Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs

Similar documents
AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Optimal Selling Strategy With Piecewise Linear Drift Function

Optimal Asset Allocation with Stochastic Interest Rates in Regime-switching Models

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Real Options and Free-Boundary Problem: A Variational View

Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Path Dependent British Options

Optimal investments under dynamic performance critria. Lecture IV

Stochastic Partial Differential Equations and Portfolio Choice. Crete, May Thaleia Zariphopoulou

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

Risk Neutral Valuation

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints. Zongxia Liang

Bandit Problems with Lévy Payoff Processes

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

The British Russian Option

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

A note on the term structure of risk aversion in utility-based pricing systems

The stochastic calculus

The value of foresight

Forward Dynamic Utility

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

MAS452/MAS6052. MAS452/MAS Turn Over SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS. Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics

The British Binary Option

Optimal Execution: II. Trade Optimal Execution

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

Martingale representation theorem

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Non-semimartingales in finance

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Lecture 15: Exotic Options: Barriers

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Risk Sensitive Benchmarked Asset Management

Portfolio optimization for an exponential Ornstein-Uhlenbeck model with proportional transaction costs

Horizon-unbiased Utility of Wealth and Consumption

Dynamic Protection for Bayesian Optimal Portfolio

The End-of-the-Year Bonus: How to Optimally Reward a Trader?

Portfolio optimization with transaction costs

Continous time models and realized variance: Simulations

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

Liquidation of a Large Block of Stock

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Continuous Time Mean Variance Asset Allocation: A Time-consistent Strategy

Doubly reflected BSDEs with jumps and generalized Dynkin games

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Asset-Liability Management

Exact Sampling of Jump-Diffusion Processes

Hedging under Arbitrage

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

On optimal portfolios with derivatives in a regime-switching market

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Research Paper Number 921. Transactions Costs and Portfolio Choice in a Discrete-Continuous Time Setting

A Controlled Optimal Stochastic Production Planning Model

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

1 Dynamic programming

Optimal Investment and Consumption for A Portfolio with Stochastic Dividends

Transcription:

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Gennady Shaikhet supervised by Dr. Gady Zohar

The model Market with two securities: b(t) - bond without interest rate p(t) - stock, an Ito process db(t) = 0 dp(t) = p(t)(µdt + σdw t ) with some b(0) > 0andp(0) > 0; µ>0 - drift-mean rate of return σ>0 -volatility W t -standard Brownian motion defined on a probability space (Ω, F, P).

Denote B(s) - current holdings in bond account S(s) - current holdings in stocks X(s) =B(s)+S(s) - total wealth at time s So the total wealth satisfy and of course dx(s) =S(s)(µdt + σdw s ) X(s) 0, for t s T for some fixed terminal time T and initial t.

At any instance the investor may rebalance his portfolio by moving capital from stocks to bond and vice versa. S(t) = S(t, X(t)) can be taken as control. The aim is to maximize an expected utility at some terminal time T, i.e. to find w(x, t) = sup A E{U(X T ) X t = x} where A - is the set of all admissible controls. The control S(t) = S(t, X(t)) is Markovian - the value we choose at time t depends only on the state of the system at this time. With such control the process X(t) is still a Markov Process.

Merton model ( 70 s ).No transactions case. The solution w(x, t) in this case is well known and is given by the Stochastic Control Methods - HJB equation: w t +sup s [ 1 2 σ2 s(t, x) 2 w xx + µs(t, x)w x ]=0 w(0,t)=0 fort [0,T) w(x, T )= xα α Such that: w(x, t) = xα α eλ(t t) µ 2 α, where λ = 2σ 2 (1 α) And the optimal investment strategy is S µ (t, X t )= σ 2 (1 α) X t So the Merton optimal strategy dictates that it is optimal to keep a fixed proportion of the total wealth invested in stocks.

Proportional transaction costs Norman and Davis (1990) Shreve and Soner (1994) Models with consumption. The local time type of the strategy The policy leads to instantaneous controls, where, one trades continuously and with infinitesimal amounts when the risky proportion process is at boundary. This is not the case in the real world.

Fixed transactions costs. At every intervention time τ i (the time where the investor rebalances his portfolio position) the investor has to pay fixed transaction cost K. Usually he pays the fee from the bond account. Now we have to choose a sequence of intervention times and to trade only at these times and NOT at every instant as it was before, because the fixed component in transaction fee can lead such a policies to bankruptcy.

Definition of control Impulse control for the process is a sequence v =((τ 1,ζ 1 ), (τ 2,ζ 2 ),...) j N ; N τ 1 <τ 2 <... are F t - stopping times ζ j are F τj - measurable random variables representing the corresponding impulses. τ 1,τ 2,... are the intervention times -thetimes when we decide to intervene and give the system the impulses ζ 1,ζ 2,.. respectively. N is the number of interventions. We are looking for w(t, S, B) =max E(U(S T +B T ) S t = S, B t = B) v I over all impulse control policies.

If v = ((τ 1,ζ 1 ), (τ 2,ζ 2 ),...) is applied to the process X(t), it behaves according to : dx(t) =S(t)(µdt + σdw t ), τ j 1 t<τ j T X(τ j )=X(τ j ) K, j =1, 2,...; τ j T B(τ j )=B(τ j ) K ζ j S(τ j )=S(τ j )+ζ j where we put τ 0 =0.

Define Intervention or maximum operator Mw(t, B, S) =max{w(t, B ζ K, S + ζ)} ζ It represents the value of the strategy, that consists of doing the best immediate action and to behave optimal afterwards. It s clear that in general holds: w(t, B, S) Mw(t, B, S), because it s not always optimal to trade at time t. But when it s optimal, then w(t, B, S) =Mw(t, B, S),

Recall the variational inequalities for optimal stopping problem: Suppose that, the process Y (t) V R k satisfies stochastic differential equation of the form dy (t) =b(y (t)) + σ(y (t))dw (t) ; Y (0) = y Define the differential operator L Lφ = k i=1 b i (y) φ y i + 1 2 k i=1 (σσ tr ) ij (y) 2 φ y i y j Find Φ(y) and a stopping time τ<tsuch that Φ(y) =sup τ<t Ey [g(y τ )] for some continuous function g

The main ideas Suppose we can find a sufficiently smooth function φ, such that φ g on V Define the continuation region Lφ 0onV \ D Lφ =0onD D = {x V : φ(x) >g(x)} then τ D = inf{t >0: Y t / D} is the optimal stopping time for this problem and φ(y) =E y [g(y τd )] = Φ(y) = sup τ<t E y [g(y τ )]

The impulse control (main ideas) We are looking for a function w, such that: w Mw on V The continuation region Lw 0onV \ D Lw =0onD D = {(t, B, S) :w>mw} The intervention times are exit times from D.

QVI verification theorem. We say that a sufficiently smooth function w = w(t, B, S) is a solution of the quasi-variational inequalities (QVI) if Lw 0 w Mw and w =Mw on D c (w Mw)Lw =0 w(t,b,s)= U(B, S) Utility function and the impulse control policy is defined as: (τ 0,ζ 0 ):=(0, 0) τ i := inf{t τ i 1 : w(t, B t,s t )=Mw(t, B t,s t )} ζ i =argmax{w(t, B ζ t ζ K, S t + ζ)} Theorem ( Eastham and Hastings (1988)) The impulse control, defined above is optimal.

...QVI s are typically very hard to solve explicitly. This is especially the case when there is a fixed finite time horizon T....I do not know of any general solution method. You are quite right that you have to do the same fantastic work for every problem. In fact, it has been said that these problems are so difficult that every explicit solution is a triumph over nature! Good luck! Best regards, Bernt Oksendal

works about fixed transaction costs Eastham and Hastings (1988) : linear utility function, finite interval. Atkinson and Willmott (1997), Korn (1998) approximation methods. Oksendal and Sulem(2002) : the extension of Shreve and Soner work for case when fixed component is added to transaction costs. Numerical methods Pliska (2002) : has solved explicitly the problem of optimally tracking a target mix of asset categories when there are fixed transaction costs. Infinite interval.

Approximation scheme Assume that the transaction cost is small K = Rε 4, for some const R Recall that in the no transaction case the optimal amount of money, invested in bond is given as B (t) =(1 u)x(t), with u = µ σ 2 (1 α) Rescale our variables by introducing the new variable Y = Y (X t,t): B(t) =B (t)+εy (X t,t)=(1 u)x(t)+εy S(t) =X(t) B(t) =ux(t) εy

assumptions the no-transaction region (NT) has the form D = {(t, x, Y ):Ŷ <Y <Ŷ + } the upper and the lower boundaries of NT are B + εŷ + and B + εŷ the upper and the lower optimal restarting lines are: B + εŷ and B + εy (the signs of Ŷ and Y are negative). all Y s can depend on X(t) Also holds Ŷ Y 0 Y + Ŷ +

The optimal policy is: 1. Don t do anything in the NT region 2. If (X, Y ) reaches either upper or lower boundary (X, Ŷ + )or(x, Ŷ )the investor has to make a transaction and to move it back to NT i.e. to corresponding restarting lines (X, Y + )or(x, Y ). So in what follows we find all the boundaries and restarting lines.

So actually now we have a different process (t, B, S) (t, X, Y ) with another characteristic operator L Lϕ = ϕ t + µ(ux εy )[ϕ X + u 1 ϕ Y ]+ ε 1 2 σ2 (ux εy ) 2 [ϕ XX +2 u 1 (u 1)2 ϕ XY + ε ε 2 ϕ YY ] and the value function has changed as well w(t, B, S) Q(t, X, Y ) More generalized version of QVI is needed Oksendal lecture notes (2002)

In the NT we expand Q as: Q(t, x, Y )=H 0 (t, x)+ε 2 H 2 (t, x)+ε 4 G(t, x, Y )+.. Substitute it into LQ = 0 then order the terms by the powers of ε. Taking only O(1) and O(ε 2 ) equations and using smoothness conditions (t <T): Q(t, x, Y )=Q(t, x k, Y + ) Y Ŷ + Q Y (t, x, Y )=Q Y (t, x k, Y + ) Y Ŷ + as well as optimality of transaction condition d d( y) Q(t, x k, Ŷ + y) y=ŷ + Y + =0 we are able to obtain Ŷ + and Y +. Just the same work is done for the lower bound.

We are free to choose some comfortable form of the Q-function, for instance -the power form Q(t, x, Y )= 1 α (x + ε2 H(t, x)+ε 4 G(t, x, Y )+...) α e λ(t t) with λ = µ2 α 2σ 2 (1 α) Results : Y + =0, Y = 0 and Ŷ + = 4 12Ru2 (u 1) 2 1 α x 3 4 also Ŷ = Ŷ +

Maximizing logarithmic utility. The new value function is w(x, t) = sup A E[ log X T X t = x] The optimal solution is always to keep the same proportion of the whole wealth in stocks. u = b σ 2 and the value function is given as w(t, B, S) =w(t, x) =lnx+λ(t t), where λ = b2 2σ 2 The solution of this problem in the no-transactions case makes us able to approach it now. We get Ŷ + = 4 12Ru 2 (1 u) 2 x 3 4 Notice that this policy can be derived as the limit power utility policy taking α 0.

Goal function Another kind of problems, arising in portfolio optimization context are so called optimal goal problems. w(t, x) = sup A P (X T =1 X t = x) The no transaction case solution was first derived by martingale methods by Heath (1993), Kulldorff (1993) and is as follows: the optimal amount of money held in stock at time s is Ss = 1 ϕ(φ 1 (X s )), t s T T s where Φ( ) is the standard normal distribution function and ϕ( ) is the density of the standard normal distribution. And the value function in this case is given by w(t, x) =Φ(Φ 1 (x)+µ T t).

Try to apply the above approximation method to the goal function problem. Rescale our variables by introducing the new variable Y = Y (t, X t ): S t = S t + εy (X t,t) T t = 1 T t [ϕ(φ 1 (X t )) + εy (t, X t )] As a result we get Ŷ + (X t,t)= 4 12R µ ϕ3 (Φ 1 (X t ))[ T t +Φ 1 (X t )] 2 8 T t