Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Model for Derivatives on Futures

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Model for Derivatives on Futures"

Transcription

1 Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Model for Derivatives on Futures Jean-Pierre Fouque, Yuri F. Saporito, Jorge P. Zubelli April 12, 2013 Abstract The goal of this article is to present a new method to extend the singular and regular perturbation techniques developed in the book by Fouque, Papanicolaou, Sircar and Sølna (2011, CUP) to price derivatives on futures when the asset presents mean reversion. We also consider the calibration procedure of the proposed model. We apply it to options on the Henry Hub natural gas futures and to options on stock and its volatility index in a consistent way. The main contribution of our work is a general method to compute the first-order approximation for the price of general compound derivatives such that no additional hypothesis on the regularity of the payoff function must be assumed. The only pre-requisite is the first-order approximation for the underlying derivative. In other words, the method proposed here allows us to derive the first-order approximation for compound derivatives keeping the hypotheses of the original approximation given in Fouque et al. (2011, CUP). Furthermore, this method maintains another desirable feature of the perturbation method: the direct calibration of the market group parameters. 1 Introduction In many financial applications the underlying asset of the derivative contract under consideration is a derivative itself. A very important example of this complex and widely traded class of products consists of derivatives on future contracts. We shall study such financial instruments in the context of multiscale stochastic volatility as presented in Fouque et al. [2011]. It is well-known that under the No-Arbitrage Hypothesis, one can find a risk-neutral probability measure such that all tradable assets in this market, when properly discounted, are martingales under this measure (see Delbaen and Schachermayer [2008] Department of Statistics & Applied Probability, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA , fouque@pstat.ucsb.edu. Work supported by NSF grant DMS Department of Statistics & Applied Probability, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA , saporito@pstat.ucsb.edu. Work supported by Fulbright grant and The CAPES Foundation, Ministry of Education of Brazil, Brasília, DF , Brazil. IMPA (Instituto de Matemática Pura e Aplicada), Est. D. Castorina 110, Rio de Janeiro, RJ , Brazil, zubelli@impa.br. Work supported by CNPq under grants and , and by FAPERJ under the CEST and PENSARIO programs. 1

2 for an extensive exposition on this subject). Here, we assume constant interest rate throughout this paper. The future contract on the asset V with maturity T is a standardized contract traded at a futures exchange for which both parties consent to trade the asset V at time T for a price agreed upon the day the contract was written. This previously arranged price is called strike. The future price at time t with maturity T t of the asset V, which will be denoted by F t,t, is defined as the strike of the future contract on V with maturity T such that no premium is paid when the contract is written. In symbols, (1.1) F t,t = E Q [V T F t ], where Q is a risk-neutral probability. If the asset V is tradable, then we simply have F t,t = e r(t t) V t, where r is the constant interest rate, and then derivatives on futures can be treated in the exact same way one handles derivatives on the asset itself. Future prices are non-trivial when the asset is not tradable and therefore the discounted asset price is not a martingale, see for example [Musiela and Rutkowski, 2008, Chapter 3]. This will be our main assumption: the asset V is not tradable. More precisely, we assume the asset price presents mean reversion. Some examples of such assets are: commodities, currency exchange rates, volatility indices, and interest rates. Because of the nature of our problem, the future price, which is the underlying asset of the derivative in consideration, has its dynamics explicitly depending on the time scales of the volatility. This creates an important difference from the usual perturbation theory to the derivative pricing problem. The method presented in this paper can be described as follows: (i) Write a stochastic differential equation (SDE) for the future F t,t with all coefficients depending only on F t,t. This means we will need to invert the future prices of V in order to write V t as a function of F t,t. (ii) Consider the pricing partial differential equation (PDE) for a European derivative on F t,t. The coefficients of this PDE will depend on the time scales of the stochastic volatility of the asset in a complicated way. At this point, we use perturbation analysis to treat such PDE by expanding the coefficients. (iii) Determine the first-order approximation for the derivatives on F t,t as it is done in Fouque et al. [2011]. Indeed, this method is not the only way to tackle this problem. Instead, we could have considered this compound derivative as a more elaborate derivative in the asset and then find the first-order approximation proposed in Hikspoors and Jaimungal [2008]. This, in turn, follows the idea designed in Cotton et al. [2004] and is based on the Taylor expansion of the payoff under consideration around the zero-order term of the approximation of the future price F t,t. Therefore, some smoothness of the payoff function must be assumed. Since the method considered here does not rely on such Taylor expansion, no restriction other than the ones intrinsic to the perturbation method is required. Furthermore, we shall show that although the method presented here is more involved, it allows a cleaner calibration. This is due to the fact we are considering the derivative as a function of the future price, which is the tradable asset and hence a martingale under the pricing risk-neutral measure. Another important set of examples that can be handled using the method proposed in this paper consists of interest rate derivatives (see Cotton et al. [2004]). Moreover, 2

3 in the equity case, the method could be use to tackle the general problem of pricing compound derivatives, as it is done in Fouque and Han [2005] by Taylor expansion of the payoff. The model presented in this paper was originally developed to consistently calibrate a geometric Brownian motion (GBM) S t with instantaneous stochastic variance V t to options on S and options on V. Such variance in turn would follow an exponential Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process with multiscale stochastic volatility of volatility (see (2.1) below). The prime example we had in mind was the S&P 500 and the VIX. We come back to this problem in Section 5. The main contribution of our work is a general method to compute the first-order approximation for the price of general compound derivatives such that no additional hypothesis on the regularity of the payoff function must be assumed. The only prerequisite is the first-order approximation for the underlying derivative. In other words, the method proposed here allows us to derive the first-order approximation for compound derivatives keeping the hypotheses of the original approximation given in Fouque et al. [2011]. Furthermore, this method maintains another desirable feature of the perturbation method: the direct calibration of the market group parameters. This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the dynamics of the underlying asset and then, in Section 3 we follow the method previously outlined to find the first-order approximation for derivatives on future contracts of V. Section 4 characterizes the calibration procedure to call options and we analyze an example of calibration to options on Henry Hub natural gas futures. In Section 5 we present a model for derivatives of a volatility index on a stock. Finally, we conclude in Section 6 with some suggestions for further research. 2 The Model We assume that the asset value V t is described under a risk-neutral probability Q by an exponential Ornstein-Uhlenbeck (exp-ou) stochastic process with a multiscale stochastic volatility. Namely, V t = e Ut, (2.1) du t = κ(m U t )dt + η(y ε t,z δ t )dw (0) t, dy ε t = 1 ε α(y ε t )dt + 1 ε β(y ε t )dw (1) t, where (W (0) t,w (1) t,w (2) t dz δ t = δc(z δ t )dt + δg(z δ t )dw (2) t, ) is a correlated Q-Brownian motion with dw (0) t dw (i) t = ρ i dt, i =1, 2, dw (1) t dw (2) t = ρ 12 dt. The main assumptions of this model are: There exists a unique solution of the SDE (2.1) for any fixed (ε, δ). The risk-neutral probability Q is chosen in order to match the future prices of V observed in the market to the prices produced by the model (2.1) and the martingale relation (1.1). 3

4 ρ 1 < 1, ρ 2 < 1, ρ 12 < 1 and 1 + 2ρ 1 ρ 2 ρ 12 ρ 2 1 ρ 2 2 ρ 2 12 > 0. These conditions ensure the positive definiteness of the covariance matrix of (W (0) t,w (1) t,w (2) t ). The interest rate is constant and equals r. α and β are such the process Y 1 has a unique invariant distribution and is meanreverting as in [Fouque et al., 2011, Section 3.2]. η(y, z) is a positive function, smooth in z and such that η 2 (,z) is integrable with respect to the invariant distribution of Y 1. It is important to notice that we could have explicitly considered the market prices of volatility risk as it is done in Fouque et al. [2011] and in doing so we have a term of order ε 1/2 and a term of order δ 1/2 in the drifts of Y ε and Z δ respectively, both depending on Y ε and Z δ, and they could have been handled in the way it is done in the aforesaid reference. For simplicity, we do not consider these market prices of volatility risk here. Simple generalizations of this model are the addition of a deterministic seasonality factor in V and a deterministic time-varying long run mean m(t) in the drift of U. Both can be easily handled. We now restate the definition of the future prices of V F t,t = E Q [V T F t ], 0 t T, and then in next the section we will develop the first-order approximation for derivatives on F t,t. Remark 2.1. More precisely, we say that a function g ε,δ is a first-order approximation to the function f ε,δ if g ε,δ f ε,δ C(ε + δ), for some constant C>0 and for sufficiently small ε, δ > 0. We use the notation g ε,δ f ε,δ = O(ε + δ). 3 Derivatives on Future Contracts 3.1 First-Order Approximation for Future Prices Here, we present the first-order approximation for future prices on mean-reverting assets. For a fixed maturity T>0, we define h ε,δ (t, u, y, z, T )=E Q [V T U t = u, Y ε t = y, Z δ t = z], and note that F t,t = h ε,δ (t, U t,y ε t,z δ t,t). Consider the formal expansion in powers of ε and δ of h ε,δ : h ε,δ (t, u, y, z, T )= ( ε) i ( δ) j h i,j (t, x, y, z, T ). i,j 0 We are interested in the first-order approximation for derivatives on mean-reverting assets, which is presented in Hikspoors and Jaimungal [2008] and Chiu et al. [2011]. We shall denote by Y 1 the process given by the second of the stochastic differential equations in (2.1) when ε = 1. 4

5 Applying this result to h ε,δ, we choose the first terms of the above formal series to be { h 0 (t, u, z, T ) = exp m +(u m)e κ(t t) + η2 (z) ( (3.1) 1 e 2κ(T t))}, 4κ (3.2) (3.3) h 1,0 (t, u, z, T )=g(t, T )V 3 (z) 3 h 0 (t, u, z, T ), u3 h 0,1 (t, u, z, T )=f(t, T )V 1 (z) 3 h 0 (t, u, z, T ), u3 where, denoting the averaging with respect to the invariant distribution of Y 1 by, we have (3.4) η 2 (z) = η 2 (,z), V 3 (z) = ρ 1 2 η(,z)β( ) φ y (,z) V 1 (z) =ρ 2 g(z) η(,z) η(z) η (z), f(t, T )= e3κ(t t) e2κ(t t) 2κ 2 e3κ(t t) 1 6κ 2, g(t, T )= e 3κ(T t) 1, 3κ and φ(y, z) is the solution of the Poisson equation, (3.5) L 0 φ(y, z) =η 2 (y, z) η 2 (z), with L 0 being the infinitesimal generator of Y 1. Moreover, we may assume h 1,1 does not depend on y and choose (3.6) h 2,0 (t, u, y, z, T )= 1 2 φ(y, h 0 z) (t, u, z, T )+c(t, u, z, T ), u2 for some function c that does not depend on y. Under all these choices and some regularity conditions similar to the ones presented in Theorem 3.2 at the end of this section, as it was shown in Chiu et al. [2011] and Hikspoors and Jaimungal [2008], we have h ε,δ (t, u, y, z) =h 0 (t, u, z, T )+ εh 1,0 (t, u, z, T )+ δh 0,1 (t, u, z, T )+O(ε + δ). Furthermore, the following simplifications hold: h 1,0 (t, u, z, T )=g(t, T )V 3 (z)e 3κ(T t) h 0 (t, u, z, T ), and h 0,1 (t, u, z, T )=f(t, T )V 1 (z)e 3κ(T t) h 0 (t, u, z, T ). 3.2 The Dynamics of the Future Prices In this section, we will derive the SDE describing the dynamics of F t,t and write its coefficients as functions of F t,t. Since F t,t is a martingale under Q, its dynamics has 5

6 no drift and hence, applying Itô s Formula to F t,t = h ε,δ (t, U t,y ε t,z δ t,t), we get df t,t = hε,δ u (t, U t,yt ε,zt δ,t)η(yt ε,zt δ )dw (0) t + 1 h ε,δ ε y (t, U t,yt ε,zt δ,t)β(yt ε )dw (1) t + δ hε,δ z (t, U t,y ε t,z δ t,t)g(z δ t )dw (2) t. We are interested in derivatives on F t,t and in applying the perturbation method to approximate their prices. Thus, we will rewrite the above SDE with all coefficients depending on F t,t instead of U t. In order to proceed, we need to make sure we can invert h ε,δ with respect to u for fixed ε, δ, y, z and T, i.e. there must exist a function H ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ) such that H ε,δ (t,, y, z, T )=(h ε,δ (t,, y, z, T )) 1. This result, together with the asymptotics of H ε,δ, is given in the following lemma. Lemma 3.1. Since h 0 (t, u, z) given by (3.1) is invertible, so is h ε,δ at least for small ε and δ. Moreover if we choose H 0, H 1,0, H 0,1 to be (i) H 0 (t,, z, T )=(h 0 (t,, z, T )) 1, (ii) H 1,0 (t, x, z, T )= h 1,0(t, H 0 (t, x, z, T ), z, T ), h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) (iii) H 0,1 (t, x, z, T )= h 0,1(t, H 0 (t, x, z, T ), z, T ), h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) where h 1,0 and h 0,1 are given by (3.2) and (3.3) respectively, then, we have H ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T )=H 0 (t, x, z, T )+ εh 1,0 (t, x, z, T )+ δh 0,1 (t, x, z, T )+O(ε + δ). Proof. The derivation is straightforward, so we skip the details. Notice that H ε,δ (t, F t,t, y, z, T )=U t and if we define ψ ε,δ 1 (t, x, y, z, T )= hε,δ u (t, Hε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ), y, z, T ), ψ ε,δ 2 (t, x, y, z, T )= hε,δ y (t, Hε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ), y, z, T ), ψ ε,δ 3 (t, x, y, z, T )= hε,δ z (t, Hε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ), y, z, T ), we obtain the desired SDE for F t,t (3.7) df t,t = ψ ε,δ 1 (t, F t,t,yt ε,zt δ,t)η(yt ε,zt δ )dw (0) t + 1 ψ ε,δ ε 2 (t, F t,t,yt ε,zt δ,t)β(yt ε )dw (1) t + δψ ε,δ 3 (t, F t,t,y ε t,z δ t,t)g(z δ t )dw (2) t. 6

7 3.3 A Pricing PDE for Derivatives on Future Contracts We now fix a future contract on V with maturity T and consider a European derivative with maturity T 0 <T and whose payoff ϕ depends only on the terminal value F T0,T. A no-arbitrage price for this derivative on F t,t is given by P ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T )=E Q [e r(t 0 t) ϕ(f T0,T ) F t,t = x, Y ε t = y, Z δ t = z], where Q is the risk-neutral probability discussed in Section 2 and we are using the fact that (F t,t,yt ε,zt δ ) is a Markov process. In this section we derive a PDE for P ε,δ. Recall that F t,t follows Equation (3.7), where Yt ε and Zt δ are given in (2.1). Then, we write the infinitesimal generator L ε,δ of (F t,t,yt ε,zt δ ), where, for simplicity of notation, we will drop the variables (t, x, y, z, T ) of ψ ε,δ i, i =1, 2, 3, L ε,δ = 1 ( L ) (3.8) ε 2 (ψε,δ 2 )2 β 2 (y) x 2 + ψε,δ 2 β2 (y) + 1 ( ) ρ 1 ψ ε,δ ε 1 ψε,δ 2 η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ ε,δ 1 η(y, z)β(y) where (3.9) + t (ψε,δ 1 )2 η 2 (y, z) x 2 r + ( ) δ ρ 2 ψ ε,δ 1 ψε,δ 3 η(y, z)g(z) x 2 + ρ 2 ψ ε,δ 1 η(y, z)g(z) x z ( ) + δ + M (ψε,δ 3 )2 g 2 (z) ( δ ρ 12 ψ ε,δ 2 ε ψε,δ 3 x 2 + ψε,δ 3 g2 (z) x z β(y)g(z) x 2 + ρ 12 ψ ε,δ 3 β(y)g(z) ), +ρ 12 ψ ε,δ 2 β(y)g(z) x z + ρ 12 β(y)g(z) y z L 0 = 1 2 β2 (y) y 2 + α(y) y, M 2 = 1 2 g2 (z) z 2 + c(z) z. It is well-known that under some mild conditions, by Feynman-Kac s Formula, P ε,δ satisfies the pricing PDE L ε,δ P ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ) = 0, (3.10) P ε,δ (T 0, x, y, z, T )=ϕ(x). 3.4 Perturbation Framework We will now develop the formal singular and regular perturbation analysis for European derivatives on F t,t following the method outlined in Fouque et al. [2011]. However, in our case we have a fundamental difference: the coefficients of the differential operator L ε,δ, given by Equation (3.8), depend on ε and δ in an intricate way. In particular, the term corresponding to the factor ε 1 is not simply of order ε 1. To circumvent 7

8 this problem, we will expand the coefficients in powers of ε and δ and then collect the correct terms for each order. Therefore, it will be necessary to compute some terms of the expansion of ψ ε,δ i. All the details for this expansion are given in the Appendix A and the final result is: L ε,δ = 1 ε L L 1 + L 2 + εl 3 + δ δm 1 + ε ε M 3 +, where L 0 is given by (3.9) and (3.11) (3.12) (3.13) (3.14) (3.15) L 1 = ρ 1 e κ(t t) η(y, z)β(y)x, L 2 = t e 2κ(T t) η 2 (y, z)x 2 x 2 r 1 t) φ e 2κ(T 2 y (y, z)β2 (y)x, (1 e M 3 = ρ 2κ(T t) ) 12 β(y)g(z) η(z) η (z)x 2κ + ρ 12 β(y)g(z) y z, L 3 =(ψ 2,3,0 (t, x, y, z, T )β 2 (y) + ρ 1 ψ 1,2,0 (t, x, y, z, T )η(y, z)β(y)) 1 ρ t) φ 1 e 3κ(T (y, z)η(y, z)β(y)x2 2 y x 2, M 1 = ρ 2 e κ(t t) (1 e 2κ(T t) ) η(y, z)g(z) η(z) η (z)x 2 2κ x 2 + ρ 2 e κ(t t) η(y, z)g(z)x x z +(ψ 2,2,1(t, x, y, z, T )β 2 (y) + ρ 2 ψ 1,1,1 (t, x, T )η(y, z)β(y)). The fundamental difference with the situation described in Fouque et al. [2011] then materializes in one term: the differential operator L 3 which contributes to the order ε in the expansion of L ε,δ. Also, observe that the coefficients of these operators are time dependent which complicates the asymptotic analysis. This difficulty has also been dealt with in Fouque et al. [2004]. 3.5 Formal Derivation of the First-Order Approximation Let us formally write P ε,δ in powers of δ and ε, P ε,δ = ( ε) k ( δ) m P k,m, m,k 0 and denote P 0,0 simply by P 0 where we assume that, at maturity T 0, P 0 (T 0, x, y, z, T )= ϕ(x). We are interested in determining P 0, P 1,0 and P 0,1. We follow the method presented in Fouque et al. [2011] with some minor modifications in order to take into account the new term L 3. 8

9 In order to compute the leading term P 0 and P 1,0, we set to be zero the following terms of the expansion of L ε,δ P ε,δ : (3.16) (3.17) (3.18) (3.19) ( 1, 0) : L 0 P 0 =0, ( 1/2, 0) : L 0 P 1,0 + L 1 P 0 =0, (0, 0) : L 0 P 2,0 + L 1 P 1,0 + L 2 P 0 =0, (1/2, 0) : L 0 P 3,0 + L 1 P 2,0 + L 2 P 1,0 + L 3 P 0 =0, where we are using the notation (i, j) to denote the term of ith order in ε and jth in δ Computing P 0 We seek a function P 0 = P 0 (t, x, z, T ), independent of y, so that the Equation (3.16) is satisfied. Since L 1 takes derivative with respect to y, L 1 P 0 = 0. Thus the second (3.17) becomes L 0 P 1,0 = 0 and for the same reason as before, we seek a function P 1,0 = P 1,0 (t, x, z, T ) independent of y. The (0, 0)-order equation (3.18) becomes L 0 P 2,0 + 0 L 1 P 1,0 + L 2 P 0 =0, which is a Poisson equation for P 2,0 with solvability condition L 2 P 0 =0, where is the average under the invariant measure of L 0. For more details on Poisson equations, see [Fouque et al., 2011, Section 3.2]. Define now (3.20) L B (σ) = t σ2 x 2 x 2 r and σ(t, y, z, T )=e κ(t t) η(y, z), where we are using the notation L B (σ) for the Black differential operator with volatility σ. Since P 0 does not depend on y and by the form of L 2 given in (3.12), the solvability condition becomes L 2 P 0 = L B (σ(t, y, z, T )) P 0 =0. Note that where L B (σ(t, y, z, T )) = t x2 σ 2 (t,, z, T ) 2 x 2 r = L B( σ(t, z, T )), (3.21) σ 2 (t, z, T )= σ 2 (t,, z, T ) = e 2κ(T t) η 2 (z), with η(z) defined in (3.4). Therefore, we choose P 0 to satisfy the PDE L B ( σ(t, z, T ))P 0 (t, x, z, T ) = 0, P 0 (T 0, x, z, T )=ϕ(x). 9

10 Note also that L B ( σ(t, z, T )) is the Black differential operator with time-varying volatility σ(t, z, T ) and hence, if we define the time-averaged volatility, σ t,t0 (z, T ), by the formula (3.22) we can write T0 σ t,t 2 0 (z, T )= 1 σ 2 (u, z, T )du T 0 t t ( = η 2 e 2κ(T T0) e (z) 2κ(T 0 t) 2κ(T t) P 0 (t, x, z, T )=P B (t, x, σ t,t0 (z, T )), where P B (t, x, σ) is the price at (t, x) of the European derivative with maturity T 0 and payoff function ϕ in the Black model with constant volatility σ. In order to simplify notation here and in what follows, we define ), (3.23) Therefore, λ(t, T 0, T, κ) = e κ(t T0) e κ(t t). κ(t 0 t) σ 2 t,t 0 (z, T ) = η 2 (z)λ 2 σ(t, T 0, T, κ), where λ σ (t, T 0, T, κ) = λ(t, T 0, T, 2κ) Computing P ε 1,0 By the (0, 0)-order equation (3.18), we get the formula (3.24) P 2,0 = L 1 0 (L B(σ) L B ( σ))p 0 + c(t, x, z, T ), for some function c which does not depend on y. Denote by φ(y, z) a solution of the Poisson equation L 0 φ(y, z) =η 2 (y, z) η 2 (z). Hence, ( ) 1 L 1 0 (L B(σ) L B ( σ)) = L (σ2 (t, y, z, T ) σ 2 (t, z, T ))x 2 x 2 where we use the notation (3.25) = 1 2 e 2κ(T t) L 1 0 (η2 (y, z) η 2 (z))x 2 x 2 = 1 2 e 2κ(T t) φ(y, z)d 2, D k = x k k x k. From the (1/2, 0)-order equation (3.19), which is a Poisson equation for P 3,0, we get the solvability condition (3.26) L 1 P 2,0 + L 2 P 1,0 + L 3 P 0 =0. 10

11 Using formula (3.24) for P 2,0 and formula (3.11) for L 1, we get L 1 P 2,0 = L 1 L 1 0 (L B(σ) L B ( σ))p 0 We also have by equation (3.12) and from (3.14) = ρ 1 e κ(t t) η(y, z)β(y)x = ρ 1 e κ(t t) xη(y, z)β(y) x y = 1 2 ρ 1e 3κ(T t) η(y, z)β(y) φ y (y, z)d 1D 2 P 0. L 2 P 1,0 = P 1,0 t Combining these equations, we get where ( ) 1 2 e 2κ(T t) φ(y, z)d 2 P 0 ( ) 1 2 e 2κ(T t) φ(y, z)d 2 P σ2 (t, y, z, T )x 2 P 1,0 x 2 rp 1,0, L 3 P 0 = 1 2 ρ 3κ(T t) φ 1e y (y, z)η(y, z)β(y)d 2P 0. L 1 P 2,0 + L 2 P 1,0 + L 3 P 0 = v 3 (t, y, z, T )D 2 P 0 + v 3 (t, y, z, T )D 1 D 2 P 0 + L B (σ(t, y, z, T ))P 1,0, v 3 (t, y, z, T )= 1 2 ρ 1e 3κ(T t) φ (y, z)η(y, z)β(y). y Therefore, averaging with respect to the invariant distribution of Y 1, we deduce from (3.26) that P1,0 ε = εp 1,0 satisfies the PDE: L B ( σ(t, z, T ))P1,0 ε (t, x, z, T )= f(t, T )Aε P 0 (t, x, z, T ), (3.27) P1,0 ε (T 0, x, z, T )=0, where (3.28) A ε = V ε 3 (z)(d 1 D 2 + D 2 ), f(t, T )=e 3κ(T t), V ε 3 (z) = ε 1 2 ρ 1 The linear PDE (3.27) is solved explicitly: (3.29) where φ y (,z)η(,z)β P ε 1,0(t, x, z, T ) = (T 0 t)λ 3 (t, T 0, T, κ)v ε 3 (z)(d 1 D 2 + D 2 )P B (t, x, σ t,t0 (z, T )), λ 3 (t, T 0, T, κ) =λ(t, T 0, T, 3κ), and λ is defined by (3.23). To see this, note that the operator A ε given by (3.28), and the operator L B ( σ(t, z, T )) given by (3.20) and (3.21), commute and therefore, the solution of the PDE (3.27) is given by ( T0 ) P1,0(t, ε x, z, T )= f(u, T )du A ε P 0 (t, x, z, T ). Thus, solving the above integral, we get (3.29). t 11.

12 3.5.3 Computing P δ 0,1 In order to compute P 0,1, we need to consider terms with order 1/2 in δ, more explicitly the following ones: (3.30) (3.31) (3.32) ( 1, 1/2) : L 0 P 0,1 =0, ( 1/2, 1/2) : L 0 P 1,1 + L 1 P 0,1 + M 3 P 0 =0, (0, 1/2) : L 0 P 2,1 + L 1 P 1,1 + M 3 P 1,0 + L 2 P 0,1 + M 1 P 0 =0. Recall that L 1 and M 3 as defined by Equations (3.11) and (3.13) take derivative with respect to y. Choosing P 0,1 = P 0,1 (t, x, z, T ) and P 1,1 = P 1,1 (t, x, z, T ) independent of y, the first two equations (3.30) and (3.31) are satisfied. The last equation (3.32) becomes L 0 P 2,1 + L 2 P 0,1 + M 1 P 0 =0, and thus the solvability condition for this Poisson equation for P 2,1 is From (3.15) we have L 2 P 0,1 + M 1 P 0 =0. M 1 P 0 = ρ 2 η(z) η (z) (1 e 2κ(T t) ) e κ(t t) η(y, z)g(z)d 2 P 0 2κ + ρ 2 e κ(t t) η(y, z)g(z)d 1 z P 0, and then, if we write P0,1 δ (t, x, z, T )= δp 0,1 (t, x, z, T ), the solvability condition above can be written as L B ( σ(t, z, T ))P0,1 δ = f 0(t, T )A δ 0 P 0 f 1 (t, T )A δ 1 P 0, (3.33) P0,1 δ (T 0, x, z, T )=0, where A δ 0 = V δ 0 (z)d 2, A δ 1 = V δ 1 (z)d 1 z, V δ 0 (z) = δ 1 2κ ρ 2 η(,z) g(z) η(z) η (z), f 0 (t, T )=e κ(t t) e 3κ(T t), V δ 1 (z) = δρ 2 η(,z) g(z), f 1 (t, T )=e κ(t t). The solution for this PDE can be explicitly computed P δ 0,1(t, x, z, T )=(T 0 t)v δ 0 (z)(λ 0 (t, T 0, T, κ)d 2 + λ 1 (t, T 0, T, κ)d 1 D 2 )P B (t, x, σ t,t0 (z, T )), where λ 0 (t, T 0, T, κ) =λ(t, T 0, T, κ) λ(t, T 0, T, 3κ), λ 1 (t, T 0, T, κ) =e 2κ(T T 0) λ(t, T 0, T, κ) λ(t, T 0, T, 3κ). The details of this computation are given in the Appendix C. 12

13 3.6 Summary and Some Remarks We now summarize the formulas involved in the first-order asymptotic expansion of the price of European derivative on futures. We recall that, as before, D k = x k / x k. We have formally derived the first-order approximation for P ε,δ : with P ε,δ P 0 + P ε 1,0 + P δ 0,1 P 0 (t, x, z, T )=P B (t, x, σ t,t0 (z, T )), P ε 1,0(t, x, z, T )=(T 0 t)λ 3 (t, T 0, T, κ)v ε 3 (z)(d 2 + D 1 D 2 )P B (t, x, σ t,t0 (z, T )), P δ 0,1(t, x, z, T )=(T 0 t)v δ 0 (z)(λ 0 (t, T 0, T, κ)d 2 + λ 1 (t, T 0, T, κ)d 1 D 2 )P B (t, x, σ t,t0 (z, T )), where η 2 (z) = η 2 (,z), V ε 3 (z) = ε 1 2 ρ 1 φ y (,z)η(,z)β, V δ 0 (z) = δ 1 2κ ρ 2 η(,z) g(z) η(z) η (z), λ(t, T 0, T, κ) = e κ(t T0) e κ(t 0 t) λ 3 (t, T 0, T, κ) =λ(t, T 0, T, 3κ), κ(t t) λ 0 (t, T 0, T, κ) =λ(t, T 0, T, κ) λ(t, T 0, T, 3κ), λ 1 (t, T 0, T, κ) =e 2κ(T T 0) λ(t, T 0, T, κ) λ(t, T 0, T, 3κ), λ 2 σ(t, T 0, T, κ) =λ(t, T 0, T, 2κ). σ 2 t,t 0 (z, T ) = η 2 (z)λ 2 σ(t, T 0, T, κ). A valuable feature of the perturbation method is that in order to compute the first-order approximation, we only need the values of the group market parameters (κ, η(z),v δ 0 (z),v ε 3 (z)). This feature can also be seen as model independence or robustness of this approximation: under some regularity conditions stated in Theorem 3.2, this approximation is independent of the particular form of the coefficients describing the process Y ε and Z δ, i.e. the functions α, β, c and g involved in the model (2.1). From now on we will use the following notation P (t, x, z, T )=P 0 (t, x, z, T ), P ε,δ (t, x, z, T )=P ε 1,0(t, x, z, T )+P δ 0,1(t, x, z, T ),, (3.34) P ε,δ (t, x, z, T )= P (t, x, z, T )+ P ε,δ (t, x, z, T ). 13

14 3.7 Accuracy of the Approximation We now state the precise accuracy result for the formal approximation determined in the previous sections. All the reasoning in Section 3.4 is only a formal procedure and a well-thought choice for the proposed first-order approximation. The next result establishes the order of accuracy of this approximation and justifies a posteriori the choices made earlier. Theorem 3.2. We assume (i) Existence and uniqueness of the SDE (2.1) for any fixed (ε, δ). (ii) The process Y 1 with infinitesimal generator L 0 has a unique invariant distribution and is mean-reverting as in [Fouque et al., 2011, Section 3.2]. (iii) The function η(y, z) is smooth in z and such the solution φ to the Poisson equation (3.5) is at most polynomially growing. (iv) The payoff function ϕ(x) and its derivatives are smooth and bounded. Then, P ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T )= P ε,δ (t, x, z, T )+O(ε + δ). Proof. The proof is provided in Appendix B. Observe that in the heuristic derivation of the approximation given by Equation (3.34) we did not use the smoothness assumption (iv) of Theorem 3.2. In fact, (iv) is only used in a technical way to derive the accuracy result as shown in Appendix B. Then, assumption (iv) can be relaxed to include the case of call options by the regularization argument presented in Fouque et al. [2003], and extended for the addition of the slow factor in Fouque et al. [2011]. Being able to apply the approximation (3.34) to call options is essential to the next section. 4 Calibration In this section we will outline a procedure to calibrate the group market parameters (κ, η(z),v0 δ(z),vε 3 (z)) to available prices of call options on F t,t. As one may conclude from [Fouque et al., 2011, Chapters 6 and 7], or from an application of Functional Itô Calculus (Dupire [2009]) to the perturbation analysis presented in the forthcoming paper Fouque and Saporito, the values of the group market parameters are the only parameters needed to price path-dependent or American options to the same order of accuracy. Therefore, once the group market parameters are calibrated to vanilla options, the same parameters are used to price exotic derivatives. This is one of the most important characteristics of the perturbation theory. 4.1 Approximate Call Prices on Future Contracts and Implied Volatilities Assume without loss of generality t = 0 and consider a European call option on F 0,T with maturity T 0 T and strike K. As we are interested in the calibration of the market group parameters to call prices at the fixed time t = 0, we will drop the 14

15 variables (t, x) in the formulas and write the variables (T 0,K) instead. We will also drop the variable z since it should be understood as just a parameter. The Black formula for a (T 0,K)-call option is defined by (4.1) C B (T 0, K, σ) =e rt 0 (F 0,T Φ(d 1 (σ)) KΦ(d 2 (σ))), where Let us also denote d 1,2 (σ) = log(f 0,T /K) ± σ2 2 T 0 σ T 0. d 1,2 = d 1,2 ( σ 0,T0 ), where σ 0,T0 (4.2) is the time-averaged volatility defined in (3.22), and notice that P (0,F 0,T, z, T )=C B (T 0, K, σ 0,T0 ). The following relations between Greeks of the Black price are well-known and they will be essential in what follows: and (4.3) C B σ (T 0, K, σ) =T 0 σd 2 C B (T 0, K, σ), ( C B D 1 σ (T 0, K, σ) = = 1 d ) 1 σ CB T 0 σ (T 0, K, σ) ( log(k/x) σ 2 T 0 ) CB σ (T 0, K, σ), where the operator D k is defined in (3.25). Using the Greeks relations stated above and (4.2), we are able to rewrite (3.34) as ( ( ) P ε,δ = P λ 3 (T 0, T, κ) B + V3 ε (z)+ λ 3(T 0, T, κ) V ε 1 3 (z) σ 0,T0 σ 0,T0 2 + log(k/f 0,T ) σ 0,T 2 0 T 0 ( )) + λ 0(T 0, T, κ) V0 δ (z)+ λ 1(T 0, T, κ) V δ 1 0 (z) σ 0,T0 σ 0,T0 2 + log(k/f 0,T ) P σ 0,T 2 0 T 0 σ. Now, we convert the price P ε,δ to a Black implied volatility I: C B (T 0, K, I(T 0, K, T )) = P ε,δ = P ε,δ +. Remark. Since we do not have a spot price readily available for trade in our model we work with futures. Thus, differently from what is done in the equity case, we consider the Black implied volatility instead of the Black Scholes implied volatility. Then, expand I(T 0, K, T ) around σ 0,T0 : I(T 0, K, T ) σ 0,T0 = εi 1,0 (T 0, K, T )+ δi 0,1 (T 0, K, T )+. 15

16 Hence, matching both expansions gives us εi1,0 (T 0, K, T )= 3 2 λ 3 (T 0, T, κ) λ σ (T 0, T, κ) V ε 3 (z) η(z) + λ 3(T 0, T, κ) λ 3 σ(t 0, T, κ) V ε 3 (z) η 3 (z) log(k/f 0,T ) T 0, λ0 (T 0, T, κ) δi1,0 (T 0, K, T )=( λ σ (T 0, T, κ) + 1 ) λ 1 (T 0, T, κ) V δ 0 (z) 2 λ σ (T 0, T, κ) η(z) + λ 1(T 0, T, κ) λ 3 σ(t 0, T, κ) V δ 0 (z) η 3 (z) log(k/f 0,T ) T 0. So, in terms of the reduced variable LMMR, the log-moneyness to maturity ratio defined by LMMR = log(k/f 0,T ) T 0, the first-order approximation of the implied volatility I(T 0, K, T ) can be written as (4.4) I(T 0, K, T ) η(z) b(t 0, T, κ)+ V ε 3 (z) η(z) bε (T 0, T, κ)+ V 0 δ(z) η(z) bδ (T 0, T, κ) η 3 (z) aε (T 0, T, κ)+ V 0 δ(z) ) η 3 (z) aδ (T 0, T, κ) LMMR, ( V ε + 3 (z) where b(t0, T, κ) =λ σ (T 0, T, κ), b ε (T 0, T, κ) = 3 λ 3 (T 0, T, κ) 2 λ σ (T 0, T, κ), b δ (T 0, T, κ) = λ 0(T 0, T, κ) λ σ (T 0, T, κ) + 1 λ 1 (T 0, T, κ) 2 λ σ (T 0, T, κ), a ε (T 0, T, κ) = λ 3(T 0, T, κ) λ 3 σ(t 0, T, κ), a δ (T 0, T, κ) = λ 1(T 0, T, κ) λ 3 σ(t 0, T, κ). Therefore, the model predicts at first-order accuracy and for fixed maturities T 0 and T that the implied volatility is affine in the LMMR variable. 4.2 Calibration Procedure Suppose that at the present time t = 0, there is available the finite set of Black implied volatilities {I(T 0ij,K ijl,t i )}, which we understand in the following way: for each i (i.e. for each future price F 0,Ti ) there are available call option prices with maturities T 0ij and, for each of these maturities, strikes K ijl. Since the data is more abundant in the K direction, we will first linearly regress the implied volatilities against the variable LMMR ijl, LMMR ijl = log(k ijl/f 0,Ti ) T 0ij, 16

17 for fixed i and j. More precisely, we will use the least-squares criterion to perform this regression, namely (â ij, ˆb ij ) = argmin (I(T 0ij,K ijl,t i ) (a ij LMMR ijl + b ij )) 2. (a ij,b ij ) l Now, using Equation (4.4), we first regress the estimate â against a ε and a δ : (4.5) ( ( )) 2 (â 0, â 1, ˆκ)=argmin (a 0,a 1,κ) â ij a 0 a ε (T 0ij,T i,κ)+a 1 a δ (T 0ij,T i,κ) and then knowing (â 0, â 1, ˆκ) we regress ˆb against b, b ε and b δ : ˆb0 = argmin b 0 i,j i,j ( ( 2 (ˆbij b 0 b(t0ij,t i, ˆκ)+b 2 0 â 0 b ε (T 0ij,T i, ˆκ) + â 1 b δ (T 0ij,T i, ˆκ)))). Therefore, we find the following estimates for the market group parameters: η(z) =ˆb 0, V ε 3 (z) = â 0ˆb 3 0, V δ 0 (z) = â 1ˆb 3 0, and ˆκ is given by Equation (4.5). In order to perform the above minimizations, the initial guesses are of utmost importance. Since we expect terms of order ε to be small, we set the initial guesses of a 0 and a 1 to be 0. On the other hand, we can construct initial guesses of κ and b 0 by estimating κ and η(z) from historical data of F t,t. 4.3 Calibration Example For this numerical example we will use the prices of call options on the Henry Hub future contracts on May 9th, For each future contract (i.e. for each maturity T i ), the option data is available just for the same maturity as the underlying future (i.e. T 0ij = T i ) and various strikes K ijl between US$ 3.00 and US$ The future prices are shown in Figure 1 and one can clearly notice that seasonality is a main factor in the data. However, we have not included seasonality in this work, although it can be done without additional mathematical difficulty, see Eydeland and Wolyniec [2002] for instance, but doing so would be outside the scope of the paper. Henceforth, we will restrict ourselves to options maturing only in the same month of the year, for example we choose November. In the following calibration, we assume r = 0 here. If one wants to capture the convexity of the implied volatility, one would have to use the second-order approximation as it is done for the Equity markets in Fouque et al. [2012]. We show in Figure 2 the implied volatility fit, where the solid line is the model implied volatility and the circles are the implied volatilities observed in the market. On the title of each subplot it is shown the time-to-maturity (TTM) of each option in years. The calibrated group market parameters are given in Table 1. It is important to notice that V3 ε our model. (z) and V δ 0 (z) are indeed small and hence these parameters are compatible with 17

18 Parameter Value ˆκ η(z) V 3 ε (z) V 0 δ (z) Table 1: Calibrated Parameters Figure 1: Future Prices on May 9th,

19 Figure 2: Implied Volatility for Call Options on the Henry Hub Future Contracts with Maturity in November 19

20 5 Joint Calibration to Options on a Stock and its Volatility Index The method detailed in Section 3 was initially developed to jointly calibrate the model described by Equation (5.2) to data from options of a stock and its volatility index. The main desired property is the tractability of the model in which the calibration procedure is direct at least for the volatility index market and that is the reason behind the choice of the exp-ou model for the volatility, which is a log-normal model under constant volatility of volatility. The crucial example to have in mind is the S&P 500 and the VIX. For the precise definition of the CBOE Volatility Index (VIX), see CBOE [2003]. Loosely, the VIX, also known as the fear index, represents the market s expectation of the volatility for the next 30 days and it is computed using options on the S&P 500 index. If we assume that the S&P 500 index is described by a geometric Brownian motion (GBM) with instantaneous stochastic variance V t, then (5.1) where τ 0 is 30 days. [ 1 t+τ0 VIX 2 t = E V γ dγ τ 0 t F t We now state precisely the problem we aim to solve. Denote the value of the stock at time t by S t and assume the following multiscale stochastic volatility dynamics: ds t = rs t dt + V t S t dwt S, V t = e 2Ut, ], (5.2) du t = κ(m U t )dt + η(y ε t,z δ t )dw (0) t, dy ε t = 1 ε α(y ε t )dt + 1 ε β(y ε t )dw (1) t, dz δ t = δc(z δ t )dt + δg(z δ t )dw (2) t, where dw S t dw (j) t = ρ Sj dt and with all notation and hypotheses stated in Section 2 also holding true. In this model, V t denotes the instantaneous variance of S t. Notice the difference between the definitions of V t in the SDE systems (5.2) and (2.1). While V t = e Ut in (2.1), V t = e 2Ut in (5.2). This will be justified in what follows. The financial instruments to which the model will be calibrated are: (5.3) C S (T S,K S )=E Q [ e r(t S t) (S TS K S ) + F t ], C V (T V,K V )=E Q [ ( V TV K V ) + F t ], for various T S, K S, T V and K V. Clearly, this is only a toy model to understand the joint calibration problem, because VIX options are actually options on the square root of integrated future variance, as one can clearly realize by (5.1). Nevertheless, the same equation shows VIX 2 t V t, if we assume V t does not change much from t to t + τ 0, and hence the joint calibration 20

21 being solved is an approximation of the original problem of joint calibration to options on the S&P 500 and the VIX. Although it is not shown explicitly by Equation (5.3), options on VIX are actually options on future contracts of VIX. Anyway, since the option and the underlying future have the same maturity, it is mathematically equivalent to understanding the price of this option as a function of the future price or the VIX. However, since the future price is a martingale (as opposed to the VIX), better formulas for the Greeks of the 0-order term are available. Mainly, Equation (4.3) holds true. Hence, the calibration procedure will be easier to describe as it is done in Section 4.2. Nevertheless, the full strength of the method described in Section 3.4 cannot be realized in this example because the maturities of the option and the underlying future contract coincide. Furthermore, in order to compute the first-order approximation for C V, we would like to use the results derived in Section 3. Note now V T = e U T and then the formulas of the first-order approximation for options on V T are given in Section 3.6 and no change needs to be made concerning the square root in Equation (5.3). The idea is to first approximate the price of options on S to the 0-order and then approximate options on V to the first-order using the method described in Section 3. The reason of not going further in the approximation for the price of options on S is twofold. Firstly, the 0-order term will be the price of the option still under a stochastic volatility model, then we expect to be able to fit the observed implied volatility. Secondly, since the 0-order term will not be given in closed form, it will have to be computed by Monte Carlo methods, and it will be harder to calculate the Greeks of the 0-order needed in the first-order correction. One should also notice that it is possible to compute the first-order approximation for VIX options, but no closed formula could be found. We will not pursue this computations here, we refer to [Fouque et al., 2011, Chapter 6] where the first-order approximation of Asian options is derived. 5.1 Options on the Stock Here, we describe the 0-order term of the price of a European option on S. Fix a maturity T S and a call payoff ϕ S (s) =(s K S ) +. A no-arbitrage price of this vanilla European option is given by the conditional expectation P ε,δ S (t, s, u, y, z) =E Q[e r(ts t) ϕ S (S TS ) S t = s, U t = u, Yt ε = y, Zt δ = z]. Let us write f(u) =e u and define the differential operator L ε,δ S = 1 ε L L S ε 1 + L S 2 + δ δm S 1 + δm 2 + ε MS 3, 21

22 where L 0 = α(y) y β2 (y) y 2, L S 1 = ρ S1 f(u)sβ(y) s y + ρ 01η(y, z)β(y) u y, L S 2 = t f 2 (u)s 2 s 2 + rs s r + κ(m u) u η2 (y, z) u 2 + ρ S0f(u)sη(y, z) u s, M S 1 = ρ S2 f(u)sg(z) s z + ρ 02η(y, z)g(z) u z, M 2 = c(z) z g2 (z) z 2, M S 3 = ρ 12 β(y)g(z) y z. Hence, Feynman-Kac s Formula tells us P ε,δ S satisfies the following pricing PDE L ε,δ (t, s, u, y, z) =0, S P ε,δ S P ε,δ S (T S, s, u, y, z) =ϕ S (s) Formal Derivation of the Zero Order Approximation If we formally write P ε,δ S in powers of δ, P ε,δ S = P ε S 0 + δp ε S 1 +, we then choose PS ε 0 to satisfy (5.4) ( 1 ε L ) L S ε 1 + L S 2 PS ε 0 (t, s, u, y, z) =0, PS ε 0 (T S, s, u, y, z) =ϕ S (x). Now, expand P ε S 0 in powers of ε, P ε 0 = m 0( ε) m P Sm,0, and substitute into Equation (5.4) to get the following PDEs (5.5) (5.6) (5.7) ( 1, 0) : L 0 P S0 =0, ( 1/2, 0) : L 0 P S1,0 + L S 1 P S0 =0, (0, 0) : L 0 P S2,0 + L S 1 P S1,0 + L S 2 P S0 =0. Therefore, we choose P S0 = P S0 (t, s, u, z) in order to satisfy Equation (5.5). Since L S 1 differentiates with respect to y in all its terms, L S 1 P S 0 = 0 and then, we also choose 22

23 P S1,0 = P S1,0 (t, s, u, z) independent of y to satisfy (5.6). Now the 0-order PDE (5.7) gives us L 0 P S2,0 + 0 L S 1 P 1,0 + L S 2 P S0 =0, which is a Poisson equation for P S2,0 with solvability condition: L S 2 P S0 =0, where is the average under the invariant measure of L 0. Since P S0 does not depend on y, the solvability condition becomes: Now, we define and notice that with η(z) = η 2 (,z) and L S 2 P 0 =0. L SV (η, ρ) = t f 2 (u)s 2 s 2 + rs s r + κ(m u) u + 1 η2 + ρf(u)sη 2 u2 u s L S 2 = L SV ( η(z), ρ(z)), η(,z) ρ(z) =ρ S0. η(z) Therefore, we choose P S0 to satisfy the PDE L SV ( η(z), ρ(z))p S0 (t, s, u, z) =0 5.2 Options on Volatility P S0 (T S, s, u, z) =ϕ S (s). Here we show again the results summarized in Section 3.6 with T 0 = T, payoff ϕ(x) = ( x K V ) + and r = 0. Remember that V t = e 2Ut and then no change in the formulas below is needed to take into account the square root in ϕ. P V0 (t, x, z) =C B (t, x, σ t,t (z)), P ε V 1,0 (t, x, z)=(t t)λ 3 (t, T, κ)v ε 3 (z)(d 1 D 2 +D 2 )C B (t, x, σ t,t (z)), P δ V 0,1 (t, x, z)=(t t)λ 0 (t, T, κ)v δ 0 (z)(d 1 D 2 +D 2 )C B (t, x, σ t,t (z)), 23

24 where η 2 (z) = η 2 (,z), V ε 3 (z) = ε 1 2 ρ 1 φ y (,z)η(,z)β, V0 δ (z) = δ 1 2κ ρ 2 η(,z) g(z) η(z) η (z), 1 e κ(t t) λ(t, T, κ) =, κ(t t) λ 3 (t, T, κ) =λ(t, T, 3κ), λ 0 (t, T, κ) =λ(t, T, κ) λ(t, T, 3κ), λ 2 σ(t, T, κ) =λ(t, T, 2κ), σ 2 t,t (z) = η 2 (z)λ 2 σ(t, T, κ). We have dropped the variable T 0, because it is equal to T, and we have also used the function C B defined by Equation (4.1) instead of P B because of the specific payoff ϕ we are using. Notice that since T 0 = T, λ 0 = λ 1 and the formula for PV δ 0,1 simplifies. 5.3 Joint Calibration Considering there is much more data available for options on the stock than for options on its volatility, the strategy we will follow for the calibration is: Calibrate (κ, m, η(z), ρ(z)) to call options on the stock; Then, calibrate (V3 ε(z),vδ 0 (z)) to call options on volatility using the values for κ and η(z) found in the previous step. A desirable feature is to have a negative skew in the implied volatility for options on the stock and a positive skew for options on volatility. This toy model presents such feature and in order to exemplify it, consider the parameter values given in Table 2 and the implied volatilities given in the Figures 3 and 4. Table 2: Parameter Values Parameter Value Parameter Value r 0.05 κ 1 T 1 year η(z) 0.5 F 0,T 20 m 0.3 S ρ -0.7 V V3 ε (z) K S [70, 130] V0 δ (z) K V [5, 25] 24

25 Figure 3: Black Scholes Implied Volatility for Options on the Stock Figure 4: Black Implied Volatility for Options on Volatility 25

26 6 Concluding Remarks and Future Directions We have presented a general method to derive the first-order approximation for compound derivatives and develop it thoroughly in the case of derivatives on future contracts. Although the method may seem to be involved, it does not require any additional hypothesis on the regularity of the payoff function other than the ones inherent to the perturbation theory. Moreover, we presented a calibration procedure associated with the method, for which we derive formulas for the market group parameters. A practical numerical example of the calibration procedure is given using data of call options on Henry Hub futures. Furthermore, we show that the method can also be used to study the joint calibration of a multiscale stochastic volatility model to option prices on the stock and its volatility index. One direction for further study would be to connect the model and asymptotic expansions proposed in this work with the celebrated Schwartz-Smith Schwartz and Smith [2000a,b] and Gibson-Schwartz Gibson and Schwartz [1990] models for commodity prices. In particular, an important question would be the computation of the risk premium as in Gibson and Schwartz [1990]. In a different direction, one could compute the first-order correction to the price of options on the stock studied in Section 5 using Monte Carlo to compute the Greeks of the 0-order approximation. The methods developed by Fournié et al. [1999, 2001] might be efficient in this context, but they would have to be adapted to the stochastic volatility context. A PDE Expansion Formally write, for k =1, 2, 3, ψ ε,δ k (t, x, y, z, T )= ( ε) i ( δ) j ψ k,i,j (t, x, y, z, T ). i,j 0 In what follows we will compute only the terms of the above expansion that are necessary for the computation of the first-order approximation of derivatives on F t,t. A.1 Expanding ψ ε,δ 1 By the chain rule ψ ε,δ 1 (t, x, y, z, T )= 1, ε,δ H (t, x, y, z, T ) x and then one can easily see that ψ 1,0,0 (t, x, y, z, T )= 1 = H 0 x (t, x, z, T ) h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ). Since h 0 u (t, u, z, T )=e κ(t t) h 0 (t, u, z, T ), we have the following formula for ψ 1,0,0 : ψ 1,0,0 (t, x, T )=e κ(t t) h 0 (t, H 0 (t, x, z, T ), z, T )=e κ(t t) x. 26

27 Moreover, by Lemma 3.1, H 1,0 (t, x, z, T )= h 1,0(t, H 0 (t, x, z, T ), z, T ) h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) = g(t, T )V 3(z)e 3κ(T t) x e κ(t t) x which is independent of x, and therefore, We also have = g(t, T )V 3 (z)e 2κ(T t), 1 H 1,0 ψ 1,1,0 (t, x, z, T )= ( ) 2 (t, x, z, T ) = 0. H0 x (t, x, z, T ) x A.2 Expanding ψ ε,δ 2 ψ 1,0,1 (t, x, z, T )=0. Recall that the first four terms of the expansion of h ε,δ do not depend on y. Thus ψ 2,0,0 = ψ 2,0,1 = ψ 2,1,0 = ψ 2,1,1 =0. Furthermore, again by the chain rule, we have ψ ε,δ 2 From this, we get (t, x, y, z, T )= ψε,δ 1 ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ) H (t, x, y, z, T ). y ψ 2,2,0 (t, x, y, z, T )= ψ 1,0,0 (t, x, T ) H 2,0 (t, x, y, z, T ) y = e κ(t t) x H 2,0 (t, x, y, z, T ). y In order to compute H 2,0 we need to go further in the expansions of h ε,δ and H ε,δ. One can compute the term of order (2, 0) in H ε,δ and then conclude which implies H 2,0 (t, x, y, z, T )= h 2,0(t, H 0 (t, x, z, T ), y, z, T ) h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) 1 2 h 0 2 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) 2 h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) H2 1,0(t, x, z, T ) h 1,0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) h 0 u (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) H 1,0(t, x, z, T ), h 2,0 H 2,0 y (t, x, y, z, T )= (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), y, z, T ) y h 0 u (t, H. 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) 27

28 From (3.6), we know that and hence h 2,0 y (t, u, y, z, T )= 1 φ 2 y (y, h 0 z) (t, u, z, T ) u2 = 1 t) φ e 2κ(T 2 y (y, z)h 0(t, u, z, T ), 1 H 2,0 y (t, x, y, z, T )= 2 Finally, this gives the formula A.3 Expanding ψ ε,δ 3 By the chain rule, we have ψ 2,2,0 (t, x, y, z, T )= 1 2 e 2κ(T t) φ y (y, z)x e κ(t t) = 1 x 2 t) φ e 2κ(T (y, z)x. y t) φ e κ(t (y, z). y and then ψ ε,δ 3 (t, x, y, z, T )= ψε,δ 1 ε,δ (t, x, y, z, T ) H (t, x, y, z, T ), z ψ 3,0,0 (t, x, z) = ψ 1,0,0 (t, x, T ) H 0 (t, x, y, z, T ) z = h 0 z (t, H 0(t, x, z, T ), z, T ) = 1 2κ η(z) η (z)(1 e 2κ(T t) )x. A.4 An Expansion of the Pricing PDE Define Ψ k,m n,p (t, x, y, z, T )= n i=0 j=0 p ψ k,i,j (t, x, y, z, T )ψ m,n i,p j (t, x, y, z, T ), which is the (n, p)-order coefficient of the formal power series of ψ ε,δ k ψε,δ m : ψ ε,δ k (t, x, y, z, T )ψε,δ m (t, x, y, z, T ) = ( ε) l+i ( δ) j+r ψ k,i,j (t, x, y, z, T )ψ m,l,r (t, x, y, z, T ) i,j,l,r 0 = ( ε) n ( n δ) p n,p 0 i=0 j=0 p ψ k,i,j (t, x, y, z, T )ψ m,n i,p j (t, x, y, z, T ). Therefore, we have the following formal expansion for the operator L ε,δ where we drop the variables (t, x, y, z, T ) for simplicity, 28

29 ( L ) 2 Ψ2,2 0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,0,0β 2 (y) L ε,δ = 1 ε + 1 ( ρ 1 Ψ 1,2 ε 0 η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,0,0 η(y, z)β(y) ) Ψ2,2 1,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,1,0β 2 (y) ( + t Ψ1,1 0 η2 (y, z) x 2 r + ρ 1 Ψ 1,2 1,0 η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,1,0 η(y, z)β(y) + 1 ) 2 Ψ2,2 2,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,2,0β 2 (y) + ( 1 ε 2 Ψ2,2 3,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,3,0β 2 (y) + ρ 1 Ψ 1,2 2,0η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,2,0 η(y, z)β(y) + 1 ) 2 Ψ1,1 1,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ( δ ρ 2 Ψ 1,3 0 η(y, z)g(z) x 2 + ρ 2 ψ 1,0,0 η(y, z)g(z) x z Ψ2,2 2,1 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,2,1β 2 (y) + ρ 2 Ψ 1,2 1,1η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 2 ψ 1,1,1 η(y, z)β(y) Ψ1,1 0,1 η2 (y, z) x 2 ( δ + ρ 12 Ψ 2,3 0 β(y)g(z) ε x 2 + ρ 12 ψ 3,0,0 β(y)g(z) +ρ 12 ψ 2,0,0 β(y)g(z) x z + ρ 12 β(y)g(z) y z Ψ2,2 1,1 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,1,1 β 2 (y) + ρ 1 Ψ 1,2 0,1η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,0,1 η(y, z)β(y) +L ε,δ R. Then we write, with obvious notation, L ε,δ = 1 ε D 2,0 + 1 ε D 1,0 + D 0,0 + εd 1,0 + δd 0,1 + δ ε D 1,1 + L ε,δ R. In order to simplify the operators D i,j, note that Ψ 2,k 0 = 0, for k =1, 2, 3, Ψ 2,2 1,0 =Ψ2,2 0,1 =Ψ1,2 1,0 =Ψ2,2 2,0 =Ψ2,2 3,0 =Ψ2,2 2,1 =Ψ1,2 1,1 =0, ) ). 29

30 and Ψ 1,1 1,0 =Ψ1,1 0,1 = 0. Hence, D 2,0 = L Ψ 2,2 0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 0 2,0,0 β 2 (y) = L 0 D 1,0 = ρ 1 0 Ψ 1,2 0 η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,0,0 η(y, z)β(y) Ψ 2,2 1,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 0 2,1,0 β 2 (y) = ρ 1 ψ 1,0,0 η(y, z)β(y) D 0,0 = t Ψ1,1 0 η2 (y, z) x 2 r + ρ 1 0 Ψ 1,2 1,0η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 0 1,1,0 η(y, z)β(y) Ψ 2,2 2,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,2,0β 2 (y) = t ψ2 1,0,0η 2 (y, z) x 2 r +ψ 2,2,0β 2 (y) ψ 1,0,0 ψ 2,2,0 D 1,0 = Ψ 2,2 3,0 β2 (y) x 2 + ψ 2,3,0β 2 (y) + ρ 1 Ψ 1,2 2,0 η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,2,0 η(y, z)β(y) Ψ 1,1 1,0 β2 (y) x 2 = ( ψ 2,3,0 β 2 (y)+ρ 1 ψ 1,2,0 η(y, z)β(y) ) 2 + ρ 1 ψ 1,0,0 ψ 2,2,0 η(y, z)β(y) x 2 D 0,1 = ρ 2 Ψ 1,3 0 η(y, z)g(z) x 2 + ρ 2 ψ 1,0,0 η(y, z)g(z) x z Ψ 2,2 + ψ 2,2,1 β 2 (y) + ρ 2 0 Ψ 1,2 1,1η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 2 ψ 1,1,1 η(y, z)β(y) Ψ 1,1 0,1 η2 (y, z) x 2 =( ρ 2 ψ 1,0,0 ψ 3,0,0 η(y, z)g(z)) x 2 2,1 β2 (y) + ρ 2 ψ 1,0,0 η(y, z)g(z) x z +(ψ 2,2,1β 2 (y)+ρ 2 ψ 1,1,1 η(y, z)β(y)) x 2 D 1,1 = ρ 12 0 Ψ 2,3 0 β(y)g(z) x 2 + ρ 23 ψ 3,0,0 β(y)g(z) + ρ 12 ψ 0 2,0,0 β(y)g(z) x z + ρ 12 β(y)g(z) y z Ψ 2,2 1,1 β2 (y) x ψ 2,1,1 β 2 (y) + ρ 1 0 Ψ 1,2 0,1η(y, z)β(y) x 2 + ρ 1 0 ψ 1,0,1 η(y, z)β(y) = ρ 12 ψ 3,0,0 β(y)g(z) + ρ 12 β(y)g(z) y z It is clear from the above choices that the coefficients of the operator L ε,δ R are of 30

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Model for Derivatives on Futures

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Model for Derivatives on Futures Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Model for Derivatives on Futures Jean-Pierre Fouque, Yuri F. Saporito, Jorge P. Zubelli arxiv:1311.4249v1 [q-fin.cp] 18 Nov 2013 June 10, 2018 Abstract In this paper we

More information

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Toronto, June 25, 2010 Multiscale Stochastic Volatility

More information

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara Joint work with R. Sircar (Princeton) and K. Sølna (UC Irvine) Special Semester on Stochastics with Emphasis

More information

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Heston 1.5

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Heston 1.5 Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Heston 1.5 Jean-Pierre Fouque Department of Statistics & Applied Probability University of California Santa Barbara Modeling and Managing Financial Risks Paris,

More information

MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY ASYMPTOTICS

MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY ASYMPTOTICS MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY ASYMPTOTICS JEAN-PIERRE FOUQUE, GEORGE PAPANICOLAOU, RONNIE SIRCAR, AND KNUT SOLNA Abstract. In this paper we propose to use a combination of regular and singular perturbations

More information

Asian Options under Multiscale Stochastic Volatility

Asian Options under Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Contemporary Mathematics Asian Options under Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Jean-Pierre Fouque and Chuan-Hsiang Han Abstract. We study the problem of pricing arithmetic Asian options when the underlying

More information

Calibration to Implied Volatility Data

Calibration to Implied Volatility Data Calibration to Implied Volatility Data Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara 2008 Daiwa Lecture Series July 29 - August 1, 2008 Kyoto University, Kyoto 1 Calibration Formulas The implied

More information

Volatility Time Scales and. Perturbations

Volatility Time Scales and. Perturbations Volatility Time Scales and Perturbations Jean-Pierre Fouque NC State University, soon UC Santa Barbara Collaborators: George Papanicolaou Stanford University Ronnie Sircar Princeton University Knut Solna

More information

Evaluation of compound options using perturbation approximation

Evaluation of compound options using perturbation approximation Evaluation of compound options using perturbation approximation Jean-Pierre Fouque and Chuan-Hsiang Han April 11, 2004 Abstract This paper proposes a fast, efficient and robust way to compute the prices

More information

Stochastic Volatility Modeling

Stochastic Volatility Modeling Stochastic Volatility Modeling Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara 28 Daiwa Lecture Series July 29 - August 1, 28 Kyoto University, Kyoto 1 References: Derivatives in Financial Markets

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities

Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities Jean-Pierre Fouque Eli Kollman January 4, 010 Abstract We develop call option price approximations for both the market index and an individual

More information

Stochastic Volatility Effects on Defaultable Bonds

Stochastic Volatility Effects on Defaultable Bonds Stochastic Volatility Effects on Defaultable Bonds Jean-Pierre Fouque Ronnie Sircar Knut Sølna December 24; revised October 24, 25 Abstract We study the effect of introducing stochastic volatility in the

More information

Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation in a Stochastic Volatility Environment

Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation in a Stochastic Volatility Environment Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation in a Stochastic Volatility Environment Jean-Pierre Fouque Tracey Andrew Tullie December 11, 21 Abstract We propose a variance reduction method for Monte Carlo

More information

Two and Three factor models for Spread Options Pricing

Two and Three factor models for Spread Options Pricing Two and Three factor models for Spread Options Pricing COMMIDITIES 2007, Birkbeck College, University of London January 17-19, 2007 Sebastian Jaimungal, Associate Director, Mathematical Finance Program,

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models Sebastian Jaimungal sebastian.jaimungal@utoronto.ca Department of Statistics and Mathematical Finance Program, University of Toronto, Toronto, Canada http://www.utstat.utoronto.ca/sjaimung

More information

Asymptotic Pricing of Commodity Derivatives using Stochastic Volatility Spot Models

Asymptotic Pricing of Commodity Derivatives using Stochastic Volatility Spot Models Asymptotic Pricing of Commodity Derivatives using Stochastic Volatility Spot Models Samuel Hikspoors and Sebastian Jaimungal a a Department of Statistics and Mathematical Finance Program, University of

More information

Singular Perturbations in Option Pricing

Singular Perturbations in Option Pricing Singular Perturbations in Option Pricing J.-P. Fouque G. Papanicolaou R. Sircar K. Solna March 4, 2003 Abstract After the celebrated Black-Scholes formula for pricing call options under constant volatility,

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Columbia November 9, 27 Contents Joint work with Sergey Nadtochyi Motivation 1 Understanding

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Applications to Fixed Income and Credit Markets

Applications to Fixed Income and Credit Markets Applications to Fixed Income and Credit Markets Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara 28 Daiwa Lecture Series July 29 - August 1, 28 Kyoto University, Kyoto 1 Fixed Income Perturbations

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This question paper consists of 3 printed pages FinKont KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 211/212) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours This exam paper

More information

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque) Small time asymptotics for fast mean-reverting stochastic volatility models Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque) March 11, 2011 Frontier Probability Days,

More information

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t Economathematics Problem Sheet 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 1. Calculate Ee X where X is a gaussian random variable with mean µ and volatility σ >.. Verify that where W is a Wiener process. Ws dw s = 1 3 W t 3

More information

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 MSc Financial Engineering 2012-13 CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013 Department EMS, Birkbeck Introduction The assignment consists of Reading

More information

Calculating Implied Volatility

Calculating Implied Volatility Statistical Laboratory University of Cambridge University of Cambridge Mathematics and Big Data Showcase 20 April 2016 How much is an option worth? A call option is the right, but not the obligation, to

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

PRICING TIMER OPTIONS UNDER FAST MEAN-REVERTING STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY

PRICING TIMER OPTIONS UNDER FAST MEAN-REVERTING STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY CANADIAN APPLIED MATHEMATICS QUARTERLY Volume 17, Number 4, Winter 009 PRICING TIMER OPTIONS UNDER FAST MEAN-REVERTING STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY DAVID SAUNDERS ABSTRACT. Timer options are derivative securities

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling 25857 UTS Business School University of Technology Sydney Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire May 15, 2014 1/36 Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire 1 The Radon-Nikodym Derivative 2 Option Pricing under Stochastic

More information

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model

Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model Option Pricing Under a Stressed-Beta Model Adam Tashman in collaboration with Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California, Santa Barbara Department of Statistics and Applied Probability Center for Research

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives John Schoenmakers 9th Summer School in Mathematical Finance

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU IFS, Chengdu, China, July 30, 2018 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 7/30/2018 1 / 35 Interest Rates and Volatility Practitioners and

More information

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 13 Haijun Li Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation Week 13 1 / 28 Outline 1 Simulation

More information

MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY FOR EQUITY, INTEREST RATE, AND CREDIT DERIVATIVES

MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY FOR EQUITY, INTEREST RATE, AND CREDIT DERIVATIVES MULTISCALE STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY FOR EQUITY, INTEREST RATE, AND CREDIT DERIVATIVES Building upon the ideas introduced in their previous book, Derivatives in Financial Markets with Stochastic Volatility,

More information

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility Abstract We try to understand the Berestycki, Busca, and Florent () (BBF) result in the context of the work presented in Lectures and. Implied Volatility from Local Volatility. Current Plan as of March

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Constructing Markov models for barrier options Constructing Markov models for barrier options Gerard Brunick joint work with Steven Shreve Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin Nov. 14 th, 2009 3 rd Western Conference on Mathematical

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard Indifference pricing and the minimal entropy martingale measure Fred Espen Benth Centre of Mathematics for Applications

More information

Asymptotic Method for Singularity in Path-Dependent Option Pricing

Asymptotic Method for Singularity in Path-Dependent Option Pricing Asymptotic Method for Singularity in Path-Dependent Option Pricing Sang-Hyeon Park, Jeong-Hoon Kim Dept. Math. Yonsei University June 2010 Singularity in Path-Dependent June 2010 Option Pricing 1 / 21

More information

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 Stochastic Financial Modelling Time allowed: 2 hours Candidates should attempt all questions. Marks for each question

More information

Lecture 11: Stochastic Volatility Models Cont.

Lecture 11: Stochastic Volatility Models Cont. E4718 Spring 008: Derman: Lecture 11:Stochastic Volatility Models Cont. Page 1 of 8 Lecture 11: Stochastic Volatility Models Cont. E4718 Spring 008: Derman: Lecture 11:Stochastic Volatility Models Cont.

More information

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS PRICING EMMS014S7 Tuesday, May 31 2011, 10:00am-13.15pm

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing Rama Cont Yu Gu Abstract When the underlying asset is a continuous martingale, call option prices solve the Dupire equation, a forward parabolic

More information

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I) Paul J. Atzberger General comments or corrections should be sent to: paulatz@cims.nyu.edu 1 Introduction When using the Black-Scholes-Merton model to price derivative

More information

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic rates Mohammed Miri Joint work with Eric Benhamou (Pricing Partners) and Emmanuel Gobet (Ecole Polytechnique Modeling and Managing Financial

More information

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Part I: Discrete-time finance Exercise 1 (20 points) a. Provide the definition of the pricing kernel k q. Relate this pricing kernel to the set of discount factors D

More information

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Jhonny Gonzalez School of Mathematics The University of Manchester Magical books project August 23, 2012 Clip for this slide Pricing

More information

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations Stan Stilger June 6, 1 Fouque and Tullie use importance sampling for variance reduction in stochastic volatility simulations.

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

One-Factor Models { 1 Key features of one-factor (equilibrium) models: { All bond prices are a function of a single state variable, the short rate. {

One-Factor Models { 1 Key features of one-factor (equilibrium) models: { All bond prices are a function of a single state variable, the short rate. { Fixed Income Analysis Term-Structure Models in Continuous Time Multi-factor equilibrium models (general theory) The Brennan and Schwartz model Exponential-ane models Jesper Lund April 14, 1998 1 Outline

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives John Crosby Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Presentation at Baruch College, in New York, 16th November 2010

More information

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk Continuous Time Finance Tomas Björk 1 II Stochastic Calculus Tomas Björk 2 Typical Setup Take as given the market price process, S(t), of some underlying asset. S(t) = price, at t, per unit of underlying

More information

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Kyiv, June 19-23, 2006 Tommi Sottinen, University of Helsinki Based on a joint work No-arbitrage pricing beyond semimartingales with C. Bender, Weierstrass

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Market interest-rate models

Market interest-rate models Market interest-rate models Marco Marchioro www.marchioro.org November 24 th, 2012 Market interest-rate models 1 Lecture Summary No-arbitrage models Detailed example: Hull-White Monte Carlo simulations

More information

Monte Carlo Simulation of Stochastic Processes

Monte Carlo Simulation of Stochastic Processes Monte Carlo Simulation of Stochastic Processes Last update: January 10th, 2004. In this section is presented the steps to perform the simulation of the main stochastic processes used in real options applications,

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

Path Dependent British Options

Path Dependent British Options Path Dependent British Options Kristoffer J Glover (Joint work with G. Peskir and F. Samee) School of Finance and Economics University of Technology, Sydney 18th August 2009 (PDE & Mathematical Finance

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models

Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 30th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 5 1 / 46 Outline 1 Bonds and Interest Rates 2 Short Rate Models 3 Forward Rate Models 4 LIBOR and

More information

An Analytical Approximation for Pricing VWAP Options

An Analytical Approximation for Pricing VWAP Options .... An Analytical Approximation for Pricing VWAP Options Hideharu Funahashi and Masaaki Kijima Graduate School of Social Sciences, Tokyo Metropolitan University September 4, 215 Kijima (TMU Pricing of

More information

Non-semimartingales in finance

Non-semimartingales in finance Non-semimartingales in finance Pricing and Hedging Options with Quadratic Variation Tommi Sottinen University of Vaasa 1st Northern Triangular Seminar 9-11 March 2009, Helsinki University of Technology

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of New South Wales Joint work with T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and K. Yousiph Seminar 26 September, 2007

More information

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Dr. Roman V Belavkin MSO4112 Contents 1 Geometric Brownian motion 1 2 The Black-Scholes pricing 2 3 The Black-Scholes equation 3 References 5 1 Geometric Brownian motion

More information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model (joint work with J. Dong and L. Korobenko) A. Deniz Sezer University of Calgary April 28, 2016 Merton s model of corporate debt A corporate bond is a contingent

More information

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam Problem A: (42 pts) Answer briefly the following questions. 1. Questions

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

King s College London

King s College London King s College London University Of London This paper is part of an examination of the College counting towards the award of a degree. Examinations are governed by the College Regulations under the authority

More information

Timing the Smile. Jean-Pierre Fouque George Papanicolaou Ronnie Sircar Knut Sølna. October 9, 2003

Timing the Smile. Jean-Pierre Fouque George Papanicolaou Ronnie Sircar Knut Sølna. October 9, 2003 Timing the Smile Jean-Pierre Fouque George Papanicolaou Ronnie Sircar Knut Sølna October 9, 23 Abstract Within the general framework of stochastic volatility, the authors propose a method, which is consistent

More information

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation. Stochastic Differential Equation Consider. Moreover partition the interval into and define, where. Now by Rieman Integral we know that, where. Moreover. Using the fundamentals mentioned above we can easily

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility Abstract Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility Artur Sepp Mail: artursepp@hotmail.com, Web: www.hot.ee/seppar 16 November 2002 We study pricing under the local volatility. Our research is mainly

More information

Valuing Early Stage Investments with Market Related Timing Risk

Valuing Early Stage Investments with Market Related Timing Risk Valuing Early Stage Investments with Market Related Timing Risk Matt Davison and Yuri Lawryshyn February 12, 216 Abstract In this work, we build on a previous real options approach that utilizes managerial

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as: Continuous Time Finance Notes, Spring 2004 Section 1. 1/21/04 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences. For use in connection with the NYU course Continuous Time Finance. This

More information

The British Russian Option

The British Russian Option The British Russian Option Kristoffer J Glover (Joint work with G. Peskir and F. Samee) School of Finance and Economics University of Technology, Sydney 25th June 2010 (6th World Congress of the BFS, Toronto)

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration Denis Belomestny Weierstraß Institute Berlin Vienna, 16 November 2007 Denis Belomestny (WIAS) Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration Vienna, 16 November

More information

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and M. Rutkowski Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, 6 February 2006 1 Based on N. Vaillant (2001) A

More information

Fast narrow bounds on the value of Asian options

Fast narrow bounds on the value of Asian options Fast narrow bounds on the value of Asian options G. W. P. Thompson Centre for Financial Research, Judge Institute of Management, University of Cambridge Abstract We consider the problem of finding bounds

More information

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends. 224 10 Arbitrage and SDEs last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends. 10.1 (Calculation of Delta First and Finest

More information

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL FABIO MERCURIO BANCA IMI, MILAN http://www.fabiomercurio.it 1 Stylized facts Traders use the Black-Scholes formula to price plain-vanilla options. An

More information

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE. Risk Neutral Pricing Thursday, May 12, 2011 2:03 PM We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE. This is used to construct a

More information

The Lognormal Interest Rate Model and Eurodollar Futures

The Lognormal Interest Rate Model and Eurodollar Futures GLOBAL RESEARCH ANALYTICS The Lognormal Interest Rate Model and Eurodollar Futures CITICORP SECURITIES,INC. 399 Park Avenue New York, NY 143 Keith Weintraub Director, Analytics 1-559-97 Michael Hogan Ex

More information