Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence (Preliminary and Incomplete*)

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence (Preliminary and Incomplete*)"

Transcription

1 Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence (Preliminary and Incomplete*) Jorge Miranda-Pinto 1, Daniel Murphy 2, Kieran James Walsh 3, and Eric R. Young 4 1 University of Queensland 2 University of Virginia Darden School of Business 3 University of Virginia Darden School of Business 4 University of Virginia and Zhejiang University September 5, 2018 Abstract We develop a theory of saving-constrained households to explain the following facts: 1) Consumption is excessively volatile relative to income (established fact), 2) the fraction of households with marginal propensities to consume near zero increases with the level of households debt, 3) lagged high expenditure is associated with low contemporaneous spending propensities. Our proposed interpretation of these facts is that household expenditure depends on time-varying minimum consumption thresholds that, if violated, yield substantial utility costs. Our theory has implications for the propagation of macroeconomic shocks. Evidence from cross-county variation in the effects of fiscal stimulus on credit markets is consistent with the theory s implications. j.mirandapinto@uq.edu.au murphyd@darden.virginia.edu walshk@darden.virginia.edu ey2d@virginia.edu 1

2 1 Introduction A large literature, building on Hall (1978), documents that the dynamics of consumption deviate substantially from the predictions of the Permanent-Income-Hypothesis. Relative to theory, consumption is excessively volatile and insufficiently persistent given the dynamics of income. Theories of consumer behavior featuring credit constraints have some hope of rationalizing this evidence: when consumption is constrained from above by debt limits, consumption moves with income. Yet recent evidence from microdata documents that many high-debt/low-wealth households exhibit behavior that is inconsistent with credit constraints. Rather than exhibiting large marginal propensities to consume (MPCs) out of income shocks, many high-debt/low-wealth households save all additional income (Sahm et al. (2015), Jappelli and Pistaferri (2014), Misra and Surico (2014)). Why do so many households, especially those with low wealth, save rather than spend out of additional income? And how is it possible to reconcile the existence of many low-mpc households with the fact that consumption tends to be excessively volatile? In this paper we propose a model of consumer behavior to rationalize this evidence. We begin by presenting a new fact that will guide and validate our theory. Using data from the Panel Study of Income and Dynamics (PSID), we show that, conditional on wealth, high lagged expenditure is associated with lower current MPCs out of income, especially for lowwealth households. The notion that prior expenditure is inversely related (or related at all) to current MPCs is, at first glance, both counterintuitive and contrary to standard theory. If anything, modifications to standard theory would predict a positive relationship. Theories of habit formation, for example, would predict that high lagged expenditure should be associated with high desired current expenditure and therefore, if income is mean-reverting, a high contemporaneous MPC. Our proposed interpretation of these facts is that household expenditure depends on time-varying minimum consumption thresholds that, if violated, yield substantial utility costs. These minimum consumption thresholds represent unanticipated shocks such as medical emergencies and auto repairs. When an adverse shock hits a household, it chooses to accumulate debt (reduce wealth) rather than let consumption fall below a threshold level. For example, rather than move out of a house or slash food consumption, households simply accumulate debt when faced with a large, unanticipated expenditure. Maintaining a low net asset position is optimal for these households but it is costly in the sense that, in the event of another adverse shock, households may be forced to consume below the threshold level (e.g., move out of a home or forgo medical care), which is associated with a large utility 1

3 cost. Therefore, households for which consumption is against the minimum threshold use additional income to pay off debt (increase net assets) as a precautionary measure. We refer to these households as saving-constrained households to capture the notion that, in the absence of minimum consumption thresholds, households would save rather than reduce their asset position. Minimum consumption thresholds effectively constrain households saving relative to a frictionless benchmark, just as credit constraints constrain consumption relative to a frictionless benchmark. We develop a heterogeneous-agent model featuring minimum consumption thresholds and calibrate it to match within-household dynamics of expenditure and income from the PSID. The model with time-varying minimum consumption thresholds easily fits the data, including the large within-household ratio of consumption volatility to income volatility, while standard one-asset heterogeneous agent models do not. Furthermore, the model generates the pathdependence of spending propensities that we observe in the PSID. High lagged expenditure is associated with lower contemporaneous propensities to spend because high expenditure is a proxy for households being saving-constrained by high minimum consumption thresholds. The model helps to rationalize a number of additional features of the empirical MPC distribution. Households with high (non-mortgage) debt are more prone to being creditconstrained or savings-constrained, and therefore exhibit a higher prevalence of MPCs near unity or near zero. We show that this pattern is consistent with the MPC distribution from Misra and Surico (2014). Our theory is able to rationalize a number of additional features of the MPC distribution, and we expect that future extensions to the theory, such as incorporating additional assets and liquidity-constrained rich households (Kaplan and Violante (2014)), will further improve the match between theory and data. Our theory has important implications for the propagation of macroeconomic shocks. We show that saving constraints are important for understanding the cross-county relationship between fiscal effects on credit markets and inequality. In particular, high inequality is associated with a larger share of saving-constrained households with low MPCs. Fiscal shocks relax credit markets more (increase interest rates less) in countries with high inequality. A tractable extension of our model with minimum consumption constraints shows that the interest rate response to fiscal stimulus depends on income inequality as in the data. 2 New Evidence on the Joint Dynamics of Income and Consumption It is well-documented that, on average, within-household consumption (C) is nearly as volatile as income (I). Table 1 presents the average coefficient of variation of consumption and income and the AR persistent coefficient of consumption and income from the PSID 2

4 and the same statistics implied by a standard Bewley model. One possible explanation for this fact is that many households are credit-constrained and thus have MPCs out of income near unity. However, recent evidence from microdata documents that a large fraction of high-debt households who would be most likely to be credit-constrained have MPCs near zero. These zero-mpc households suggest that alternative explanations are necessary to rationalize the excess volatility of consumption. Table 1 Volatility and persistence of consumption and income: PSID and Bewley model PSID Bewley Model Avg. Coefficient of Variation (I t ) AR coeff. (I t ) Avg. Coefficient of Variation (C t ) AR coeff. (C t ) Note: The coefficient of variation for consumption (income) is defined as the within-household ratio between the mean and standard deviation of consumption (income) ( σ ). The PSID AR coefficients are estimated after removing household and time µ fixed effects. Model statistics are from quarterly simulations aggregated to a 2-year frequency. The model is a standard Bewley model with uninsured idiosyncratic shocks, one asset, and borrowing constraints. Details of the calibration are in section 3. Here we present a new, likewise puzzling, fact about the joint movement of consumption and income: lagged high expenditure is associated with low contemporaneous MPCs. The PSID is a unique biennial panel dataset that contains household-level information on expenditure and income. The expenditure data is available as of Using this data, we identify episodes of high expenditure (income) for each household based on whether expenditure (income) exceeds its within-household average by a standard deviation. Our main specification is logc it = β 0 High_I it + β 1 High_C it 1 + β 2 High_I it High_C it 1 + γx t + ɛ it, (1) where High_I it is a dummy variable that equals one when the income of households i exceeds the within-household average by a standard deviation at period t. High_C it 1 is defined analogously. X t includes household wealth, the interaction of wealth with high income, and time fixed effects. We also control for household fixed effects. Table 2 shows that the dependence of consumption on having a high-income episode is lower when a household had a high-expenditure episode in the previous period. The effect of lagged high expenditure on current spending propensities is especially strong for low-wealth households (Column 1). One possible interpretation of this evidence is that high lagged expenditure is simply a proxy for lagged high income or wealth (which may be associated with lower spending propensities). The regressions in columns (1) and (2) partially account for this possibility by controlling for wealth (and its interaction with high income). further isolate the role of lagged high expenditure, columns (3) and (4) limit the sample to 3 To

5 Table 2 Effect of Lagged Expenditure on Spending Propensities (PSID) Dependent Variable: Log Consumption (t) [only if High_I t 1 = 0] Low Wealth High Wealth Low Wealth High Wealth High_I t High_C t *** *** *** (0.027) (0.021) (0.034) (0.025) Fraction of av. effect of High Income N 26,166 26,159 21,939 22,038 R Note: A household has high income (consumption) in periods in which income (consumption) is over a standard deviation above average income (consumption) for the household. All regressions control for polynomial terms in household wealth and the interaction of wealth terms with high income. Low-wealth households have average wealth (across time) below the sample median. Robust standard errors in parentheses. households that do not experience high income in the previous period. In these specifications, the role of lagged high expenditure is strong for both high-wealth and low-wealth households, and it is especially strong for low-wealth households. Similar results are obtained when using different measures of expenditure, including expenditure on exclusively non-durable goods. We also report the ratio between our interaction coefficient (β 2 ) and the coefficient of high income in the current period (β 0 ). This represents how important is previous consumption in today s consumption relative to the direct effect of just having higher income today. Consistent with our previous results, the effect of past consumption in current consumption is more important for low wealth households and households that did not experience high income in the previous period. 3 A Theory of Saving-Constrained Households Here we present a theory to rationalize the large volatility and persistence of consumption. We first introduce minimum consumption thresholds into a standard Huggett (1993) model and calibrate it to match the consumption and income dynamics from the PSID. We then demonstrate that the model replicates the dependence of spending propensities on lagged high expenditure (Section 2). Finally, we examine the model s predictions relative to recent evidence that many high-debt households have MPCs near zero. The model features households subject to idiosyncratic income risk and random minimum consumption thresholds. We explore partial equilibrium to illustrate the puzzling nature of our PSID findings and to show that saving-constraints offer a potential resolution. In Section ongoing work we demonstrate how to incorporate saving constraints into a calibrated general equilibrium model with multiple assets, including capital. 4

6 3.1 Model There are many households, each of which has exogenous idiosyncratic stochastic income y and minimum consumption level c. The recursive optimization problem is subject to V (a,y,c) = max c 0,a a { c 1 γ 1 γ λmax{c c,0} + βe[v (a,y,c )] c + 1 R a = y + a, where V is the value function, a is savings, R is the gross interest rate, and c is consumption. If a household consumes below the current realization of the minimum consumption level c it suffers a utility penalty λ(c c), where λ > 0. Given a particular realization of c, a wealthy household voluntarily consumes above it, extremely poor borrowers pay the utility penalty, and households with intermediate wealth borrow/dis-save just enough to consume the minimum. In MPC terms, for a given c, the extremely poor are effectively hand to mouth, the rich have normal MPCs, and many intermediate wealth households have MPCs of exactly zero. Indeed, for an intermediate range of wealth, households facing a minimum consumption shock borrow/dis-save simply to avoid paying the utility penalty. In the absence of the shock, they would have saved more and are thus saving constrained: with an unexpected splash of income, all they do is save and pay down debts, that is, their MPCs are zero. } 3.2 Calibration We assume households make decisions at the quarterly frequency and set γ = 2, β =.99, and a = 2. For simplicity, we set the real quarterly interest rate to 0 (R = 1). For income, we employ a very simple three-state Markov chain that matches two key moment of income (after the removal time and household fixed-effects) from the PSID. In particular, if y {.05, 1, 1.95}, the probability of staying the current state is.7, and the probability of switching to any other state is.15, then aggregating quarterly simulations to the two year frequency yields a coefficient of variation 1 of.46 and an autocorrelation of.10, which approximates what we find in the PSID (after removing fixed effects). Lastly, we choose the minimum consumption process and utility penalty to generate reasonable consumption dynamics. With λ = 100, c {0,.85,1.75}, a.85 probability of staying the current state, and a.075 chance of switching to any other state, we get a consumption coefficient of variation of.41 and an autocorrelation of The coefficient of variation is the standard deviation divided by the mean. 5

7 3.3 Results As we see in Table 3, including the minimum consumption shock improves the fit of the simple model to the PSID. Without this new feature, consumption is far too persistent (.77) and has an unreasonably low coefficient of variation (.14). Introducing c, the coefficient of variation rises to.41 and autocorrelation falls to.32, much closer to the PSID numbers of.40 and.20. Table 3 Summary Statistics: Model vs. PSID PSID Model (c = 0) Model (c > 0) Ave. σ µ (inc.) AR coeff. (inc.) Ave. σ µ (cons.) AR coeff. (cons.) Note: PSID AR coefficients estimated after removing household and time fixed effects. Model statistics are from quarterly simulations aggregated to 2 year frequency. Minimum consumption thresholds help rationalize the inverse relationship between MPCs and lagged expenditure. Table 4 shows that, among low-wealth households, spending propensities out of a high-income realization are lower when households experienced high expenditure in the previous period. To make the results comparable with the PSID, we aggregate eight-quarter episodes into a period and define income and consumption over that period as their eight-quarter average. The intuition for the dependence of MPCs on lagged expenditure is that high lagged expenditure is a proxy for a binding minimum consumption threshold and an associated MPC of zero. The zero-mpc households are evident from the consumption functions of households with different realizations of c. Figure 1 shows that households with the median value of c tend to have consumption that is flat with respect to wealth (MPCs of zero) until wealth is sufficiently high that the minimum consumption threshold is no longer binding. These constrained households use all additional wealth/income to save. However, not all low-wealth households with high realizations of c have MPCs of zero. The poorest households are creditconstrained and cannot even achieve the minimum consumption level. They experience severe dis-utility and consume all additional income, up until they are able to consume at the threshold. What does this imply for the MPC distribution across households? Figure 2 shows the average consumption function across realizations of y and c. Comparing this consumption function with the ergodic wealth distribution (Figure 3), we see that in the ergodic distribu- 6

8 Interaction term Table 4 Effect of Lagged Expenditure on Spending Propensities (Model) Dependent Variable: Log Consumption (t) [only if High_I t 1 = 0] Low Wealth High Wealth Low Wealth High Wealth PSID -0.06*** *** -0.08*** Model (standard) Model with Saving Constraints -0.08*** ** -0.01*** Fraction of av. effect of high income PSID Model (standard) Model with Saving Constraints Note: The model-based estimates are derived from simulations with 100 quarters and 10,000 agents. Standard errors omitted due to high precision of tion many agents have an MPC of zero and the highest MPCs come from the very rich and poor. While MPCs are U shaped in wealth, averaged over coarse wealth quantiles there is not much variation in MPCs by wealth. In Figure 4 we explicitly report the fraction of zero MPC households across wealth quintiles, for households with low wealth. We observe that most of saving-constrained households (binding at c) are in the second and third quantile of wealth. The very poor households in quintile one pay the utility cost of consuming below c, while the richer households in quintile 5 are able to move away from the constraint. 4 Evidence of Saving-Constrained Households from the Consumer Expensiture Survey (CEX) Here we examine the theory s predictions of low-wealth, zero-mpc households using recent estimates of MPC heterogeneity from the CEX. The evidence here complements recent work that documents that large shares of high-debt households plan to save rather than spend additional disposable income (e.g., Sahm et al. (2015)). We follow Misra and Surico (2014) and estimate households consumption response to the 2001 tax rebates in the U.S. We augment their analysis by gathering data on households total wealth and non-mortgage debt. With the additional data at hand, we study whether the micro evidence supports the existence of low-wealth and indebted households with MPCs 7

9 Consumption cbar = 0 cbar =.85 cbar = Wealth Figure 1 Note: The figure shows consumption by wealth (a) for different realizations of c. near zero. The advantage of using the quantile regression approach in Misra and Surico (2014) is that we estimate marginal propensities to consume (MPC) that are heterogeneous across households, even for households with similar observed characteristics. Therefore, taking the MPC estimates we are able to relate the MPC heterogeneity to proxies of debt-burdened households implied by our model. 4.1 The 2001 Tax Rebate The mailing of the 2001 tax rebate was randomized based on the penultimate number of the tax filer social security number. Hence, the rebate receipt was exogenous to individual characteristics. Using households level data on consumption from the CEX and individual tax records, Johnson et al. (2006) estimate the consumption responses to the tax rebate receipt. The main specification in Johnson et al. (2006) is C it+1 = s α 0s M s + α 1X it + α 2 R it+1 + u it+1, (2) 8

10 2 Consumption stochastic cbar cbar = Wealth Figure 2 Note: The figure shows consumption by wealth (a), averaged across realizations of y and c, with and without stochastic c. where C it+1 is household i change in nondurable consumption in the three month periods where the tax rebate was received. M s is a set of time controls that capture seasonal effects and aggregate shocks. The matrix X it contains household controls, in particular average age and the change in the number of family members. The main variable R it+1 is the total dollar amount of tax rebate received by households i in the three months period t + 1. The authors find that between 20 to 40 percent of the tax rebate in 2001 was spent on non-durable goods. To capture the heterogeneity in the consumption responses, Johnson et al. (2006) interact the tax rebate variable R it+1 with indicators variables describing households with low (high) income and low (high) level of liquid assets. The results suggest that households with low income and low assets liquidity have larger responses. Misra and Surico (2014) amend the approach in Johnson et al. (2006) to account for the possibility that consumption responses may be heterogeneous, even within subgroups based on income. The authors estimate a version of equation (1) using quantile regression and find that high-income households are likely to have very low and very high consumption 9

11 Frequency Wealth Figure 3 Note: The figure shows the ergodic wealth distribution with stochastic c. responses to the 2001 (and 2008) tax rebate. As we are interested in understanding the determinants low MPCs, we exploit the Misra and Surico (2014) approach. The main specification is a linear quantile model of the form C it+1 = q(r it+1,x it,m s,λ it+1 ) with λ it+1 R it+1,x it,m s U(0,1), (3) where λ it+1 captures the unobserved heterogeneity in households with similar observed characteristics (R it+1,x it,m s ). Let q(r it+1,x it,m s,τ) the conditional τ-th quintile of C it+1, given observables, for each τ (0,1), the linear quantile model is 2 C it+1 = q(r it+1,x it,m s,τ) = s α 0s (τ) M s + α 1 (τ) X it + α 2 (τ)r it+1. (4) As mentioned above, this model does not impose common MPCs among households with similar observable characteristics. The estimated consumption responses are only common within a quantile τ but are heterogeneous across quantiles, representing unobserved hetero- 2 Misra and Surico (2014) extend the set of households controls X by adding squared age and changes in the squared number of family members. 10

12 Figure 4 Note: The figure shows MPC across wealth quintiles households with wealth below median. geneity. 4.2 Extending the Misra and Surico (2014) Analysis We start by replicating the estimation of α 2 in equation (3) in Misra and Surico (2014). We focus on the estimated tax rebate coefficient of non-durable consumption for the 2001 tax rebate. Then, we gather additional from the CEX on households total wealth and nonmortgage debt. We define wealth as the sum of the balance in checking accounts, saving accounts, U.S. bond, value of stocks, and the value of properties, minus the outstanding mortgage debt and outstanding non-mortgage debt. Non-mortgage debt is composed of credit card debt, bank loans, credit union debt, dentist and hospital debt, finance companies debt, and excludes business debt and car loans. Figure 5 shows the distribution of MPC for the group of low-wealth households (below median wealth). Consistent with our theory, there is large fraction of low-wealth households with very low MPCs. 11

13 Figure 5 MPC distribution low-wealth Households We now study who these zero-mpc households are. We define a dummy variable called zero-mpc that equals one when the MPC is below 0.05 and equal to zero otherwise. Figures 6 and 7 show the fraction of zero-mpc households across quantiles of non-mortgage debt and mortgage debt, respectively. We observe that, consistent with our theory in Figure 4, the fraction of zero-mpc households grows with debt. 12

14 Figure 6 Fraction of low-mpc HH by non-mortgage debt quintile Figure 7 Fraction of low-mpc HH by mortgage debt quintile 5 Cross-Country Testable Implications Our theory has implications for the transmission mechanism of fiscal shocks. In this section, we take advantage of cross-country heterogeneity in income inequality to show that in countries with more debt-burdened households (higher inequality) fiscal shocks generate smaller 13

15 increases (larger decreases) in interest rates. 5.1 The interest rate response to fiscal stimulus and Inequality To estimate country-level fiscal shocks and the interest response to fiscal shocks (IRRFs), we collect quarterly data on real government consumption, real GDP, and interest rates across countries. Obtaining reliable country-level estimates of fiscal shocks requires a sufficient time span of data. Therefore we limit our focus to OECD countries, most of which provide quarterly data that spans a period of over twenty years. The primary data source is the OECD. We supplement the OECD numbers with data from Haver when the Haver sample extends the OECD sample. A detailed description of the data used to estimate fiscal shocks is in Table 6 of our Appendix. Our study focuses on government bond yields because they are the interest rate that is the most widely available for our sample. An advantage of examining yields on longerdated bonds is that yields are not directly controlled by central banks but depend on credit conditions more generally. Our sample includes all OECD countries for which we observe government bond yields for at least 10 consecutive years prior to the end of our estimation period, Our baseline estimation period ends in 2007 in order to avoid structural breaks that may have been associated with the global financial crisis. The results presented below are similar when we include the most recent data, however. We also examine data on shorter-term interest rates, which we refer to as policy rates. We use direct measures of central bank policy rates when available. For countries that do not have policy rate data, we use the short-term interest rate series in Ilzetzki et al. (2013). The policy rates for members of the European Monetary Union (EMU) are equal to European Central Bank rates Country-level estimates of fiscal shocks We identify government spending shocks following the approach in Blanchard and Perotti (2002). The key identification assumption is that, within a quarter, government spending is predetermined with respect to other macro variables. Hence government spending responds contemporaneously to its own shock but not to other shocks in the economy. Based on the delay in the political process that typically justifies this restriction, much of the literature has adopted the Blanchard-Perotti approach (e.g., Bachmann and Sims (2012), Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012), Rossi and Zubairy (2011), Brinca et al. (2016)). Despite the widespread use of the Blanchard-Perotti approach and the plausibility of its identifying assumptions, there are potential limitations. If changes in government spending are anticipated, the Blanchard-Perotti approach will not capture the exogenous component of government spending (Ramey (2011)). To overcome this challenge, Ramey (2011) uses news 14

16 about future defense spending to identify fiscal shocks. As Ilzetzki et al. (2013) point out, this approach is not viable when estimating fiscal shocks across countries. Data on military buildups on which the estimates are based are not available across countries, and even within the U.S. there is little variation in the military measure in the post-war period. Therefore, we adapt the Blanchard-Perotti approach. We acknowledge the potential limitations of this approach but note that the estimated effects of stimulus on interest rates are relatively consistent across empirical specifications, at least for the U.S. (Murphy and Walsh (2017)). As a robustness check, we also identify shocks using semi-annual data on forecast errors for government spending, as in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013). We identify fiscal shocks independently for each country in our sample. To do so, we estimate 4 A 0 X t = A j X t j + ε t, (5) j=1 where X t = [G t,y t,r t ] consists of log real government spending G t, log real GDP, and government bond yields r t. ε t = [ ν t,ε 2 t,ε 3 t ] is a vector of structural shocks, and vt is the shock to government spending. The identifying assumption amounts to a zero restriction on the (1,2) and (1,3) elements of A 0. Unlike Blanchard and Perotti (2002), we do not have quarterly data on tax revenue for our sample. 3, Inequality and the IRRF Here we demonstrate that higher inequality is associated with a lower IRRF, as predicted by our theory. Our measure of inequality is the ratio of the income of the richest 10 percent of the population to the income of the poorest 10 percent, which is provided by the OECD. For each country, we take the average over (inequality is stable over time within countries). There is substantial cross-sectional dispersion in income inequality in our sample. The U.S. is the most unequal country of the sample with an average ratio of 6.2, while Denmark has a ratio of 2.8. Figure 8 documents the inverse relationship between the IRRF and inequality. Indeed, the U.S., which is among the most unequal countries, also has one of the lowest (most negative) IRRFs. 5 What else could account for this inverse relationship? One possibility is that monetary 3 To explore how important is the omission of the tax revenue data, we check how the interest response to fiscal shocks in the VAR changes when tax revenue is included for the U.S. We find that the cumulative one year interest rate response is practically unchanged when tax revenue is added to the VAR. This is consistent with the findings in Ilzetzki et al. (2013) with respect to the output multiplier. 4 We follow Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) and estimate the VAR with the variables in log levels to preserve the cointegration relations. The fiscal shocks backed out from the VAR are stationary. 5 We provide the variance adjusted IRRFs in Figure 2. In Figure 6 of the appendix, we show that a similar relationship holds when using the IRRFs point estimates. Similarly, we find a similar negative relationship between the IRRF and inequality when identify fiscal shocks based on Blanchard and Perotti (2002). See Figure 10 in our Appendix. 15

17 Figure 8 Inequality and Gov. Bond Yield Response policy may be more accommodative of fiscal shocks in unequal countries. The same relationship does not hold when examining policy rates, suggesting that government spending relaxes credit markets relatively more in unequal countries, beyond any response of monetary policy to government spending shocks. 6 This is consistent with the evidence in Murphy and Walsh (2017) that monetary accommodation cannot fully account for the negative IRRF in the U.S. To further isolate the role of inequality from central bank policy and other determinants, we regress the IRRF on measures of central bank independence and financial openness. We use inflation volatility as a measure of central bank independence. There exists a central bank independence (CBI) index from Dincer and Eichengreen (2014). However, this index is only available for a sub-sample of 14 countries. Thus, motivated by Alesina and Summers (1993), who find that the CBI is negatively correlated with the average inflation rate and the volatility of inflation for 16 developed countries in their sample, we use the volatility of inflation as a proxy for central bank independence. Our inflation measures are from the OECD. There is substantial variation: in Iceland and the Slovak Republic the standard deviation of inflation exceeds 3%, while in Germany and Switzerland it is below 1%. Our measure 6 See Figure 11 in our Appendix. 16

18 of financial openness, from Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007), is financial assets plus liabilities, over GDP. Mundell-Fleming predicts that countries that are more open to international financial markets have smaller or zero response of interest rates to fiscal shocks. Table 5 shows that the dependence of the IRRF on inequality, conditional on these other determinants. A one standard deviation increase in inequality is associated with an 15 basis point decline in the IRRF. This relationship remains when adding inflation volatility and financial openness in the regression (columns 2 and 3). It is possible that the relationship between inequality and the IRRF is due to a higher elasticity of output with respect to fiscal stimulus (perhaps due to slack, as in Murphy and Walsh (2017)) in countries with high inequality. In this case, interest rates would increase less in countries with more inequality, resulting in higher fiscal multipliers. One way to control for this channel is to include the fiscal multiplier in the regression. Here we define the fiscal multiplier as the cumulative multiplier over a horizon of one year, consistent with Ilzetzki et al. (2013): 3h=0 y h 3h=0 g h, (6) where y h and g h are the impulse responses of output and government consumption at horizon h. Including the cumulative multiplier has no effect on the estimated dependence of the IRRF on inequality (column 4). These results suggest that the measured relationship is not driven by other mechanisms associated with high fiscal multipliers. 7 6 A Simple Model of Debt-Burdened While the previous cross-country facts are indirectly implied by our theory of saving constrained households, in this section we develop a simple model that analytically relates income inequality (the fraction of debt-burdened households) with the interest rate response to fiscal stimulus. Suppose there are two agent types, rich(r) and non-rich (p). The measure of non-rich agents is π [1/2,1), and the measure of rich agents is 1 π. Each agent elastically supplies up to L units of labor in each period, of which there are two: t {0,1}. In each period, there is a representative private firm that solves Π = max (Al α wl), l where w is the wage, which is stuck, and 0 < α < 1. Given w, firm labor demand is l = (w/(αa)) 1/(α 1). We assume that (1) L > l, (2) the firm randomly hires amongst the agents, 7 A similar relationship between inequality and the IRRF (as in Table 5) holds if we use the GINI coefficient of income instead of the ratio p90p10. 17

19 Table 5 Gov. Bond Yields Response and Country Characteristics (1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Bond IRRF Bond IRRF Bond IRRF Bond IRRF p ** -0.13** -0.12* -0.13* (0.07) (0.06) (0.07) (0.07) St. Dev. Inflation (0.08) (0.09) (0.08) Financial Openness (0.08) (0.08) Fiscal Mult. 4 qtrs (0.08) Constant 0.78* (0.38) (0.37) (0.38) (0.44) Observations R-squared * Note: The standard deviation of inflation is measured using the 4 quarters percent change of the CPI index from the OECD databases. Our measure of financial openness is the ratio financial assets plus liabilities to GDP (Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007)). Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 and (3) A = (w/α) α (a simplifying normalization). Therefore, firm and worker optimization imply that Π + wl = Al α = 1, that l = α/w, and that each agent s private sector labor income is wl = α, a fraction π of which goes to non-rich agents. Moreover, since l < L there is slack in the labor market in the sense that each agent is willing to supply more labor that the private sector is unwilling to hire at the stuck wage w. In t = 0, the government also hires the agents (again, randomly across types). Specifically, the government demands G = G/w < L l units of labor, which the agents are willing to supply since G + l < L. The government uses the workers to produce government goods and effectively buys these goods from itself. For the purposes of national accounting, these public purchases are valued at their cost. So, G = Gw = π Gw +(1 π) Gw is both the public wage paid to each agent and the value of government purchases in the national accounts. GDP or national income is, in the two periods, Y 0 = Π + wl + w G = Al α + G = 1 + G Y 1 = Π + wl + w G = Al α = 1 We assume that the rich collectively own half of firm profits. Thus, the total private sector pre-tax income of the rich is Π/2+(1 π)wl, while the income of a rich individual is y r = Π/(2(1 π))+wl. Similarly, the private sector pre-tax income of a non-rich individual 18

20 is y p = Π/(2π) + wl, so (1 π)y r + πy p = 1. A useful feature of this setup is that a single parameter, π, governs inequality. As π varies between 1/2 and 1, total private income is fixed at Π+wl = 1. However, since the poorest 50% of agents are always non-rich, the total private pre-tax income of the richest 50% of agents is Π + wl 1 2 ( ) Π 2π + wl, which is monotonically increasing in π. Also, as π 1, half of firm profits are owned by an increasingly small fraction of agents. In the first period, the agents and the government trade zero net supply bonds at gross interest rate R. The government pays for purchases with a flat proportional tax τ on private income in the second period. Since (1 π)y r +πy p = 1, the government budget constraint is RG = τ. The problem of an arbitrary agent of type i {r,p} is max {log(c c 0,c 0 ) + log(c 1 )} subject to 1 (i) : c R c 1 = y i + 1 R yi (1 τ) + G (ii) : c 0 c, where c is the minimum consumption level. Recall that G = Gw is wage income from government work, and y i includes both private profits and wages. Since taxes are proportional to private income but government wages are uniform across agents, fiscal policy redistributes from rich to non-rich. Under the above assumptions, equilibrium with slack in the labor market consists of an interest rate R, agent consumption, and taxes τ such that goods markets clear (π ( c p 0,cp 1) + (1 π)(c r 0,c r 1) = (1,1)), consumption solves the agents problems given prices and taxes, and the government budget constraint is satisfied (RG = τ). 8 To restrict attention to the case of interest in which c r 0 > c p 0 = c, we impose the following additional parameter restriction: Π 4 ( 2π 1 π ) G + Π 2π + wl c < 1. Since Π/(2π) + wl < 1 for π > 1/2, there exists c (0,1) satisfying this condition provided 8 The government goods market clears for free since, by assumption, the government consumes whatever it produces. The labor market doesn t clear since each agent is willing to supply L, while at stuck wage w private and public firms only demand l + G < L units of labor from each agent. 19

21 π > 1/2 and G is sufficiently small. In this case, optimal rich consumption satisfies c r 0 = 1 2 G yr ( R (1 τ) ), which after plugging in the government budget constraint becomes c r 0 = 1 2 (1 yr )G + 1 ( 2 yr ). R Finally, imposing market clearing (πc p 0 + (1 π)cr 0 = 1) and y r = Π/(2(1 π)) + wl, we get 1 R = It immediately follows that 2(1 πc) Π 2 + wl (1 π) 1 ( 1 2(1 πc) = R (1 π)y r 1 yr y r G 1 2 (1/R) G π > 0 Π 2(1 π) + wl ) Π 2(1 π) + G 1 wl = 2 R G π < 0. In other words, the impact of G on R is declining in inequality. Note, however, that in this stripped-down model increasing government purchases actually unambiguously decreases the interest rate, contrary to standard intuition. This is because here government spending destroys no resources. It is straightforward to extend the model to include private goods in government production, in which case the sign of R/ G is ambiguous, and in that case we still have 2 R/( G π) < 0. 7 Conclusions We have presented a new set of micro facts on the consumption behavior of U.S households. In particular, using PSID data we find that low wealth households with high lagged expenditure present low contemporaneous spending propensities. On the other hand, using CEX data we find that the share of households with near zero marginal propensities to consume out of tax rebates increases with household debt. To explain these facts, we develop a theory of saving-constrained household. Our proposed interpretation of these facts is that household expenditure depends on time-varying minimum consumption thresholds that, if violated, yield substantial utility costs. In our setting, debt burdens do not reflect credit constraints but rather result from households 20

22 minimum consumption needs. Adverse idiosyncratic shocks, such as emergency expenditures or temporary declines in income, cause households to take on debt rather than experience a decline in non-emergency consumption. This additional debt is burdensome in the sense that households pay it off more quickly out of additional income than they would in the absence of a minimum consumption constraint. Quick debt repayment helps households avoid very low future consumption (and associated welfare loss) in the event of future adverse shocks. Our theory has implications for the propagation of macroeconomic shocks. Evidence from cross-county variation in the effects of fiscal stimulus on credit markets is consistent with the theory s implications. In the cross section, fiscal shocks increase interest rates less (decrease interest rate more) in countries with high income inequality. Motivated by our main model and the additional facts, we present a tractable model of debt-burdened households where the interest rate response to fiscal shocks depends on income inequality as in the data. 21

23 References Alesina, A. and Summers, L. H. (1993). Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance: Some comparative evidence. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 25(2): Auerbach, A. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012). Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(2):1 27. Auerbach, A. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2013). Output spillovers from fiscal policy. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 103(3). Bachmann, R. and Sims, E. R. (2012). Confidence and the transmission of government spending shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(3): Blanchard, O. and Perotti, R. (2002). An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4):1329. Brinca, P., Holter, H. A., Krusell, P., and Malafry, L. (2016). Fiscal mutipliers in the 21st century. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77: Dincer, N. N. and Eichengreen, B. (2014). Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures. International Journal of Central Banking, 10(1): Hall, R. E. (1978). Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 86(6): Huggett, M. (1993). The risk-free rate in heterogeneous-agent incomplete-insurance economies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17: Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. G., and Vegh, C. A. (2013). How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics, 60(2): Jappelli, T. and Pistaferri, L. (2014). Fiscal policy and mpc heterogeneity. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4): Johnson, D. S., Parker, J. A., and Souleles, N. S. (2006). Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of American Economic Review, 96(5): Kaplan, G. and Violante, G. L. (2014). A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments. Econometrica, 82(4):

24 Lane, P. R. and Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2007). The external wealth of nations mark II: Revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, Journal of International Economics, 73(2): Misra, K. and Surico, P. (2014). Consumption, Income Changes, and Heterogeneity: Evidence from Two Fiscal Stimulus Programs. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4): Murphy, D. and Walsh, K. (2017). Government Spending and Interest Rates. Mimeo University of Virginia. Ramey, V. A. (2011). Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It s all in the Timing. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1):1 50. Rossi, B. and Zubairy, S. (2011). What Is the Importance of Monetary and Fiscal Shocks in Explaining U.S. Macroeconomic Fluctuations? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 43(6): Sahm, C. R., Shapiro, M. D., and Slemrod, J. (2015). Balance-Sheet Households and Fiscal Stimulus: Lessons from the Payroll Tax Cut and Its Expiration. NBER Working Papers 21220, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. 23

25 8 Appendix Figure 9 Inequality and Gov. Bond Yield Response (not variance adjusted) Figure 10 Inequality and Gov. Bond Yield Response (Robustness check that controls for anticipated changes in G) 24

26 Figure 11 Inequality and Policy Rates Response 25

27 Table 6 Sample for VAR estimation G GDP Interest Rates Credit Country OECD Haver OECD Haver bond ylds. policy rate BIS Australia 1959-Q Q Q Q Q4 Austria 1988-Q Q Q Q Q4 Belgium 1995-Q Q Q Q4 Canada 1957-Q Q Q Q Q2 Czech Republic 1996-Q Q Q Q Q4 Denmark 1977-Q Q Q Q Q4 Finland 1990-Q Q Q Q Q4 France 1955-Q Q Q Q Q4 Germany 1970-Q Q Q Q Q1 Greece 1970-Q Q Q Q Q1 Hungary 1995-Q Q Q Q Q4 Iceland 1997-Q Q Q Q1 Ireland 1997-Q Q Q Q Q1 Italy 1981-Q Q Q Q Q4 Japan 1957-Q Q Q Q Q4 Korea 1960-Q Q Q Q Q4 Netherlands 1988-Q Q Q Q4 New Zealand 1987-Q Q Q Q Q4 Norway 1961-Q Q Q Q Q1 Poland 1995-Q Q Q Q Q4 Portugal 1995-Q Q Q Q Q4 Slovak Republic 1997-Q Q Q Q2 Slovenia 1995-Q Q Q Q1 Spain 1995-Q Q Q Q Q4 Sweden 1960-Q Q Q Q Q1 Switzerland 1980-Q Q Q Q Q4 United Kingdom 1955-Q Q Q Q Q4 United States 1955-Q Q Q Q Q3 * Supplemented by ECB policy rates since 1999-Q1 ** Supplemented by by short term rates from Ilzetzki et al. (2013) and ECB rates Note: Information in cursive means data were not originally seasonally adjusted 26

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence.

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence. Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence. Jorge Miranda-Pinto 1, Daniel Murphy 2, Kieran Walsh 2, Eric Young 1 1 UVA, 2 UVA Darden School of Business

More information

Saving Constraints, Debt, and the Credit Market Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence

Saving Constraints, Debt, and the Credit Market Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence Saving Constraints, Debt, and the Credit Market Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence Jorge Miranda-Pinto 1, Daniel Murphy 2, Kieran James Walsh 3, and Eric R. Young 4 1 University

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo) Exchange rate regimes and fiscal multipliers Benjamin Born (Ifo Institute) Falko Jüßen (TU Dortmund and IZA) Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo) Fiscal Policy in the Aftermath of the Financial

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY Neil R. Mehrotra Brown University Peterson Institute for International Economics November 9th, 2017 1 / 13 PUBLIC DEBT AND PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH

More information

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries PAOLA PROFETA RICCARDO PUGLISI SIMONA SCABROSETTI June 30, 2015 FIRST DRAFT, PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE WITHOUT THE AUTHORS PERMISSION Abstract Focusing

More information

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? Greg Kaplan New York University Gianluca Violante New York University, CEPR, IFS and NBER Boston University Macroeconomics Seminar Lunch Kaplan-Violante, Insurance

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances Enrique G. Mendoza University of Maryland, IMF & NBER Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR & NBER José-Víctor Ríos-Rull

More information

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Tatjana Dahlhaus Danilo Leiva-Leon November 7, VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper assesses the effect of monetary policy during

More information

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government spending and firms dynamics Government spending and firms dynamics Pedro Brinca Nova SBE Miguel Homem Ferreira Nova SBE December 2nd, 2016 Francesco Franco Nova SBE Abstract Using firm level data and government demand by firm we

More information

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Johannes Wieland University of California, San Diego and NBER 1. Introduction Markets are incomplete. In recent

More information

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments Greg Kaplan University of Pennsylvania Gianluca Violante New York University Federal Reserve Board May 31, 2012 1/47 Fiscal stimulus payments

More information

Day 4. Redistributive and macro effects of fiscal stimulus policies

Day 4. Redistributive and macro effects of fiscal stimulus policies Day 4 Redistributive and macro effects of fiscal stimulus policies Gianluca Violante New York University Mini-Course on Policy in Models with Heterogeneous Agents Bank of Portugal, June 15-19, 2105 p.

More information

Optimal fiscal policy

Optimal fiscal policy Optimal fiscal policy Jasper Lukkezen Coen Teulings Overview Aim Optimal policy rule for fiscal policy How? Four building blocks: 1. Linear VAR model 2. Augmented by linearized equation for debt dynamics

More information

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions By DAVID BERGER AND JOSEPH VAVRA How big are government spending multipliers? A recent litererature has argued that while

More information

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks Eunseong Ma September 27, 218 Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station,

More information

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth Lorenzo Burlon August 11, 2014 In this note we report the empirical exercises we conducted to motivate the theoretical insights

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Georgia State University From the SelectedWorks of Fatoumata Diarrassouba Spring March 29, 2013 Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Fatoumata

More information

Austerity, Inequality, and Private Debt Overhang

Austerity, Inequality, and Private Debt Overhang Austerity, Inequality, and Private Debt Overhang By Mathias Klein a and Roland Winkler b a TU Dortmund University, Department of Economics, Vogelpothsweg 87, 44221 Dortmund, Germany; e-mail: mathias.klein@tu-dortmund.de

More information

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area Presentation by Val Koromzay, Director for Country Studies, OECD to the Brussels Forum, April 2004 1 1 I. Introduction: Why is the issue important?

More information

What determines government spending multipliers?

What determines government spending multipliers? What determines government spending multipliers? Paper by Giancarlo Corsetti, André Meier and Gernot J. Müller Presented by Michele Andreolli 12 May 2014 Outline Overview Empirical strategy Results Remarks

More information

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis Jan Kuckuck and Frank Westermann Working Paper 96 June 213 INSTITUTE OF EMPIRICAL ECONOMIC RESEARCH Osnabrück University Rolandstraße 8 4969

More information

The design of the funding scheme of social security systems and its role in macroeconomic stabilization

The design of the funding scheme of social security systems and its role in macroeconomic stabilization The design of the funding scheme of social security systems and its role in macroeconomic stabilization Simon Voigts (work in progress) SFB 649 Motzen conference 214 Overview 1 Motivation and results 2

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy ECO 209Y Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Lecture 3: Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Income Gustavo Indart Slide 1 Assumptions We will assume that: There is no depreciation There are no indirect taxes

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments Greg Kaplan 1 Gianluca Violante 2 1 Princeton University 2 New York University Presented by Francisco Javier Rodríguez (Universidad Carlos

More information

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER and Sarah Zubairy Texas A&M April 2015 Do Multipliers

More information

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries Davide Furceri University of Palermo Georgios Karras Uniersity of Illinois at Chicago Abstract The main purpose of this

More information

Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality:

Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality: Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality: Evidence from Large Predetermined Payments Lorenz Kueng Northwestern University and NBER Motivation: understanding consumption is important

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011 Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation Gabriele Camera Purdue University YiLi Chien Purdue University August 2011 BROAD VIEW Study impact of macroeconomic policy in heterogeneous-agent

More information

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist? Does the Confidence Fairy Exist? Evidence from a New Narrative Dataset on Fiscal Austerity Announcements Oana Furtuna 1, Roel Beetsma 2 and Massimo Giuliodori 1 1 University of Amsterdam, Tinbergen Institute

More information

Austerity in the Aftermath of the Great Recession

Austerity in the Aftermath of the Great Recession Austerity in the Aftermath of the Great Recession Christopher L. House University of Michigan and NBER. Christian Proebsting EPFL École Polytechnique Fédérale de Lausanne Linda Tesar University of Michigan

More information

Aviation Economics & Finance

Aviation Economics & Finance Aviation Economics & Finance Professor David Gillen (University of British Columbia )& Professor Tuba Toru-Delibasi (Bahcesehir University) Istanbul Technical University Air Transportation Management M.Sc.

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 vs 2008

A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 vs 2008 A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 vs 2008 Greg Kaplan Princeton University & NBER Gianluca Violante New York University, CEPR & NBER American Economic Associa-on Annual Mee-ng January 5, 2013 Fiscal

More information

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK DANMARKS NATIONALBANK WEALTH, DEBT AND MACROECONOMIC STABILITY Niels Lynggård Hansen, Head of Economics and Monetary Policy. IARIW, Copenhagen, 21 August 2018 Agenda Descriptive evidence on household debt

More information

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame Consumption ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2016 1 / 36 Microeconomics of Macro We now move from the long run (decades and longer) to the medium run

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt Econometric Research in Finance Vol. 4 27 A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt Leonardo Augusto Tariffi University of Barcelona, Department of Economics Submitted:

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet MYTH = GLOBALIZATION GENERATES GROWING ECONOMIC WEALTH AND WELL-BEING FOR ALL Fact: Economic growth boils down to rising

More information

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact and forecasting

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact and forecasting Georgia State University From the SelectedWorks of Fatoumata Diarrassouba Spring March 21, 2013 Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact and forecasting

More information

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication. Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

More information

on Inequality Monetary Policy, Macroprudential Regulation and Inequality Zurich, 3-4 October 2016

on Inequality Monetary Policy, Macroprudential Regulation and Inequality Zurich, 3-4 October 2016 The Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks on Inequality Davide Furceri, Prakash Loungani and Aleksandra Zdzienicka International Monetary Fund Monetary Policy, Macroprudential Regulation and Inequality Zurich,

More information

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis University of Western Ontario February 2013 Question Main Question: what is the welfare cost/gain of US social safety

More information

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15 The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15 Jana Hvozdenska Masaryk University Faculty of Economics and Administration, Department of Finance Lipova 41a Brno, 602 00 Czech

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks The Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest Doctoral School of Finance and Banking Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks Coordinator LEC. UNIV. DR. BOGDAN COZMÂNCĂ MSC Student Andreea Alina Matache Dissertation

More information

HOUSEHOLDS LENDING MARKET IN THE ENLARGED EUROPE. Debora Revoltella and Fabio Mucci copyright with the author New Europe Research

HOUSEHOLDS LENDING MARKET IN THE ENLARGED EUROPE. Debora Revoltella and Fabio Mucci copyright with the author New Europe Research HOUSEHOLDS LENDING MARKET IN THE ENLARGED EUROPE Debora Revoltella and Fabio Mucci copyright with the author New Europe Research ECFin Workshop on Housing and mortgage markets and the EU economy, Brussels,

More information

Household finance in Europe 1

Household finance in Europe 1 IFC-National Bank of Belgium Workshop on "Data needs and Statistics compilation for macroprudential analysis" Brussels, Belgium, 18-19 May 2017 Household finance in Europe 1 Miguel Ampudia, European Central

More information

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014 UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session Geneva, 15 26 September 2014 Item 3: High-level segment Tackling inequality through trade and development:

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University March 2013 Idiosyncratic risk and the business cycle How much and what types

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 1-13 1 The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee and Artatrana Ratha

More information

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through Igor Velickovski & Geoffrey Pugh Applied Economics 43 (27), 2011 National Bank

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring Introduction The recent Great Recession has highlighted the potential importance of financial market

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2016 Karl Whelan (UCD) VAR Studies Spring 2016 1 / 23 Examples of VAR Studies We will look at four different

More information

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID AEA Papers and Proceedings 28, 8: 7 https://doi.org/.257/pandp.2849 Nonlinear and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID By Manuel Arellano, Richard Blundell, and Stephane Bonhomme*

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW BIG (SMALL?) ARE FISCAL MULTIPLIERS? Ethan Ilzetzki Enrique G. Mendoza Carlos A. Végh

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW BIG (SMALL?) ARE FISCAL MULTIPLIERS? Ethan Ilzetzki Enrique G. Mendoza Carlos A. Végh NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW BIG (SMALL?) ARE FISCAL MULTIPLIERS? Ethan Ilzetzki Enrique G. Mendoza Carlos A. Végh Working Paper 16479 http://www.nber.org/papers/w16479 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth & Employment

Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth & Employment Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth & Employment Owen Zidar University of California, Berkeley ozidar@econ.berkeley.edu October 1, 2012 Owen Zidar (UC Berkeley) Tax

More information

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap (R&R Quarterly Journal of nomics) October 31, 2016 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal

More information

The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy

The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy Andrea Neri 1 Concetta Rondinelli 2 Filippo Scoccianti 3 Bank of Italy 1 Statistical Analysis Directorate 2 Economic Outlook and

More information

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Syed M. Hussain Lin Liu August 5, 26 Abstract In this paper, we estimate the

More information

Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset

Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset Incomes Across the Distribution Dataset Stefan Thewissen,BrianNolan, and Max Roser April 2016 1Introduction How widely are the benefits of economic growth shared in advanced societies? Are the gains only

More information

Fiscal Policy Uncertainty and the Business Cycle: Time Series Evidence from Italy

Fiscal Policy Uncertainty and the Business Cycle: Time Series Evidence from Italy Fiscal Policy Uncertainty and the Business Cycle: Time Series Evidence from Italy Alessio Anzuini, Luca Rossi, Pietro Tommasino Banca d Italia ECFIN Workshop Fiscal policy in an uncertain environment Tuesday,

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016 Evolution of top wealth inequality

More information

Debt Financing and Real Output Growth: Is There a Threshold Effect?

Debt Financing and Real Output Growth: Is There a Threshold Effect? Debt Financing and Real Output Growth: Is There a Threshold Effect? M. Hashem Pesaran Department of Economics & USC Dornsife INET, University of Southern California, USA and Trinity College, Cambridge,

More information

Tax Evasion, Tax Monitoring Expenses and Economic Growth: An Empirical Analysis in OECD Countries

Tax Evasion, Tax Monitoring Expenses and Economic Growth: An Empirical Analysis in OECD Countries Tax Evasion, Tax Monitoring Expenses and Economic Growth: An Empirical Analysis in OECD Countries Konstantinos Chatzimichael, Pantelis Kalaitzidakis and Vangelis Tzouvelekas October 17, 2013 Abstract Based

More information

Housing Markets and the Macroeconomy During the 2000s. Erik Hurst July 2016

Housing Markets and the Macroeconomy During the 2000s. Erik Hurst July 2016 Housing Markets and the Macroeconomy During the 2s Erik Hurst July 216 Macro Effects of Housing Markets on US Economy During 2s Masked structural declines in labor market o Charles, Hurst, and Notowidigdo

More information

Why so low for so long? A long-term view of real interest rates

Why so low for so long? A long-term view of real interest rates Why so low for so long? A long-term view of real interest rates Claudio Borio, Piti Disyatat, and Phurichai Rungcharoenkitkul Bank of Finland/CEPR Conference, Demographics and the Macroeconomy, Helsinki,

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings.

International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings. MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings. Faruk Balli and Rosmy J. Louis and Mohammad Osman Massey University, Vancouver Island University, University

More information

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 702 Extensions of Permanent Income

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018 Economics 210c/236a Fall 2018 Christina Romer David Romer LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence September 19, 2018 I. INTRODUCTION Theoretical Considerations (I) A traditional Keynesian

More information

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis S. Gilchrist 1 1 Boston University and NBER MFM Summer Camp June 12, 2016 DISCLAIMER: The views expressed are solely the responsibility of the authors and

More information

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers Final Exam Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, 2004 Answers This exam consists of two parts. The first part is a long analytical question. The second part is a set of short discussion questions.

More information

Nils Holinski, Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken. Taking Home Bias Seriously: Absolute and Relative Measures Explaining Consumption Risk-Sharing RM/08/025

Nils Holinski, Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken. Taking Home Bias Seriously: Absolute and Relative Measures Explaining Consumption Risk-Sharing RM/08/025 Nils Holinski, Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken Taking Home Bias Seriously: Absolute and Relative Measures Explaining Consumption Risk-Sharing RM/08/025 JEL code: F36, F41, G15 Maastricht research school of

More information

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Active labour market policies Measures aimed at improving recipients prospects of finding gainful employment or increasing their earnings capacity or, in the case of

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD European Economic Review 42 (1998) 887 895 The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD Philip R. Lane *, Roberto Perotti Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Columbia University,

More information

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation Evidence from Randomly Assigned Judges Omar Bamieh University of Vienna November 13th 2018 1 / 27 Why should we care about firing costs? Firing costs make it

More information

Bond Markets Help Lower Inflation Andrew K. Rose*

Bond Markets Help Lower Inflation Andrew K. Rose* Bond Markets Help Lower Inflation Andrew K. Rose* 02 October 2014 Contact: Andrew K. Rose, Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720 1900 Tel: (510) 642 6609 Fax: (510) 642

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute Lisbon Conference on Structural Reforms, 6 July

More information