in equilibrium, are supposed to hold across international markets. Covered Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity y( (also called the Law of

Similar documents
HOMEWORK 8 (CHAPTER 16 PRICE LEVELS AND THE EXCHANGE RATE IN THE LONG RUN) ECO41 FALL 2015 UDAYAN ROY

Econ 340. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Outline: Exchange Rates

Assignment 4 Economics 222, Fall 2006 Due: Drop Box 2 nd floor Dunning Hall by noon Nov. 24th, 2006 Maximum Group Size: 4 people

10/14/2011. EXCHANGE RATES I: PPP and THE MONETARY APPROACH IN THE LONG RUN. Introduction to Exchange Rates and Prices

Exchange Rate Fluctuations Revised: January 7, 2012

Chapter 6. International Parity Conditions. International Parity Conditions: Learning Objectives. Prices and Exchange Rates

Rutgers University Spring Econ 336 International Balance of Payments Professor Roberto Chang. Problem Set 2. Deadline: March 1st.

Less Reliable International Parity Conditions

1 trillion units * ($1 per unit) = $500 billion * 2

Midterm - Economics 160B, Fall 2011 Version A

International Parity Conditions

Introduction to Macroeconomics M Problem set 4

CLASS MATERIALS INTERNATIONAL PARITY CONDITIONS

Chapter 2 Foreign Exchange Parity Relations

1+R = (1+r)*(1+expected inflation) = r + expected inflation + r*expected inflation +1

Relationships among Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Interest Rates

Long term exchange rate and inflation

2. Discuss the implications of the interest rate parity for the exchange rate determination.

INTRODUCTION TO EXCHANGE RATES AND THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET

Lower prices. Lower costs, esp. wages. Higher productivity. Higher quality/more desirable exports. Greater natural resources. Higher interest rates

MCQ on International Finance

Replies to one minute memos, 9/21/03

Final exam Non-detailed correction 3 hours

Chapter 16. Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run

Money and Exchange rates

Exchange Rate Regimes and Monetary Policy: Options for China and East Asia

OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS: BASIC CONCEPTS

International Finance

Exchange Rates in the Long Run

International Parity Conditions

8: Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates

Problem Set 4 The currency market

Foreign Exchange Markets: Key Institutional Features (cont)

Homework Assignment #2

National Income & Business Cycles

In frictionless markets, freely tradable goods should have the same price anywhere: S = P P $

to T5? dollar. T4 T1 to T2 but T4 to T5. rate needed to market model) 1 Problem

Chapter 3 Foreign Exchange Determination and Forecasting

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 13. Exchange Rates

Chapter 10. The Foreign Exchange Market

A Primer in International Financial Economics

In this chapter, we study a theory of how exchange rates are determined "in the long run." The theory we will develop has two parts:

Final exam Non-detailed correction 3 hours. This are indicative directions on how structure the essay questions and what was expected.

Global Business Economics. Mark Crosby SEMBA International Economics

OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS: BASIC CONCEPTS

2/10/2011 PREDICTING EXCHANGE RATES: THE LONG-RUN MONETARY APPROACH and the The SHORT-RUN ASSET APPROACH

Chapter 17. Exchange Rates and International Economic Policy

Lessons V and VI: FX Parity Conditions

Open economy macroeconomics and exchange rates Part I

Agenda. Learning Objectives. Chapter 19. International Business Finance. Learning Objectives Principles Used in This Chapter

Exchange rate and interest rates. Rodolfo Helg, February 2018 (adapted from Feenstra Taylor)

Chapter 15. The Foreign Exchange Market. Chapter Preview

Introduction to Exchange Rates and the Foreign Exchange Market

Chapter 11 An Introduction to International Finance Adapted by H. Dellas

CHAPTER 31 INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE FINANCE

Study Questions. Lecture 13. Exchange Rates

Midterm - Economics 160B, Spring 2012 Version A

Yen and Yuan. The Impact of Exchange Rate Fluctuations on the Asian Economies. C. H. Kwan RIETI

Chapter 6. The Open Economy

ECO 328 SUMMER Sample Questions Topics I.1-3. I.1 National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments

INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMIC GROWTH. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

dr Bartłomiej Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

International Parity Conditions. 1. The Law of One Price. 2. Absolute Purchasing Power Parity

Lessons V and VI: Overview

Quoting an exchange rate. The exchange rate. Examples of appreciation. Currency appreciation. Currency depreciation. Examples of depreciation

Chapter 13 Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy

LECTURE XIII. 30 July Monday, July 30, 12

MBF1223 Financial Management Prepared by Dr Khairul Anuar

Forward Foreign Exchange

Open economy macroeconomics and exchange rates Part I

What does the Eurostat-OECD PPP Programme do? Why is GDP compared from the expenditure side? What are PPPs? Overview

05/07/55. International Parity Conditions. 1. The Law of One Price

International Parity Conditions

Part I: Multiple Choice (36%) circle the correct answer

Widening Deviation among East Asian Currencies

Regional Monetary Cooperation in East Asia against Asymmetric Responses to the US Dollar Depreciation 1)

BBM2153 Financial Markets and Institutions Prepared by Dr Khairul Anuar

EconS 327 Test 2 Spring 2010

The Big Mac Index and the Valuation of the Chinese Currency

Nominal exchange rate

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

Yen and Yuan RIETI, Tokyo

Exam 2 Sample Questions FINAN430 International Finance McBrayer Spring 2018

Governments and Exchange Rates

The Foreign Exchange Market

Madura: International Financial Management Chapter 8

The Balassa-Samuelson Relationship and the Renminbi

Parity Conditions in International Finance and Currency Forecasting. Chapter 4

Chapter 17 Appendix A

Introduction to Macroeconomics M

International Parity Conditions. Introduction. Parity Conditions. Fall Stephen Sapp

Chapter 9. Forecasting Exchange Rates. Lecture Outline. Why Firms Forecast Exchange Rates

ECN 160B SSI Midterm Exam July 11 th, 2012

International Macroeconomics

Answers to Questions: Chapter 7

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Guest Lecture: Currency Manipulation and Currency Misalignment 3/27/2017

The Open Economy. Inflation Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER 5

Lectures 24 & 25: Determination of exchange rates

A SIMULTANEOUS-EQUATION MODEL OF THE DETERMINANTS OF THE THAI BAHT/U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE

Transcription:

Week 4 The Parities

The Parities There are three fundamental parity conditions that, in equilibrium, are supposed to hold across international markets. Covered Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity y( (also called the Law of One Price ) Uncovered Interest Rate Parity (also called the International Fisher effect ).

Covered Interest t Rate Parity The covered interest rate parity is simply a fancy term for the relation between the forward price, the spot, and interest rates (that we have already seen): F = S(1 + r n/36)/(1 + r*n/360). In other words, the forward premium or discount for one currency relative to another should be proportional to the difference between nominal interest rates. If this relation does not hold, then there is an arbitrage. In equilibrium, there should not be arbitrage opportunities. Therefore, this relation should always hold.

The Other Two Parities Unlike the covered interest rate parity, the PPP and the uncovered interest rate parities are not arbitrage relationships. They are relationships that we expect to hold in equilibrium but if they do not hold, it may not be possible to arbitrage the violation of the parity. Because we cannot arbitrage them, we only expect these parities to hold over the long run. In the long run, what factors would we expect to determine the exchange rate?

In general, we will see that one might expect inflation, interest rates, and exchange rates (across the two countries) to be determined simultaneously. We will express the relation between exchange rates and inflations in terms of a Purchasing Power Parity (or the Law of One Price). And we will term the relation between exchange rates and interest rates as the International Fisher Effect or the Uncovered interest rate parity. This is a fancy term for the carry trade.

Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) We use money to buy goods. Given a certain amount of money, should we, in the long run, be able to buy the same quantity of goods in either country? If we can, then given the existing gp price levels (or inflation) in each country, we should be able to figure out the exchange rate. P(DC) = S(DC/FC) x P*(FC) Here, P is the price-level in the domestic country,and P* is the price level in the foreign country (FC). S=exchange rate in direct terms. This equation is called the Law of One Price. We can use the PPP to compute the real exchange rate.

Real Exchange Rate The real exchange rate is defined as the ratio of the actual exchange rate and the exchange rate implied by PPP. Real S = (Actual S)/(PPP Implied Exchange Rate) If there was PPP, then the real exchange rate would be equal to 1. If it is greater than 1, then the foreign currency is overvalued relative to the domestic currency (and, of course, the domestic currency is undervalued.) If it is less than 1, the foreign currency is undervalued relative to the domestic currency.

An Illustration The Economist constructs the Big Mac Index as a (light-hearted) way of computing PPP using the prices of Big Macs across different countries. The current level (July 2007) of the index is provided here: http://www.economist.com/finance/displaystory.cf m?story_id=9448015 These rates can be compared to those prevailing a year ago as noted in the following article from 2006.

Italians like their coffee strong and their currencies weak. That, at least, is the conclusion one can draw from their latest round of grumbles about Europe's single currency. But are the Italians right to moan? Is the euro overvalued? Our annual Big Mac index (see table) suggests they have a case: the euro is overvalued by 17% against the dollar. How come? The euro is worth about $1.22 on the foreign-exchange markets. A Big Mac costs 2.92, on average, in the euro zone and $3.06 in the United States. The rate needed to equalise the burger's price in the two regions is just $1.05. To patrons of McDonald's, at least, the single currency is overpriced.

Calculation of PPP and Real Exchange Rate How does one compute the real over- or under-valuation? One Big Mac cost $3.06 in the US, and Euro 2.92, on average, in the Euro Zone. The current exchange rate is 1.22 $/Euro. The Big Mac PPP implies an absolute PPP implied exchange rate of 3.06/2.92=1.05 $/Euro. Thus, the real exchange rate (in direct terms for the US): Real Rate = Actual/PPP = (1.22)/(1.05)=1.1642. So the Euro is 16.42% stronger in real terms compared to the US$. In indirect terms, the real rate is 1/1.1642. Therefore, the US$ is (1-1/1.1642)=(1 0.86) = 14% weaker in real terms relative to the Euro.

Here is another way of computing the real rate, which is equivalent to the earlier methodology hdl (please (l verify). if) The cost of a Big Mac in US is $3.06. The cost of a Big Mac in China is $1.27. Thus, the amount of money that buys 1 Big Mac in China buys only 0.415 (1.27/3.06) Big Macs in US. Thus, the real value of the Chinese Yuan is 0.415. Equivalent, the Yuan is 58.5% (1-0.415) undervalued against the US$. By the Big Mac index, the Chinese currency is the most undervalued currency in the world (and the Swiss Franc, by 65%, is the most overvalued).

Rates in 2007 Referring to the July 2007 article from the Economist on the Big Mac Index, how have the real value of the US$ changed relative to the Euro?

Real Impact of the Asian Currency Crisis The following example is instructive in understanding the real impact of the Asian currency crisis. (From The Economist (2/7/1998)) Indonesia: 1996 GDP = $226b, 1998 Feb: $51b. However, GDP measured in PPP = $1020b. S Korea: 1996 GDP =$485b, 1998 Feb=$272b, GDP using PPP = 660 B.$ Hong Kong: 1998: $188b, and PPP is also 190b (That is, no change).. Singapore also had little change in GDP on a PPP basis.

Why should PPP not hold for a single good? Do we really expect PPP to hold for every single good? Here are some good reasons why PPP would not hold at the single good level. 1. Transaction costs of undertaking spatial arbitrage. 2. The goods may not be equivalent, or the perceived quality might be different. 3. Tariffs and other trade barriers may prevent arbitrage. 4. The good may not be tradable.

So why are Big Mac prices so different across countries? Big Macs are perishable, so cannot be traded. However, if the components of the Big Mac (labor, material, other costs) are tradable, then we again might expect the Big Mac prices to converge. However, major components of costs are not tradable labor, electricity, and rent. These costs comprise between 55 and 64% of the cost of the Big Mac. For more detail, see David Parsley and Shang-Jin Wei, A Prism into PPP Puzzles. http://www2.owen.vanderbilt.edu/david.parsley/research.htm)

Absolute PPP Traditionally, we do not compare PPP at the level of a single good. We do so using price indices. Absolute PPP: P(US) = S ($/FC) x P*(FC) This is the same as what we saw earlier, except that P, P* are now the price indices (like the CPI). All the reasons that suggest why PPP would not hold for a single good also apply when we compute PPP using price indices. In addition, absolute PPP may not hold for yet another reason: The weights that construct ct the price deflator may be different in different countries, depending on the relative importance of the good in the country.

Alternative to Absolute PPP In fact, even within a single country, the relative importance of a consumption item changes. For example, the basket used dto calculate l the CPI in the US has recently (1997-98) been changed to include, amongst others, communication costs, and the fact that Americans eat more pasta than meat than in 1987 (when the previous update took place.) Given all these problems, it is not surprising if absolute PPP does not hold. Thus, we instead ask whether PPP holds in a relative sense.

Relative PPP Suppose we assume that the exchange rates at some point in time (either now or in the past) was correct. Then, assuming relative PPP, we expect that the exchange rate changes thereafter should reflect relative difference in iflti inflations. S(t) = exchange rate at time t S(T) = PPP implied exchange rate at time T (after t) I = cumulative domestic inflation between T and t I* = cumulative foreign inflation between T and t Then: S(T) = S(t) (1 + I)/(1+I*) [S(T) - S(t)]/S(t) = (I - I*)/(1 + I*)

Real Exchange Rate using Price Indices Consider the base year as 1973. The CPI for US=40.3, and Japan=44. The exchange rate then was $0.003762/Yen. In 1989: the CPI for US is 117.2 and Japan is 104.6. The exchange rate is $0.006971/Y. 006971/Y The PPP implied exchange rate for 1989 is: 0.003762 (117.2/40.3)/(104.6/44)=$0.004602. / ) The real exchange rate in 1989: actual/ppp= 0.006971/0.004602=1.5148. 006971/0 004602 1 Thus, the Yen has appreciated in real terms, and is overvalued by 51.48%.

Real Effective Exchange Rate The effective exchange rate (or the trade-weighted exchange rate) is defined as an average of the country s exchange rates with its trading partners, weighted by the proportion of trade done with it. Thus, it is a measure of the competitiveness i of the country. Suppose the base year is 1995, and US has 60% of its trade with Japan, and 40% of its trade with Germany.Suppose the actual exchange rate in the base year was 100Yen/$, and DM 1.5/$. Let the effective exchange rate index be defined to be 100 in this base year.

In 1996: suppose the actual exchange rate is Yen105/$, and DM1.65/$. The effective real exchange rate is then:100 [(105/100)x0.60 + (1.65/1.5)x0.4]=107. 5) 107 So that the US$ has appreciated by 7%, against its trading partners. The effective exchange rate is useful when we we are trying to determine the overall effect of exchange rate changes on the country s trade. If we use real exchange rates to make the above calculations, then the real effective exchange rate will give us an overall picture of the competitiveness of the US economy in the global economy.

Empirical Evidence for PPP First, of all it is important to understand that the inflation series is less volatile than exchange rates - so there is going to be considerable noise when we compare the two series. Empirical ii evidence seems to suggest that there are persistent deviations from PPP both in the short and long run.

Empirical Evidence for PPP 1. In a simple regression of changes in nominal exchange rate on inflation differentials, the slope coefficient is less than 1. Thus, the exchange rate change is less than what one would expect. (This is not entirely surprising, as one would expect that inflation is only one of the factors that determine exchange rate changes.). 2. The slope coefficient increases with the length of the interval. 3. The coefficient is stronger under hyperinflation.

Other Evidence The regression tests demonstrate the simple observation that the exchange rate series is far more volatile than the inflation series. Perhaps it is worth asking how long and by how much the real exchange rate can vary from 1. This can be tested by checking if the changes in the real exchange rate follow a random walk. Abuaf and Jorian (Journal of Finance, 1990) find that the real exchange rate seems to mean-revert to 1, but may take 3-5 years to reduce its over/under valuation by half.

Uncovered Interest Rate Parity What should be the relation between exchange rates and interest rates? Suppose you have a choice of investing your money in USA at the eurodollar interest rate, r, or in Japan at the euro-yen interest rate, r*. Which will you choose? Of course, as we have seen before, that if you invested in the foreign currency and hedged yourself, then the covered interest rate parity (i.e. by the definition of the forward rate) tells you that, in either case, you should earn the same amount. But what if you did not want to hedge yourself?

In the long run, if economies were globally integrated then one might again expect that it should not matter. Suppose S(t) is the current spot rate, and S(t+1) is the spot rate you expect to hold ldin the future (so to be precise we should actually write it as E[S( t+1)]). If you invest $1 today in the US, you will get $(1+r) one year from now. If you invest $1 in the foreign currency, you expect to get $(1)(1+r*)( s(t+1)/s(t) ).

So that if in equilibrium you were indifferent between the two, then you should expect E[S(t+1)] = S(t)(1 + r)/(1 + r*) This is the same equation as we had earlier for the forward price except that we replaced the forward price, F, by the expected future spot price, E[S(t+1)].

As previously we can rewrite this as: [E(S(t+1)-S(t)]/S(t) S(t)]/S(t) = (r-r*)/(1+r*) r r ) So that the expected change in spot rate is approximately equal to the difference in interest rates. This suggests that if the domestic interest rate is higher than the foreign, then investors expect a depreciation of the US$, and if its lower than the foreign then they expect an appreciation i of the $. This is the same as saying that the speculators expect tthe future spot rate to be the forward rate.

Empirical Evidence The empirical evidence regarding the central prediction of the interest rate parity is very poor. We can, as we did with the PPP, test the relation by a linear regression: if we regress (S[t+1]- S[t])/S[t] []) [] on interest rate differentials,,(r-r*), then the theory would indicate a slope coefficient of 1. But when we do the empirical test, we rarely get such a coefficient, and even sometimes get a negative slope coefficient! For example, the Japanese interest rates have been about consistently lower than the US for the last few years - but the fluctuations in the Yen have included d both a 20% depreciation, and a 20% appreciation.