Policy Discussion Paper

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Policy Discussion Paper"

Transcription

1 Policy Discussion Paper No. 97/10 University of Adelaide Adelaide SA 5005 Australia IMPLICATIONS OF REGIONAL AND MULTILATERAL AGREEMENTS FOR INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS Keith E. Maskus October 1997

2 CIES POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER 97/10 IMPLICATIONS OF REGIONAL AND MULTILATERAL AGREEMENTS FOR INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS Keith E. Maskus Department of Economics Campus Box 256 University of Colorado Boulder, CO USA ph: fax: October 1997 Forthcoming in The World Economy 20(5), September ii

3 SUMMARY Over the last decade there has been a marked rise in international interest in the protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs) in different nations and the impacts of IPRs on competition, innovation, and international technology transfer. This paper focuses on one understudied aspect of the issue. Specifically, it compares the effectiveness of regional trade agreements, most specifically the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), and the multilateral approach within the World Trade Organisation (WTO) in fostering stronger and more harmonised levels of intellectual property protection. Preferential trade agreements could generate stronger IPRs within regionally integrated markets than in the global trade regime. Accordingly, the paper also considers some implications of regional harmonisation of IPRs for economic welfare and the trading system. The first task is to compare the WTO and NAFTA agreements on intellectual property in order to illustrate economic issues surrounding the multilateral and regional approaches and the advantages and drawbacks to each. On the multilateral scale, the WTO Agreement on Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) is a watershed in global protection of intellectual property. Before its implementation, each country's IPRs regime was largely a matter of choice. However, the inconsistency between the existence of different national IPRs regimes and the need for international exploitation of the gains from innovation through trade and FDI had become well-recognised by the mid-1980s. The TRIPs accord commits all developing countries in the WTO to undertake a significant extension of IPRs protection, albeit with a long phase-in period for the poorest countries, thereby bringing about a substantive convergence in international minimum standards. Despite some shortcomings in the standards and commitments of the TRIPs agreement, at least from the view of technology and product developers in the United States, it represents a substantial strengthening of global IPRs systems. On its own merits, the TRIPs accord could have negative impacts on many nations, at least in the short run, because of higher prices associated with newly protected products. It is interesting to ask, therefore, why such a comprehensive agreement commanded widespread adherence in the Uruguay Round. The most relevant answer is that the Uruguay Round agreements provided enough collateral benefits to developing countries, particularly in terms of market access for agricultural goods, textiles and apparel, along with greater teeth to dispute settlement, that it was worth accepting the short-term (though uncertain) losses from TRIPs. This ability to trade concessions across disparate interests is a key advantage of the multilateral approach. Further, a multilateral approach based on minimum standards and disciplines is preferable to competition among these countries in terms of IPRs to attract FDI and technology. This last observation provides a further powerful argument on behalf of a multilateral approach. The NAFTA agreement on IPRs is stronger than TRIPs in some important ways, though there remain significant exclusions. The successful installation in Mexico of strong IPRs, along with changes in Canadian compulsory-licensing practices, points to one important advantage of the regional approach over the multilateral approach. In the former, it is easier to achieve broad consensus over harmonised standards because of greater commonality of interests associated with regional market integration. In the latter, (at least perceived) economic interests continue to diverge widely and it would have been extremely difficult to procure an intellectual property agreement as strong as TRIPs without the broad potential for trading off market and policy concessions across numerous economic activities. Another salient distinction between NAFTA and TRIPs is that the former agreement provides less leeway to participants in setting national implementation strategies. For example, Mexico would find it more difficult to adopt strong fair-use exemptions and compulsory-licensing procedures under iii

4 NAFTA than under TRIPs. In this important sense the regional approach generally may be counted on to erect stronger minimum standards for protecting IPRs. The paper also reviews recent empirical evidence on the importance of IPRs for international commerce. For example, studies have demonstrated that international variations in the strength of patent laws do have an impact on trade flows, with stronger patents associated with rising imports. Extending one methodology to the case of U.S. exports to Mexico, if the result of NAFTA is to improve Mexican patent protection to the American level, we might expect an increase in trade of perhaps $3 billion per year (in 1984 dollars). There is also tentative empirical evidence that foreign direct investment is attracted by strong IPRs. Again, one methodology suggests that if the IPRs agreement in NAFTA raises Mexican patent protection to U.S. levels, FDI would rise from the United States to Mexico on the order of $893 million, or approximately 22% of 1989 assets. In normative terms, IPRs are inherently second-best policies within each country and it is difficult to specify workable rules that necessarily satisfy conditions for welfare optimality. Rules of thumb, such as providing copyright protection to software but leaving open the possibility of patent protection under particular circumstances, may in some cases be too weak and in other cases too strong. Extended to the international context, these ambiguities are magnified. In terms of economic theory, it is unclear whether TRIPs and NAFTA will be globally pro-competitive or anti-competitive, while questions of international distributional impacts are important. Finally, the article comments on some important differences in the potential international economic effects of multilateral and regional harmonisation of IPRs. The issues relate to the inherently second-best character of both regional trade preferences and IPRs. For example, the essence of regional trade agreements is to provide preferential treatment in commercial policy. Drawing a page from the economic theory of economic integration, define the concepts of intellectual property creation (IPC) and intellectual property diversion (IPD). The former would exist to the extent that more intellectual property is created and marketed within a regional market, such as NAFTA, strictly due to the expansion of markets and the replacement of inefficient technology developers with more efficient ones. The latter would occur to the extent that less intellectual property owned by non-member firms is exploited within the free trade area. These effects are possible even if the intellectual property standards within a free trade area are non-discriminatory. In a related vein, greater harmonisation of both regional and global IPRs standards does not necessarily represent a movement toward less effective variability in world practices. A final, and related, observation is that the trend toward stronger IPRs, within both the WTO and certain regional agreements, has sometimes come with insufficient regard for changes in important complementary regulatory policies. Chief among these is competition policy. This review suggests that, while there are reasons to anticipate net efficiency gains from the new international IPRs systems, the significant differences remaining between TRIPs standards and those emerging under regional trade agreements pose new questions about the role of deep integration in the international regulation of intellectual property use. iv

5 Implications of Regional and Multilateral Agreements for Intellectual Property Rights Keith Maskus 1. Introduction Over the last decade there has been a marked rise in international interest in the protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs) in different nations and the impacts of IPRs on competition, innovation, and international technology transfer. In this paper I focus on one understudied aspect of the issue. Specifically, I compare the effectiveness of regional trade agreements, most specifically the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), and the multilateral approach within the World Trade Organization (WTO) in fostering stronger and more harmonized levels of intellectual property protection. Preferential trade agreements could generate stronger IPRs within regionally integrated markets than in the global trade regime. Accordingly, I consider some implications of regional harmonization of IPRs for economic welfare and the trading system. In the next section I compare the WTO and NAFTA agreements on intellectual property in order to illustrate economic issues surrounding the multilateral and regional approaches and the advantages and drawbacks to each. In the following section I discuss the general question of global protection for intellectual property and note some recent empirical evidence on the importance of such regulations for international commerce. In the fourth section I comment on some important differences in the potential international economic effects of multilateral and regional harmonization of IPRs. Concluding observations are provided in the final section. 2. Multilateralism and Regionalism in Protecting IPRs The successes that advocates of stronger global IPRs have experienced in recent years are striking. Keep in mind that only twelve years ago the Uruguay Round had not begun, no considerations were under way of folding Mexico into a trade agreement, and pressures on developing countries to change their IPRs practices were only beginning. Yet numerous countries have undertaken significant upgrading of their IPRs systems since For example, the list of nations that adopted stronger patent legislation over that period includes Canada, New 1

6 Zealand, Portugal, Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Thailand, Bangladesh, Benin, Burkina Faso, Chile, Ecuador, Paraguay, Hungary, Mali, Egypt, and China (twice). 1 To some unknown extent, these policy shifts reflect both domestic emerging economic interests in these countries and strong external pressures exerted by the United States and the European Union. From the United States such actions range simply from mentioning the countries in the annual USTR National Trade Estimates Report to designating them as a "priority watch" country or the subject of actual negotiations on IPRs. A number of nations, however, did not change their laws in response to this attention (India, Pakistan, and Philippines are prominent examples). Thus, there has been considerable room for broader multilateral and regional negotiating approaches. For example, it is fair to claim that Canada and Mexico adopted stronger laws under the influence of NAFTA, while Egypt's efforts were evidently taken in the context of ongoing negotiations over a Partnership Agreement with the European Union. On the multilateral scale, the WTO Agreement on Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) is a watershed in global protection of intellectual property. Before its implementation, each country's IPRs regime was largely a matter of choice, subject to the requirements of any international conventions it might have joined. These conventions required only national treatment and allowed no substantive means for dispute settlement. In brief, the prior global IPRs system was based on mutual recognition in protecting intellectual property and a strong commitment to sovereignty. This system was perceived by American and European innovative interests, which produce a majority of intellectual property worldwide, to be seriously inadequate. The inconsistency between the existence of different national IPRs regimes and the need for international exploitation of the gains from innovation through trade and FDI had become wellrecognized by the mid-1980s. Strong lobbying efforts by firms in pharmaceuticals, software, entertainment, and other sectors placed IPRs at the forefront of both trade policy and trade negotiations. 1 Information taken from World Intellectual Property Organization, Industrial Property, various issues. 2

7 2a. The Multilateral Approach: TRIPs The TRIPs accord commits all developing countries in the WTO to undertake a highly significant extension of IPRs protection, albeit with a long phase-in period for the poorest countries, thereby bringing about a substantive harmonization in international standards. This accomplishment represents a signal victory for intellectual-property interests in the technologyexporting nations and a substantial "concession" (in GATT terms) by the poor countries. It also should have the effect of easing the path toward greater harmonization among the developed economies, within which a number of international controversies over IPRs continue. Table 1 presents in summary form the major substantive requirements embodied in the TRIPs agreement. These issues require significant change in policies in most countries. The most important changes in global norms include copyright protection for computer software and databases, stronger protection for well-known trademarks, the extension of patents to pharmaceutical products and biotechnological inventions, restrictions on the use of compulsory licensing, requirements for trade-secrets protection, and the need for effective border and judiciary enforcement measures. The poorest nations receive a form of "special and differential treatment" through long transition periods. Particularly controversial in the latter context for pharmaceutical firms is the absence of pipeline protection. On the other hand, the administrative costs of implementing and enforcing this agreement are likely to be large for many nations, calling for technical and financial assistance (UNCTAD, 1996). Despite some shortcomings in the standards and commitments of the TRIPs agreement, at least from the view of technology and product developers in the United States, it represents a substantial strengthening of global IPRs systems. On its own merits, the TRIPs accord could have negative impacts on many nations, at least in the short run, because of higher prices associated with newly protected products. It is interesting to ask, therefore, why such a comprehensive agreement commanded widespread adherence in the Uruguay Round. The most relevant answer is that the Uruguay Round agreements provided enough collateral benefits to developing countries, particularly in terms of market access for agricultural goods, textiles and apparel, along with greater teeth to dispute settlement, that it was worth accepting the short-term (though uncertain) losses from TRIPs. This ability to trade concessions across disparate economic categories is the key advantage of multilateral negotiations. 3

8 Table 1. Substantive Requirements of the TRIPs Agreement in the WTO General Obligations Comments 1. National Treatment Applied for persons 2. Most-Favored-Nation Reciprocity exemptions for copyright; prior regionals/bilaterals allowed 3. Transparency Copyright and Related Rights 4. Observes Berne Convention Does not require moral rights 5. Minimum 50-year term Clarifies corporate copyrights 6. Programs protected as literary works A significant change in global norms 7. Data compilations protected similarly 8. Neighboring rights protection for phonogram producers, performers 9. Rental Rights A significant change in global norms Trademarks and Related Marks 10. Confirms and clarifies Paris Convention 11. Strengthens protection of Deters use of confusing marks and speculative well-known marks registration 12. Clarifies non-use Deters use of collateral restrictions to invalidate marks 13. Prohibits compulsory licensing 14. Industrial Designs Minimum term of protection of 10 years Patents 15. Subject matter coverage Patents provided for products and processes in all fields of technology 16. Biotechnology Must be covered but exceptions allowed for plants and animals of traditional methods 17. Plant breeders' rights Effective sui generis system required 18. Exclusive right of importation 4

9 19. Severe restrictions on compulsory Domestic production can no longer be required; non-exclusive licenses with licensing adequate compensation 20. Minimum 20 years patent length from filing date 21. Reversal of burden of proof in process patents Integrated Circuits Designs 22. Protection extended to articles incorporating infringed design 23. Minimum 10 years protection Undisclosed Information 24. Trade secrets protected against unfair methods of disclosure Abuse of IPRs 25. Wide latitude for competition policy to Cannot contradict remainder of WTO control competitive abuses agreement Enforcement Measures 26. Requires civil, criminal measures and Will be costly for developing countries border enforcement Transitional Arrangements 27. Transition periods 5 years for developing and transition economies; 11 for poorest countries 28. Pipeline protection for pharmaceuticals Not required but a provision for maintaining novelty and exclusive marketing rights Institutional Arrangements 29. TRIPs Council Agreement to be monitored and updated 30. Dispute settlement Standard approach with 5-year moratorium in some cases 5

10 While it is accurate to characterize TRIPs as a marked strengthening in international protection for IPRs, analysts often neglect the fact that the agreement itself is somewhat flexible in allowing nations to adopt varying implementation strategies. Countries are given considerable discretion in choosing regulations that maintain a pro-competitive balance in the exploitation of IPRs, so long as they do not unduly frustrate the intentions of TRIPs. For example, little is said in the agreement about fair-use exceptions in copyright for educational and research purposes, meaning that wide exceptions of this kind may be allowed. Further, nothing in the agreement prevents judicious use of compulsory licensing of patents in cases where abusive practices by the patent-holder may be demonstrated under local law, so long as adequate compensation is paid. The agreement also calls for each country to employ competition policies as it sees fit in disciplining abusive exploitation of IPRs, requiring only that such use be based on national treatment. Indeed, given the limited development of competition policies in many developing countries, the implementation period for TRIPs provides a propitious time for them to consider their options in this regard. This flexibility in the final TRIPs document, while frustrating to some economic interests in the developed economies, is also partially responsible for its widespread ratification. 2 Moreover, some developing countries may have feared that a refusal to accede to TRIPs could have subjected them to bilateral disciplines imposed by the United States and other nations. This outcome might have been worse in terms of the development of their IPRs regimes and the evolution of their trade flows. This negative view is misleading, however. Many nations take the view that the adoption and enforcement of TRIPs could have a powerful signaling effect to foreign firms, helping to attract technology and investment. This view is gaining greater currency in the world. Moreover, the higher-income developing countries continue to recognize that a viable IPRs system may well be in their long-run interests in its own right. Accordingly, a multilateral approach based on minimum standards and disciplines is preferable to a competition among these countries in terms of IPRs (or other business regulations) to attract FDI and technology. This last observation provides a further powerful argument on behalf of a multilateral approach, at least as far as the global economy is concerned. 2 See UNCTAD (1996) and Reichman (1993) for detailed expositions of competitive implementation strategies for developing economies. 6

11 Many developing countries have chosen to accelerate their adherence to TRIPs. Most, however, are only now beginning to come to terms with what implementation implies in terms of legislation and administrative costs. It is fair to say that efforts are underway to determine the least-cost means of adopting the various TRIPs disciplines. There is some potential for delays and emerging legislation that will be dissatisfactory for intellectual property developers, while enforcement is sure to remain a problem for some time. 2b. The Regional Approach: NAFTA It was considerably less difficult to reach agreement on IPRs in NAFTA. To a certain extent, this outcome is surprising since NAFTA similarly represented a movement toward significant market integration between a low-wage developing economy and a pair of highincome developed economies. However, NAFTA requires relatively little of the United States in terms of trade-policy changes, while there are substantive potential gains for American firms in the intellectual-property arena. For its part, the government of Mexico views NAFTA as a means of locking in numerous shifts in its commercial policy toward a more outward-looking strategy. A key component of this trend in Mexico lies in cementing the important changes in intellectual property law that took place in 1991, when comprehensive patent and copyright laws were adopted. NAFTA does have the effect of expanding IPRs in Mexico to new areas. Canada, on the other hand, successfully retained rights to protect its cultural industries through variations in its copyright laws. Canada is currently undertaking a major examination of its copyright laws with respect to information industries, including the advisability of maintaining its cultural exemptions to the same degree (Information Highway Advisory Council, 1995). Table 2 presents an overview of the main components of Chapter 17 of NAFTA, the intellectual property rights agreement. As noted, the national treatment principle suffers some injury due to Canada's insistence on exemptions for cultural industries, while Mexico provides limited protection for broadcasts of performances by virtue of invoking reciprocity in treatment. The requirements in copyright go beyond those in TRIPs by clarifying that decoding devices for intercepting satellite transmissions are declared illegal. This last issue remains controversial on a global scale, even among developed nations, and is an issue for future international negotiations. American firms were disappointed that effective opportunities for firms to oppose trademark registration were not required of Mexico. 7

12 Table 2. Substantive Agreements on IPRs in NAFTA General Obligations Comments 1. National Treatment Explicit reciprocity exemption for secondary use (broadcasts) of sound recordings Exemptions for Canadian cultural industries Copyright and Related Rights 2. Observes Berne Convention Does not require moral rights 3. Minimum 50-year term Clarifies corporate copyrights 4. Programs protected as literary works New for Mexico 5. Data compilations protected similarly New for Mexico 6. Sound recordings protected Mexico can withhold copyright for recordings produced before NAFTA in effect 7. Encrypted satellite signals Illegal to produce or use decoding devices without authorization Trademarks and Related Marks 8. Observes Paris Convention 9. Prohibits compulsory licensing and force trademark linkage 10. Trademark registration opposition Not required in Mexico 11. Industrial designs Slightly different standards for protection maintained Patents 12. Subject matter coverage Patents provided for products and processes in all fields of technology 13. Biotechnology Some exclusions from patentability allowed for biotechnological processes and plants and animals of traditional methods 14. Plant breeders' rights Effective sui generis system required; Mexico given two years to adopt UPOV 15. Severe restrictions on compulsory Domestic production can no longer be required; non-exclusive licenses with licensing adequate compensation to serve local market 16. Pipeline protection for pharmaceuticals 17. Minimum 20 years patent length from filing date 18. Reversal of burden of proof in process patents 8

13 Integrated Circuits Designs 19. Based on strongest provisions of 1989 Treaty 20. Protection extended to articles incorporating infringed design 21. Minimum 10 years protection Allows lapsed protection after 15 years 22. Prohibits compulsory licensing 23. Transition period Mexico has four years to comply Undisclosed Information 24. Full trade secrets protection "Gross negligence" standard 25. Confidential test data protected Exclusive use of submitter for marketing purposes for five years Abuse of IPRs 26. Wide latitude for competition policy to Cannot contradict remainder of NAFTA control competitive abuses Enforcement Measures 27. Closely mirrors U.S. system Enforcement problems continue in Mexico Transitional Arrangements 28. Transition period Mexico given three years to comply with enforcement requirements 29. Motion pictures U.S. will protect foreign-made motion pictures it has declared in the public domain 9

14 At Mexico's insistence, NAFTA allows broader exclusions from patentability for biotechnological processes than does TRIPs. On the other hand, during the negotiations for NAFTA, Canada removed its compulsory licensing scheme in pharmaceuticals, a victory for pharmaceutical firms operating there. Further, NAFTA requires pipeline protection for pharmaceuticals, rather than the limited marketing rights provided during the transition periods for TRIPs. Finally, NAFTA provides somewhat stronger protection than TRIPs in standards covering semiconductors, trade secrets, and enforcement requirements. Perhaps most significant, the transition periods are much shorter in NAFTA and, in fact, Mexico may choose not avail itself of the full periods in coming into compliance. Overall, it is fair to claim that NAFTA provides stronger standards for IPRs than does the WTO agreement, though it should be kept in mind that both agreements are comprehensive in setting effective minimum standards. Thus, the NAFTA agreement on IPRs seems stronger than TRIPs in some important ways, though there remain significant exclusions. Presumably, in cases in which NAFTA standards are found to be less rigorous, they would be the prevailing obligation. In any case, the successful installation in Mexico of strong IPRs, along with changes in Canadian compulsorylicensing practices, points to one important advantage of the regional approach over the multilateral approach. In the former, it is easier to achieve broad consensus over harmonized standards because of greater commonality of interests associated with regional market integration. In the latter, (at least perceived) economic interests continue to diverge widely and it would have been extremely difficult to procure an intellectual property agreement as strong as TRIPs without the broad potential for trading off market and policy concessions across numerous economic activities. A final salient distinction between NAFTA and TRIPs is that the former agreement provides less leeway to participants in setting national implementation strategies. For example, Mexico would find it more difficult to adopt strong fair-use exemptions and compulsorylicensing procedures under NAFTA than under TRIPs. In this important sense the regional approach generally may be counted on to erect stronger minimum standards for protecting IPRs. One manifestation of this theme is that the European Union currently seeks to negotiate preferential trading arrangements with many countries in North Africa and the Middle East, with an important component of such agreements being a requirement to accelerate adherence to the conditions of TRIPs. 10

15 It is worth noting briefly that the adoption of strong minimum IPRs standards in NAFTA is analogous to the harmonization efforts within the European Union (Maskus, 1993). Consistent protection of intellectual property throughout the EU lies at the core of ongoing regulatory standardization. Thus, for example, the accession of Spain in 1986 required a rapid convergence of its IPRs regimes with Community standards, including adoption of the European Patent Convention within five years (Baker, 1997). The EU maintains an emphasis on such convergence in negotiating accession with new members. 3. The International Economics of IPRs Both the TRIPs agreement and the IPRs chapter in NAFTA represent a significant alteration in international policy norms. There are important implications for both positive questions concerning the abilities of firms to exploit intellectual property and for normative issues of international welfare. Concerning commercial behavior, global strengthening of IPRs improves the choice set considerably for firms selecting strategies for earning rents from their innovations. That choice set includes: selection of which countries in which to procure a patent or copyright; terms under which to sell licenses to subsidiaries and unrelated foreign firms; location of FDI for purposes of taking advantage of factor costs in producing a new product for local sales, satisfaction of regional markets, and re-exports back to the home country; opportunities for research joint ventures, patent-pooling or cross-licensing agreements with competing foreign firms; and greater latitude in pricing to market as a result of the implicit increase in market segmentation associated with IPRs. International trade in high-technology goods is significant and growing rapidly (Maskus, 1993). The interesting question is whether stronger and more harmonized international IPRs will have an important impact on these trade flows. They could do so through a number of mechanisms. For instance, the strength of IPRs in different markets could affect both price and volume decisions of firms deciding on export markets (Maskus and Penubarti, 1995). In theory, a firm choosing its export strategy to particular markets would charge a higher price in those countries with strengthening IPRs, though the export quantity could be higher (if there is less local infringing activity) or lower (if the law raises market power for the foreign firm). Recent empirical work has demonstrated that international variations in the strength of patent laws do have an impact on trade flows (Maskus and Penubarti, 1995; Primo Braga, 1995, Maskus and Eby Konan, 1994). For example, Maskus and Penubarti (1995) estimated bilateral 11

16 trade equations for 28 3-digit ISIC sectors in 1984, using 22 OECD countries as exporting nations and the same countries plus 49 others, primarily developing economies, as importing nations. In these econometric equations, bilateral imports in each sector were regressed across countries on several variables from a general-equilibrium model of trade, including trade restrictions and economic distortions. They included an index of patent strength in each importing country, corrected for measurement error and endogeneity. This patent index was also interacted with dummy variables for country size in developing markets. The evidence from these regressions is clear that stronger patent laws attract greater amounts of bilateral imports (in comparison with levels expected in equilibrium without patent distortions) into larger (and generally richer) developing countries. The implied elasticities of imports with respect to patent strength are positive, though small. Overall, the results suggest that as global patent strength increases due, say, to the implementation of the TRIPs agreement in the WTO, global trade in patent-sensitive goods could expand by perhaps $15 billion to $25 billion per year. This is a relatively small sum but still a dividend that has not been recognized. Extending the same methodology to U.S. exports to Mexico, if the result of NAFTA is to improve Mexican patent protection to the American level, we might expect an increase in trade of perhaps $3 billion per year (in 1984 dollars), simply on this score. 3 Note that these findings relate to patents; comparable work has yet to be done on the trade impacts of trademarks and copyrights. The activities of multinational enterprises (MNEs) also depend on global IPRs. Firms realize the economic value from intellectual creations in several ways, including FDI in subsidiaries in which production of goods using intellectual property occurs. Parent firms earn license fees and investment income from these affiliates. Further, intellectual property assets may be sold or rented through licensing agreements with unaffiliated firms. It is difficult to establish strong theoretical and empirical linkages between intellectual property rights and FDI and technology trade. Given the economic complexities in these forms of competition, no general claims may be made about the effects of IPRs on such transactions. On one hand, a nation with stronger IPRs could induce more incoming FDI because recognizing the intellectual property of a foreign firm increases the value of that firm's unique asset. In turn, the firm would be more willing to undertake operations abroad. On the other hand, it has been argued that MNEs may undertake greater FDI in countries with limited IPRs in order to 12

17 maintain proprietary information within organizational control. In fact, this factor seems relevant in explaining the importance of foreign investment in the pharmaceuticals industry. Theoretical predictions about impacts on technology transfer are ambiguous as well, in that they depend on cost characteristics of firms, market structure, and other factors. There is some tentative empirical evidence on the relationship between IPRs and FDI. Mansfield (1994) reports survey evidence claiming that IPRs are important for location decisions in FDI, though the importance varies by type of investment. He also asked U.S. firms for their perceptions about the weakness of IPRs in various partner countries, with these perceptions being based on whether IPRs impeded or enhanced decisions to undertake licensing and joint ventures. He then estimated a relationship between U.S. direct investment flows to different countries and their GDP and perceived IPRs protection. He found that the weakness of IPRs was significantly and negatively related to investment decisions across countries, suggesting that countries that strengthen their patent regimes could well attract additional FDI inflows. The situation in Mexico seemed to be of particular interest to firms in this regard. It is possible to improve on Mansfield's model specification by recognizing the joint decisions made by firms to exploit their IPRs and adding further determinants of FDI. In performing this task, I find that a typical result is the following regression equation for the stock of U.S. assets across countries, taken from a four-equation systems approach: Assets = *GDP *DIST *PATD. This equation was estimated across 46 foreign countries in a pooled sample from , using total assets of affiliates as the dependent variable. GDP is the host nation's gross domestic product per capita, DIST is distance of the country's capital city from Washington, DC, and PATD is the previously discussed index of patent strength in developing countries. 4 All variables are significantly different from zero. Thus, it appears that, for two otherwise identical host countries, the country with a one-unit higher level of the patent index attracts additional FDI of around $1.931 billion. To put this in perspective, imagine that the IPRs agreement in NAFTA raises Mexican patent protection to U.S. levels. This equation would predict a rise in FDI from the United States to Mexico on the order of $893 million, or approximately 22% of 1989 assets. Again, this figure does not account for other NAFTA impacts on FDI. If this finding holds up to other specifications it points directly to the importance of IPRs in providing 3 This calculation does not account for other trade-expanding effects of NAFTA, which could increase the figure through certain interaction effects between trade liberalization and IPRs harmonization. 13

18 incentives for inward FDI. Presumably the additional FDI embodies greater levels of technology transfer as well, though the extent of this effect remains an open empirical question. It is important also to consider some dynamic implications of the agreements. There are essentially two dynamic processes that matter here: the pace of innovation and the rate at which new innovation is diffused, or transferred, into the general economy. To assess the system, then, requires investigating the linkages between strength of intellectual property rights, innovation, and imitation. Recent theoretical treatments of the impacts of IPRs on technology diffusion in endogenous growth models are discouraging. In these models, technology is transferred through imitation by firms in developing countries. When IPRs are strengthened in those countries, imitation becomes harder. The rate of imitation slows down and, in turn, the global rate of innovation diminishes. The reason is that if innovative firms expect less rapid loss of their technological advantages they can enjoy higher rents per innovation, thereby reducing the need to engage in R&D (Helpman, 1993; Glass and Saggi, 1995). A more optimistic view comes from studies of international patenting behavior (Eaton and Kortum, 1995). The value of patent rights varies across countries and technology fields, but nonetheless is typically significant in key technologies and products. Additional patent protection in important developing countries, such as Mexico, could enhance this value, inducing further R&D. Moreover, there appear to be considerable spillovers of technological information through patenting and trade in patented products. Eaton and Kortum (1995, p. 1) state that, "...except for the United States, OECD countries derive almost all of their productivity growth from abroad." Indeed, the importance of technology transfer through trade in technologically advanced inputs (machinery, chemicals, software, producer services, and so on), should be emphasized. Evidence is emerging that this channel is responsible for significant amounts of productivity spillovers across borders and a key part of the technology convergence that has happened among the developed economies in recent decades (Coe and Helpman, 1993). In conjunction with the earlier evidence that countries with stronger patent regimes tend to attract more trade in inputs, this finding suggests that developing nations do have a dynamic interest in linking their IPRs regimes with those of the OECD countries. 4 Other variables included tariff rates, R&D expenditures, and incentives and disincentives for FDI, in a fourequation system with assets, exports, sales, and number of patent applications as the dependent variables. 14

19 Turn next to normative issues regarding global IPRs. In economic terms, the contrast between agreements to liberalize barriers to merchandise trade and harmonization of IPRs standards is striking. With regard to trade in goods, strong theoretical arguments and empirical evidence point to the multilateral elimination of trade barriers as a welfare-enhancing policy for all countries concerned. Though distributional problems emerge in each country, the aggregate competitive gains from static and dynamic efficiency tend to outweigh the costs of trade liberalization, save perhaps for some terms-of-trade effects in large countries, which should be largely self-canceling in the multilateral context. In short, global free trade serves as a benchmark of optimality against which to assess the net costs of departures. This point may also be argued on behalf of the elimination of investment barriers, allowing investment to flow to its globally most efficient uses. In contrast, IPRs are inherently second-best policies within each country and it is difficult to specify workable rules that necessarily satisfy conditions for welfare optimality. Rules of thumb, such as providing copyright protection to software but leaving open the possibility of patent protection under particular circumstances, may in some cases be too weak and in other cases too strong. Extended to the international context, these ambiguities are magnified. Each country is liable to have different economic interests in IPRs, which interests could well vary over time. Consider the notion of "global optimality" in IPRs. There is a fundamental tradeoff between static efficiency (each potential user should have the product or technology available at marginal cost) and dynamic efficiency (incentives must be sufficient to induce R&D in socially desirable innovations). Presumably the TRIPs agreement will tilt the balance toward greater innovation and greater exclusion, which is sensible if the world had been under-investing in R&D in the status quo ante. A number of dynamic efficiency gains could ensue from this change, including R&D becoming more closely targeted on projects with the highest expected global demand and financing advantages stemming from global price discrimination. But there might emerge dynamic efficiency losses as well, including excessive and duplicative investments in R&D. To this mix must be added the additional complexity that the location in which IPRs are owned (typically developed nations) may well differ from the location in which they now receive stronger protection (typically developing nations). Thus, a significant issue emerges with respect to international rent transfers. In short, it is unclear whether TRIPs will be globally pro-competitive or globally anti-competitive, while questions of international distributional impacts are important. 15

20 4. Economic Differences between Regional and Multilateral Approaches The experiences of NAFTA and the European Union suggest that IPRs protection is becoming stronger and more harmonized within regional economic groupings than on a global scale. This is consistent with the trend toward deeper integration of regional regulatory regimes. It raises interesting questions about the efficiency implications of strong regional harmonization. Some of these questions, which have been little studied, are stated here in order to stimulate further discussion and analysis, rather than to provide definitive answers. The issues relate to the inherently second-best character of both regional trade preferences and IPRs. For example, the essence of regional trade agreements is to provide preferential treatment in commercial policy. Drawing a page from the economic theory of economic integration, define the concepts of intellectual property creation (IPC) and intellectual property diversion (IPD). The former would exist to the extent that more intellectual property is created and marketed within a regional market, such as NAFTA, strictly due to the expansion of markets and the replacement of inefficient technology developers with more efficient ones. Fully integrating North American markets for technology and product development with harmonized IPRs should have strong rationalization impacts on R&D programs in all three countries. For example, in some industries, such as chemicals, food products, and advanced textiles, plant-level scale economies are high relative to firm-level scale economies. In conjunction with high transport costs to Mexico, this situation would tend to transfer R&D programs southward within North American multinational enterprises. At the same time, in sectors with high firm-level economies associated with knowledge capital, such as transport equipment, machinery, and telecommunications, the effect should be to concentrate R&D efforts in the United States. Such rationalization effects should provide long-term dynamic efficiency gains for all three nations, perhaps at the expense of some transition costs. Perhaps more interesting is the concept of IPD, which occurs to the extent that less intellectual property owned by non-member firms is exploited within the free trade area. Channels through which this could happen include reduced demand for those firms products due to trade preferences, reductions in FDI within the area due to investment diversion, and (market-based) exclusion of foreign firms from regional technology-development programs through joint ventures. Notice that these effects are possible even if the intellectual property standards within a free trade area are non-discriminatory. 16

21 In a related vein, greater harmonization of both regional and global IPRs standards does not necessarily represent a movement toward less effective variability in world practices. It is likely that many developing countries will choose to implement TRIPs at minimal allowable levels, leaving a large economic mass at that stage. Meanwhile, more and larger blocs sustaining regionally distinctive IPRs would impart a discrete character to the international distribution of standards. Thus, while TRIPs is likely to induce more incentives for innovation programs directed to global demands, they could be offset by more-skewed incentives aimed at regional blocs. 5. Concluding Remarks This review suggests that, while there are reasons to anticipate net gains in dynamic global efficiency from the new international IPRs systems, concerns remain about the implications of these systems for the distribution of gains between developed and developing economies. Moreover, significant differences exist between effective standards that will be attained as TRIPs is implemented and standards that are emerging under regional trade agreements. These differences pose new questions about the role of deep integration in the international regulation of intellectual property use. A final, and related, observation is that the trend toward stronger IPRs, within both the WTO and certain regional agreements, has sometimes come with insufficient regard for changes in important complementary regulatory policies. Chief among these is competition policy, which should be intimately related to both intellectual property protection and trade liberalization (UNCTAD, 1996). For example, Spanish accession to the European Union in 1986 resulted in rapid and sharp increases in patent applications and trademark registrations in Spain (Baker, 1997). One reason for this appears to be that firms realized that Spanish membership would expand the region within which parallel imports would be allowed, inducing broader registration of intellectual property. Competition rules for regulating IPRs use across countries remain highly variable, with little effort yet in evidence in most developing countries to develop a coherent and appropriate system to deal with problems that could emerge in the new regime. In this regard, it is noteworthy that NAFTA says nothing about harmonizing competition rules beyond a vague requirement that their use should not counteract the operation of the trade agreement. Neither does the European Union require changes in competition policy in developing countries with which it negotiates Partnership Agreements, though within the Community there is substantial 17

22 harmonization. This means that stronger IPRs could interact with inadequate competition rules to render particular markets less competitive. For example, it is common in the Middle East for governments to allow local distribution of imported branded products and technologies to be monopolized by sole importing agents. As patents and trademarks achieve stronger protection, the implicit monopoly privileges are enhanced for such firms. Thus, a system is emerging in which regional protection for intellectual property could be stronger than global norms while complementary business regulations could be inadequate for either set of policies. It is likely that such a system would result in significant structural inefficiencies in many countries, even as it might raise the global return to innovation. In at least this sense, both regional and global initiatives in IPRs are incomplete in design and execution. 18

23 REFERENCES Baker, Mark E. (1997), Innovation and the European Union: A Case Study of the Economic Effects of Spanish Accession, unpublished MA thesis, University of Colorado. Coe, David and Elhanan Helpman (1993), "International R&D Spillovers," (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research) Working Paper No Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel Kortum (1995), "Trade In Ideas: Patenting and Productivity in the OECD," (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research) Working Paper no Glass, Amy J. and Kamal Saggi (1995), "Intellectual Property Rights, Foreign Direct Investment, and Innovation," (Columbus, OH: Ohio State University), manuscript. Helpman, Elhanan (1993), "Innovation, Imitation, and Intellectual Property Rights," Econometrica 61, Information Highway Advisory Council (1995), The Challenge of the Information Highway (Ottawa: Ministry of Supply and Services). Mansfield, Edwin (1994), "Intellectual Property Protection, Foreign Direct Investment, and Technology Transfer," (The World Bank and International Finance Corporation), Discussion Paper no. 19. Maskus, Keith E. (1993), "Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights," The European Economy, no. 52, Maskus, Keith E. (1996), "Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Information Economy," in T. Courchene (ed.), Policy Frameworks for a Knowledge Economy, (Kingston, ON: John Deutsch Institute), Maskus, Keith E. and Denise Eby Konan (1994), "Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights: Issues and Exploratory Results," in A.V. Deardorff and R.M. Stern, eds., Analytical and Negotiating Issues in the Global Trading System, (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press), Maskus, Keith E. and Mohan Penubarti (1995), "How Trade-Related Are Intellectual Property Rights?" Journal of International Economics 39, Reichman, J. H. (1993), "The TRIPs Component of the GATT's Uruguay Round: Competitive Prospects for Intellectual Property Owners in an Integrated World Market," Fordham Intellectual Property, Media, and Entertainment Law Journal, 4, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (1996), The TRIPs Agreement and Developing Countries, (New York: United Nations). 19

THE TRIPS AGREEMENT AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES. Jayashree Watal

THE TRIPS AGREEMENT AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES. Jayashree Watal UNCTAD Expert meeting on the impact of FDI on development: Globalization of R&D by TNCs and implications for developing countries THE TRIPS AGREEMENT AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Jayashree Watal Wednesday,

More information

Comments in Response to Executive Order Regarding Trade Agreements Violations and Abuses Docket No. USTR

Comments in Response to Executive Order Regarding Trade Agreements Violations and Abuses Docket No. USTR Comments in Response to Executive Order Regarding Trade Agreements Violations and Abuses Docket No. USTR 2017 0010 Submitted by Business Roundtable July 31, 2017 Business Roundtable is an association of

More information

II Copyright and related rights 36. contents

II Copyright and related rights 36. contents CONTENTS List of figures xvi List of boxes xvii List of tables xviii Preface xix Acknowledgements xxii List of acronyms and abbreviations xxiii I Introduction to the TRIPS Agreement 1 A Introduction 1

More information

Econ 340. The Issues. The Washington Consensus. Outline: International Policies for Economic Development: Trade

Econ 340. The Issues. The Washington Consensus. Outline: International Policies for Economic Development: Trade Econ 340 Lecture 19 International Policies for 2 3 The Issues The Two Main Issues: Should developing countries be open to international trade? Should developing countries be open to international capital

More information

Impact of Intellectual Property Rights Reforms on the Diffusion of Knowledge through FDI

Impact of Intellectual Property Rights Reforms on the Diffusion of Knowledge through FDI Impact of Intellectual Property Rights Reforms on the Diffusion of Knowledge through FDI Ioana Popovici Florida International University May 2006 This paper examines the impact of intellectual property

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WT/GC/W/633 21 April 2011 (11-2080) General Council Trade Negotiations Committee ISSUES RELATED TO THE EXTENSION OF THE PROTECTION OF GEOGRAPHICAL INDICATIONS PROVIDED FOR IN ARTICLE

More information

Uruguay Round. The GATT. A Negotiating History ( ) KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL TERENCE P. STEWART, EDITOR VOLUME IV: THE END GAME (PART I)

Uruguay Round. The GATT. A Negotiating History ( ) KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL TERENCE P. STEWART, EDITOR VOLUME IV: THE END GAME (PART I) The GATT Uruguay Round A Negotiating History (1986-1994) TERENCE P. STEWART, EDITOR VOLUME IV: THE END GAME (PART I) KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL The Hague London Boston TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction xxi

More information

International Journal of Scientific & Engineering Research, Volume 4, Issue 6, June ISSN

International Journal of Scientific & Engineering Research, Volume 4, Issue 6, June ISSN International Journal of Scientific & Engineering Research, Volume 4, Issue 6, June-2013 1932 PROSPECTS AND VIEWS ON TO STRENGTHENING INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS (IPRS) IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES, WITH SPECIAL

More information

Intellectual Property-Related Preferential Trade Agreements and the Composition of Trade

Intellectual Property-Related Preferential Trade Agreements and the Composition of Trade Intellectual Property-Related Preferential Trade Agreements and the Composition of Trade Keith E. Maskus and William Ridley Presentation at IPSDM November 14, 2017 Introduction International economists

More information

GATT Council's Evaluation

GATT Council's Evaluation CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, RUE DE LAUSANNE 154, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL. 022 739 5111 GATT/1611 27 January 1994 TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF TURKEY ' 20-21 JANUARY 1994 GATT Council's Evaluation The GATT Council conducted

More information

Pre-Hearing Statement of Linda M. Dempsey, Vice President, International Economic Affairs, National Association of Manufacturers

Pre-Hearing Statement of Linda M. Dempsey, Vice President, International Economic Affairs, National Association of Manufacturers Pre-Hearing Statement of Linda M. Dempsey, Vice President, International Economic Affairs, National Association of Manufacturers Before the U.S. International Trade Commission Hearing on Investigation

More information

European Parliament resolution of 6 April 2011 on the future European international investment policy (2010/2203(INI))

European Parliament resolution of 6 April 2011 on the future European international investment policy (2010/2203(INI)) P7_TA(2011)0141 European international investment policy European Parliament resolution of 6 April 2011 on the future European international investment policy (2010/2203(INI)) The European Parliament,

More information

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES CHAPTER 9 Chapter 9: Trade-related Investment Measures TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF THE RULES After the late 1980s, a significant increase in foreign direct investment,

More information

Impacts on Global Trade and Income of Current Trade Disputes

Impacts on Global Trade and Income of Current Trade Disputes Public Disclosure Authorized July 2018 Number 2 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Impacts on Global Trade and Income of Current Trade Disputes Caroline

More information

CETA s Legal and Political Implications for the TTIP. David A. Gantz Samuel M. Fegtly Professor

CETA s Legal and Political Implications for the TTIP. David A. Gantz Samuel M. Fegtly Professor CETA s Legal and Political Implications for the TTIP David A. Gantz Samuel M. Fegtly Professor Introduction Completion of CETA Negotiations (except for investment chapter?) raises significant challenges

More information

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights Kiyoshi Matsubara May 2009 Abstract This paper extends Symeonidis (2003) s duopoly model with product differentiation to discusses how FDI spillovers that

More information

IMITATION, PATENT PROTECTION AND ENTRY MODE

IMITATION, PATENT PROTECTION AND ENTRY MODE IMITATION, PATENT PROTECTION AND ENTRY MODE «Intellectual Property Rights for Business and Society London Conference» 14 15 September 2006 M. Pluvia Zuniga Elif Bascavusoglu 1 otivation : Firms choose

More information

Thailand and TPP 30 November 2012 Apiradi Tantraporn, Executive Chairperson The International Institute for Asia Pacific Studies (INSAPS), Bangkok

Thailand and TPP 30 November 2012 Apiradi Tantraporn, Executive Chairperson The International Institute for Asia Pacific Studies (INSAPS), Bangkok Thailand and TPP 30 November 2012 Apiradi Tantraporn, Executive Chairperson The International Institute for Asia Pacific Studies (INSAPS), Bangkok University 1. Thailand and TPP TPP Countries and Thailand

More information

ANNEX ONE SINGAPORE 1. INTRODUCTION

ANNEX ONE SINGAPORE 1. INTRODUCTION ANNEX ONE SINGAPORE 1. INTRODUCTION As described in section 2 of the position paper, following the pause in negotiations of the regional ASEAN-EU FTA in March 2009, the Council in December 2009 gave the

More information

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific Enhancing the contribution of PTAs to inclusive and equitable trade: Bangladesh

More information

Investment and Sustainable Development: Developing Country Choices for a Better Future

Investment and Sustainable Development: Developing Country Choices for a Better Future The Fifth Annual Forum of Developing Country Investment Negotiators 17-19 October, Kampala, Uganda Investment and Sustainable Development: Developing Country Choices for a Better Future BACKGROUND DOCUMENT

More information

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC.

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC. NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC. 1625 K STREET, NW, WASHINGTON, DC 20006-1604 TEL: (202) 887-0278 FAX: (202) 452-8160 March 2001 Proposal for the Elimination of Industrial Tariffs Executive Summary

More information

Chapter 5. Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Import Quota Liberalization: The Case of Textile Industry. ISHIDO Hikari. Introduction

Chapter 5. Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Import Quota Liberalization: The Case of Textile Industry. ISHIDO Hikari. Introduction Chapter 5 Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Import Quota Liberalization: The Case of Textile Industry ISHIDO Hikari Introduction World trade in the textile industry is in the process of liberalization. Developing

More information

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Foreign direct investments are investments in which a firm acquires a controlling interest in a foreign firm. called portfolio investments

More information

THESIS SUMMARY FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND THEIR IMPACT ON EMERGING ECONOMIES

THESIS SUMMARY FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND THEIR IMPACT ON EMERGING ECONOMIES THESIS SUMMARY FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND THEIR IMPACT ON EMERGING ECONOMIES In the doctoral thesis entitled "Foreign direct investments and their impact on emerging economies" we analysed the developments

More information

A Proactive Investment Agenda for 2018

A Proactive Investment Agenda for 2018 A Proactive Investment Agenda for 2018 March 2018 The world is facing unprecedented challenges. To address these challenges, we need investment, and to make the necessary investments, we need business.

More information

JONES DAY COMMENTARIES

JONES DAY COMMENTARIES January 2002 JONES DAY COMMENTARIES China s Accession to the WTO On November 11, 2001, the fourth WTO Ministerial Conference at Doha, Qatar, approved the terms of China s accession to the WTO (World Trade

More information

The Estey Centre Journal of. International Law. and Trade Policy. Technical Annex

The Estey Centre Journal of. International Law. and Trade Policy. Technical Annex Volume 6 Number 2, 2005/p. 201-209 esteyjournal.com The Estey Centre Journal of International Law and Trade Policy Technical Annex Accession to the World Trade Organisation: Challenges and Prospects for

More information

Summary Report. Question Q 156. International Exhaustion of Industrial Property Rights

Summary Report. Question Q 156. International Exhaustion of Industrial Property Rights Summary Report Question Q 156 International Exhaustion of Industrial Property Rights I Introduction The question considers the issues surrounding international exhaustion of industrial property rights

More information

Analysis of Regional Investment Frameworks Worldwide

Analysis of Regional Investment Frameworks Worldwide Analysis of Regional Investment Frameworks Worldwide Sophie WERNERT Policy analyst Meeting of Working Group 1 MENA-OECD Investment Programme 15-16 February 2010, Amman, Jordan OECD Private Sector Development

More information

PANAMA. Foreign Trade Barriers 297

PANAMA. Foreign Trade Barriers 297 PANAMA In 1996, the U.S. trade surplus with Panama was $1.0 billion, a decrease of $52 million from the U.S. trade surplus of $1.1 billion in 1995. U.S. merchandise exports to Panama were $1.4 billion,

More information

1. OVERVIEW OF RULES. (1) Rules of Origin

1. OVERVIEW OF RULES. (1) Rules of Origin CHAPTER 9 RULES OF ORIGIN 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES (1) Rules of Origin Rules of origin are used to determine the nationality of goods traded in international commerce, however, there are no internationally

More information

ENHANCING TRADE AND INVESTMENT, SUPPORTING JOBS, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT: OUTLINES OF THE TRANS-PACIFIC PARTNERSHIP AGREEMENT

ENHANCING TRADE AND INVESTMENT, SUPPORTING JOBS, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT: OUTLINES OF THE TRANS-PACIFIC PARTNERSHIP AGREEMENT OFFICE OF THE UNITED STATES TRADE REPRESENTATIVE EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT WASHINGTON, D.C. ENHANCING TRADE AND INVESTMENT, SUPPORTING JOBS, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT: OUTLINES OF THE TRANS-PACIFIC

More information

REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS AND THE MULTILATERAL TRADING SYSTEM PREPARED BY THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION DISCUSSION PAPER FOR THE G20

REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS AND THE MULTILATERAL TRADING SYSTEM PREPARED BY THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION DISCUSSION PAPER FOR THE G20 REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS AND THE MULTILATERAL TRADING SYSTEM PREPARED BY THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION DISCUSSION PAPER FOR THE G20 This version: 21 September 2015 PREPARED IN CONSULTATION WITH THE WORLD

More information

by Svetla Trifonova Marinova and Martin Alexandrov Marinov Aldershot, Ashgate Pp. 352

by Svetla Trifonova Marinova and Martin Alexandrov Marinov Aldershot, Ashgate Pp. 352 Book Review For oreign Direct Investment in Central and Eastern Europe by Svetla Trifonova Marinova and Martin Alexandrov Marinov Aldershot, Ashgate 2003. Pp. 352 reviewed by Dimitrios Kyrkilis* Since

More information

CROATIA S EU CONVERGENCE REPORT: REACHING AND SUSTAINING HIGHER RATES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH, Document of the World Bank, June 2009, pp.

CROATIA S EU CONVERGENCE REPORT: REACHING AND SUSTAINING HIGHER RATES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH, Document of the World Bank, June 2009, pp. CROATIA S EU CONVERGENCE REPORT: REACHING AND SUSTAINING HIGHER RATES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH, Document of the World Bank, June 2009, pp. 208 Review * The causes behind achieving different economic growth rates

More information

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF MALAYSIA JULY GATT Council's Evaluation

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF MALAYSIA JULY GATT Council's Evaluation CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, RUE DE LAUSANNE 154, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL. 022 7395111 I 20 July 1993 TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF MALAYSIA 19-20 JULY 1993 GATT Council's Evaluation The GATT Council conducted its first

More information

PREFERENTIAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS

PREFERENTIAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS PREFERENTIAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS The Treaty of Rome, reached in 1957, set in motion a process of integrating the economies of Western Europe. This process has culminated with the European Union which

More information

A MULTILATERAL AGREEMENT ON INVESTMENT

A MULTILATERAL AGREEMENT ON INVESTMENT GENERAL DISTRIBUTION OCDE/GD(95)65 A MULTILATERAL AGREEMENT ON INVESTMENT REPORT BY THE COMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT AND MULTINATIONAL ENTERPRISES (CIME) AND THE COMMITTEE ON CAPITAL MOVEMENTS

More information

NEW ZEALAND HONG KONG CEP DISCUSSION PAPER SUBMISSION BY BUSINESS NEW ZEALAND MAY 2001

NEW ZEALAND HONG KONG CEP DISCUSSION PAPER SUBMISSION BY BUSINESS NEW ZEALAND MAY 2001 1. Introduction NEW ZEALAND HONG KONG CEP DISCUSSION PAPER SUBMISSION BY BUSINESS NEW ZEALAND MAY 2001 1.1 With 76,000 members, Business New Zealand is the leading national organisation representing the

More information

Japan-ASEAN Comprehensive Economic Partnership

Japan-ASEAN Comprehensive Economic Partnership Japan- Comprehensive Economic Partnership By Dr. Kitti Limskul 1. Introduction The economic cooperation between countries and Japan has been concentrated on trade, investment and official development assistance

More information

Under Secretary Robert D. Hormats World Investment Forum, Doha, Qatar, April 20 23, 2012

Under Secretary Robert D. Hormats World Investment Forum, Doha, Qatar, April 20 23, 2012 Under Secretary Robert D. Hormats World Investment Forum, Doha, Qatar, April 20 23, 2012 The Continuing Importance of Investment in the Global Economy At the previous World Investment Forum in Xiamen in

More information

Trends in Indian Tax Policy: Practitioner's perspective

Trends in Indian Tax Policy: Practitioner's perspective Trends in Indian Tax Policy: Practitioner's perspective Mumbai, 6 December 2013 Presentation by: Mr. Ajay Vohra India: A land of opportunities Demography & Economy: some statistics Population: 1.3 Billion

More information

ICC recommendations for completing the Doha Round. Prepared by the Commission on Trade and Investment Policy

ICC recommendations for completing the Doha Round. Prepared by the Commission on Trade and Investment Policy International Chamber of Commerce The world business organization Policy Statement ICC recommendations for completing the Doha Round Prepared by the Commission on Trade and Investment Policy 2006: the

More information

PRESS COMMUNIQUE RELEASE DE PRESSE

PRESS COMMUNIQUE RELEASE DE PRESSE PRESS COMMUNIQUE RELEASE DE PRESSE GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE ACCORD GÉNÉRAL SUR LES TARIFS DOUANIERS ET LE COMMERCE CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, 154, RUE DE LAUSANNE, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL. 022 31

More information

PART I CHAPTER 1 MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

PART I CHAPTER 1 MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE PART I CHAPTER 1 MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES (1) The Background of Rules: Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment (MFN) Most-Favoured-Nation treatment or MFN, which requires Members

More information

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE Chapter 2 NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES National treatment (GATT Article III) stands alongside MFN treatment as one of the central principles of the WTO Agreement. Under the national

More information

Competition Policy Review Panel Research Paper Summary. Author: Walid Hejazi, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto

Competition Policy Review Panel Research Paper Summary. Author: Walid Hejazi, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto Competition Policy Review Panel Research Paper Summary Author: Walid Hejazi, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto Title: Inward Foreign Direct Investment and the Canadian Economy Subjects

More information

Regionalism in Services

Regionalism in Services Regionalism in Services Pierre Sauvé Examples of RTAs in services Early agreements: EU NAFTA Newer agreements: MERCOSUR ANDEAN Pact ASEAN US bilateral FTAs (Chile, Jordan, Singapore, Vietnam) More agreements

More information

The European Union Trade Policy

The European Union Trade Policy The European Union Trade Policy Content 1. The EU in world trade 2. EU trade policy Basic features 3. EU trade policy How it works 4. EU trade policy Competing in the world 5. A renewed strategy for Europe

More information

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES Chapter 8 TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES After the late 1980s, a significant increase in foreign direct investment, especially in developing countries, took place throughout the

More information

Economic Impact of Canada s Participation in the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership

Economic Impact of Canada s Participation in the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership Economic Impact of Canada s Participation in the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership Office of the Chief Economist, Global Affairs Canada February 16, 2018 1. Introduction

More information

THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION JOANN M. WEINER * & HUGH J. AULT **

THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION JOANN M. WEINER * & HUGH J. AULT ** THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION THE OECD S REPORT ON HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION JOANN M. WEINER * & HUGH J. AULT ** Abstract - In response to pressures created by the increasing globalization

More information

OCR Economics A-level

OCR Economics A-level OCR Economics A-level Macroeconomics Topic 4: The Global Context 4.5 Trade policies and negotiations Notes Different methods of protectionism Protectionism is the act of guarding a country s industries

More information

Presentation by Economy Under Review - Chile

Presentation by Economy Under Review - Chile 2008/SOM3/013anx3 Agenda Item: IV Presentation by Economy Under Review - Chile Purpose: Consideration Submitted by: APEC Secretariat Third Senior Officials Meeting Lima, Peru 22-23 August 2008 CHILE IAP

More information

Raising the bar: Home country efforts to regulate foreign investment for sustainable development. November 12-13, 2014 Columbia University PROGRAM

Raising the bar: Home country efforts to regulate foreign investment for sustainable development. November 12-13, 2014 Columbia University PROGRAM Raising the bar: Home country efforts to regulate foreign investment for sustainable development November 12-13, 2014 Columbia University PROGRAM With support from: What role should home countries play

More information

Frequently Asked Questions Transparency International 2008 Bribe Payers Index

Frequently Asked Questions Transparency International 2008 Bribe Payers Index Frequently Asked Questions Transparency International 1. What is the Transparency International (BPI)? 2. Which countries are included in the 2008 BPI? 3. How is the 2008 BPI calculated? 4. Whose views

More information

DOMINICAN REPUBLIC TRADE SUMMARY

DOMINICAN REPUBLIC TRADE SUMMARY DOMINICAN REPUBLIC TRADE SUMMARY The U.S. goods trade surplus with the Dominican Republic was $1.9 billion in 2007, an increase of $1.1 billion from $818 million in 2006. U.S. goods exports in 2007 were

More information

ANNEX XIII REFERRED TO IN PARAGRAPH 1 OF ARTICLE 7.1 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

ANNEX XIII REFERRED TO IN PARAGRAPH 1 OF ARTICLE 7.1 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS ANNEX XIII REFERRED TO IN PARAGRAPH 1 OF ARTICLE 7.1 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS ANNEX XIII REFERRED TO IN PARAGRAPH 1 OF ARTICLE 7.1 Article 1 International Conventions 1. The Parties reaffirm their

More information

World Trade Organization: Its Genesis and Functioning. Shashank Priya Professor Centre for WTO Studies Indian Institute of Foreign Trade

World Trade Organization: Its Genesis and Functioning. Shashank Priya Professor Centre for WTO Studies Indian Institute of Foreign Trade World Trade Organization: Its Genesis and Functioning Shashank Priya Professor Centre for WTO Studies Indian Institute of Foreign Trade Genesis of the Multilateral Trading System In 1944, Bretton Woods

More information

Recent Activities of the OECD Working Group on International Investment Statistics (WGIIS)

Recent Activities of the OECD Working Group on International Investment Statistics (WGIIS) Twenty-Seventh Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Washington, D.C. October 27 29, 2014 BOPCOM 14/24 Recent Activities of the OECD Working Group on International Investment Statistics

More information

Can Regionalism Work? Caroline Freund

Can Regionalism Work? Caroline Freund Can Regionalism Work? Caroline Freund Number of PTAs Evolution of PTAs Why Do Countries Impose Trade Barriers? Economists agree free trade is best. Why have trade barriers? To raise revenue. To protect

More information

ANNEX. to the. Recommendation for a Council Decision. authorising the opening of negotiations for a Free Trade Agreement with New Zealand

ANNEX. to the. Recommendation for a Council Decision. authorising the opening of negotiations for a Free Trade Agreement with New Zealand EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 13.9.2017 COM(2017) 469 final ANNEX 1 ANNEX to the Recommendation for a Council Decision authorising the opening of negotiations for a Free Trade Agreement with New Zealand

More information

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development Plenty of good land, and liberty to manage their own affairs their own way, seem to be the two great causes of prosperity of all new colonies. Adam

More information

TRANSFER PRICING AND INTANGIBLES: SCOPE OF THE OECD PROJECT

TRANSFER PRICING AND INTANGIBLES: SCOPE OF THE OECD PROJECT ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT TRANSFER PRICING AND INTANGIBLES: SCOPE OF THE OECD PROJECT DOCUMENT APPROVED BY THE COMMITTEE ON FISCAL AFFAIRS ON 25 JANUARY 2011 CENTRE FOR TAX

More information

KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C Comments on the Discussion Draft on Cost Contribution Arrangements

KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C Comments on the Discussion Draft on Cost Contribution Arrangements KPMG LLP 2001 M Street, NW Washington, D.C. 20036-3310 Telephone 202 533 3800 Fax 202 533 8500 To Andrew Hickman Head of Transfer Pricing Unit Centre for Tax Policy and Administration OECD From KPMG cc

More information

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific Enhancing the contribution of PTAs to inclusive and equitable trade: Viet Nam 15-17

More information

157. Preferential trade agreements Item 157 Grade 3

157. Preferential trade agreements Item 157 Grade 3 International economics 3.4 Economic Integration 157. Preferential trade agreements Item 157 Grade 3 Ib question Distinguish between bilateral and multilateral (WTO) trade agreements. Economic integration!

More information

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE Chapter 2 National Treatment Principle Chapter 2 NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE OVERVIEW OF RULES National treatment (GATT Article III) stands alongside MFN treatment as one of the central principles of

More information

Regionalism in Services. Aaditya Mattoo and Pierre Sauvé

Regionalism in Services. Aaditya Mattoo and Pierre Sauvé Regionalism in Services Aaditya Mattoo and Pierre Sauvé Examples of RTAs in services Early agreements: EU NAFTA Newer agreements: MERCOSUR ANDEAN Pact ASEAN US bilateral FTAs (Chile, Jordan, Singapore,

More information

20 years of TRIPS Disputes

20 years of TRIPS Disputes Fordham 23 nd Annual Intellectual Property Law & Policy Conference Plenary Session 4C-B: Multilateral Developments 20 years of TRIPS Disputes 8 April 2015 Wolf MEIER-EWERT World Trade Organization wolf.meier-ewert@wto.org

More information

1.5 The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)

1.5 The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) 1.5 The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) LEARNING OBJECTIVES 1. Learn the basic principles underpinning the GATT. 2. Identify the special provisions and allowable exceptions to the basic principles

More information

MULTILATERAL TRADE MTN.GNG/NG11/W/39 NEGOTIATIONS THE URUGUAY ROUND. Original: English

MULTILATERAL TRADE MTN.GNG/NG11/W/39 NEGOTIATIONS THE URUGUAY ROUND. Original: English MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS THE URUGUAY ROUND Group of Negotiations on Goods (GATT) Negotiating Group on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, including Trade in Counterfeit Goods

More information

Economic Nationalism: Reality or Rhetoric? Ian Sheldon AED Economics Ohio State University. AAII Columbus Chapter November 8, 2017

Economic Nationalism: Reality or Rhetoric? Ian Sheldon AED Economics Ohio State University. AAII Columbus Chapter November 8, 2017 Economic Nationalism: Reality or Rhetoric? Ian Sheldon AED Economics Ohio State University AAII Columbus Chapter November 8, 2017 Prospects for Global Trade 2012-15, slowdown in trade growth in both absolute

More information

Mega-Regional Trading Arrangements: TPP and TTIP - how China and other emerging economy react to the new rules governing the trade and investment?

Mega-Regional Trading Arrangements: TPP and TTIP - how China and other emerging economy react to the new rules governing the trade and investment? Mega-Regional Trading Arrangements: TPP and TTIP - how China and other emerging economy react to the new rules governing the trade and investment? Jiang, Qing-Yun Shanghai University of International Business

More information

Models for Services Negotiation in RTA/FTA: Options for Developing Countries

Models for Services Negotiation in RTA/FTA: Options for Developing Countries 2006/SOM1/CTI/FTA-RTA/009 Models for Services Negotiation in RTA/FTA: Options for Developing Countries Submitted by: USA APEC Workshop on Best Practices in Trade Policy for RTAs/FTAs: Practical Lessons

More information

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC.

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC. NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC. 1625 K STREET, NW, WASHINGTON, DC 20006-1604 TEL: (202) 887-0278 FAX: (202) 452-8160 September 7, 2012 Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development Centre

More information

Free Trade Agreements and the Multilateral Trade System. FTA and WTO/Harmonization /Developing Countries/Environment Mitsuo Matsushita

Free Trade Agreements and the Multilateral Trade System. FTA and WTO/Harmonization /Developing Countries/Environment Mitsuo Matsushita Free Trade Agreements and the Multilateral Trade System FTA and WTO/Harmonization /Developing Countries/Environment Mitsuo Matsushita 1 1. Proliferation of FTA In 1990, 27 FTA, in 2007, 205 FTA were registered

More information

In this chapter, you will explore business-government trade relations. You will also: Examine the political, economic, and cultural reasons why

In this chapter, you will explore business-government trade relations. You will also: Examine the political, economic, and cultural reasons why In this chapter, you will explore business-government trade relations. You will also: Examine the political, economic, and cultural reasons why governments intervene in trade. Learn about the instruments

More information

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ISSUES FOR THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN: DISPUTES AND COMMON INTERESTS

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ISSUES FOR THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN: DISPUTES AND COMMON INTERESTS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ISSUES FOR THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN: DISPUTES AND COMMON INTERESTS Keith E. Maskus Department of Economics 256 UCB University of Colorado Boulder, CO 80309-0256 maskus@colorado.edu

More information

Bilateral Agreements in EU trade policy

Bilateral Agreements in EU trade policy SPEECH/06/574 Peter Mandelson EU Trade Commissioner Bilateral Agreements in EU trade policy London School of Economics London, 9 October 2006 at 20h00 CET In this speech at the London School of Economics

More information

Trade and Development. Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Trade and Development. Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Trade and Development Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1 International Trade: Some Key Issues Many developing countries rely heavily on exports of primary products for income

More information

Trade and Development and NAMA

Trade and Development and NAMA United Nations Conference of Trade and Development Trade and Development and NAMA International Trade and the Doha Round New York, December 2007 Santiago Fernández de Córdoba Economist UNCTAD Content Part

More information

Guide to Establishing a Subsidiary in China

Guide to Establishing a Subsidiary in China Guide to Establishing a Subsidiary in China by jie chen As China s strength in the global economy continues to grow, businesses need to consider the prospect of establishing operations within its borders.

More information

GROWTH DETERMINANTS IN LOW-INCOME AND EMERGING ASIA: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

GROWTH DETERMINANTS IN LOW-INCOME AND EMERGING ASIA: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS GROWTH DETERMINANTS IN LOW-INCOME AND EMERGING ASIA: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS Ari Aisen* This paper investigates the determinants of economic growth in low-income countries in Asia. Estimates from standard

More information

The Report. The Joint Study Group. on the Possible Trilateral Investment Arrangements. among China, Japan, and Korea

The Report. The Joint Study Group. on the Possible Trilateral Investment Arrangements. among China, Japan, and Korea The Report of The Joint Study Group on the Possible Trilateral Investment Arrangements among China, Japan, and Korea Summary In October 2003 in Bali, Indonesia, the leaders of the People s Republic of

More information

An essential condition of the accession

An essential condition of the accession The New OECD Members The New OECD Members Robert Ley and Pierre Poret The Czech Republic became a member of the OECD in December 1995, Hungary in May 1996, Poland in November 1996 and Korea in December

More information

Investment Climate Study of ASEAN Member Countries

Investment Climate Study of ASEAN Member Countries Chapter 3 Investment Climate Study of ASEAN Member Countries Shujiro Urata Waseda University and Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA) Mitsuyo Ando Keio University, Japan. March 2011

More information

A new design for the corporate income tax?

A new design for the corporate income tax? A new design for the corporate income tax? Michael Devereux Paris, October 17, 2013 Three issues 1. Why tax corporate profit, and what economic problems arise in attempting to do so? 2. Defining the domestic

More information

EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITEE

EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITEE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITEE Hearing in the framework of the EESC opinion on Investment Protection and ISDS in EU Trade and Investment Agreements Brussels, 3 February 2015 Investment Treaty Making:

More information

TPP11 Agreement in Principle: Japan s Role in Mega-regional Trade Agreements

TPP11 Agreement in Principle: Japan s Role in Mega-regional Trade Agreements TPP11 Agreement in Principle: Japan s Role in Mega-regional Trade Agreements December 15, 2017 Shujiro URATA Waseda University Contents Mega-regional FTA Negotiations Japan s objectives behind mega-regional

More information

BUSINESSEUROPE POSITION ON THE EU-KOREA FREE-TRADE AGREEMENT (FTA)

BUSINESSEUROPE POSITION ON THE EU-KOREA FREE-TRADE AGREEMENT (FTA) POSITION PAPER 18 July 2007 BUSINESSEUROPE POSITION ON THE EU-KOREA FREE-TRADE AGREEMENT (FTA) SUMMARY BUSINESSEUROPE calls for: An ambitious EU-Korea FTA covering goods, investments, services and trade

More information

China s Bogor Goals Progress Report (as at 13 August 2012) Highlights of Achievements and Areas for Improvement

China s Bogor Goals Progress Report (as at 13 August 2012) Highlights of Achievements and Areas for Improvement Progress Report - China 1 China s Bogor Goals Progress Report (as at 13 August 2012) Highlights of Achievements and Areas for Improvement - Tariffs in five items were reduced or eliminated unilaterally

More information

Korea's IAP Peer Review Presentation

Korea's IAP Peer Review Presentation 2007/SOM3/024anx3 Agenda Item: III 's IAP Peer Review Presentation Purpose: Consideration Submitted by: APEC Secretariat Third Senior Officials Meeting Cairns, Australia 3 July 2007 Republic of APEC IAP

More information

THE ASEAN BUSINESS OUTLOOK SURVEY 2011

THE ASEAN BUSINESS OUTLOOK SURVEY 2011 THE ASEAN BUSINESS OUTLOOK SURVEY 2011 THAILAND REPORT Compiled by: The American Chamber of Commerce (AmCham) in Singapore 1 Scotts Road #23-03/04/05 Shaw Centre Singapore 228208 Copyright Standards This

More information

Ben S Bernanke: Modern risk management and banking supervision

Ben S Bernanke: Modern risk management and banking supervision Ben S Bernanke: Modern risk management and banking supervision Remarks by Mr Ben S Bernanke, Chairman of the Board of Governors of the US Federal Reserve System, at the Stonier Graduate School of Banking,

More information

How far away is China from TPP?

How far away is China from TPP? How far away is China from TPP? Prof. Dr. Zhang Jianping Abstract China s attitude towards TPP has undergone a fundamental change since 2013, but no matter the seven misunderstanding of TPP before 2013

More information

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES CHAPTER 9 TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF THE RULES After the late 1980s, a significant increase in foreign direct investment, especially in developing countries,

More information

DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL, FISCAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS OECD INVESTMENT POLICY REVIEWS: ISRAEL. Overview. September 2002

DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL, FISCAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS OECD INVESTMENT POLICY REVIEWS: ISRAEL. Overview. September 2002 DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL, FISCAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS OECD INVESTMENT POLICY REVIEWS: ISRAEL Overview September 2002 This report forms part of an OECD publication entitled OECD Investment Policy Reviews:

More information

TRADE PREFERENCE INDEX

TRADE PREFERENCE INDEX TRADE PREFERENCE INDEX Maria Cipollina (Università del Molise) David Laborde (International Food Policy Research Institute) Luca Salvatici (Università del Molise) Agricultural, Food and Bio-energy Trade

More information