidence from the Dismantling of the License System in India Ivan T. andilov Aslı Leblebicioğlu Ruchita Manghnani Public Disclosure

More information

The European Union, the Euro, and Equity Market Integration

The European Union, the Euro, and Equity Market Integration The European Union, the Euro, and Equity Market Integration Geert Bekaert, Columbia University Campbell R. Harvey, Duke University Christian T. Lundblad, University of North Carolina Stephan Siegel, University

More information

G20 Finance and Central Bank Deputies Meeting February February, Structural Reform in a Crisis Environment.

G20 Finance and Central Bank Deputies Meeting February February, Structural Reform in a Crisis Environment. G20 Finance and Central Bank Deputies Meeting February 24-25 February, 2012 Structural Reform in a Crisis Environment Note by the OECD Structural reform is an essential ingredient to achieve sustainable

More information

The Cost of Non-Europe Revisited

The Cost of Non-Europe Revisited The Cost of Non-Europe Revisited Thierry Mayer Vincent Vicard Soledad Zignago January 21, 2018 STILL PRELIMINARY In this paper we quantify the Cost of Non-Europe, i.e. the trade-related welfare losses

More information

Essays on Trade, Inequality, and Gravity

Essays on Trade, Inequality, and Gravity Essays on Trade, Inequality, and Gravity by Eldar Sehic A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Economics University of Alberta

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach

Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach Osei-Agyeman Yeboah 1 Saleem Shaik 2 Victor Ofori-Boadu 1 Albert Allen 3 Shawn Wozniak 4

More information

Regionalism and Falling External Protection in High and Low Tariff Members

Regionalism and Falling External Protection in High and Low Tariff Members WPS 14-08-2 Working Paper Series Regionalism and Falling External Protection in High and Low Tariff Members Pramila Crivelli August 2014 Regionalism and Falling External Protection in High and Low Tariff

More information

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin June 15, 2008 Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The trade effect of the euro is typically

More information

MINIMUM WAGES ACROSS OECD COUNTRIES: BACK TO THE FUTURE?

MINIMUM WAGES ACROSS OECD COUNTRIES: BACK TO THE FUTURE? Paris, 20 October 2017 MINIMUM WAGES ACROSS OECD COUNTRIES: BACK TO THE FUTURE? Andrea Garnero Economist Employment, Labour and Social Affairs OECD A widespread (but heterogenous) wage setting institution

More information

Productivity and income differences in the 20 th century

Productivity and income differences in the 20 th century Productivity and income differences in the 20 th century Robert Inklaar and Daniel Gallardo Albarrán (University of Groningen) World KLEMS Conference, June 4 5 2018 Development accounting What can account

More information

Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide

Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Atif Mian, Amir Sufi, and Emil Verner Princeton University, University of Chicago, and Princeton University IMF Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference November

More information

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics PhD Topics in Macroeconomics Lecture 16: heterogeneous firms and trade, part four Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 214 1 This lecture Trade frictions in Ricardian models with heterogeneous firms 1- Dornbusch,

More information

Gravity, Distance, and International Trade

Gravity, Distance, and International Trade Gravity, Distance, and International Trade Scott L. Baier Amanda Kerr Yoto V. Yotov CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 6357 CATEGORY 8: TRADE POLICY FEBRUARY 2017 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Vitor Gaspar Director, Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund Peterson Institute for International Economics June 3, 15 Background The study draws on an

More information

The Effect of the Uruguay Round on the Intensive and Extensive Margins of Trade

The Effect of the Uruguay Round on the Intensive and Extensive Margins of Trade The Effect of the Uruguay Round on the Intensive and Extensive Margins of Trade Ines Buono Guy Lalanne First version: June 2008. This version: September 2009. Abstract Do tariffs inhibit trade flows by

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

The Impact of Free Trade Agreements on Foreign Direct Investment: Controlling for Endogeneity through a Dynamic Model Specification

The Impact of Free Trade Agreements on Foreign Direct Investment: Controlling for Endogeneity through a Dynamic Model Specification The Impact of Free Trade Agreements on Foreign Direct Investment: Controlling for Endogeneity through a Dynamic Model Specification Cristina Lira* Junsoo Lee Byung Ki Lee Robert Reed February 15, 2010

More information

An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry. December 19, Regulatory Induced Risk Aversion in. Contracting Behavior

An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry. December 19, Regulatory Induced Risk Aversion in. Contracting Behavior An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry December 19, 2011 The Puzzle Why do price-regulated firms purchase input coal through both contract Figure and 1(a): spot Contract transactions,

More information

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Results from Growth Curve Models of Manufacturing Share of Employment (MSE) To formally test trends in manufacturing share of

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

Credit Supply, Household Debt, and Business Cycles

Credit Supply, Household Debt, and Business Cycles Credit Supply, Household Debt, and Business Cycles Amir Sufi University of Chicago Booth School of Business; NBER; co-director of IGM February 2017 Big Picture Questions What is the source of macroeconomic

More information

Supporting information for. Mainstream or niche? Vote-seeking incentives and the programmatic strategies of political parties

Supporting information for. Mainstream or niche? Vote-seeking incentives and the programmatic strategies of political parties Supporting information for Mainstream or niche? Vote-seeking incentives and the programmatic strategies of political parties Thomas M. Meyer, University of Vienna Markus Wagner, University of Vienna In

More information

EFFECTS OF NEW US AUTO TARIFFS ON GERMAN EXPORTS, AND ON INDUSTRY VALUE ADDED AROUND THE WORLD

EFFECTS OF NEW US AUTO TARIFFS ON GERMAN EXPORTS, AND ON INDUSTRY VALUE ADDED AROUND THE WORLD 1 ifo Institute ifo Center for International Economics Gabriel Felbermayr & Marina Steininger Feb 15, 2019 EFFECTS OF NEW US AUTO TARIFFS ON GERMAN EXPORTS, AND ON INDUSTRY VALUE ADDED AROUND THE WORLD

More information

International Trade and Income Differences

International Trade and Income Differences International Trade and Income Differences By Michael E. Waugh AER (Dec. 2010) Content 1. Motivation 2. The theoretical model 3. Estimation strategy and data 4. Results 5. Counterfactual simulations 6.

More information

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights Angelo Lobosco and Dan DiBartolomeo Style analysis is a form of constrained regression that uses a weighted combination of market indexes

More information

HOV with technology and consumption dissimilarity

HOV with technology and consumption dissimilarity bilaterally HOV with technology and consumption dissimilarity Neil Foster and Robert Stehrer The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (wiiw) Version: 2012-04-25 Study carried out within

More information

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Haichao Fan Amber Li Sichuang Xu Stephen Yeaple Fudan, HKUST, HKUST, Penn State and NBER May 2018 Mark-Ups

More information

Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members International Trade?

Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members International Trade? Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members International Trade? Scott L. Baier Jeffrey H. Bergstrand* The John E. Walker Department Department of Finance of Economics Mendoza College of Business

More information

Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality. March 13, 2014

Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality. March 13, 2014 Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality March 13, 2014 Inequality has been increasing in most economies 0.55 Disposable Income Inequality: 1980 2010 0.5 0.45 Gini coefficient 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 1980 1985

More information

Cross-Country Income Differences Revisited: Accounting for the Role of Intangible Capital

Cross-Country Income Differences Revisited: Accounting for the Role of Intangible Capital Cross-Country Income Differences Revisited: Accounting for the Role of Intangible Capital Presented at the Fourth World KLEMS Conference, Madrid, Spain Wen Chen University of Groningen, The Netherlands

More information

Gains from Trade 1-3

Gains from Trade 1-3 Trade and Income We discusses the study by Frankel and Romer (1999). Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review 89(3), 379-399. Frankel and Romer examine the impact of trade on real income using

More information

Formation of North-South Agreements and Institutional Distance

Formation of North-South Agreements and Institutional Distance Draft: Please Do Not Quote or Cite Formation of North-South Agreements and Institutional Distance Sophie Therese Schneider University of Hohenheim July 28, 2017 Abstract The number of signed trade agreements

More information

(Asymmetric) Trade Costs, Real Exchange Rate Hedging, and Equity Home Bias in a Multi-Country Model *

(Asymmetric) Trade Costs, Real Exchange Rate Hedging, and Equity Home Bias in a Multi-Country Model * (Asymmetric) Trade Costs, Real Exchange Rate Hedging, and Equity Home Bias in a Multi-Country Model * Ju Hyun Pyun Korea University Business School September 15, 017 Abstract There has been controversy

More information

The geography of conflicts and regional trade agreements Si Vis Pacem Para Mercatum

The geography of conflicts and regional trade agreements Si Vis Pacem Para Mercatum The geography of conflicts and regional trade agreements Si Vis Pacem Para Mercatum Philippe Martin Thierry Mayer Mathias Thoenig January 4, 2010 Abstract We analyze the interaction of economic and political

More information

Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better!

Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better! Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better! Serge Shikher 11 In his presentation, Serge Shikher, international economist at the United States International Trade Commission, reviews

More information

Yannan Hu 1, Frank J. van Lenthe 1, Rasmus Hoffmann 1,2, Karen van Hedel 1,3 and Johan P. Mackenbach 1*

Yannan Hu 1, Frank J. van Lenthe 1, Rasmus Hoffmann 1,2, Karen van Hedel 1,3 and Johan P. Mackenbach 1* Hu et al. BMC Medical Research Methodology (2017) 17:68 DOI 10.1186/s12874-017-0317-5 RESEARCH ARTICLE Open Access Assessing the impact of natural policy experiments on socioeconomic inequalities in health:

More information

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis WenShwo Fang Department of Economics Feng Chia University 100 WenHwa Road, Taichung, TAIWAN Stephen M. Miller* College of Business University

More information

Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK. Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS)

Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK. Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS) Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS) Introduction This presentation reviews three recent UK-based studies estimating the effect of R&D tax credits

More information

Original citation: Baier, S.L., Bergstrand, J.H. and Mariutto, R. (2010) The growth of bilateralism. Working Paper. Coventry: Department of Economics, University of Warwick. (CAGE Online Working Paper

More information

ECON 385. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II. Solow Model With Technological Progress and Data. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON 385. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II. Solow Model With Technological Progress and Data. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko ECON 385. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II. Solow Model With Technological Progress and Data Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 / 35 Examples of technological progress 1970: 50,000 computers in the world;

More information

EX-POST ASSESSMENT OF SIX EU FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS AN ECONOMETRIC ASSESSMENT OF THEIR IMPACT ON TRADE FEBRUARY 2011

EX-POST ASSESSMENT OF SIX EU FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS AN ECONOMETRIC ASSESSMENT OF THEIR IMPACT ON TRADE FEBRUARY 2011 EX-POST ASSESSMENT OF SIX EU FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS AN ECONOMETRIC ASSESSMENT OF THEIR IMPACT ON TRADE FEBRUARY 2011 COLOPHON Authors: Client: Jeffrey Bergstrand, Scott Baier, Eva R. Sunesen, and Martin

More information

The Gravity Model: A workhorse model for empirical analysis of international trade

The Gravity Model: A workhorse model for empirical analysis of international trade INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT AA 2018-2019 The Gravity Model: A workhorse model for empirical analysis of international trade PROF. PIERLUIGI MONTALBANO pierluigi.montalbano@uniroma1.it

More information

Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade

Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade To assess the quantitative impact of WTO accession on Russian trade, we draw on estimates for merchandise trade between

More information

Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion

Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion Investment and Taxation in Germany - Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data Discussion Bronwyn H. Hall Nuffield College, Oxford University; University of California at Berkeley; and the National Bureau of

More information

THE EFFECT OF NONRECIPROCAL PREFERENTIAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON BENEFACTORS EXPORTS

THE EFFECT OF NONRECIPROCAL PREFERENTIAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON BENEFACTORS EXPORTS THE EFFECT OF NONRECIPROCAL PREFERENTIAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON BENEFACTORS EXPORTS Salvador Gil-Pareja * Rafael Llorca-Vivero José Antonio Martínez-Serrano University of Valencia July 10th, 2015 Abstract

More information