PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives"

Transcription

1 PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of New South Wales Joint work with T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and K. Yousiph Seminar 26 September, 2007

2 Outline The Model 1 The Model Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire 2 Martingale Measure 3 Martingale Measure 4 Pricing PDEs 5 Pricing PDEs 6 Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names

3 REFERENCES

4 References Bielecki, T., Jeanblanc, M. and Rutkowski, M.: PDE approach to valuation and hedging of credit derivatives. Quantitative Finance 5 (2005), Rutkowski, M. and Yousiph, K.: PDE approach to the valuation and hedging of basket credit derivatives. Forthcoming in International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance. Bielecki, T., Jeanblanc, M. and Rutkowski, M.: Hedging of credit derivatives in models with totally unexpected default. In: Stochastic Processes and Applications to Mathematical Finance, J. Akahori et al., eds., World Scientific, Singapore, 2006, Bielecki, T., Jeanblanc, M. and Rutkowski, M.: Replication of contingent claims in a reduced-form credit risk model with discontinuous asset prices. Stochastic Models 22 (2006),

5 Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire THE MODEL

6 Default Time The Model Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire The default time τ is a non-negative random variable on (Ω, G, Q). Note that Q is the statistical probability measure. The filtration generated by the default process H t = 1 {τ t} is denoted by H. We set G = F H, so that G t = F t H t for every t R +, where F = (F t) t R+ is a reference filtration. We define the processes F t and G t as F t = Q{τ t F t} and G t = 1 F t = Q{τ > t F t}.

7 Hazard Process The Model Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire The process Γ, given as Γ t = ln(1 F t) = ln G t is the F-hazard process under the statistical probability Q. We shall assume that the F-hazard process is absolutely continuous: Γ t = R t γu du. 0 Hence, the compensated default process M t = H t Z t τ 0 γ u du = H t Z t 0 ξ u du, is a G-martingale under Q, where we denote ξ t = γ t1 {t<τ}.

8 Hypothesis (H) The Model Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire Hypothesis (H). We assume throughout that any F-martingale under Q is also a G-martingale under Q. Hypothesis (H) is satisfied if a random time τ is defined through the canonical construction. If the representation theorem holds for the filtration F and a finite family Z i, i n, of F-martingales then, under Hypothesis (H), it holds also for the filtration G and with respect to the G-martingales Z i, i n and M. Remark. Hypothesis (H) is not invariant with respect to an equivalent change of a probability measure, in general.

9 Dynamics of Traded Assets Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire Let Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 be semimartingales on (Ω, G, G, Q). We interpret Y i t as the cash price at time t of the ith traded asset in the market model M = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ; Φ), where Φ stands for the class of all self-financing trading strategies. We postulate that the process Y i is governed by the SDE with Y i 0 > 0. dy i t = Y i t `µi dt + σ i dw t + κ i dm t, i = 1, 2, 3, Here W is a one-dimensional Brownian motion and the M is the compensated martingale of the default process H.

10 Assumptions The Model Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire We assume that that κ i 1 and κ 1 > 1 so that Yt 1 > 0 for every t R +. This assumptions allows us to take the first asset as a numeraire. Note that the constant coefficient κ 1 > 1 corresponds to a fractional recovery of market value for the first asset. In general, we do not assume that a risk-free security exists. Hence we do not refer to the theory involving the risk-neutral probability associated with the choice of a savings account as a numeraire.

11 Change of a Numeraire Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire An equivalent martingale measure e Q is characterized by the property that the relative prices Y i (Y 1 ) 1, i = 1, 2, 3, are e Q-martingales. We will derive the dynamics for the process Y i,1 = Y i (Y 1 ) 1 for i = 2, 3. From Itô s formula, we first obtain «1 d = 1 Yt 1 Yt 1 1 Y 1 t µ 1 + σ ξ t 1 σ 1 dw t + κ κ 1 dm t ««1 + κ 1 dt 1 + κ 1 «.

12 Dynamics of Relative Prices Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire Consequently, the Itô s integration by parts formula yields the following dynamics for the processes Y i,1 ( dy i,1 t = Y i,1 t µ i µ 1 σ 1 (σ i σ 1 ) ξ t(κ i κ 1 ) + (σ i σ 1 ) dw t + κ i κ κ 1 dm t ). κ κ 1 «dt

13 Equivalent Martingale Measure Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire By assumption, e Q is equivalent to the statistical probability Q on (Ω, G T ) and such that Y i,1, i = 2, 3 are e Q-martingales. Kusuoka (1999) showed that any probability equivalent to Q on (Ω, G T ) is defined by means of its Radon-Nikodým density process η satisfying the SDE dη t = η t `θt dw t + ζ t dm t, η0 = 1, where θ and ζ are G-predictable processes satisfying mild technical conditions (in particular, ζ t > 1 for t [0, T ]). Since M is stopped at τ, we may and do assume that ζ is stopped at τ.

14 Radon-Nikodým Density Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire We define e Q by setting d e Q dq = η T = E T (θw )E T (ζm), Q-a.s. Then the processes W c and M b given by, for t [0, T ], Z t cw t = W t θ u du, bm t = M t 0 Z t 0 Z t Z t ξ uζ u du = H t ξ u(1 + ζ u) du = H t bξ u du, 0 0 where b ξ u = ξ u(1 + ζ u), are G-martingales under e Q.

15 Martingale Condition The Model Default Time Prices of Traded Assets Change of a Numeraire Proposition Processes Y i,1, i = 2, 3 are e Q-martingales if and only if drifts in their dynamics, when expressed in terms of c W and b M, vanish. Hence the following equalities hold for i = 2, 3 and every t [0, T ] j Y i,1 t µ 1 µ i + (σ 1 σ i )(θ t σ 1 ) + ξ t(κ 1 κ i ) ζt κ ff 1 = κ 1 Equivalently, we have for i = 2, 3, on the set Y i,1 t 0, µ 1 µ i + (σ 1 σ i )(θ t σ 1 ) + ξ t(κ 1 κ i ) ζt κ κ 1 = 0.

16 Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A CASE A: STRICTLY POSITIVE PRIMARY ASSETS

17 Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A Case A: standing assumptions: We postulate that κ 1 > 1 so that Y 1 > 0. We assume, in addition, that κ i > 1 for i = 2, 3, so that the price processes Y 2 and Y 3 are strictly positive as well. Martingale condition: From the general theory of arbitrage pricing, it follows that the market model M is complete and arbitrage-free if there exists a unique solution (θ, ζ) such that the process ζ > 1. Since Y i,1 > 0, we search for processes (θ, ζ) such that for i = 2, 3 κ 1 κ i θ t(σ 1 σ i ) + ζ tξ t = µ i µ 1 + σ 1 (σ 1 σ i ) + ξ t(κ 1 κ i ). 1 + κ κ 1 κ 1

18 Martingale Condition The Model Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A Since ξ t = γ1 {t τ}, we deal here with four linear equations. For t τ: θ t(σ 1 σ 2 ) + ζ tγ κ 1 κ κ 1 = µ 2 µ 1 + σ 1 (σ 1 σ 2 ) + γ (κ 1 κ 2 )κ κ 1, θ t(σ 1 σ 3 ) + ζ tγ κ 1 κ κ 1 = µ 3 µ 1 + σ 1 (σ 1 σ 3 ) + γ (κ 1 κ 3 )κ κ 1. For t > τ: θ t(σ 1 σ 2 ) = µ 2 µ 1 + σ 1 (σ 1 σ 2 ), θ t(σ 1 σ 3 ) = µ 3 µ 1 + σ 1 (σ 1 σ 3 ). The first (the second, resp.) pair of equations is referred to as the pre-default (post-default, resp.) no-arbitrage condition.

19 Notation The Model Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A To solve explicitly these equations, we find it convenient to write a = det A, b = det B, c = det C, where A, B and C are the following matrices:»» σ1 σ A = 2 κ 1 κ 2 σ1 σ, B = 2 µ 1 µ 2 σ 1 σ 3 κ 1 κ 3 σ 1 σ 3 µ 1 µ 3» κ1 κ C = 2 µ 1 µ 2. κ 1 κ 3 µ 1 µ 3,

20 Auxiliary Lemma The Model Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A Lemma The pair (θ, ζ) satisfies the following equations θ ta = σ 1 a + c, ζ tξ ta = κ 1 ξ ta (1 + κ 1 )b. In order to ensure the validity of the second equation after the default time τ (i.e., on the set {ξ t = 0}), we need to impose an additional condition, b = 0, or more explicitly, (σ 1 σ 2 )(µ 1 µ 3 ) (σ 1 σ 3 )(µ 1 µ 2 ) = 0. If this holds, then we obtain the following equations θ ta = σ 1 a + c, ζ tξ ta = κ 1 ξ ta.

21 Existence of a Martingale Measure Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A Proposition (i) If a 0 and b = 0 then the unique martingale measure e Q has the Radon-Nikodým density of the form d e Q dq = E T (θw )E T (ζm), where the constants θ and ζ are given by and where we write, for t [0, T ], θ = σ 1 + c a, ζ = κ 1 > 1, E t(θw ) = exp θw t 1 2 θ2 t E t(ζm) = `1 + 1 {τ t} ζ) exp ` ζγ(t τ).

22 Existence of a Martingale Measure Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A Proposition (ii) If a 0 and b = 0 then the model M = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ; Φ) is arbitrage-free and complete. Moreover, the process (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3, H) has the Markov property under e Q. (iii) If a = 0 and b = 0 then a solution (θ, ζ) exists provided that c = 0 and the uniqueness of a martingale measure e Q fails to hold. In this case, the model M = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ; Φ) is arbitrage-free, but it is not complete. (iv) If b 0 then a martingale measure fails to exist and consequently the model M = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ; Φ) is not arbitrage-free.

23 Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A Example A: Extension of the Black-Scholes Model Assume that the asset Y 1 is risk-free, the asset Y 2 Y 1 is default-free, and Y 3 is a defaultable asset with non-zero recovery, so that dyt 1 = ryt 1 dt, dyt 2 = Yt 2 `µ2 dt + σ 2 dw t, dy 3 t = Y 3 t `µ3 dt + σ 3 dw t + κ 3 dm t. We thus have σ 1 = κ 1 = 0, µ 1 = r, σ 2 0, κ 2 = 0, and κ 3 0, κ 3 > 1. Therefore, a = σ 2 κ 3 0, c = κ 3 (r µ 2 ), and the equality b = 0 holds if and only if σ 2 (r µ 3 ) = σ 3 (r µ 2 ).

24 Example A (Continued) Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example A It is easy to check that θ = r µ 2 σ 2, ζ = 0, and thus under the martingale measure e Q we have (irrespective of whether σ 3 > 0 or σ 3 = 0) dyt 1 = ryt 1 dt, dyt 2 = Yt 2 `r dt + σ2 dw c t, dy 3 t = Y 3 t `r dt + σ3 d c W t + κ 3 dm t. Since ζ = 0 the risk-neutral default intensity bγ coincides here with the statistical default intensity γ. This implies the equality b M = M.

25 Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading CASE B: DEFAULTABLE ASSET WITH ZERO RECOVERY

26 Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading Case B: standing assumptions: We postulate that κ i > 1 for i = 1, 2 and κ 3 = 1. This implies that the price of a defaultable asset Y 3 vanishes after τ, and thus the findings of the preceding section are no longer valid. Martingale condition: Since Y 3 jumps to zero at τ, the first equality in the martingale condition µ 2 µ 1 + (σ 2 σ 1 )(θ t σ 1 ) + ξ t(κ 2 κ 1 ) ζt κ κ 1 = 0 should still be satisfied for every t [0, T ]. The second equality in the martingale condition µ 3 µ 1 + (σ 3 σ 1 )(θ t σ 1 ) + ξ t(κ 3 κ 1 ) ζt κ κ 1 = 0 is required to hold on the set {τ > t} only (i.e. when ξ t = γ).

27 Martingale Condition The Model Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading Lemma Under the present assumptions, the unknown processes θ and ζ in the Radon-Nikodým density of e Q with respect to Q satisfy the following equations µ 2 µ 1 + (σ 2 σ 1 )(θ t σ 1 ) = 0, for t > τ, µ 2 µ 1 + (σ 2 σ 1 )(θ t σ 1 ) + γ(κ 2 κ 1 ) ζt κ κ 1 = 0, for t τ, µ 3 µ 1 + (σ 3 σ 1 )(θ t σ 1 ) + γ( 1 κ 1 ) ζt κ κ 1 = 0, for t τ. This leads to the following result.

28 Existence of a Martingale Measure Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading Proposition The pair (θ, ζ) satisfies the following equations, for t τ, θ ta = σ 1 a + c, ζ tγa = κ 1 γa (1 + κ 1 )b. Moreover, for t > τ, µ 2 µ 1 + (σ 2 σ 1 )(θ t σ 1 ) = 0. Let a 0, σ 1 σ 2 and γ > b/a. Then the unique solution is θ t = 1 {t τ} σ 1 + c + 1 {t>τ} σ 1 µ «1 µ 2, ζ t = κ 1 (1 + κ 1)b > 1. a σ 1 σ 2 γa The model M = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ; Φ) is arbitrage-free, complete, and has the Markov property under the unique martingale measure e Q.

29 Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading Example B: Extension of the Black-Scholes Model Assume that the asset Y 1 is risk-free, the asset Y 2 Y 1 is default-free, and Y 3 is a defaultable asset with zero recovery, so that dyt 1 = ryt 1 dt, dyt 2 = Yt 2 `µ2 dt + σ 2 dw t, dy 3 t = Y 3 t `µ3 dt + σ 3 dw t dm t. This corresponds to the following conditions: σ 1 = κ 1 = 0, µ 1 = r, σ 2 0, κ 2 = 0, κ 3 = 1. Hence a = σ 2 0. Assume, in addition, that γ > b/a = r µ 3 σ 3 σ 2 (r µ 2 ).

30 Example B (Continued) Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading Then we obtain θ = r µ 2 σ 2, ζ = b γa = 1 γ µ 3 r σ «3 (µ 2 r) > 1. σ 2 Consequently, we have under the unique martingale measure e Q dyt 1 = ryt 1 dt, dyt 2 = Yt 2 `r dt + σ2 dw c t, dy 3 t = Y 3 t `r dt + σ3 d c W t d b M t. We do not assume here that b = 0; if this holds then ζ = 0, as in Example A. In Case B, the risk-neutral default intensity bγ and the statistical default intensity γ are different, in general,

31 Case of Stopped Trading Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading Suppose that the recovery payoff at the time of default is exogenously specified in terms of some economic factors related to the prices of traded assets (e.g. credit spreads). The valuation problem for a defaultable claim is reduced to finding its pre-default value, and it is natural to search for a replicating strategy up to default time only. It thus suffices to examine the stopped model in which asset prices and all trading activities are stopped at time τ. In this case, we search for a pair (θ, ζ) of real numbers satisfying θa = σ 1 a + c, ζγa = κ 1 γa (1 + κ 1 )b.

32 Case of Stopped Trading Martingale Condition Martingale Measure Example B Stopped Trading If a 0 then the unique solution (θ, ζ) to the above pair of equations is θ = σ 1 + c a, ζ = κ 1 (1 + κ 1)b γa > 1, where the last inequality holds provided that γ > b/a. As expected, in the stopped model, we obtain the unique martingale measure e Q for any choice of recovery coefficients κ 2 and κ 3. In the case of stopped trading, hedging of a contingent claim after the default time τ is not considered.

33 Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A CASE A: PRICING PDEs AND HEDGING

34 Contingent Claim The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Let us now discuss the PDE approach in a model in which the prices of all three primary assets are non-vanishing. It is natural to focus on the case when the market model M = (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 ; Φ) is complete and arbitrage-free. Therefore, we shall work under the assumptions of part (i) in the proposition on the existence of a martingale measure. We are interested in the valuation and hedging of a generic contingent claim with maturity T and the terminal payoff Y = G(Y 1 T, Y 2 T, Y 3 T, H T ). The technique derived for this case can be easily applied to a defaultable claim that is subject to a fairly general recovery scheme.

35 Risk-Neutral Price The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Let a 0 and b = 0, and let e Q be the unique martingale measure associated with the numeraire Y 1. Then where θ and ζ are explicitly known. d e Q dq = E T (θw )E T (ζm) If Y (YT 1 ) 1 is Q-integrable e then the risk-neutral price of Y equals, for every t [0, T ], π t(y ) = Yt 1 1 E eq`(y T ) 1 Y G t = Y 1 t E eq `(Y 1 T ) 1 G(Y 1 T, Y 2 T, Y 3 T, H T ) Y 1 t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, H t where the second equality is a consequence of the Markov property of (Y 1, Y 2, Y 3, H) under e Q.

36 Pricing PDEs: Case A The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Proposition Let the price processes Y i, i = 1, 2, 3 satisfy dyt i = Yt i `µi dt + σ i dw t + κ i dm t with κ i > 1 for i = 1, 2, 3. Assume that a 0 and b = 0. Then the risk-neutral price π t(y ) of the claim Y equals π t(y ) = 1 {t<τ} C(t, Y 1 t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, 0) + 1 {t τ} C(t, Y 1 t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, 1) for some function C : [0, T ] R 3 + {0, 1} R. Assume that for h = 0 and h = 1 the function C(, h) : [0, T ] R 3 + R belongs to the class C 1,2 ([0, T ] R 3 +, R).

37 Pricing PDEs: Case A The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Proposition Then the functions C(, 0) and C(, 1) solve the following PDEs: tc(, 0) + and 3X (α γκ i )y i i C(, 0) i=1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 0) αc(, 0) i,j=1 + γˆc(t, y 1 (1 + κ 1 ), y 2 (1 + κ 2 ), y 3 (1 + κ 3 ), 1) C(t, y 1, y 2, y 3, 0) = 0 tc(, 1) + α 3X y i i C(, 1) i=1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 1) αc(, 1) = 0 i,j=1 c where α = µ i + σ i, subject to the terminal conditions a C(T, y 1, y 2, y 3, 0) = G(y 1, y 2, y 3, 0), C(T, y 1, y 2, y 3, 1) = G(y 1, y 2, y 3, 1).

38 Comments The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A The valuation problem splits into two pricing PDEs, which are solved recursively. In the first step, we solve the PDE satisfied by the post-default pricing function C(, 1). Next, we substitute this function into the first PDE, and we solve it for the pre-default pricing function C(, 0). The assumption that we deal with only three primary assets and the coefficients are constant can be easily relaxed, but a general result is too heavy to be stated here. Observe that the real-world default intensity γ under Q, rather than the risk-neutral default intensity ˆγ under e Q, enters the valuation PDE.

39 Black and Scholes PDE Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A We consider the set-up of Example A, with a 0 and b = 0. Let Y = G(Y 2 T ) for some function G : R R such that Y (Y 1 T ) 1 is eq-integrable. It is possible to show that π t(y ) = C(t, Y 2 t ). The two valuation PDEs of Proposition A2 reduce to a single PDE tc + (µ 2 σ 2 θ)y 2 2 C σ2 2y C (µ 2 σ 2 θ)c = 0 with θ = (r µ 2 )/σ 2. After simplifications, we obtain the classic Black and Scholes PDE tc + ry 2 2 C σ2 2y C rc = 0.

40 Trading Strategies The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Recall that φ = (φ 1, φ 2, φ 3 ) is a self-financing strategy if the processes φ 1, φ 2, φ 3 are G-predictable and the wealth process satisfies V t(φ) = φ 1 t Yt 1 + φ 2 t Yt 2 + φ 3 t Yt 3 dv t(φ) = φ 1 t dy 1 t + φ 2 t dy 2 t + φ 3 t dy 3 t. We say that φ replicates a contingent claim Y if V T (φ) = Y. If φ is a replicating strategy for a claim Y then, for t [0, T ], π t(y ) = φ 1 t Y 1 t + φ 2 t Y 2 t + φ 3 t Y 3 t. To find a replicating strategy, we combine the sensitivities of the valuation function C with respect to primary assets with the jump C t = C t C t associated with default event.

41 Hedging with Sensitivities and Jumps Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Proposition Under the present the assumptions, the claim G(YT 1, YT 2, YT 3, H T ) is replicated by φ = (φ 1, φ 2, φ 3 ), where the components φ i, i = 2, 3, are given in terms of the valuation functions C(, 0) and C(, 1): φ 2 t = φ 3 t = 1 ay 2 t 1 ay 3 t! 3X (κ 3 κ 1 ) σ i Yt i i C σ 1 C (σ 3 σ 1 )( C κ 1 C) i=1! 3X (κ 2 κ 1 ) σ i Yt i i C σ 1 C (σ 2 σ 1 )( C κ 1 C) i=1 and φ 1 equals φ 1 t = (Y 1 t ) 1 C t 3X i=2 φ i tyt i.

42 Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Example A: Extension of the Black-Scholes Model Assume that the asset Y 1 is risk-free, the asset Y 2 Y 1 is default-free, and Y 3 is a defaultable asset with non-zero recovery, so that dyt 1 = ryt 1 dt, dyt 2 = Yt 2 `µ2 dt + σ 2 dw t, dyt 3 = Yt 3 `µ3 dt + σ 3 dw t + κ 3 dm t with σ 2 0 and κ 3 0, κ 3 > 1. We may assume, without loss of generality, that C does not depend explicitly on the variable y 1. Assume that a = σ 2 κ 3 0 and σ 2 (r µ 3 ) = σ 3 (r µ 2 ). The following result combines and adapts previous results to the present situation.

43 Example A: Pricing PDEs Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Corollary The arbitrage price of a claim Y = G(YT 2, YT 3, H T ) can be represented as π t(y ) = C(t, Yt 2, Yt 3, H t), where C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) satisfies tc(, 0) + ry 2 2 C(, 0) + y 3 (r κ 3 γ) 3 C(, 0) rc(, 0) + 1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 0) + γ`c(t, y 2, y 3 (1 + κ 3 ), 1) C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) = 0 2 i,j=2 with C(T, y 2, y 3, 0) = G(y 2, y 3, 0), and C(t, y 2, y 3, 1) satisfies tc(t, y 2, y 3, 1) + ry 2 2 C(t, y 2, y 3, 1) + ry 3 3 C(t, y 2, y 3, 1) rc(t, y 2, y 3, 1) + 1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(t, y 2, y 3, 1) = 0 2 i,j=2 with C(T, y 2, y 3, 1) = G(y 2, y 3, 1).

44 Example A: Hedging The Model Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Corollary The replicating strategy for Y equals φ = (φ 1, φ 2, φ 3 ), where! 3X φ 1 t = (Yt 1 ) 1 C t φ i tyt i, φ 2 t = 1 σ 2 κ 3 Y 2 t κ 3 i=2 3X i=2 σ i y i i C(t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, H t ) σ 3`C(t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t (1 + κ 3 ), 1) C(t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, 0)!, φ 3 t = 1 `C(t, Y 2 κ 3 Yt 3 t, Yt (1 3 + κ 3 ), 1) C(t, Yt, 2 Yt, 3 0).

45 Example A: Survival Claim Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A By a survival claim we mean a claim of the form Y = 1 {τ>t } X, where an F T -measurable random variable X represents the promised payoff. In other words, a survival claim is a contract with zero recovery in the case of default prior to maturity T. We assume that the promised payoff has the form X = G(Y 2 T, Y 3 T ), where Y i T is the (pre-default) value of the ith asset at time T. It is obvious that the pricing function C(, 1) is now equal to zero, and thus we are only interested in the pre-default pricing function C(, 0).

46 Example A: Survival Claim Pricing PDEs Hedging Example A Corollary The pre-default pricing function C(, 0) of a survival claim of the form Y = 1 {τ>t } G(Y 2 T, Y 3 T ) solves the PDE tc(, 0) + ry 2 2 C(, 0) + y 3 (r κ 3 γ) 3 C(, 0) + 1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 0) (r + γ)c(, 0) = 0 2 i,j=2 with C(T, y 2, y 3, 0) = G(y 2, y 3 ). The components φ 2 and φ 3 of a replicating strategy φ are given by the following expressions φ 2 t = 1 κ 3 σ 2 Y 2 t κ 3 3X i=2 σ i Yt i i C(, 0) σ 3 C(, 0), φ 3 C(, 0) t =. κ 3 Yt 3

47 Pricing PDEs Example B CASE B: PRICING PDEs AND HEDGING

48 Pricing PDEs Example B Standing assumptions: We now assume that the prices Y 1 and Y 2 are strictly positive, but κ 3 = 1 so that Y 3 is a defaultable asset with zero recovery. Of course, the price Yt 3 vanishes after default, that is, on the set {t τ}. We assume here that a 0 and σ 1 σ 2, but we no longer postulate that b = 0. We still assume that γ > b/a, however. Let us denote α i = µ i + σ i c a, β i = µ i σ i µ 1 µ 2 σ 1 σ 2.

49 Valuation PDEs: Case B Pricing PDEs Example B Proposition Let the price processes Y i, i = 1, 2, 3, satisfy dyt i = Yt i `µi dt + σ i dw t + κ i dm t with κ i > 1 for i = 1, 2 and κ 3 = 1. Assume that a 0, σ 1 σ 2, γ > b/a. Consider a contingent claim Y with maturity date T and the terminal payoff G(Y 1 T, Y 2 T, Y 3 T, H T ). In addition, we postulate that the pricing functions C(, 0) and C(, 1) belong to the class C 1,2 ([0, T ] R 3 +, R).

50 Pricing PDEs: Case B The Model Pricing PDEs Example B Proposition Then the pre-default pricing function C(t, y 1, y 2, y 3, 0) satisfies the pre-default PDE tc(, 0) + 3X (α i γκ i )y i i C(, 0) i=1 + γ b a α 1 + κ 1 b a 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 0) i,j=1 ˆC(t, y1 (1 + κ 1 ), y 2 (1 + κ 2 ), 0, 1) C(t, y 1, y 2, y 3, 0) C(, 0) = 0 subject to the terminal condition C(T, y 1, y 2, y 3, 0) = G(y 1, y 2, y 3, 0).

51 Pricing PDEs: Case B The Model Pricing PDEs Example B Proposition The post-default pricing function C(t, y 1, y 2, 1) solves the post-default PDE 2X tc(, 1) + β i y i i C(, 1) + 1 2X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 1) β 1 C(, 1) = 0 2 i=1 i,j=1 subject to the terminal condition C(T, y 1, y 2, 1) = G(y 1, y 2, 0, 1). The components of the replicating strategy φ are given by the general formulae.

52 Example B (Continued) Pricing PDEs Example B We assume that the processes Y 1, Y 2, Y 3 satisfy Let us write br = r + bγ, where dyt 1 = ryt 1 dt, dyt 2 = Yt 2 `µ2 dt + σ 2 dw t, dy 3 t = Y 3 t `µ3 dt + σ 3 dw t dm t. bγ = γ(1 + ζ) = γ b a = γ + µ 3 r + σ 3 σ 2 (r µ 2 ) > 0 stands for the default intensity under e Q. The quantity br is interpreted as the credit-risk adjusted short-term rate. Straightforward calculations show that the following corollary is valid.

53 Example B: Pricing PDEs Pricing PDEs Example B Corollary Assume that σ 1 = κ 1 = κ 2 = 0, κ 3 = 1 and Then C(, 0) satisfies the PDE γ > b/a = r µ 3 σ 3 σ 2 (r µ 2 ). tc(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + ry 2 2 C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + bry 3 3 C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) brc(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + 1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + bγc(t, y 2, 1) = 0, 2 i,j=2 with C(T, y 2, y 3, 0) = G(y 2, y 3, 0), and the function C(, 1) solves tc(t, y 2, 1) + ry 2 2 C(t, y 2, 1) σ2 2y C(t, y 2, 1) rc(t, y 2, 1) = 0, with C(T, y 2, 1) = G(y 2, 0, 1).

54 Example B: Survival Claim Pricing PDEs Example B For a survival claim, we have C(, 1) = 0, and thus we obtain following results. Corollary The pre-default pricing function C(, 0) of a survival claim Y = 1 {τ>t } G(Y 2 T, Y 3 T ) solves the following PDE: tc(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + ry 2 2 C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + bry 3 3 C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) + 1 3X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(t, y 2, y 3, 0) brc(t, y 2, y 3, 0) = 0 2 i,j=2 with the terminal condition C(T, y 2, y 3, 0) = G(y 2, y 3 ).

55 Corollary B2 (Continued) Pricing PDEs Example B Corollary The components φ 2 and φ 3 of the replicating strategy are, for every t < τ, φ 2 t = φ 3 t = 1 σ 2 Y 2 t 3X i=2 1 C(t, Yt, 2 Yt, 3 0). Yt 3 σ i Yt i i C(t, Yt, 2 Yt, 3 0) + σ 3 C(t, Yt, 2 Yt, 3 0), We have φ 3 t Yt 3 = C(t, Yt, 2 Yt, 3 0) for every t [0, T ]. Hence the following relationships holds, for every t < τ, φ 3 t Y 3 t = C(t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, 0), φ 1 t Y 1 t + φ 2 t Y 2 t = 0. The last equality is a special case of a balance condition introduced in Bielecki et al. (2006) in a semimartingale set-up.

56 Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names PDE APPROACH TO BASKET CLAIMS

57 Case of Two Credit Names Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names We first consider a special case of two credit names: Let τ 1 and τ 2 be strictly positive random variables defined on a probability space (Ω, G, Q). We introduce the corresponding jump processes H i t = 1 {τi t} for i = 1, 2, and we denote by H i the filtration generated by the process H i. Finally, we set G = F H 1 H 2, where the filtration F is generated by some Brownian motion W (which is also a G-Brownian motion). We now need at least four traded assets, since we deal with three (possibly independent) sources of uncertainty.

58 Dynamics of Traded Assets Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Standing assumptions: For the sake of simplicity, we assume that Yt 1 = 1, so that Y 1 represents the savings account corresponding to the short-term rate r = 0. We postulate that the asset price Y i satisfies, for i = 2, 3, 4, dyt i = Yt `µi i dt + σ i dw t + κ i dmt 1 + ψ i dmt 2 where M i is the Q-martingale associated with the default process H i, that is, Z t Mt i = Ht i γu(1 i Hu) i du. 0 To ensure the Markov property, we assume that γ i u = g i (u, H 1 u, H 2 u ). Defaults cannot occur simultaneously: H 1 t H 2 t = 0.

59 Contingent Claim The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Consider a contingent claim of the form Y = G(Y 2 T, Y 3 T, Y 4 T, H 1 T, H 2 T ). Its arbitrage price can be represented as a function π t(y ) = C(t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, Y 4 t, H 1 t, H 2 t ) or equivalently, as a quadruplet of functions: C(, 1, 1), C(, 0, 1), C(, 1, 0) and C(, 0, 0). The pricing functions satisfy the terminal condition C(T, y 2, y 3, y 4, h 1, h 2 ) = G(y 2, y 3, y 4, h 1, h 2 ). The process C t = C(t, Y 2 t, Y 3 t, Y 4 t, H 1 t, H 2 t ) is a G-martingale under e Q.

60 Pricing PDEs The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Let bγ 1 0 and bγ 2 0 be the intensities of τ 1 and τ 2 prior to the first default, bγ 1 2 be the intensity of the default time τ 1 on the event {τ 2 t < τ 1 }, bγ 2 1 be the intensity of the default time τ 2 on the event {τ 1 t < τ 2 }. We obtain the following pricing PDE prior to the first default: 4X tc(, 0, 0) (κ i bγ ψ i bγ 0)y 2 i i C(, 0, 0) i=2 4X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 0, 0) i,j=2 + bγ 1 0`C(, 1, 0) C(, 0, 0) + bγ 2 0`C(, 0, 1) C(, 0, 0) = 0.

61 Pricing PDEs (continued) Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names After the first default, we have 4X tc(, 1, 0) ψ i bγ 1y 2 i i C(, 1, 0) i=2 + bγ 2 1`C(, 1, 1) C(, 1, 0) = 0, 4X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 1, 0) i,j=2 4X tc(, 0, 1) κ i bγ 2y 1 i i C(, 0, 1) i=2 + bγ 2`C(, 1 1, 1) C(, 0, 1) = 0, and after the second default 4X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 0, 1) i,j=2 tc(, 1, 1) + 1 4X σ i σ j y i y j ij C(, 1, 1) = 0. 2 i,j=2

62 Case of m Credit Names Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Standing assumptions: Let the random times τ 1, τ 2,..., τ m, defined on a common probability space (Ω, G, Q), represent the default times of m credit names. Under real-world probability Q, the price processes Y 1, Y 2,..., Y n of primary traded assets are governed by dyt i = Yt i µ i t dt + dx k=1 σ k i (t) dw k t + mx κ l i(t) dmt l where the G-martingales M l, l = 1, 2,..., m are given by Z τl Mt l = Ht l t Z t γu l du = Ht l ξu l du. 0 0 l=1

63 The Markovian Model The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names The processes µ i, σ i, κ i are given by some functions on R + R n and µ i t = µ i (t, Y 1 t,..., Y n t ), σ i (t) = σ i (t, Y 1 t,..., Y n t ) κ i (t) = κ i (t, Y 1 t,..., Y n t ). The functions above are sufficiently regular, so that the SDE admits a unique strong solution for i = 1, 2,..., n. The pre-default intensities λ l are deterministic functions of asset prices, that is, λ l t = λ l (t, Yt, 1..., Yt ) n for every t R + and l = 1, 2,..., m.

64 Kusuoka s Theorem The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Proposition Any probability measure e Q equivalent to Q on (Ω, G T ) is given by the Radon-Nikodým derivative process η satisfying, for t [0, T ], dq e G t = η t = dq dy Z. Y m Z E t θu k dwu k. E t ζu l dmu l k=1 0 where θ 1, θ 2,..., θ d, ζ 1, ζ 2,..., ζ m are some G-predictable processes such that ζ l t > 1 for every t [0, T ]. The processes W fk, k = 1,..., d and M e l, l = 1,..., m are G-martingales under Q e where l=1 0 fw k t = W k t Z t θu k du, 0 Z t M e l t = Mt l ξuζ l u l du. 0

65 Martingale Condition The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Assume that the number of primary traded assets is equal to the number of driving orthogonal martingales W 1,..., W d, M 1,..., M m plus one, i.e., n = d + m + 1. In addition, let the price Y 1 be strictly positive. Proposition A probability measure e Q equivalent to Q on (Ω, G T ) is a martingale measure associated with a numeraire Y 1 if and only if the processes θ and ζ satisfy the following equation Y i,1 t µ 1 µ i + for i = 2, 3,..., n. dx mx (σ1 k σi k )(θt k σ1) k + k=1 l=1 ξt(κ l l 1 κ l i) ζl t κ l 1 = κ l 1

66 Pre-default Martingale Condition Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Lemma Martingale condition can be represented as follows where: A tx t = b t x t = (θ, λζ) T is an R d+m -valued process with λζ = (λ 1 ζ 1,..., λ m ζ m ), the R n 1 -valued process b t is explicitly known, the (n 1) (m + d) matrix A t given by 2 σ 1 1 σ σ1 d σ d κ 1 1 κ κ 1 1 A t = σ1 1 σn 1... σ1 d σn d κ 1 1 κ1 n... 1+κ 1 1 κ m 1 κm 2 1+κ m 1 κ m 1 κm n 1+κ m

67 Existence of a Martingale Measure Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names The pre-default intensities λ l t satisfy the equality λ l t = γ l t on the event {τ (1) > t}, that is, prior to occurrence of the first default. Proposition Assume that the pre-default intensities λ l t, l = 1,..., m are strictly positive for every t [0, T ]. Then the martingale measure Q e for the relative prices Y i,1, i = 2, 3,..., m stopped at τ (1) T exists and is unique if and only if A 1 t exists. The Radon-Nikodým derivative of e Q with respect to Q on (Ω, G T ) is given by dq e dy Z. dq = Y m Z E T θu k dwu k. E T ζu l dmu l. k=1 0 l=1 0

68 First-to-Default Claim (FTDC) Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Let us denote τ (1) = τ 1 τ 2... τ m = min (τ 1, τ 2,..., τ m). Definition A first-to-default claim with maturity T is a defaultable claim (X, Z, τ (1) ), where X is a constant amount payable at maturity if no default occurs, and Z = (Z 1, Z 2,..., Z l ) is the vector of G-adapted processes, where Z l τ (1) specifies the recovery received at time τ (1) if the lth name is the first defaulted name, that is, on the event {τ l = τ (1) T }. Assumptions: The processes Z l, l = 1, 2,..., m, are given by some real-valued functions on [0, T ] R n, specifically, Zt l = Z l (t, Yt 1,..., Yt n ). X = g(yt 1,..., YT n ) for some function g : R n R.

69 Valuation of an FTDC The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Assuming that Y is admissible, that is, Y (Yτ 1 (1) ) 1 is Q-integrable, e we can represent the risk-neutral value of Y on the random interval [0, τ (1) ) as follows π t(y ) = Yt 1 E eq`y (Y 1 τ(1) ) 1 G t. In the Markovian set-up, we can deduce the existence of a function C : [0, T ] R n + R representing the pre-default price of the claim. Lemma There exists a function C : [0, T ] R n + R such that we have for every t [0, T ] π t(y ) = C(t, Yt 1,..., Yt n ) on the event {τ (1) > t}.

70 Pricing PDE for an FTDC Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Proposition The function C(t, y 1,..., y n) satisfies the following PDE tc nx i,j=1 k=1 (α 1 + β)c + dx σi k σj k y i y j ij C + mx l=1 nx i=1 α i λ l 1 + ζ l 1 + κ l l C = 0 1 mx l=1 κ l iλ l (1 + ζ l ) y i i C with the terminal condition C(T, y 1,..., y n) = g(y 1,..., y n), where and α i = µ i + dx σi k (θ k σ1), k β = k=1 mx λ l κ l ζl, 1 + κ l 1 l C = Z l (t, y 1 (1 + κ l 1),..., y n(1 + κ l n)) C(t, y 1,..., y n). l=1

71 Replication of an FTDC Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Let C t be a candidate for the pre-default arbitrage price of an FTDC (X, Z, τ (1) ). Our goal is to establish the existence of a self-financing trading strategy φ such that nx C t = V t(φ) = φ i tyt i on the interval [0, τ (1) T ]. Equivalently, e C = C(Y 1 ) 1 satisfies dc e Vt(φ) t = d = Y 1 t i=1 nx i=2 φ i t dy i,1 t. In that case, we say that a trading strategy φ replicates an FTDC We will show that an FTDC can be replicated and thus the pre-default risk-neutral value is also the arbitrage price of an FTDC prior to default.

72 Notation The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Let P 1 t P 1 t stand for the 1 d vector = ˆ P n i=1 σ1 i Y i t i C σ 1 1C t... P n i=1 σd i Y i t i C σ d 1 C t Let P 2 t the 1 m vector for the 1 m vector P 2 t = h 1 C t κ 1 1 C t 1+κ mc t κ m 1 C t 1+κ m 1 i.

73 Lemma The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Lemma The Itô differential of e C t can be represented as follows d e C t = (Y 1 t ) 1 P t d ew t where P t = [P 1 t, P 2 t ] and 2 d ew t = 6 4 dw f t 1. d f W d t d e M 1 t d e M m t

74 Lemma The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Lemma The joint dynamics of relative prices Y i,1 t, i = 2,..., n can be represented as follows dy t = Y t A t d ew t where y t is the (n 1) 1 vector y t = Y 2,1 t... Y n,1 t and the diagonal (n 1) (n 1) matrix Y t equals 2 3 Y 2,1 t... 0 Y t = Y n,1 t 3 7 5

75 Replicating Strategy The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Proposition Consider a first-to-default claim (X, Z, τ (1) ) with the pricing function C. The claim can be replicated by the self-financing trading strategy φ = (φ 1,..., φ n ) where (φ 2 t,..., φ n t ) = (Yt ) 1 1 P ty 1 A 1 and φ 1 t = (Y 1 t ) 1 C t nx i=2 t t φ i tyt i.

76 Example: Four Assets and Two Defaults Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names We consider a market model with four primary assets that are driven by two possible sources of default and a one-dimensional Brownian motion. We thus have under the real-world probability Q, for i = 1,..., 4, dyt i = Yt i µ i (t) dt + σi 1 (t) dwt 1 + 2X κ l i(t) dmt l. Note that condition n = m + d + 1 is satisfied and the matrix A t becomes 2 σ1 1 σ 1 κ 1 1 κ1 2 κ κ 1 1 κ2 2 1+κ A t = 6 σ1 1 σ3 1 κ 1 1 κ1 3 κ κ 1 1 κ κ σ1 1 σ4 1 κ 1 1 κ1 4 κ 2 1 κ2 4 1+κ 1 1 l=1 1+κ 2 1

77 Example (continued) The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names Assuming that the matrix A t is non-singular and λ l t 0 for t [0, T ], we find that the unique martingale measure e Q is given by dq e Z. dq = E T 0 2Y Z θu 1 dwu 1. E T ζu l dmu l l=1 where θ 1, ζ 1 and ζ 2 are given by 2 3 θ 1 4 λ 1 ζ 1 5 = A 1 λ 2 ζ 2 t b t with 2 b t = 6 4 µ 2 µ 1 + σ1(σ σ2) 1 + P 2 l=1 λl (κ l 1 κ l 2) κl 1 1+κ l 1 µ 3 µ 1 + σ1(σ σ3) 1 + P 2 l=1 λl (κ l 1 κ l 3) κl 1 1+κ l 1 µ 4 µ 1 + σ1(σ σ4) 1 + P 2 l=1 λl (κ l 1 κ l 4) κl 1 1+κ l

78 Example (continued) The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names The dynamics of relative prices Y i,1, i = 2, 3, 4, under e Q are given by dy i,1 t = Y i,1 t (σi 1 σ1) 1 dw f t 1 2X l=1 κ l i κ l κ l 1 d e M l t Consider a first-to-default claim (X, Z, τ (1) ) where Z = (Z 1, Z 2 ). Then P t becomes h P4 i P t = i=1 σ1 i Yt i i C σ1c 1 t 1 C t κ 1 1 C t 1+κ C t κ 2 1 C t 1+κ 2 1 where the function C solves the pre-default pricing PDE The replicating strategy for an FTDC (X, Z, τ (1) ) can be found from the equality (φ 2 t, φ 3 t, φ 4 t ) = (Yt ) 1 1 P ty 1 t A 1 t, combined with the formula φ 1 t = (Y 1 t ) 1 C t 4X i=2 φ i tyt i.

79 Final Remarks The Model Case of Two Credit Names Case of m Credit Names In a single-name case: we distinguished between the case of strictly positive assets and the case of zero recovery for defaultable asset, we examined the pre-default and post-default pricing PDEs, explicit representation for replicating strategies were derived. In a multi-name case: we concentrated on the case of a first-to-default claim, the pricing PDE and the formula for replicating strategy were derived, the method can be extended to kth-to-default claims.

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default T. Bielecki, M. Jeanblanc and M. Rutkowski Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, 6 February 2006 1 Based on N. Vaillant (2001) A

More information

Risk Neutral Measures

Risk Neutral Measures CHPTER 4 Risk Neutral Measures Our aim in this section is to show how risk neutral measures can be used to price derivative securities. The key advantage is that under a risk neutral measure the discounted

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations Anne EYRAUD-LOISEL Workshop : Enlargement of Filtrations and Applications to Finance and Insurance May 31st - June 4th, 2010, Jena

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria   web:   July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Girsanov s Theorem Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Girsanov s Theorem Decomposition of P-Martingales as Q-semi-martingales Theorem

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach Ying JIAO Université Paris 7 This presentation is based on joint works with N. El Karoui, M. Jeanblanc and H. Pham Introduction Motivation :

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Joint work with Ernst Eberlein Croatian Quants Day University of Zagreb, 9th

More information

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r. Lecture 7 Overture to continuous models Before rigorously deriving the acclaimed Black-Scholes pricing formula for the value of a European option, we developed a substantial body of material, in continuous

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that. 1. EXERCISES RMSC 45 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk Exercises 1 Exercises 1. (a) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-martingale. Show that E(X n ) = E(X ) n N (b) Let X = {X n } n= be a {F n }-submartingale.

More information

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging Introduction and echniques Lecture 9 in Financial Mathematics UiO-SK451 Autumn 15 eacher:s. Ortiz-Latorre Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging 1 Risk Neutral Pricing Assume that we are in the basic

More information

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium Department of Banking and Finance University of Zurich April 22 2013 Math Finance Colloquium USC Change of the probability measure Change of

More information

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps Jhonny Gonzalez School of Mathematics The University of Manchester Magical books project August 23, 2012 Clip for this slide Pricing

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

Enlargement of filtration

Enlargement of filtration Enlargement of filtration Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 6, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M Enlargement of Filtration Enlargement of Filtration ([1] 5.9) If G is a

More information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics The Third Western Conference in Mathematical Finance November 14, 2009 How should an investor trade

More information

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1) Part I: Discrete-time finance Exercise 1 (20 points) a. Provide the definition of the pricing kernel k q. Relate this pricing kernel to the set of discount factors D

More information

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

25857 Interest Rate Modelling 25857 UTS Business School University of Technology Sydney Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire May 15, 2014 1/36 Chapter 20. Change of Numeraire 1 The Radon-Nikodym Derivative 2 Option Pricing under Stochastic

More information

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model (joint work with J. Dong and L. Korobenko) A. Deniz Sezer University of Calgary April 28, 2016 Merton s model of corporate debt A corporate bond is a contingent

More information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models 1.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 1.2 No-arbitrage theory and

More information

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) 6: Multi-Period Market Models 1 / 55 Outline We will examine

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards Chapter 7 Forwards and Futures Copyright c 2008 2011 Hyeong In Choi, All rights reserved. 7.1 Basics of forwards and futures The financial assets typically stocks we have been dealing with so far are the

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure Mathematical Models in Economics and Finance Topic 3 Fundamental theorem of asset pricing 3.1 Law of one price and Arrow securities 3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure 3.3 Valuation

More information

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory Dr. Roman V Belavkin MSO4112 Contents 1 Geometric Brownian motion 1 2 The Black-Scholes pricing 2 3 The Black-Scholes equation 3 References 5 1 Geometric Brownian motion

More information

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components: 1 Mathematics in a Pill The purpose of this chapter is to give a brief outline of the probability theory underlying the mathematics inside the book, and to introduce necessary notation and conventions

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations Stan Stilger June 6, 1 Fouque and Tullie use importance sampling for variance reduction in stochastic volatility simulations.

More information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8 Magnus Wiktorsson September 27, 2018 Magnus Wiktorsson L8 September 27, 2018 1 / 14 The risk neutral valuation formula Let X be contingent claim with maturity T.

More information

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Option Pricing Models for European Options Chapter 2 Option Pricing Models for European Options 2.1 Continuous-time Model: Black-Scholes Model 2.1.1 Black-Scholes Assumptions We list the assumptions that we make for most of this notes. 1. The underlying

More information

Mean-variance hedging when there are jumps

Mean-variance hedging when there are jumps Mean-variance hedging when there are jumps Andrew E.B. Lim Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research University of California Berkeley, CA 9472 Email: lim@ieor.berkeley.edu March 22,

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007

Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007 Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 References Indifference valuation in binomial models (with

More information

Hedging under arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage Hedging under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics AnStAp10 August 12, 2010 Motivation Usually, there are several trading strategies at one s disposal to obtain a given

More information

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices Dmitry Kramkov (joint work with Peter Bank) Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford 5th Oxford-Princeton Workshop on Financial

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 166 Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information by Hans Föllmer ) Martin Schweizer ) October 199 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft,

More information

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS Wolfgang M. Schmidt HfB - Business School of Finance & Management Center of Practical Quantitative Finance schmidt@hfb.de Frankfurt MathFinance Workshop, April

More information

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information Rüdiger Frey Universität Leipzig Bressanone, July 2007 ruediger.frey@math.uni-leipzig.de www.math.uni-leipzig.de/~frey joint with Abdel Gabih and Thorsten

More information

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Algorithmic Quantitative Finance July 15, 2017 Christopher Ting July 15, 2017 1/33

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance Bernardo D Auria email: bernardo.dauria@uc3m.es web: www.est.uc3m.es/bdauria July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M The Financial Market The Financial Market We assume there are

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES THE SOURCE OF A PRICE IS ALWAYS A TRADING STRATEGY SPECIAL CASES WHERE TRADING STRATEGY IS INDEPENDENT OF PROBABILITY MEASURE COMPLETENESS,

More information

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes Fabio Trojani Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, Switzerland Correspondence address: Fabio Trojani,

More information

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property Dmitry Kramkov joint work with Sergio Pulido (Évry, Paris) Carnegie Mellon University Workshop on Equilibrium Theory, Carnegie Mellon,

More information

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh Option Pricing Mrinal K. Ghosh 1 Introduction We first introduce the basic terminology in option pricing. Option: An option is the right, but not the obligation to buy (or sell) an asset under specified

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory Christa Cuchiero University of Vienna 9 th Bachelier World Congress July 15, 2016 Christa Cuchiero (University of Vienna) Polynomial processes in SPT

More information

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara Joint work with R. Sircar (Princeton) and K. Sølna (UC Irvine) Special Semester on Stochastics with Emphasis

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Finance Stochast. 1, 251 257 1997 c Springer-Verlag 1997 A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting Tina Hviid Rydberg University of Aarhus, Department of Theoretical

More information

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE Proceedings of the 44th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, and the European Control Conference 005 Seville, Spain, December 1-15, 005 WeA11.6 OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF

More information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Columbia November 9, 27 Contents Joint work with Sergey Nadtochyi Motivation 1 Understanding

More information

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE. Risk Neutral Pricing Thursday, May 12, 2011 2:03 PM We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE. This is used to construct a

More information

Stochastic Volatility

Stochastic Volatility Stochastic Volatility A Gentle Introduction Fredrik Armerin Department of Mathematics Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden Contents 1 Introduction 2 1.1 Volatility................................

More information

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS Stat 391/FinMath 346 Lecture 8 STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS X t = CONTINUOUS PROCESS θ t = PORTFOLIO: #X t HELD AT t { St : STOCK PRICE M t : MG W t : BROWNIAN MOTION DISCRETE TIME: = t < t 1

More information

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE DOI: 1.1214/ECP.v7-149 Elect. Comm. in Probab. 7 (22) 79 83 ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE FIMA KLEBANER Department of Mathematics & Statistics,

More information

Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information

Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information Umut Çetin Robert Jarrow Philip Protter Yıldıray Yıldırım June 5, Abstract This paper provides an alternative approach to Duffie and Lando 7] for obtaining

More information

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t Economathematics Problem Sheet 1 Zbigniew Palmowski 1. Calculate Ee X where X is a gaussian random variable with mean µ and volatility σ >.. Verify that where W is a Wiener process. Ws dw s = 1 3 W t 3

More information

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options By Yasin LUT Supevisor:Prof. Tuomo Kauranne December 2010 Introduction Pricing an European call option Conclusion INTRODUCTION A stochastic

More information

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY 4 th World Congress Tokyo, 26 Investments and forward utilities Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Topics Utility-based measurement of performance Utilities

More information

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL FABIO MERCURIO BANCA IMI, MILAN http://www.fabiomercurio.it 1 Stylized facts Traders use the Black-Scholes formula to price plain-vanilla options. An

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree Lecture Notes for Chapter 6 This is the chapter that brings together the mathematical tools (Brownian motion, Itô calculus) and the financial justifications (no-arbitrage pricing) to produce the derivative

More information

Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk Neutral Valuation copyright 2012 Christian Fries 1 / 51 Risk Neutral Valuation Christian Fries Version 2.2 http://www.christian-fries.de/finmath April 19-20, 2012 copyright 2012 Christian Fries 2 / 51 Outline Notation Differential

More information

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Pricing theory of financial derivatives Pricing theory of financial derivatives One-period securities model S denotes the price process {S(t) : t = 0, 1}, where S(t) = (S 1 (t) S 2 (t) S M (t)). Here, M is the number of securities. At t = 1,

More information

ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE

ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE Stéphane CRÉPEY University of Evry, France stephane.crepey@univ-evry.fr AMAMEF at Vienna University of Technology 17 22 September 2007 1 We derive the pricing equation

More information

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Jan Večeř, Columbia University, Department of Statistics, Mingxin Xu, Carnegie Mellon University, Department of Mathematical Sciences, Olympia

More information

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives John Schoenmakers 9th Summer School in Mathematical Finance

More information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES Marek Rutkowski Faculty of Mathematics and Information Science Warsaw University of Technology 00-661 Warszawa, Poland 1 Call and Put Spot Options

More information

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Constructing Markov models for barrier options Constructing Markov models for barrier options Gerard Brunick joint work with Steven Shreve Department of Mathematics University of Texas at Austin Nov. 14 th, 2009 3 rd Western Conference on Mathematical

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes Bluff our Way Through Black-Scholes Saurav Sen December 000 Contents What is Black-Scholes?.............................. 1 The Classical Black-Scholes Model....................... 1 Some Useful Background

More information

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as: Continuous Time Finance Notes, Spring 2004 Section 1. 1/21/04 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences. For use in connection with the NYU course Continuous Time Finance. This

More information

Forward Dynamic Utility

Forward Dynamic Utility Forward Dynamic Utility El Karoui Nicole & M RAD Mohamed UnivParis VI / École Polytechnique,CMAP elkaroui@cmapx.polytechnique.fr with the financial support of the "Fondation du Risque" and the Fédération

More information

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance and Its Applications to Mathematical Finance Department of Mathematical Science, KAIST Workshop for Young Mathematicians in Korea, 2010 Outline Motivation 1 Motivation 2 Preliminary : Stochastic Calculus

More information

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science Multi-Asset Options A Numerical Study Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL Department of Mathematical Sciences Chalmers University of Technology

More information

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models Xiaoguang Wang STAT 598W January 21th, 2014 (STAT 598W) Lecture 3 1 / 51 Outline 1 Some model independent definitions and principals

More information

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

Martingale invariance and utility maximization Martingale invariance and utility maximization Thorsten Rheinlander Jena, June 21 Thorsten Rheinlander () Martingale invariance Jena, June 21 1 / 27 Martingale invariance property Consider two ltrations

More information

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk Portfolio optimization problem with default risk M.Mazidi, A. Delavarkhalafi, A.Mokhtari mazidi.3635@gmail.com delavarkh@yazduni.ac.ir ahmokhtari20@gmail.com Faculty of Mathematics, Yazd University, P.O.

More information

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing? Kyiv, June 19-23, 2006 Tommi Sottinen, University of Helsinki Based on a joint work No-arbitrage pricing beyond semimartingales with C. Bender, Weierstrass

More information

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather Review of some financial models for MAT 483 Parity and Other Option Relationships The basic parity relationship for European options with the same strike price and the same time to expiration is: C( KT

More information

Indifference fee rate 1

Indifference fee rate 1 Indifference fee rate 1 for variable annuities Ricardo ROMO ROMERO Etienne CHEVALIER and Thomas LIM Université d Évry Val d Essonne, Laboratoire de Mathématiques et Modélisation d Evry Second Young researchers

More information

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING FABIO MERCURIO BANCA IMI, MILAN http://www.fabiomercurio.it Daiwa International Workshop on Financial Engineering, Tokyo, 26-27 August 2004 1 Stylized

More information

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels Kiseop Lee Department of Statistics, Purdue University Mathematical Finance Seminar University of Southern California

More information

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models Sebastian Jaimungal sebastian.jaimungal@utoronto.ca Department of Statistics and Mathematical Finance Program, University of Toronto, Toronto, Canada http://www.utstat.utoronto.ca/sjaimung

More information

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T 1 Derivatives Pricing and Financial Modelling Andrew Cairns: room M3.08 E-mail: A.Cairns@ma.hw.ac.uk Tutorial 10 1. (Ho-Lee) Let X(T ) = T 0 W t dt. (a) What is the distribution of X(T )? (b) Find E[exp(

More information

Interest rate models in continuous time

Interest rate models in continuous time slides for the course Interest rate theory, University of Ljubljana, 2012-13/I, part IV József Gáll University of Debrecen Nov. 2012 Jan. 2013, Ljubljana Continuous time markets General assumptions, notations

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

The Valuation of Bermudan Guaranteed Return Contracts

The Valuation of Bermudan Guaranteed Return Contracts The Valuation of Bermudan Guaranteed Return Contracts Steven Simon 1 November 2003 1 K.U.Leuven and Ente Luigi Einaudi Abstract A guaranteed or minimum return can be found in different financial products,

More information

Path Dependent British Options

Path Dependent British Options Path Dependent British Options Kristoffer J Glover (Joint work with G. Peskir and F. Samee) School of Finance and Economics University of Technology, Sydney 18th August 2009 (PDE & Mathematical Finance

More information

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management Omar El Euch and Mathieu Rosenbaum École Polytechnique 4 October 2017 Omar El Euch and Mathieu Rosenbaum

More information