(Asymmetric) Trade Costs, Real Exchange Rate Hedging, and Equity Home Bias in a Multi-Country Model *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "(Asymmetric) Trade Costs, Real Exchange Rate Hedging, and Equity Home Bias in a Multi-Country Model *"

Transcription

1 (Asymmetric) Trade Costs, Real Exchange Rate Hedging, and Equity Home Bias in a Multi-Country Model * Ju Hyun Pyun Korea University Business School September 15, 017 Abstract There has been controversy between (two-country) theory and the empirics about whether hedging against real exchange rate fluctuations in the goods market influences foreign equity holdings. This study reconciles the theory with the empirics by introducing a multi-country framework with asymmetric trade costs. We find that the incentive to hold foreign equities to hedge real exchange rate risk is negligible because multiple trade partners act as a hedging channel for real exchange rate fluctuations. Further, our theory calls for a country s covariance-variance ratio to be constructed as the sum of the bilateral covariance-variance ratios of the multiple partners. The empirical analysis of 4 advanced countries confirms the theoretical prediction. Keywords: Multi-country model, International portfolio allocation, Real exchange rate hedging, Equity home bias, Trade costs, Non-tradable goods JEL Code : F30, F36, F41, G11 * I gratefully acknowledge Paul Bergin and two anonymous referees for constructive suggestions. This work was supported by the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-015S1A5A801550). All remaining errors are my own. Korea University Business School, 145, Anam-Ro, Seongbuk-Gu, Seoul , Tel: , jhpyun@korea.ac.kr 1

2 1. Introduction A stream of general equilibrium (GE) research in international macro-finance has explained portfolio home bias by invoking frictions in international goods markets, such as trade costs and the existence of non-tradable goods. The portfolio decision drawn from this line of research is determined by the equilibrium-hedging properties of relative equity returns against the consumption risk that comes from the relative price difference between home and foreign goods owing to trade costs. In this model, technically, home equity holdings can be presented as a proportion of the covariance of the home real exchange rate (with the convention that a decrease in the home real exchange rate denotes a depreciation) and the home excess equity return divided by the variance of the home excess return (hereafter, the covariance-variance ratio). For instance, a positive covariance-variance ratio implies that home assets are a better hedge than foreign assets because the real exchange rate and home excess return move in the same direction. Previous studies using two-country GE models have debated whether the motive for hedging real exchange rate risk generates equity home bias in the model. This debate is closely related to the value of the abovementioned covariance-variance ratio. Obstfeld and Rogoff (000) derive a positive covariance-variance ratio from their parametric assumption that relative risk aversion is equal to the inverse of the elasticity of substitution and demonstrate that home bias in equities increases with trade costs. By contrast, using a more realistic parameterization, Coeurdacier (009) shows that the covariance-variance ratio is negative. He suggests that in his model, home consumers are better insured against real exchange rate fluctuations when they hold more foreign equities than home equities (i.e., they show bias toward foreign equities). 1 1 Obstfeld (007) allows separated equity claims on traded and non-traded industries and shows possible home bias in both tradable and non-tradable goods equities.

3 However, the subsequent empirical finding by van Wincoop and Warnock (010) pose a challenge to these theoretical studies. They compute the covariance-variance ratio for the United States and other developed countries based on the two-country model and find that the computed ratio is close to zero. A zero covariance-variance ratio means that demand for holding foreign equities to hedge against real exchange rate fluctuations hardly exists, and thus goods market frictions, which affect real exchange rates, do not influence the equity position. Some theoretical studies have begun to address this zero covariance-variance ratio by introducing an additional assumption that real exchange rate risk is fully hedged by either the forward market or the bond market (e.g., Engel and Matsumoto, 009; Coeurdacier, Kollmann, & Martin, 010; Coeurdacier & Gourinchas, 016). 3 Further, the literature focuses on other sources of shocks to explain a reasonable degree of equity home bias. For example, Berriel and Bhattarai (013) introduce a government spending shock and Coeurdacier and Gourinchas (016) examine redistributive shocks to the share of financial income relative to total output. This study bridges the gap between the theory and empirics by extending a two-country model to a multi-country model with asymmetric trade costs. 4 By doing so, we can derive a close to zero covariance-variance ratio in the model with reasonable trade cost parameters, which nullifies both the home bias and the foreign bias driven by trade costs. Our theory also calls for a country s covariance-variance ratio to be constructed by the sum of the bilateral covariancevariance ratios with multiple partners. Furthermore, we show that the computed covariance- This is an equity market capitalization-weighted average of 1 other industrialized countries. 3 Engel and Matsumoto (009) introduce nominal rigidities so that the real exchange rate can be hedged by forward foreign exchange markets, and Coeurdacier et al. (010) and Coeurdacier and Gourinchas (016) allow trade in real bonds denominated in goods to hedge real exchange rate risk. 4 Previous works such as Berg and Mark (015) and Bergin and Pyun (016) explain some of the anomalies in international macro-finance in a two-country setting by introducing a multi-country setting. Dedola, Lombardo, & Straub (011) introduce a multi-country model to allow for differences in financial development between advanced and emerging markets to investigate the impact of financial development on portfolio allocation. 3

4 variance ratios in the multi-country setting using price and equity return data for 4 advanced countries are consistent with the theoretical prediction. In the two-country model, the covariance-variance ratio is intuitively negative, as pointed out by Coeurdacier (009). When output in the home country is high, the home real exchange rate depreciates owing to the scarcity of foreign goods. Conversely, home equity returns are higher because home production is higher. Thus, home equity returns and the home real exchange rate move in opposite directions. However, in the multi-country framework, the motive for hedging home exchange rate fluctuation is weakened by the presence of multiple partner countries. Consider the following three-country example. Suppose there is a rise in country 1 s output (equity return), which leads to a decrease in the price of country 1 s goods. Now, if there is a third country (country 3), which substitutes country s goods with country 1 s goods, both of which are imported and require the payment of possibly different trade costs, then the demand for country s goods in the international market lowers, which results in an additional decrease in the price of country s goods. Thus, the relative price of goods in countries 1 and would not decrease as much as in the two-country setting. 5 The theoretical contribution of this study is that while we start building upon the twocountry work of Coeurdacier (009), we allow for multilateral trade partners and asymmetric trade costs among them. We show that the tremendous foreign equity bias disappears with reasonable trade cost parameters in a multi-country setting. Following Coeurdacier (009), we further include non-tradable goods into the model. While this generates slight equity home bias, we still preserve the property of the covariance-variance ratio driven by the multi-country setting. We also 5 Relative demand for home (country 1) goods compared with a bilateral partner s (country ) goods depends not only on the relative prices of both goods but also on those for home goods and the third country s (country 3) goods. Thus, the existence of a third country moderates the negative relationship between relative demand and price for the goods of countries 1 and. 4

5 demonstrate that when considering a higher-order approximation (over the first-order approximation), the symmetric two-country model and symmetric multi-country model provide slightly different implications because of the covariance structure at a risky steady state (Coeurdacier, Rey, & Winant, 011). 6 In addition, while van Wincoop and Warnock (010) calculate the covariance-variance ratio by using a two-country framework, our theory calls for a country s covariance-variance ratio to be constructed by the sum of the bilateral covariancevariance ratios. Lastly, we show that our empirical results are consistent with the theoretical prediction from the model. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section develops the two-country model of Coeurdacier (009) into a three-country model and then discusses the implications. In Section 3, we show the simulation results with the calibrated parameters. Section 4 presents the empirical results for the covariance-variance ratios. Concluding remarks follow in Section 5.. A Three-Country Model.1. Goods market and preference We begin with a simple extension of Coeurdacier s (009) model to a multi-country framework. The model is a two-period (t = 0,1) endowment economy, as in Coeurdacier (009), with three symmetric countries: country 1 (home), country, and country 3. Each country produces one tradable good, and the representative agent in each country consumes all goods; goods can be shipped from one country to another with trade costs. In period t = 0, no consumption takes place, but agents can trade equities, which create claims on the country s future endowment. The 6 One may argue that along with the assumption that all countries are symmetric, when the number of countries increases, the importance of home-produced goods in the consumption of a representative agent decreases. Thus, the decrease in the importance of hedging the price risk of domestically produced goods is purely mechanical in this symmetric model. 5

6 representative household of country i has a standard CRRA preference, with the coefficient of relative risk aversion, γ, 1 C i U i E0 where 1 C i /( 1) 3 ( 1)/ cij for i = 1,,3, (1) j 1 where cij is the total consumption of goods from country j by the representative agent in country i. The parameter ϕ is the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods, which is assumed to be ϕ >1. Denote iceberg-type trade costs, τij. When a unit of goods is shipped across countries, 1/(1 ij ) goods arrive at the destination i. pi denotes the price of one unit of output in country i, and the price of one unit of country j s output sold in country i is p ( 1 ) p. The terms of i j ij j trade between countries is defined as the relative price of each country s tradable goods. Hence, the terms of trade between countries 1 and are q 1 p1 p. The consumption price index (CPI) of country i (i = 1,,3) is P 3 {(1 ) p } i ij j j1 1 1/(1 ), where τii=0. For simplicity, assume this trade cost is destination specific, τij = τi (j i). is defined as Based on the price index of each country, the real exchange rate between countries 1 and RER P p ((1 ) p ) ((1 ) p ) P ((1 ) p1) p ((1 ) p3) 1/(1 ) () where RER 1 p1 p 1, p p3 and (1 1) x (1 1) y ( x, y) (1 ) x (1 ) y 1/(1 ). A decrease in RER1 means the depreciation of the real exchange rate between country 1 and country. When 6

7 the terms of trade, q1, decrease, RER1 also depreciates... Financial markets Financial markets work in the same manner as described by Coeurdacier (009). Each country has an equity that creates claims on future endowment. The supply of each country s equity is normalized to unity. Each country s representative household has its own equity at birth and then trades equities in period 0. Country i has the following budget constraint at t = 0: 3 p for i = 1,,3, (3) S p S j1 where μij is the share of stock j held by country i at the end of period 0. ps is the stock share price, which is identical for all three countries. ij.3. Market equilibrium.3.1. Goods market conditions In period 1, a consumer in country i maximizes his/her utility under a budget constraint: for i = 1,,3, i j. (4) PC p c (1 ) p c p y p y i i i ii i j ij ii i i ij j j ji ji The budget constraint equalizes consumption expenditure to aggregate the (financial) incomes of the representative agent in country i, where financial incomes depend on the portfolio share {μij}. At this point, we take the portfolios chosen in period 0 as given. From the first-order conditions, we derive the following allocation across goods: c ii p C i i Pi, c ij (1 i ) p j Pi C i for i,j = 1,,3, i j. (5) The endowment constraints are given by 7

8 y c (1 ) c 3 i ii i ji ji for i = 1,,3, i j. (6) By using equations (5) and (6), we derive the relative outputs of countries 1 and : y y P P1 C P 3 P1 1 3 q1, C1 C1 where ( x, y) is a continuous function of x and y such that C (7), 1 x(1 ) y(1 ) ( xy, ). x (1 ) (1 ) y Note that in equation (7), the relative outputs of countries 1 and depend on country 3 s information, which is different from the two-country model in Coeurdacier (009)..3.. Financial market conditions In period 0, equity trade is allowed. The marginal cost of buying an additional unit of stock i in period 0 is equal to the expected marginal gain from the endowment in period 1. 7 We rewrite the first-order conditions in relative terms for countries 1 and by using the shadow endowment price as follows: C1 C E0 ( )( R1 R ) P1 P 0, where p j y j R j for i = 1,. (8) p s Further, market clearing in asset markets requires the sum of the portfolio shares of the three countries and the net supply of equities to be equal to 1: 1 i 1 i i3 for i = 1,,3, (9) 7 i,0 ps E0 p y j j C i P for j = 1,,3, where λi,0 is the Lagrange multiplier of the period 0 budget constraint (3). i 8

9 1 for i = 1,,3. (9 ) 1i i 3i.3.3. Competitive equilibrium A competitive equilibrium is described as a set of endogenous variables ФN that satisfies the consumer utility maximization problem, market-clearing conditions, initial endowment, and exogenous trade costs. The endogenous variable set ФN comprises all consumption allocations, asset allocations, prices, and the terms of trade, that is, ФN ={cij, μij, pj, ps, qij} (for i,j=1,,3). The exogenous variable set includes output (endowment) and trade costs, as follows: ФX ={yi, τi} (for i=1,,3)..4. Log-linearization around the equilibrium Denote the deviations of the variables from the equilibrium (in percent) by (^): x x xˆ, where x x is the steady-state value at the equilibrium. We follow the higher-order approximation techniques of Devereux and Sutherland (011) and Tille and van Wincoop (010). We take an approximation around the equilibrium where all three countries have the same endowment yi (for i=1,,3). At the steady-state equilibrium, the prices of goods are the same and the zero components of prices are assumed to be p p p First-order approximation The first-order component of the real exchange rate is ^ RER P ˆ P ˆ q ˆ q ˆ, (10)

10 (1 1) where 1 (1 (1 1) ) (1 1) (1 (1 ) ) 1 1 1, 1(1 ) (1(1 ) ) (1 ) (1 (1 ) ) 1 (1 ) (1 ) (1 (1 ) ) (1 ) (1 (1 ) ). ^ RER P ˆ P ˆ q ˆ q ˆ (10 ) (1 1) (1(1 1) ) (1 1) (1(1 3) ) where3 1 1, 1(1 3) (1(1 3) ) (1 1) (1 3) (1(1 3) ) (1 ) (1 (1 ) ) (1 ) (1 (1 ) ). Take the first-order approximation of equation (7), the relative outputs of countries 1 and, as a benchmark, ˆ ˆ ˆ y1 y q1 1 PC1 ( 1) RER1 PC13( 1) RER13 (7 ), where 1 PC 1 1 P C PC denotes the relative consumption expenditure. The excess stock returns between countries 1 and can be derived from (7 ), R p y p y qˆ1 1 3 qˆ13 1 PC1 PC13 (1 )(1 ) ( 1)( ) (11) R p y p y qˆ qˆ1 4 PC1 3 PC13 (1 )(1 ) ( 1)( ). (11 ) In a multi-country setting, if there is a rise in the output of country 1 (home), the relative price of home goods (the terms of trade) will not fall by as much as it did in a two-country setting, 10

11 because the relative outputs of countries 1 and are positively related to the relative prices of goods from countries 1 and 3. Moreover, the period 1 budget constraint, equation (4), is loglinearized. We express the period 1 budget constraint in relative terms by using the portfolio holdings in equations (9) and (9 ). Note that in this exercise, we assume that the trade costs are source-specific (μ11 = μ1) as well as symmetric trade costs for countries and 3. Hence, the equity share solution is refined as follows. The home equity shares of countries and 3 are pinned down as the same (μ = μ = μ33), and country 1 would hold the same share of foreign equities as countries and 3 (μ1 = μ13 = (1 μ1)/): 1 1 PC1 ( ) R1 ( 1 ) R13, (1) 1 1 PC13 ( 1 ) R13( ) R1. (1 ).4.. Second-order approximation The second-order approximation of the portfolio equation (8) is We also derive this for countries 1 and 3: cov( PC 1, R 1 ) (1 1/ ) cov( RER 1, R 1 ). (8 ) cov( PC13, R13) (1 1/ ) cov( RER13, R13). (8 ) Equations (8 ) and (8 ) are rewritten by using equations (1) and (1 ): 1 1 ( ) var( R1) (1 1/ ) 1cov( q1, R1) cov( q13, R1), (13) ( 1) var( R13) (1 1/ ) 3cov( q13, R13 ) 4cov( q1, R13), (13 ) where var( R 1 ) denotes the variance of excess returns of country 1 s stock over country s and 11

12 cov( q, R 1 ) 1 denotes the covariance between the terms of trade and excess stock returns for countries 1 and..5. Solution for the equilibrium portfolio From equations (13) and (13 ), we derive an equilibrium expression for the home portfolio share for country 1, μ1, which is similar to that in Coeurdacier (009) and van Wincoop and Warnock (010): 1 1 cov( RER1, R1 ) cov( RER13, R13) var( R1) var( R13) 1 1 cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) 1. (14) var( R1) var( R13) In equation (14), home equity holdings, μ1, depend on two terms: (i) the market portfolio (1/3) due to the diversification motive and (ii) the hedging component due to real exchange rate fluctuations, leading to 1 cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) var( R1) var( R13) This term is also called the home bias measure in van Wincoop and Warnock (010). The equity solution for the home country in a three-country model is similar to that in a two-country model. However, when computing the covariance-variance term in the hedging component, the three-country model differs from the two-country model. First, in this three-country framework, country 1 s excess stock returns over country s depend not only on the terms of trade between countries 1 and but also on those between countries 1 and 3 (see equation (11)). Thus, the 1

13 additional variability due to the existence of country 3 makes the covariance-variance ratio greater than that in the two-country setting. Note that if we assume symmetric trade costs in all countries here (τ1 = τ = τ3), then our home bias measure collapses into a simpler form as follows (where θ1 = θ3 =θ and θ = θ4 = 0): 1 cov(, ) 1 3 q1 R1 cov( q13, R13) var( R1) var( R13)..6. An N-country model with trade costs Now, we extend the three-country model to an N-country model. First, we conjecture the equity solution for the N-country case with trade costs: N 1 N 1 1 cov( RERi, j, Ri, j) i 1 N N. (15) j1, ji var( Ri, j) The home equity share (µ) in the N-country model in equation (15) resembles that of the threecountry model in equation (14). Again, it comprises (i) the market portfolio (which is 1/N) due to the diversification motive and (ii) the home bias measure, which includes the hedging component due to real exchange rate fluctuations, namely the covariance-variance ratio. Here, the latter home bias measure can be divided into three terms. The first term (N-1)/N is related to the number of countries, which contributes to increasing the home bias measure when N goes from two to infinity. The second term includes risk aversion (γ) with which home bias increases. The last term is the sum of the covariance-variance terms. The home country s real exchange rate risk can be diversified if there are more trade partners in the international market. Hence, the covariancevariance ratio decreases with the number of countries. Note that when trade costs are symmetric 13

14 across countries, N j1, ji cov( RER, R ) cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ) cov( q, R ). i, j i, j i1 i1 i i in in i... var( Ri, j) var( Ri1) var( Ri) var( RiN).7. Adding non-tradable goods into the three-country model Coeurdacier (009) also extends his model by allowing countries to receive endowments of nontradable goods along with tradable goods. Here, we closely follow Coeurdacier (009). The hedging portfolio now depends on the covariance between the relative equity returns and relative price of tradeable to non-tradable goods Model set-up Each country now produces two goods, a tradable (T) and a non-tradable good (NT). In period 0, agents trade home and foreign equities, which are claims to aggregate output of individual countries, but they cannot trade separate claims on tradable and non-tradable output in each country. 8 The equity returns of country i are a weighted share of the returns in both sectors. In period 1, country i receives an exogenous endowment NT exogenous endowment yi T yi of the tradable good of country i and an of the non-tradable good. The stochastic properties of endowment shocks are assumed to be symmetric: ( T ) T E0 yi yi ; ( T Var ) 0 yi T; ( NT E ) 0 yi yi for i=1,,3. NT, and ( NT Var ) 0 yi A household in country i has the same CRRA preferences over the aggregate consumption index. Here, the aggregate consumption index is a bundle of tradable and non-tradable goods as follows: NT 8 See Coeurdacier (009) for a detailed justification of this assumption. 14

15 1 C i U i E0 where 1 /( 1) 1/ T ( 1)/ 1/ NT ( 1)/ Ci ( ci ) (1 ) ( ci ), (16) where T c i is the consumption of a composite tradable good using tradable goods and NT c i is the consumption of non-tradable goods. ε is the elasticity of substitution between tradable and nontradable goods. η is the steady-state share of spending devoted to tradable goods. The tradable consumption index for country i is c T i 3 j1 T ( c ) ij ( 1)/ /( 1), where T c ij is country i's consumption of the tradable good from country j. The consumer price index is as follows: 1/(1 ) T 1 NT 1 Pi ( Pi ) (1 )( Pi ), (17) where T P i is the price index over tradable goods in country i and NT Pi is the price of non-tradable goods. The tradable goods price index is defined by P p p 3 T T 1 T 1 i ( i ) {(1 ij) j} ji 1/(1 ), where T pi is the price of the tradable goods in country i. The terms of trade between countries i and j are T T defined by q p / p. ij i j The goods market constraints for the tradable and non-tradable goods in country i=1,,3 are given by 3 T T T i ii (1 ij) ji ji y c c for i = 1,,3, i j (18) y NT i c for i = 1,,3, (18 ) NT i y y y for i = 1,,3. (18 ) T NT i i i The set-up of financial markets is the same as the case without non-tradable goods. However, note that here with non-tradable goods, a stock gives investors a claim on the aggregate output of the 15

16 country at the market value (where aggregate output at the market value of country i is the sum of sales in the tradable and non-tradable sectors). A household in country i owns the local stock and faces the budget constraint shown in equation (3). We also recall the market-clearing conditions in asset markets and those of net equity supply (equations (9) and (9 ))..7.. Solution methods and equilibrium portfolios As in the benchmark model, we solve the equilibrium equity portfolios μ by using the first-order approximation of the non-portfolio equations and second-order approximation of the Euler equations. We do not describe the resolution and approximation of the model (as the steps are similar to those of the benchmark model) and simply present some of the key equations (see also Coeurdacier, 009). The first-order approximation of the real exchange rate equations of countries 1 and is ^ ^ ˆ ˆ NT 1 1 ˆ 1 1 ˆ 13 (1 ) 1 RER P P q q P, (19) where ^ ^ ^ NT NT NT 1 1 P P P is the (first-order approximation of) the relative price of the non-tradable (1 1) goods of countries 1 and. 1 (1 (1 1) ) (1 1) (1 (1 ) ) (1 ) (1(1 ) ) (1 1) and 1 (1 ) (1 (1 1) ) (1 1) (1 (1 ) ) (1 ) (1 (1 ) ) Importantly, the real exchange rate now depends positively on the terms of trade (q) as well as on the relative price of the non-tradable goods (P NT ). The intertemporal allocation across goods from the consumer s utility maximization problem (16) and market-clearing conditions for tradable and non-tradable goods (equations (4), (18), (18 ), and (18 )) implies the following 16

17 equilibrium conditions for countries 1 and : T T ˆ ˆ ˆ y1 y ˆ ˆ q1 1 ( )( 1q1 q13) ( 1) RER PC 1 1 ( )( 3qˆ ˆ 13 4q1) ( 1) RER13 PC13, (0) NT NT NT (1) yˆ yˆ P ( 1) RER PC These two conditions are similarly derived for countries 1 and 3. The excess stock returns between countries 1 and can be derived from (7 ): T NT NT R1 qˆ ˆ ˆ 1 y1 P1 y1 ( ) (1 )( ). () We also derive the excess stock returns between countries 1 and 3 in the same way: T NT NT R13 qˆ ˆ ˆ 13 y13 P13 y13 ( ) (1 )( ). ( ) Again, we recall equations (1) and (1 ) of the first-order approximation of the budget constraints and the second-order approximation of the portfolio equations (8) and (8 ). We rewrite these second-order approximation equations as follows: NT ( ) var( R1) (1 ) 1cov( q1, R1) cov( q13, R1) (1 ) cov( P1, R1), (3) ( 1 ) var( 13) (1 1 R ) 4cov( q1, R13) 3cov( q13, R13) (1 ) cov( P NT 13, R13), (3 ) where var( R 1 ) denotes the variance of the excess returns of country 1 s stock over country s and cov( q, R 1 ) denotes the covariance between the terms of trade and excess stock returns for 1 NT countries 1 and. cov( P, R1) 1 indicates the covariance between the relative price of the nontradable goods and excess stock returns. Then, we solve μ1 by using these two equations, (3) and 17

18 (3 ), as follows: NT 1 q1 R1 q13 R1 P1 R1 var( 1) 1 1 cov(, ) cov(, ) (1 )cov(, ) 1 1 [ R NT 4 q1 R13 3 q13 R13 P13 R13 var( R13) cov(, ) cov(, ) (1 )cov(, ) ]. (4) Note that when assuming symmetric trade costs across countries, this formula collapses into NT NT 1 1 1cov( q1, R1) (1 )cov( P1, R1) 3cov( q13, R13) (1 )cov( P13, R13) var( R1) var( R13 ) 3. Simulation This section depicts the home equity solution and the covariance-variance ratio derived from the theory on trade costs. Here, we highlight the role of the multi-country setting in shaping the home bias measure and covariance-variance ratio. First, we assume symmetric trade costs and then allow for asymmetric trade costs Symmetric trade costs: Comparison with the two-country GE model Baseline simulation Figure 1 plots the home equity share (μ) and covariance-variance ratio with respect to trade costs from the two-country model to the multi-country model. Note that Coeurdacier (009) derives an analytical form of the home equity share (μ) from the two-country framework as follows: cov( RER 1 var( R 1 1, R ) 1 ) (1 )(1 ) (1 1 ), (5) 18

19 where, again, γ is relative risk aversion, is the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods, and the trade cost parameter, 1 (1 ) 1 (1 ) , is different from that in the multi-country model. We use the same parameter values relative risk aversion (γ) is and the elasticity of substitution (ϕ) is 5 as Coeurdacier (009) in his two-country model. In Panel A of Figure 1, when N= (for the two-country case), the blue line with a circle marker indicates foreign equity bias when trade costs are less than 14% (e.g., Anderson & van Wincoop, 004, estimated trade costs are in the range of 40% to 70%). In addition, an increase in trade costs (τ) rather increases foreign bias in the portfolio, in contrast to the argument that trade costs lead to home bias in equities. If trade costs are higher than 14%, the portfolio starts to be biased toward home equities; however, the model with unrealistically high trade costs seems to deliver too much home bias, which is not consistent with the real data. As the number of countries increases, the balanced portfolio share changes from 1/ (twocountry setting) to 1/N (N-country setting), which shifts the home equity share at the origin downward. However, interestingly, the home equity shares respond to trade costs differently as the number of countries increases. For a greater number of countries, the home equity share becomes closer to the balanced portfolio share while even increasing trade costs, and it begins to show foreign bias only for very large trade costs (i.e., for N=50, foreign bias starts to appear when trade costs are above 100%). When we allow for a multi-country setting, foreign bias starts to disappear with reasonable trade cost parameters in the range of 40% to 70%. In particular, when N=50, there is no longer foreign bias and home equity holdings are not sensitive to the size of trade costs. Panel B of Figure 1 plots the home country s covariance-variance ratio. First, the covariance-variance ratio starts from zero and decreases with trade costs. However, when the

20 number of trade partners increases, the covariance-variance ratio approaches zero with reasonable trade cost parameters and its curvature flattens. This finding implies that the diversification benefits driven by the multiple partners help nullify the foreign equity bias observed in a twocountry setting. One may argue that this is unsurprising in that the multi-country model simply results from decreasing the size of each country relative to the world and, therefore, decreasing the importance of home-produced non-tradable goods in the optimal consumption basket. To address this concern, the present study could be developed in various directions. For example, as Dedola et al. (011) use the benefit of the multi-country setting in their analysis by allowing for asymmetry in the size (or development) of individual countries, it could be interesting to examine the consequence of a multi-country model with asymmetry assumptions. In the following subsection, we therefore relax the assumption of symmetric trade costs across countries and discuss the implication from the adoption of asymmetric trade costs. [Insert Figure 1] 3.. Asymmetric trade costs with a multi-country model In Figure, we allow for asymmetric trade costs and examine how these influence the equity positions from our baseline three-country model to an N-country model. The same parameter values are used as in Figure 1 (γ =, ϕ = 5). For simplicity, we assume that the trade costs for all countries except for country 1 (home) are 63%. We simulate the home equity share and covariance-variance ratio for country 1 with respect to country 1 s trade costs. Panel A of Figure shows the home bias measure that quantifies the degree to which home equity holdings deviate from the balanced portfolio, instead of depicting home equity holdings, for comparison purposes. There is home bias if this measure is greater than zero and foreign bias otherwise. 0

21 For all cases from N = 3 to N = 50, the home bias measure deviates little from zero in contrast to the cases with symmetric costs, even when trade costs vary from 0% to 300%. In addition, compared with Figure 1 with symmetric trade costs, the discontinuity of equity solutions disappears in all cases. Indeed, home equity holdings change little as trade costs move. For the three-country case, there is still foreign equity bias with reasonable trade costs ranging from 40% to 70%. However, the degree of foreign equity bias becomes much smaller (the home bias measure is at most 0. compared with 0.5 for the three-country case with symmetric trade costs). More importantly, when increasing the number of trade partners, foreign equity bias reduces. For N=50, the home bias measure turns out to be close to zero regardless of the trade costs for country 1. In Panel B of Figure, the covariance-variance ratios also display similar patterns to the home equity shares. When trade costs are 63% in the baseline three-country model, the covariancevariance ratio is around 0.37, while it is 0.5 in the two-country model. Furthermore, when increasing the number of countries, the value of the covariance-variance ratios turns out to be starkly different from that of the two-country model of Coeurdacier (009). For instance, if trade costs are 63%, the covariance-variance ratio is about zero in the multi-country model (when N=50 or greater). Thus, the simulation result from the multi-country model with asymmetric trade costs shows that the asymmetric structure of trade costs contributes to decreasing the magnitude of the large negative covariance-variance ratio observed in the two-country model. In particular, it helps obtain a covariance-variance ratio of almost zero. It is thus conjectured that combinations of asymmetric trade costs may abolish a negative covariance-variance ratio. [Insert Figure ] 3.3. Model with non-tradable goods 1

22 In this section, we simulate the model with non-tradable goods following Obstfeld (007) and Coeurdacier (009) to strengthen the robustness of the results. While our simulation results derived from using the multi-country model with trade costs indeed make the negative covariancevariance ratio close to zero and thereby eliminate foreign equity bias, we fail to generate equity home bias. Here, we include non-tradable goods to focus on the role of goods market frictions in generating equity home bias. This approach also allows us to check the interaction between trade costs and non-tradable goods (e.g., Collard, Dellas, Diba, & Stockmann, 007; Obstfeld, 007; Coeurdacier, 009). Note that previous studies of equity home bias introduce not only non-tradable goods but also various shocks to generate equity home bias in the model. Figure 3 plots the home equity share (μ) and covariance-variance ratio of the model including non-tradable goods with respect to trade costs. We use the same parameter values used in Coeurdacier (009): risk aversion (γ) is, the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods (ϕ) is 5, the elasticity of substitution between tradable and non-tradable goods (ε) is 0.5, and the share of tradable goods in consumption expenditure (η) is In particular, we follow Coeurdacier s (009) benchmark case on the exogenous income process. The volatility ratio of the exogenous endowment process ( / ) is 0.5 and the correlation of the shocks NT T between sectors within each country ( ( ˆ T NT Corr y, y ˆ )) is 0.3. [Insert Figure 3] First, Panel A of Figure 3 replicates the home equity share and corresponding covariancevariance ratio for the two-country model with symmetric trade costs as shown in Coeurdacier (009). The dashed line indicates the balanced portfolio share. The home equity share here shows similar patterns to that of the two-country model with only trade costs: as trade costs increase, the home equity share begins to exhibit foreign bias and then switches to home bias with extremely

23 high trade costs. However, unlike the model with only trade costs, non-tradable goods generate equity home bias when trade costs are less than about 50%, which also generates a positive covariance-variance ratio. Panel B of Figure 3 shows home equity holdings and the covariance-variance ratio for the three-country model with symmetric trade costs and Panel C illustrates those for the three-country model with asymmetric trade costs (we assume that the trade costs for countries and 3 are 63%). The non-tradable goods in both cases contribute to producing equity home bias. In addition, when extending the two-country model to the three-country model, we show that a negative covariancevariance ratio turns out be close to zero or even positive. In Panel B of the three-country model with symmetric costs, the covariance-variance ratio is slightly greater than zero when trade costs range from 40% to 80%. Then, the covariance-variance ratio becomes negative when the trade costs for all three countries are above 80%. Panel C of the three-country model with asymmetric trade costs shows that the home equity share and covariance-variance ratio are not sensitive to trade costs, as also shown in Figure. Here, the asymmetric structure of trade costs again eliminates the discontinuity of home equity holdings. Unlike trade costs, non-tradable goods play a role in generating home bias and making the covariance-variance ratio greater than zero for any trade costs parameters ranging from 0% to 300%. In particular, the covariance-variance ratio turns out to be 0.1~0. with trade costs from 40% to 80%. 4. Empirical Analysis In this section, we compute the covariance-variance ratios by using real data based on a multicountry theoretical setting. We set the United States as the reference country. Note that our multi- 3

24 country setting does not require an equity market capitalization-weighted average of the individual countries to represent the rest of the world (as the counterpart of the United States), as in the twocountry model of van Wincoop and Warnock (010). Instead, we calculate the covariance-variance ratio of the real exchange rate and excess stock returns between the United States and individual countries j and then sum them according to the formula N j1, jus cov( RERUS, j, RUS, j ) shown in var( RUS, j ) equation (15). We introduce our data and present the results in the following subsection Data We collect monthly equity (stock) market price index data for 4 advanced countries, including the United States, from DataStream for comparison purposes with van Wincoop and Warnock (010). Note that data for some emerging markets are available. However, owing to possible heterogeneity in this group, we exclude emerging countries from this analysis. Most advanced countries stock index data are available from 1961 (see Table 1 for the list of countries and data availability). We limit data up to 007 to avoid abnormal influence from the global financial crisis on equity returns and prices. For the relative prices of countries that measure the real exchange rate index in the model, we collect four kinds of price index data to calculate the real exchange rate. First, the price measure is the price level of GDP (production price index (PPP)/exchange rate) from Penn World Table 8.0 ( An advantage of using these data is that they allow for the wider coverage of countries (up to 4 countries including the United States). Second, we use the countries general price index, the Consumption Price Index (CPI) from the World Bank, and the Production Price Index (PPI) from OECD statistics for robustness checks. 4

25 Lastly, we introduce the deflators of countries value-added over all industries from the OECD Structural Analysis (STAN) database. [Insert Table 1] 4.. Calculation of the covariance-variance ratio Figure 4, using the GDP deflator from Penn World Table 8.0, shows our baseline result for the bilateral covariance-variance ratio between the United States and other individual countries with respect to distance from the United States. Here, we use geographical distance as a proxy for trade costs. The bilateral covariance-variance ratios are scattered in the range between 0.5 and 0.3 with respect to trade costs. Interestingly, most of them are close to zero except for Iceland (ISL), the Netherlands (NLD), and Switzerland (CHE) for which the ratios are somewhat large or small (0.5 for ISL, 0.43 for NLD, and 0.41 for CHE). Among the 1 countries except for the above three, 1 show negative covariance-variance ratios but the magnitude is small and close to zero. Nine countries exhibit ratios greater than zero but less than 0.1. However, our theory calls for the US covariance-variance ratio not to depend on specific partners but rather be computed by summing the bilateral covariance-variance ratios of all partners. When summing all these bilateral ratios, we find that the US covariance-variance ratio, zero. N j1, jus cov( RERUS, j, RUS, j ) var( US, j ) R 0.05, which is close to [Insert Figure 4] We use the alternative measures for countries price levels as robustness checks. Figures 5 and 6 show the covariance-variance ratios by using the CPI and PPI, respectively. The covariancevariance ratios calculated by using the CPI in Figure 5 range from 0.11 to The US bilateral 5

26 covariance-variance ratios against most countries are close to zero. Figure 6 shows that the covariance-variance ratios by using PPI are between 0.18 and 0.1. Finally, we sum all the bilateral ratios over all partner countries in both figures and construct the US covariance-variance ratio ( and , respectively). Again, the US covariance-variance ratios are close to zero, which is consistent with our theoretical prediction. Lastly, Figure 7 uses the deflator of the value-added of all sectors (industries) in a country. Here, we present interesting findings: While the bilateral covariance-variance ratios are again between 0.16 and 0.1, the US covariance-variance ratio that comprises all the bilateral ratios turns out to be 0.87, which is slightly greater than zero. This result echoes our simulation result for the model with non-tradable goods. Note that when using real data for the United States and 1 industrialized countries, van Wincoop and Warnock (010) compute their benchmark covariancevariance ratios based on the two-country framework; these ratios are close to zero but slightly positive (0.16 when relative risk aversion (γ) is 5 and 0.3 when γ goes to infinity). However, the covariance-variance ratios calculated by van Wincoop and Warnock (010) are not exactly comparable with those from our theoretical results in the three-country model because they impose a two-country setting. [Insert Figure 5] [Insert Figure 6] [Insert Figure 7] 5. Conclusion In this study, we shed light on the role of equity holdings on real exchange rate hedging and examine theoretically whether trade costs play a role in generating bias in equity positions. 6

27 We extend the two-country GE model to a multi-country model and allow for asymmetric trade costs. While previous studies built upon two-country models show the gap between the theory and empirics, we reconcile the theory with the empirics simply by introducing a multi-country framework. Then, we show that the calculated covariance-variance ratios for excess stock returns and real exchange rates using data for 4 advanced countries are consistent with our theoretical prediction in the multi-country setting. An implication from this study is that our theoretical and empirical finding supports those of Berriel and Bhattarai (013) and Coeurdacier and Gourinchas (016), who maintain that equity home bias does not occur from real exchange rate hedging but rather from the hedging properties of stock returns against other sources of risk. Indeed, the presence of (asymmetric) trade costs in a multi-country framework supports that trade costs play a role in generating neither equity home bias nor foreign bias. Here, the existence of only trade costs (even very high trade costs of about 300%) is unlikely to explain equity home bias portfolios. However, non-tradable goods as an extreme friction in goods markets can work to generate home bias and render the covariancevariance ratio positive. Our theory-based covariance-variance ratios between the real exchange rate and equity returns in a multi-country setting help decompose the covariance-variance ratio into trade costs, the covariance between the terms of trade change and equity return, and that between the price of non-tradable goods and equity returns. Future research could aim to examine individual margins to explain the covariance-variance ratio more in detail. Lastly, the results from the multi-country model suggest that future GE model research should consider the multi-country framework and explore various sources of risk across countries with asymmetry assumptions to understand home bias in the portfolios in the international market. 7

28 References Anderson, J., & van Wincoop, E. (004). Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature, 4, Berg, K. A., & Mark, N. C. (015). Third-country effects on the exchange rate. Journal of International Economics, 96(), Bergin, P. R., & Pyun, J. H. (016). International portfolio diversification and multilateral effects of correlations. Journal of International Money and Finance, 6, Berriel, T. C., & Bhattarai, S. (013). Hedging against the government: A solution to the home asset bias puzzle. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(1), Coeurdacier, N. (009). Do trade costs in goods markets lead to home bias in equities? Journal of International Economics, 77, Coeurdacier, N., & Gourinchas, P.-O. (016). When bonds matter: Home bias in goods and assets. Journal of Monetary Economics, xx, xx xx. Coeurdacier, N., Kollmann, R., & Martin, P. (010). International portfolios, capital accumulation and foreign assets dynamics. Journal of International Economics, 80, Coeurdacier, N., Rey, H., & Winant, P. (011). The risky steady state. American Economic Review, 101(3), Collard, F., Dellas, H., Diba, H., & Stockmann, A. (007). Goods trade and international equity portfolios. NBER Working Papers Dedola, L., Lombardo, G., & Straub, R., 011. Home bias and portfolio dynamics in a multicountry model, mimeo. Devereux, M. B., & Sutherland, A. (011). Country portfolios in open economy macro models. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, Engel, C., & Matsumoto, A. (009). The international diversification puzzle when goods prices are sticky: It s really about exchange-rate hedging, not equity portfolios. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1, Obstfeld, M. (007). International risk sharing and the costs of trade. Ohlin Lecture, Stockholm School of Economics. Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (000). The six major puzzles in international macroeconomics: Is there a common cause? NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Tille, C., & van Wincoop, E. (010). International capital flows. Journal of International 8

29 Economics, 80, van Wincoop, E., & Warnock, F. (010). Is home bias in assets related to home bias in goods? Journal of International Money and Finance, 9,

30 Figure 1. Symmetric trade costs and equity home bias in a multi-country model (comparison with Coeurdacier, 009) Home equity holdings Covariance-variance ratio 1.9 Panel A. Home equity share N= N=3 N=10 N= τ1 (trade cost) Panel B. Covariance-variance ratio N= N= N=10 N= τ1 (trade cost) 30

31 Figure. Asymmetric trade costs and equity home bias in a multi-country model (γ =, ϕ = 5, tau(-i)=0.63) Home bias measure Covariance-variance ratio Panel A. Home bias measure N=3 N=5 N=10 N= τ1 (trade cost) Panel B. Covariance-variance ratio N=3 N=5 N=10 N= τ1 (trade cost) 31

32 Figure 3. Model including non-tradable goods Home equity holdings & Cov-var ratio Panel A. country model with symmetric trade cost Home equity share Covariance-variance ratio Balanced portfolio line τ 1 (trade cost) Home equity holdings & Cov-var ratio 3

33 Home equity holdings & Cov-var ratio Panel C. 3 country model with asymmetric trade cost Home equity share Covariance-variance ratio Balanced portfolio line τ1 (trade cost) 33

34 Figure 4. Covariance-variance ratio for the United States, price of GDP, PWT 8.0 Cov_var ratio (GDP deflator, PWT 8.0) CAN ISL IRL ESP FRA NOR ITA GBR BELFIN DNK PRT DEU SWE NLD CHE GRC ISR N j1, jus cov( RERUS, j, RUS, j ) JPN KOR var( RUS, j ) HKG 0.05 NZL AUS simple distance (most populated cities, km) Figure 5. Covariance-variance ratio for the United States, CPI, WDI Cov_var ratio (Consumer price index, WDI) CAN ISL BEL IRLGBR DEU DNK CHE ESP FRA NLD SWE NOR FIN ITA PRT GRC ISR N j1, jus cov( RERUS, j, RUS, j ) JPN KOR var( RUS, j ) HKG NZL AUS simple distance (most populated cities, km) 34

35 Figure 6. Covariance-variance ratio for the United States, PPI, OECD Cov_var ratio (Product price index, OECD) IRL NLD BEL DEU DNK FIN FRA NOR SWE GBR ESP ITA GRC N j1, jus cov( RERUS, j, RUS, j ) var( US, j ) R JPN AUS simple distance (most populated cities, km) Figure 7. Covariance-variance ratios for the United States, Value-added deflator, OECD Cov_var ratio (Value added deflator, OECD) GBR NOR BEL ESP FRA DNK CHE FIN ITA PRT NLD DEU SWE GRC N j1, jus JPN cov( RERUS, j, RUS, j ) var( RUS, j ) simple distance (most populated cities, km) 35

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification Part 1) Working through a complete markets case - In the previous lecture, I claimed that assuming complete asset markets produced a perfect-pooling

More information

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports 1 Thierry Mayer (Science Po, Banque de France) and Walter Steingress (Bank of Canada) BIS Workshop 1 The views expressed in this paper are

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

International Capital Flows, Returns and World Financial Integration

International Capital Flows, Returns and World Financial Integration International Capital Flows, Returns and World Financial Integration July 13, 2011 Martin D. D. Evans 1 Viktoria Hnatkovska Georgetown University and NBER University of British Columbia Department of Economics

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Giancarlo Corsetti Luca Dedola Sylvain Leduc CREST, May 2008 The International Consumption Correlations Puzzle

More information

Global Pricing of Risk and Stabilization Policies

Global Pricing of Risk and Stabilization Policies Global Pricing of Risk and Stabilization Policies Tobias Adrian Daniel Stackman Erik Vogt Federal Reserve Bank of New York The views expressed here are the authors and are not necessarily representative

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNDERSTANDING INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIO DIVERSIFICATION AND TURNOVER RATES. Amir A. Amadi Paul R. Bergin

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNDERSTANDING INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIO DIVERSIFICATION AND TURNOVER RATES. Amir A. Amadi Paul R. Bergin NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNDERSTANDING INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIO DIVERSIFICATION AND TURNOVER RATES Amir A. Amadi Paul R. Bergin Working Paper 12473 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12473 NATIONAL BUREAU OF

More information

Diversi cation through Trade

Diversi cation through Trade Diversi cation through Trade Francesco Caselli, Miklos Koren, Milan Lisicky, and Silvana Tenreyro Very preliminary May 2010 Caselli et al. (Very preliminary) Diversi cation through Trade May 2010 1 / 39

More information

What is the economic outlook for OECD countries?

What is the economic outlook for OECD countries? The outlook What is the economic outlook for OECD countries? Paul van den Noord Counselor to the Chief Economist The outlook Real GDP growth, in per cent.....9. -..9 Japan. -... Total OECD.... Brazil....

More information

International Monetary Policy Coordination and Financial Market Integration

International Monetary Policy Coordination and Financial Market Integration An important paper that opens an important conference. In my discussion I will attempt to: cast the paper within the broader context of the current literature and debate on coordination; suggest an interpretation

More information

Topic 6: Optimal Monetary Policy and International Policy Coordination

Topic 6: Optimal Monetary Policy and International Policy Coordination Topic 6: Optimal Monetary Policy and International Policy Coordination - Now that we understand how to construct a utility-based intertemporal open macro model, we can use it to study the welfare implications

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #3 1 1 on-traded goods and the real exchange rate So far we have looked at environments

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Financial Heterogeneity and Monetary Union

Financial Heterogeneity and Monetary Union Financial Heterogeneity and Monetary Union S. Gilchrist R. Schoenle 2 J. Sim 3 E. Zakrajšek 3 Boston University Brandeis University 2 Federal Reserve Board 3 MEFM, NBER SI B J, 25 Disclaimer The views

More information

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I) 14.581 Week 13 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 13) Trade Policy Theory (I) Spring 2013 1 / 29 Trade Policy Literature A Brief Overview Key questions:

More information

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice for Emerging Market Countries Masato Takahashi Master of Philosophy University of York Department of Economics and Related Studies July 2011 Abstract This thesis includes

More information

Topic 8: Financial Frictions and Shocks Part1: Asset holding developments

Topic 8: Financial Frictions and Shocks Part1: Asset holding developments Topic 8: Financial Frictions and Shocks Part1: Asset holding developments - The relaxation of capital account restrictions in many countries over the last two decades has produced dramatic increases in

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Jinill Kim, Korea University Sunghyun Kim, Sungkyunkwan University March 015 Abstract This paper provides two illustrative examples

More information

Credit Supply, Household Debt, and Business Cycles

Credit Supply, Household Debt, and Business Cycles Credit Supply, Household Debt, and Business Cycles Amir Sufi University of Chicago Booth School of Business; NBER; co-director of IGM February 2017 Big Picture Questions What is the source of macroeconomic

More information

International Trade and Income Differences

International Trade and Income Differences International Trade and Income Differences By Michael E. Waugh AER (Dec. 2010) Content 1. Motivation 2. The theoretical model 3. Estimation strategy and data 4. Results 5. Counterfactual simulations 6.

More information

Can employment be increased only at the cost of more inequality?

Can employment be increased only at the cost of more inequality? Can employment be increased only at the cost of more inequality? Engines for More and Better Jobs in Europe ZEW Conference, Mannheim April 2013 Torben M Andersen Aarhus University Policy questions How

More information

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point A Web-Appendix A.1 Information on data sources Individual level responses on benefit morale, tax morale, age, sex, marital status, children, education (captured by the school leaving age), household income

More information

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy Volume 38, Issue 1 The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz Department of Economics, University of Utah Abstract This paper studies if the supply

More information

From Here to Eternity: The Outlook for Fiscal Adjustment in Advanced Economies. Carlo Cottarelli Director, Fiscal Affairs Department

From Here to Eternity: The Outlook for Fiscal Adjustment in Advanced Economies. Carlo Cottarelli Director, Fiscal Affairs Department From Here to Eternity: The Outlook for Fiscal Adjustment in Advanced Economies Carlo Cottarelli Director, Fiscal Affairs Department Peterson Institute May 2, 213 1 Main Questions How bad is the fiscal

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

International Monetary Economics

International Monetary Economics International Monetary Economics Lecture 2: Global Imbalances Master d Affaires Publiques SciencesPo Spring 2013 Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas Roadmap The Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account The

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

A Technical Appendix for Burstein and Gopinath (2015)

A Technical Appendix for Burstein and Gopinath (2015) A Technical Appendix for Burstein and Gopinath (2015) A.1 Definitions of variables used in construction of trade-weighted measures Define the nominal exchange rate e in,t between countries n and i as the

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Topic 10: Asset Valuation Effects

Topic 10: Asset Valuation Effects Topic 10: Asset Valuation Effects Part1: Document Asset holding developments - The relaxation of capital account restrictions in many countries over the last two decades has produced dramatic increases

More information

WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD)

WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD) WHAT DO HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS SUGGEST ABOUT THE TOP 1% INCOMES AND INEQUALITY IN OECD COUNTRIES? Nicolas Ruiz (OECD) Motivation: the Inclusive growth puzzle the top percentile managed to capture a very large

More information

Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy

Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy Currency Risk Factors in a Recursive Multi-Country Economy R. Colacito M.M. Croce F. Gavazzoni R. Ready NBER SI - International Asset Pricing Boston July 8, 2015 Motivation The literature has identified

More information

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS PRICE FLEXIBILITY Michael B. Devereux HKIMR Working Paper No.20/2004 October 2004 Working Paper No.1/ 2000 Hong Kong Institute

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

University of Pennsylvania & NBER. This paper reflects only the authors views, and not those of the IMF

University of Pennsylvania & NBER. This paper reflects only the authors views, and not those of the IMF An Anatomy of Credit Booms and their Demise Enrique G. Mendoza University of Pennsylvania & NBER Marco E. Terrones IMF This paper reflects only the authors views, and not those of the IMF Motivation and

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHEN BONDS MATTER: HOME BIAS IN GOODS AND ASSETS. Nicolas Coeurdacier Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHEN BONDS MATTER: HOME BIAS IN GOODS AND ASSETS. Nicolas Coeurdacier Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHEN BONDS MATTER: HOME BIAS IN GOODS AND ASSETS Nicolas Coeurdacier Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas Working Paper 17560 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17560 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

WORKING PAPERS. Global Trends of Multi-Factor Productivity. Jeong Yeon Lee. Economics Series. No. 136, March 2014

WORKING PAPERS. Global Trends of Multi-Factor Productivity. Jeong Yeon Lee. Economics Series. No. 136, March 2014 WORKING PAPERS E A S T- W E S T C E N T E R WOR K I N G PAP E R S Economics Series No. 136, March 2014 Global Trends of Multi-Factor Productivity Jeong Yeon Lee E A S T- W E S T C E N T E R WOR K I N G

More information

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area Presentation by Val Koromzay, Director for Country Studies, OECD to the Brussels Forum, April 2004 1 1 I. Introduction: Why is the issue important?

More information

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Reforms in a Debt Overhang Structural Javier Andrés, Óscar Arce and Carlos Thomas 3 National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4 Universidad de Valencia, Banco de España Banco de España 3 Banco de España National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Introducing nominal rigidities. Introducing nominal rigidities. Olivier Blanchard May 22 14.452. Spring 22. Topic 7. 14.452. Spring, 22 2 In the model we just saw, the price level (the price of goods in terms of money) behaved like an

More information

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure

More information

Why is Japan s inward FDI so low?

Why is Japan s inward FDI so low? Why is Japan s inward FDI so low? Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research August 8, 2017 Japan s low level of inward foreign direct investment stock In May, it was reported

More information

Costs of Business Cycles Empirical Evidence

Costs of Business Cycles Empirical Evidence Costs of Business Cycles Empirical Evidence Petr Sedláček Bonn University Summer Term 2014 1 / 48 Background and some empirical evidence Seminal contribution by, Lucas (2003) Empirical evidence on the

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Topic 2: International Comovement Part1: International Business cycle Facts: Quantities

Topic 2: International Comovement Part1: International Business cycle Facts: Quantities Topic 2: International Comovement Part1: International Business cycle Facts: Quantities Issue: We now expand our study beyond consumption and the current account, to study a wider range of macroeconomic

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Incidence of Social Security Contributions: Evidence from France

Incidence of Social Security Contributions: Evidence from France Incidence of Social Security Contributions: Evidence from France Antoine Bozio, Thomas Breda et Julien Grenet Paris School of Economics PSE Public and Labour Economics Seminar Paris, 15 September 2016

More information

High Debt, Slow Growth, Financial Instability, Growing Inequality: What Role for Economic Policy?

High Debt, Slow Growth, Financial Instability, Growing Inequality: What Role for Economic Policy? High Debt, Slow Growth, Financial Instability, Growing Inequality: What Role for Economic Policy? Paul van den Noord Counsellor to the Chief Economist, OECD 1 Central projection growth, annualised, in

More information

Nero Meeting: Alain de Serres OECD Economics Department. 21 June 2013

Nero Meeting: Alain de Serres OECD Economics Department. 21 June 2013 Nero Meeting: The structural reform agenda to boost longterm growth and its side-effects on nearterm activity and other objectives Alain de Serres OECD Economics Department 21 June 2013 Benchmarking exercise

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies

Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies By Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi, Luis Felipe Cespedes, Alessandro Rebucci Bank of Canada and European Central

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

OECD Workshop on effective corporate taxation. Corporate taxation on FDI; Kwang-Yeol. YOO, Korean Ministry of Finance. July.

OECD Workshop on effective corporate taxation. Corporate taxation on FDI; Kwang-Yeol. YOO, Korean Ministry of Finance. July. OECD Workshop on effective corporate taxation Corporate taxation on FDI; 1991-001 Kwang-Yeol YOO, Korean Ministry of Finance July.4th, 006 Table of contents I. How to measure tax burden on FDI II. Tax

More information

INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIOS IN THE NEW OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS MODEL

INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIOS IN THE NEW OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS MODEL INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIOS IN THE NEW OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS MODEL A Dissertation submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in partial fulfillment

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence Loyola University Chicago Loyola ecommons Topics in Middle Eastern and orth African Economies Quinlan School of Business 1999 Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MEA Countries: Theory

More information

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model R. Barrell S.G.Hall 3 And I. Hurst Abstract This paper argues that the dominant practise of evaluating the properties

More information

Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various

Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various VI Investment Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various policy measures or other exogenous shocks depend importantly on how one models the responsiveness of the components of aggregate demand

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Exorbitant Duty. Hélène Rey London Business School CEPR & NBER Nicolas Govillot Mines de Paris

Exorbitant Duty. Hélène Rey London Business School CEPR & NBER Nicolas Govillot Mines de Paris Exorbitant Privilege and Exorbitant Duty PO P.O. Gourinchas UC Berkeley, CEPR & NBER Hélène Rey London Business School CEPR & NBER Nicolas Govillot Mines de Paris Research Agenda on balance sheet of countries

More information

HOUSING MARKETS, BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES

HOUSING MARKETS, BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES HOUSING MARKETS, BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES Austrian National Bank Workshop - Housing Market Challenges in Europe and the US - any solutions available? September 29, 2008 - Vienna Christophe

More information

International Trade Gravity Model

International Trade Gravity Model International Trade Gravity Model Yiqing Xie School of Economics Fudan University Dec. 20, 2013 Yiqing Xie (Fudan University) Int l Trade - Gravity (Chaney and HMR) Dec. 20, 2013 1 / 23 Outline Chaney

More information

Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment

Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment Céline Carrère Université de Genève and CEPR Anja Grujovic Université de Genève Frédéric Robert-Nicoud Université de Genève, SERC and CEPR July

More information

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno Fabrizio Perri Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR fperri@umn.edu December

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Vitor Gaspar Director, Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund Peterson Institute for International Economics June 3, 15 Background The study draws on an

More information

Conference Presentation

Conference Presentation Conference Presentation Trade and long-term unemployment: A quantitative assessment CARRERE, Céline, ROBERT-NICOUD, Frédéric, GRUJOVIC, Anja Abstract We develop a multi-country, multi-sector, gravity model

More information

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities - The models we studied earlier include only real variables and relative prices. We now extend these models to have

More information

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap Peter N Bell University of Victoria 12. April 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/38347/ MPRA Paper

More information

Monetary and Macro-Prudential Policies: An Integrated Analysis

Monetary and Macro-Prudential Policies: An Integrated Analysis Monetary and Macro-Prudential Policies: An Integrated Analysis Gianluca Benigno London School of Economics Huigang Chen MarketShare Partners Christopher Otrok University of Missouri-Columbia and Federal

More information

POLICY STRATEGIES FOR GROWTH- AND EQUITY- FRIENDLY FISCAL CONSOLIDATION

POLICY STRATEGIES FOR GROWTH- AND EQUITY- FRIENDLY FISCAL CONSOLIDATION POLICY STRATEGIES FOR GROWTH- AND EQUITY- FRIENDLY FISCAL CONSOLIDATION Jan Stráský With input from Boris Cournède, André Goujard and Álvaro Pina Prague, 19 October 2015 Remarks The opinions expressed

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

Home Bias in Open Economy Financial Macroeconomics

Home Bias in Open Economy Financial Macroeconomics Home Bias in Open Economy Financial Macroeconomics Nicolas Coeurdacier SciencesPo and CEPR and Hélène Rey London Business School, CEPR and NBER January, 2012 Abstract Home bias is a perennial feature of

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Olivier Blanchard May 25 14.452. Spring 25. Topic 7. 1 Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? An informal walk-through. In the model we

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication. Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

More information

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM Pierre Chaigneau pierre.chaigneau@hec.ca November 8, 2011 Can we price all assets by appropriately discounting their future cash flows? What determines the risk

More information

Market Reforms in the Time of Imbalance: Online Appendix

Market Reforms in the Time of Imbalance: Online Appendix Market Reforms in the Time of Imbalance: Online Appendix Matteo Cacciatore HEC Montréal Romain Duval International Monetary Fund Giuseppe Fiori North Carolina State University Fabio Ghironi University

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

Nils Holinski, Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken. Taking Home Bias Seriously: Absolute and Relative Measures Explaining Consumption Risk-Sharing RM/08/025

Nils Holinski, Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken. Taking Home Bias Seriously: Absolute and Relative Measures Explaining Consumption Risk-Sharing RM/08/025 Nils Holinski, Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken Taking Home Bias Seriously: Absolute and Relative Measures Explaining Consumption Risk-Sharing RM/08/025 JEL code: F36, F41, G15 Maastricht research school of

More information

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles Martin Beraja Erik Hurst Juan Ospina University of Chicago University of Chicago University of Chicago Fall 2017 This Paper Can we use cross-sectional

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union. OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug.

Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union. OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug. Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug. 10, 2014 1 Introduction How do we conduct monetary policy in a currency

More information

Monetary and Macro-Prudential Policies: An Integrated Analysis

Monetary and Macro-Prudential Policies: An Integrated Analysis Monetary and Macro-Prudential Policies: An Integrated Analysis Gianluca Benigno London School of Economics Huigang Chen MarketShare Partners Christopher Otrok University of Missouri-Columbia and Federal

More information

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013 OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 213 CANADA HIGHLIGHTS Canada experienced a decline in business spending on R&D between 21 and 211, despite generous public support, mainly through tax incentives

More information

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853 yw57@cornell.edu Abstract

More information

Volume 29, Issue 1. Juha Tervala University of Helsinki

Volume 29, Issue 1. Juha Tervala University of Helsinki Volume 29, Issue 1 Productive government spending and private consumption: a pessimistic view Juha Tervala University of Helsinki Abstract This paper analyses the consequences of productive government

More information

Diversification through trade

Diversification through trade Diversification through trade by Francesco Caselli, Miklos Koren, Milan Lisicky and Silvana Tenreyro Discussion by: Fabrizio Perri University of Minnesota and Minneapolis FED ESSIM, May 2009 The general

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information