A Model with Costly-State Verification

Similar documents
Macroeconomic Models. with Financial Frictions

A Model of Financial Intermediation

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Notes for a Model With Banks and Net Worth Constraints

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Utility Maximizing Entrepreneurs and the Financial Accelerator

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

Understanding the Aggregate Effects of Credit Frictions and Uncertainty *

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model

The Financial Accelerator and the Optimal Lending Contract

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy I

Money, Sticky Wages, and the Great Depression

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Reserve Requirements and Optimal Chinese Stabilization Policy 1

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Evaluating Macroprudential Policy in a DSGE Framework with Financial Frictions

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

... The Great Depression and the Friedman-Schwartz Hypothesis Lawrence J. Christiano, Roberto Motto and Massimo Rostagno

Abstract: JEL classification: E32, E44, E52. Key words: Bank capital regulation, banking instability, financial friction, business cycle

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

1 Dynamic programming

Mortgage Amortization and Amplification

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Incorporate Financial Frictions into a

Interest-rate pegs and central bank asset purchases: Perfect foresight and the reversal puzzle

Booms and Banking Crises

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Banks balance sheets, uncertainty and macroeconomy

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Risk Aversion and the Financial Accelerator *

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Energy and Capital in a New-Keynesian Framework

... The Great Depression and the Friedman-Schwartz Hypothesis Lawrence J. Christiano, Roberto Motto and Massimo Rostagno

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Risk, Uncertainty, and Financial Frictions

Bank Leverage Regulation and Macroeconomic Dynamics

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model. Lawrence J. Christiano Daisuke Ikeda

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Financial Frictions, Financial Shocks, and Aggregate Volatility

Unconventional Monetary Policy

Asset Prices and Business Cycles with. Financial Frictions

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

The new Kenesian model

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

On the new Keynesian model

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Estimating Contract Indexation in a Financial Accelerator Model. Charles T. Carlstrom, Timothy S. Fuerst, Alberto Ortiz, and Matthias Paustian

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

U.S. Business Cycles, Monetary Policy and the External Finance Premium *

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Estimating Contract Indexation in a Financial Accelerator Model

Banks, Credit Market Frictions, and Business Cycles

Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Uncertainty Shocks, Financial Frictions and Business Cycle. Asymmetries Across Countries

... Monetary Policy and a Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycle. Lawrence Christiano, Roberto Motto, Massimo Rostagno

The Bank Lending Channel and Monetary Policy Transmission When Banks are Risk-Averse

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy

Volume 35, Issue 1. Monetary policy, incomplete asset markets, and welfare in a small open economy

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Asset-price driven business cycle and monetary policy

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

The Zero Lower Bound

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Transcription:

A Model with Costly-State Verification Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 19, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 1 / 47

A Model with Costly-State Verification Tradition of financial accelerator of Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999), Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), and Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2009). Elements: 1 Information asymmetries between lenders and borrowers costly state verification (Townsend, 1979). 2 Debt contracting in nominal terms: Fisher effect. 3 Changing spreads. We will calibrate the model to reproduce some basic observations of the U.S. economy. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 2 / 47

Flowchart of the Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 3 / 47

Households Representative household: E 0 t=0 β t e d t { ( )} mt u (c t, l t ) + υ log p t d t is an intertemporal preference shock with law of motion: d t = ρ d d t 1 + σ d ε d,t, ε d,t N (0, 1). Why representative household? Heterogeneity? Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 4 / 47

Asset Structure The household saves on three assets: 1 Money balances, m t. 2 Deposits at the financial intermediary, a t, that pay an uncontingent nominal gross interest rate R t. 3 Arrow securities (net zero supply in equilibrium). Therefore, the household s budget constraint is: where: c t + a t p t + m t+1 p t = w t l t + R t 1 a t 1 p t + m t p t tre t = (1 γ e ) n t w e + T t + Ϝ t + tre t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 5 / 47

Optimality Conditions The first-order conditions for the household are: Asset pricing kernel: e d t u 1 (t) = λ t { λ t = βe t R t λ t+1 Π t+1 u 2 (t) = u 1 (t) w t SDF t = E t β λ t+1 λ t and standard non-arbitrage conditions. } Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 6 / 47

The Final Good Producer Competitive final producer with technology ( 1 y t = 0 ) ε y ε 1 ε 1 ε it di. Thus, the input demand functions are: y it = ( pit p t ) ε y t i, Price level: ( 1 p t = 0 ) 1 pit 1 ε 1 ε di. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 7 / 47

Intermediate Goods Producers Continuum of intermediate goods producers with market power. Technology: where y it = e z t k α it 1 l 1 α it z t = ρ z z t 1 + σ z ε z,t, ε z,t N (0, 1) Cost minimization implies: ( ) 1 1 α ( ) 1 α wt 1 α rt mc t = α 1 α α e z t k t 1 l t = α 1 α w t r t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 8 / 47

Sticky Prices Calvo pricing: in each period, a fraction 1 θ of firms can change their prices while all other firms keep the previous price. Then, the relative reset price Π t = p t /p t satisfies: εg 1 t = (ε 1)g 2 t g 2 t gt 1 = λ t mc t y t + βθe t Πt+1g ε t+1 1 ( Π = λ t Πt y t + βθe t Πt+1 ε 1 ) t gt+1 2 Π t+1 Given Calvo pricing, the price index evolves as: 1 = θπ ε 1 t + (1 θ) Π 1 ε t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 9 / 47

Capital Good Producers I Capital is produced by a perfectly competitive capital good producer. Why? It buys installed capital, x t, and adds new investment, i t, to generate new installed capital for the next period: ( [ ]) it x t+1 = x t + 1 S i t where S [1] = 0, S [1] = 0, and S [ ] > 0. Alternative: i t 1 1 Adjustment cost in capital. 2 Time to build. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 10 / 47

Capital Good Producers II Technology illiquidity. Importance of irreversibilities? The period profits of the firm are: ( [ ]) ) it q t (x t + 1 S i t q t x t i t = q t (1 S i t 1 where q t is the relative price of capital. [ it i t 1 ]) i t i t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 11 / 47

Capital Good Producers III q t (1 S Discounted profits: E 0 β t λ t t=0 λ 0 ( [ ]) ) it (q t 1 S i t i t i t 1 Since this objective function does not depend on x t, we can make it equal to (1 δ) k t 1. First-order condition of this problem is: [ it i t 1 ] [ ] ) S it it λ t+1 + βe t q t+1 S i t 1 i t 1 λ t and the law of motion for capital is: k t = (1 δ) k t 1 + [ it+1 i t ( [ ]) it 1 S i t i t 1 ] ( ) 2 it+1 = 1 i t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 12 / 47

Entrepreneurs I Entrepreneurs use their (end-of-period) real wealth, n t, and a nominal bank loan b t, to purchase new installed capital k t : q t k t = n t + b t p t The purchased capital is shifted by a productivity shock ω t+1 : 1 Lognormally distributed with CDF F (ω) and 2 Parameters µ ω,t and σ ω,t 3 E t ω t+1 = 1 for all t. Therefore: E t ω t+1 = e µ ω,t+1 + 1 2 σ2 ω,t+1 = 1 µω,t+1 = 1 2 σ2 ω,t+1 This productivity shock is a stand-in for more complicated processes such as changes in demand or the stochastic quality of projects. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 13 / 47

Entrepreneurs II The standard deviation of this productivity shock evolves: log σ ω,t = (1 ρ σ ) log σ ω + ρ σ log σ ω,t 1 + η σ ε σ,t, ε σ,t N (0, 1). The shock t + 1 is revealed at the end of period t right before investment decisions are made. Then: log σ ω,t log σ ω = ρ σ (log σ ω,t 1 log σ ω ) + η σ ε σ,t σ ω,t = ρ σ σ ω,t 1 + η σ ε σ,t More general point: stochastic volatility. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 14 / 47

Entrepreneurs III The entrepreneur rents the capital to intermediate goods producers, who pay a rental price r t+1. Also, at the end of the period, the entrepreneur sells the undepreciated capital to the capital goods producer at price q t+1. Therefore, the average return of the entrepreneur per nominal unit invested in period t is: R k t+1 = p t+1 p t r t+1 + q t+1 (1 δ) q t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 15 / 47

Debt Contract Costly state verification framework. For every state with associated Rt+1 k, entrepreneurs have to either: 1 Pay a state-contingent gross nominal interest rate R l t+1 on the loan. 2 Or default. If the entrepreneur defaults, it gets nothing: the bank seizes its revenue, although a portion µ of that revenue is lost in bankruptcy. Hence, the entrepreneur will always pay if it ω t+1 ω t+1 where: R l t+1b t = ω t+1 R k t+1p t q t k t If ω t+1 < ω t+1, the entrepreneur defaults, the bank monitors the entrepreneur and gets (1 µ) of the entrepreneur s revenue. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 16 / 47

Zero Profit Condition The debt contract determines Rt+1 l to be the return such that banks satisfy its zero profit condition in all states of the world: ωt+1 +(1 µ) [1 F (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )] R l t+1b t }{{} Revenue if loan pays ωdf (ω, σ ω,t+1 ) Rt+1p k t q t k t } 0 {{ } Revenue if loan defaults = s t R t b t }{{} Cost of funds s t = 1 + e s+ s t is a spread caused by the cost of intermediation such that: s t = ρ s s t 1 + σ s ε s,t, ε s,t N (0, 1). For simplicity, intermediation costs are rebated to the households in a lump-sum fashion. External finance premium. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 17 / 47

Optimality of the Contract This debt contract is not necessarily optimal. However, it is a plausible representation for a number of nominal debt contracts that we observe in the data. Also, the nominal structure of the contract creates a Fisher effect through which changes in the price level have an impact on real investment decisions. Importance of working out the optimal contract. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 18 / 47

Characterizing the Contract I Define share of entrepreneurial earnings accrued to the bank: Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) = ω t+1 (1 F (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )) + G (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) where: G (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) = ωt+1 0 ωdf (ω, σ ω,t+1 ) Thus, we can rewrite the zero profit condition of the bank as: R k t+1 s t R t [Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) µg (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )] q t k t = b t p t which gives a schedule relating R k t+1 and ω t+1. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 19 / 47

Characterizing the Contract II Now, define the ratio of loan over wealth: ϱ t = b t /p t n t = q tk t n t n t = q tk t n t 1 and we get R k t+1 s t R t [Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) µg (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )] (1 + ϱ t ) = ϱ t that is, all the entrepreneurs, regardless of their level of wealth, will have the same leverage, ϱ t. A most convenient feature for aggregation. Balance sheet effects. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 20 / 47

Problem of the Entrepreneur Maximize its expected net worth given the zero-profit condition of the bank: max ϱ t,ω t+1 E t R k t+1 R t (1 Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )) + [ ] R k η t+1 t s t R t [Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) µg (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )] ϱ t 1+ϱ t After a fair amount of algebra: E t R k t+1 R t (1 Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )) = E t η t n t q t k t where the Lagrangian multiplier is: η t = s t Γ ω (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) Γ ω (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) µg ω (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) This expression shows how changes in net wealth have an effect on the level of investment and output in the economy. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 21 / 47

Death and Resurrection At the end of each period, a fraction γ e of entrepreneurs survive to the next period and the rest die and their capital is fully taxed. They are replaced by a new cohort of entrepreneurs that enter with initial real net wealth w e (a transfer that also goes to surviving entrepreneurs). Therefore, the average net wealth n t is: n t = γ e 1 [ ] (1 µg (ω t, σ ω,t )) R k b t 1 t q t 1 k t 1 s t 1 R t 1 + w e Π t p t 1 The death process ensures that entrepreneurs do not accumulate enough wealth so as to make the financing problem irrelevant. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 22 / 47

The Financial Intermediary A representative competitive financial intermediary. We can think of it as a bank but it may include other financial firms. Intermediates between households and entrepreneurs. The bank: 1 Lends to entrepreneurs a nominal amount b t at rate R l t+1, 2 But recovers only an (uncontingent) rate R t because of default and the (stochastic) intermediation costs. 3 Thus, the bank pays interest R t to households. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 23 / 47

The Monetary Authority Problem Conventional Taylor rule: R t R = ( Rt 1 R ) γr ( ) γπ (1 γ Πt R ) ( ) y γy (1 γ R ) t exp (σ m m t ) Π y through open market operations that are financed through lump-sum transfers T t. The variable Π represents the target level of inflation (equal to inflation in the steady-state), y is the steady state level of output, and R = Π β the steady state nominal gross return of capital. The term ε mt is a random shock to monetary policy distributed according to N (0, 1). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 24 / 47

Aggregation Using conventional arguments, we find expressions for aggregate demand and supply: where v t = 1 0 y t = c t + i t + µg (ω t, σ ω,t ) (r t + q t (1 δ)) k t 1 y t = 1 v t e z t k α t 1l 1 α t ( pit p t ) ε di is the ineffi ciency created by price dispersion. By the properties of Calvo pricing, v t evolves as: v t = θπ ε tv t 1 + (1 θ) Π ε t. We have steady state inflation Π. Hence, v t = 0 and monetary policy has an impact on the level and evolution of measured productivity. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 25 / 47

Equilibrium Conditions I The first-order conditions of the household: e d t u 1 (t) = λ t R t λ t = βe t {λ t+1 } Π t+1 u 2 (t) = u 1 (t) w t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 26 / 47

Equilibrium Conditions II The first-order conditions of the intermediate firms: εg 1 t = (ε 1)g 2 t g 2 t gt 1 = λ t mc t y t + βθe t Πt+1g ε t+1 1 ( Π = λ t Πt y t + βθe t Πt+1 ε 1 ) t gt+1 2 mc t = Π t+1 k t 1 = α w t l t 1 α r t ( ) 1 1 α ( ) 1 α wt 1 α rt α 1 α α e z t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 27 / 47

Equilibrium Conditions III Price index evolves: Capital good producers: 1 = θπ ε 1 t q t (1 S [ it i t 1 +βe t λ t+1 λ t q t+1 S k t = (1 δ) k t 1 + + (1 θ) Π 1 ε t ] S [ it [ it+1 i t 1 ] it i t 1 i t 1 ) ] ( ) 2 it+1 = 1 i t i t ( [ ]) it 1 S i t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 28 / 47

Equilibrium Conditions IV Entrepreneur problem: R k t+1 = Π t+1 r t+1 + q t+1 (1 δ) q t R k t+1 s t R t [Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) µg (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )] = q tk t n t q t k t Rt+1 k E t (1 Γ (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 )) = R ( t 1 F (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) E t s t 1 F (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) µω t+1 F ω (ω t+1, σ ω,t+1 ) R l t+1b t = ω t+1 R k t+1p t q t k t q t k t = n t + b t p t ) nt n t = γ e 1 Π t [ (1 µg (ω t, σ ω,t )) R k t q t 1 k t 1 s t 1 R t 1 b t 1 p t 1 q t k t ] + w e Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 29 / 47

Equilibrium Conditions V The government follows its Taylor rule: R t R = Market clearing ( Rt 1 R ) γr ( ) γπ (1 γ Πt R ) ( ) y γy (1 γ R ) t exp (σ m m t ) Π y y t = c t + i t + µg (ω t, σ ω,t ) (r t + q t (1 δ)) k t 1 y t = 1 v t e z t k α t 1l 1 α t v t = θπ ε tv t 1 + (1 θ) Π ε t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 30 / 47

Equilibrium Conditions VI Stochastic processes: d t = ρ d d t 1 + σ d ε d,t z t = ρ z z t 1 + σ z ε z,t s t = 1 + e s+ s t s t = ρ s s t 1 + σ s ε s,t log σ ω,t = (1 ρ σ ) log σ ω + ρ σ log σ ω,t 1 + η σ ε σ,t Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 31 / 47

Calibration Utility function: u (c t, l t ) = log c t ψ l t 1+ϑ 1 + ϑ ψ: households work one-third of their available time in the steady state and ϑ = 0.5, inverse of Frisch elasticity. Technology: Entrepreneur: α δ ε S [1] 0.33 0.023 8.577 14.477 µ σ ω w e s 0.15 2.528 n n k 2 25bp. For the Taylor rule, Π = 1.005, γ R = 0.95, γ Π = 1.5, and γ y = 0.1 are conventional values. For the stochastic processes, all the autoregressive are 0.95. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 32 / 47

Computation We can find the deterministic steady state. We linearize around this steady state. We solve using standard procedures. Alternatives: 1 Non-linear solutions. 2 Estimation using likelihood methods. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 33 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 34 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 35 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 36 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 37 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 38 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 39 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 40 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 41 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 42 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 43 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 44 / 47

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 45 / 47

How Can We Use the Model? Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2003): Great depression. Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2008): Business cycle fluctuations. Fernández-Villaverde and Ohanian (2009): Spanish crisis of 2008-2010. Fernández-Villaverde (2010): fiscal policy. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 46 / 47

Figure: IRFs of Output to Different Fiscal Policy Shocks Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-State December 19, 2012 47 / 47