The Spanish Personal Income Tax: Facts and Parametric Estimates

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Spanish Personal Income Tax: Facts and Parametric Estimates"

Transcription

1 The Spanish Personal Tax: Facts and Parametric Estimates Esteban García-Miralles Banco de España Nezih Guner CEMFI Roberto Ramos Banco de España October 2017 [PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE] Abstract The purpose of this paper is twofold. First, we characterize the distribution of income and taxes pertaining to the personal income tax in Spain. Specifically, we use administrative data on tax returns to describe the distribution of pre- and after-tax income, as well as income sources, tax rates, tax liabilities and tax benefits, for both individuals and households. And second, we estimate a variety of tax functions that capture the underlying heterogeneity of the data in a parsimonious way. We do so for the years 2002 to 2013, as well as for microsimulated data for Moreover, we distinguish between individuals and households by sociodemographic groups, as well as between income types. These parametric functions can be readily used in applied work in macroeconomics and public finance. JEL codes: E62, H24, H31 Keywords: Personal Tax, Tax Functions, Distribution We thank seminar participants at Banco de España for comments and discussions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily coincide with the views of the Banco de España or the Eurosystem. Corresponding author: 1

2 1 Introduction This paper presents two contributions. First, we characterize the distribution of income and taxes of the personal income tax in Spain, covering both pre- and after-tax income, as well as income sources, tax rates, tax liabilities, and tax benefits, for both individuals and households corresponding to And second, we provide estimates of effective tax functions for the years 2002 to 2013, as well as for microsimulated data of We estimate these functions for both individuals and households, as well as for different income types and tax credits. These functions capture the underlying heterogeneity of the data in a parsimonious way and constitute a readily available input to be used for applied work, such as in the flourishing dynamic macro models with heterogenous agents, see Heathcote et al. (2009). Our paper follows the work by Guner et al. (2014), who estimate tax functions of the US personal income tax. Our data come from an administrative dataset containing a stratified random sample of tax returns, which includes almost the complete set of fiscal and sociodemographic information taxpayers fill therein. The dataset is representative of the population of Spanish taxpayers and is not censored, making it ideal for our purposes. The data cover 15 regions and the 2 autonomous cities, for 2013 containing 2.16 million observations, which amounts to 11% of the population. For the household estimates we use the panel version of the dataset that allows us to link individual tax-fillers from the same household. This sample contains more than 500,000 observations, around 3.3% of the population. We find a large degree of heterogeneity in income and in taxes effectively paid. For 2013, the top quintile earns 46% of gross income and accounts for 70.9% of tax liabilities. Effective average tax rates are close to zero in the two lowest quintiles, while they are 20.2% on average in the top quintile, and 33.1% in the top 1%. Most deductions are regressive, with the tax credit for employed mothers, regional tax credits and the labor income tax credit accruing relatively more to taxpayers in the middle of the income distribution. Labor income is by far the largest source of income, but capital and self-employment income are relatively important for the lowest quintile. Also, capital income is relatively more concentrated in the well-off and the top 1%. Our estimates of the household income distribution are similar when compared to the Survey of Household Finances (EFF). For the estimation of the functional forms, we follow two different approaches. First, we estimate one single expression for the final tax liabilities as a function of gross income. We estimate four different specifications: a log function, used by Guner et al (2012a, 2012b), the HSV specification, used by Benabou (2002) and Heathcote et al. (2011), the Power specification, used by Guvenen et al. (2014) and the GS specification, used by Gouveia and Strauss (1994). In all these four specifications we account for the fact that low incomes are subject to zero effective tax rates. Therefore, we estimate an income threshold under which tax liabilities are zero. This threshold is chosen so as to minimize the mean squared error. Our results show that the HSV and 2

3 the GS functions provide the best fit of the data, both in terms of the amount and the distribution of tax liabilities. In the second approach we estimate three different functions, one for the general tax rates that apply to the general taxable income, one for the savings tax rates, applied to the savings taxable income and one for the tax credits. For the general tax rates we use the HSV and the GS functions; for the savings tax rate we use a piece-wise function that increases linearly up to a certain threshold and takes a constant value after it. For the tax credits we estimate a Ricker model. We also estimate parametric functions for households, distinguishing between single and married. Our functions cover the period 2002 to Moreover, in order to account for the 2015 tax reform, we construct microsimulated data for this year and estimate the set of tax functions. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the Spanish Personal Tax. Section 3 describes the dataset and lays out the definitions and sample restrictions. Section 4 presents the basic facts of the income and tax distributions. Section 5 presents the parametric estimates of the tax functions. Section 6 concludes. 2 The Spanish Personal Tax 2.1 Structure of the Tax The Spanish Personal Tax (PIT) or Impuesto sobre la Renta de las Personas Físicas (IRPF), taxes the Spanish residents income. In 2015, it amounted to 7.4% of GDP, being the largest source of revenue after social security contributions. 1 The tax is withheld at source. Every year, between April and June, taxpayers must fill in the tax return corresponding to the previous calendar year s income. As of 2016, this obligation applied, in general, to taxpayers whose labor income was above e22,000, or capital income was above e1,600, or real-estate income was above e1,000, or they were self-employed. Note however that most taxpayers below the labor income threshold decide to fill in the tax return (around 81%), as they are likely to obtain a refund from the taxes withheld at source. The structure of the tax is fairly complicated, see a simplified diagram in Figure I. subject to the tax can be of several types: labor income, capital income (both financial and realestate) and self-employment income. From these gross income source, a set of deductible expenses can be subtracted, including among other social security contributions paid by the employee, an amount for labor income earners, and expenses associated to the activity of the self-employed. The result of this subtraction gives rise to a concept that we name adjusted gross income. Adjusted gross income is then grouped into two categories, which are subsequently taxed at different rates. On the one hand, general income comprises labor income, self-employment 1 According to the OECD, taxes on income, profits and capital gains of individuals represent around 21% of total tax revenues in Spain (including social contributions). Compared to the Euro Area, the size of this source of revenue is around 2.6 percentage points below the average. 3

4 income and some capital income (each item being the result of gross income minus deductible expenses). On the other hand, saving income includes the largest portion of capital income. From each type of income a wide set of tax deductions can be applied. For example, general income can be reduced by a tax deduction for couples filling in a single tax return (joint filers) as well as by the amounts contributed to private pension plans (up to a limit), among many other. If the taxpayer is entitled to apply deductions exceeding the general income, he/she can apply the remnant to the saving income. The subtraction of these deductions from general and saving income results in concepts named general taxable income and saving taxable income. Each category of income is taxed according to different tax scales. Moreover, the tax scales are split into a state and a region portion. This is so because around half of the tax is transferred to the regions, which are entitled to design their tax scales and introduce their own tax benefits. In 2013 the state general tax scale consisted in 7 tax bands and a top marginal rate of 30.5%. The region general tax scale, which is applied on top of the state one, can vary substantially across regions. For example, that of the Community of Madrid comprised four tax bands and a top marginal rate of 21.4%, whereas that of Catalonia encompassed 6 tax bands and a top marginal tax rate of 25.5%. Therefore, Madrid taxpayers faced in 2013 a top marginal rate of 51.9% (30.5% %), while taxpayers in Catalonia were subject to a top marginal tax rate of 56% (30.5% %). The saving tax scale is much less progressive. In 2013 the state portion consisted in 3 bands and a top marginal rate of 16.5%, whereas the region portion comprised 2 bands and a top rate of 10.5%. In this case, the region layer does not vary across regions. In 2015, a significant reform of the tax was implemented, which led to a substantial decrease in marginal rates. See Figure II for a description of the tax scales in the two selected regions in 2013 and The resulting amount from applying the (state and region) tax scales to general taxable income is reduced by the family allowance, which again has a state and a region portion (although in practice they are very similar). The family allowance is calculated by applying the (state and region) general tax scale to a (state and region) amount that depends on the characteristics of the taxpayer and his/her family, such as age, number of dependent children, number of dependent parents, and disability of the taxpayer and the dependent members of his/her family. If the general taxable income is smaller than the family allowance, the remnant can be subtracted from the gross saving income, as long as it does not turn the saving taxable income into negative amount. 2 After subtracting the family allowance, the state general income and state saving income tax liabilities are pooled together. Similarly, the region tax liabilities (from general and saving income) are added up. To these two types of tax liabilities a set of non-refundable tax credits can be applied, some state or region specific, some pertaining to both. Among this set one can find that associated to house purchases (if they were carried out before 2013), the extended set of region tax credits and a tax credit for low labor income earners. After the application of the non-refundable tax 2 Starting in 2015, the family allowance applied to saving income was computed as in the general income. 4

5 credits, the state and region tax liabilities are pooled together. Finally, these pooled tax liabilities can be reduced by a set of refundable tax credits. In 2013, it was one, granted to employed mothers with children below 3 years old, while in 2015 the set was expanded to include mainly taxpayers with disable dependents and large families. The subtraction of this tax credit gives rise to the tax liabilities of the taxpayer. Figure I Structure of the Spanish Personal Tax (2013) 2.2 Recent Reforms ( ) The Spanish PIT has been subject to several reforms during the lapse of time encompassing our data. In this section we provide with a brief description of them, which will be helpful to interpret the over time evolution of the tax functions presented in Section In broad terms, the tax has zigzagged during the last decade and a half. Between 2003 and 2007 it underwent several reductions in a context of rapid economic growth and favorable macroeconomic conditions. Furthermore, in 2008 the government implemented additional cuts in order to counteract a slowdown in activity. Once the economic woes were confirmed, the sharp fall in GDP and the subsequent deterioration of the budget balance led to sizable tax increases in Finally, following the economic recovery, a major overhaul took place in 2015, resulting in a significant tax cut. The first major reform of the personal income tax during this century came into effect in It involved a reduction in the number of tax bands and tax rates, an increase in the family 5

6 Figure II Statutory Marginal Tax Rates (2013 & 2015) Panel A: General (2013): Panel B: Saving (2013) Statutory Marginal Tax Rates Statutory Marginal Tax Rates , , , , , , , ,000 Euros 0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 Euros Madrid Catalonia All Regions Panel C: General (2015) Panel D: Saving (2015) Statutory Marginal Tax Rates Statutory Marginal Tax Rates , , , , ,000 Euros 0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 60,000 70,000 Euros Madrid Catalonia All Regions Notes: This figure shows the statutory marginal tax rates of the personal income tax in 2013 and 2015 for residents in Madrid and Catalonia. Panels A and C display the rates applied to general income, consisting mainly in labor income, self-employment income and imputed rents. Panels B and D show the tax rates of saving income, comprised roughly by capital income and gains and losses. allowance and the introduction of a tax credit on employed mothers with at least one child below 3 years old. During the next two years there were no important actions, save a tax band update to keep up with inflation and the introduction of some one-off benefits to compensate for an increase in oil prices. In 2007 the government implemented a big reform, consisting in a reduction of tax bands and tax rates, an increase in the family allowance, which was redefined as a general income tax credit, a raise in saving tax rates and the introduction of a tax credit on births and adoptions. Moreover, a further tax cut was passed in 2008, involving e400 tax credit in order to spur private expenditures. Also in 2008 some regions lowered their tax rates, a new deduction for house tenants was introduced and tax bands were updated in order to accommodate the recent inflation developments. During the period the successive governments approved a set of tax increases in the 6

7 context of the economic crisis and the attendant deterioration of the budget balance. In 2010 the cabinet overrode the e400 tax benefit and raised the saving tax rates, while in 2011 it removed the tax credit on births and adoptions and it raised the marginal tax rates of the well-off. During these years there were also some changes associated to the new system of region financing, agreed on in Specifically, in 2010 tax rates shifted from the state to the region layer and the following year each region used their normative power to set their own tax scale. In 2012 the government approved a significant increase of marginal rates, affecting the whole income distribution. This tax raise, set initially to last two years, was extended to Furthermore, it suppressed in 2013 a large deduction on house purchases and the exemption of lottery prizes. After the crisis, the cabinet adopted a big reform of the tax code in 2015, leading to a tax cut of around 0.9% of GDP. It consisted mainly in a reduction of tax bands and tax rates, which overturned partly the 2012 tax raise. Also, the family allowance was increased and new refundable tax credits depending on family characteristics were introduced. The reform involved also a deep overhaul of tax deductions, some of them being decreased or repealed, partially offsetting the previous measures. 3 Data 3.1 Micro data on Tax Returns We use an administrative dataset containing a (stratified) random sample of tax returns, which includes almost the complete set of fiscal and sociodemographic information taxpayers fill therein. Hence, the dataset provides a very detailed account of income by income sources, tax benefits and family characteristics (number of dependent relatives, disability, location, etc.). Noteworthy, the dataset is not censored either at the bottom or at the top of the distribution. 3 The unit of observation in the dataset is the tax return, which can be of two types: single and joint. Single tax returns are filed at the individual level, whereas joint tax returns represent two spouses filing together, or single-parent families with at least one child. In joint tax returns incomes are pooled together and taxpayers are entitled to an additional tax deduction on top of those accruing to single filings. Save by these and other small differences, the computation of tax liabilities under both types is similar. The decision on which way to file is made by the taxpayer. In general, joint tax returns benefit couples in which one partner earns little or no income, as well as single-parent families with no child income. The different waves of the data comprise both a cross-section and a panel dimension. Repeated cross-sections are available for the years 2002 to 2013, and they have a large sample size. For 3 A detailed description of the dataset (in Spanish) and some statistics are provided every year in the working paper series of the Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. For example, see Pérez et al. (2016) for a description of the 2013 cross-section wave. 7

8 example, the 2013 dataset features 2.2 million observations, amounting to around 11% of the universe of tax returns; while for the periods and the sample size equals around 10% and 5% of the population, respectively. These cross-sections do not identify spouses filing single tax returns, hence they do not allow for a representation of taxes at the household level. The panel dataset covers the period and it renders a smaller sample size (around 3.3% of the universe of taxpayers in 2012). For this paper the main advantage of this dataset is that it provides an identifier of spouses filing single tax returns. Therefore, it allows to account for taxes paid by households. Note that we use the cross-section and the panel dimensions of the data to describe and estimate the functional forms of the personal income tax from the perspective of taxpayers and households, respectively. Moreover, the panel allows us to compare household income aggregates from tax data with those obtained in survey data, specifically the Survey of Household Finances (EFF). Table I provides a comparison between the cross-section sample aggregates and the population counterparts in As expected, the data render a very accurate representation of income and tax liabilities of the 19.2 million tax return filers, the differences being lower than 1% on the selected items. Table I Accuracy of the 2013 Cross-Section Data (emillion) Sample Aggregate Population Aggregate Difference (1) (2) (3) Number of Taxpayers (million) % Gross Labor % Gross Capital % Gross Self-Employment % Taxable % Tax Liabilities % Notes: The source of the population aggregates is the Spanish Tax Agency (Estadísticas de los declarantes del Impuesto sobre la Renta de las Personas Físicas (IRPF)) The definitions of the variables are described in Section 3.2. Gross capital income excludes some small items for which no population aggregates are reported. 3.2 Definitions and Sample Restrictions In this section we explain in detail the definition of the main variables used in the paper. Specifically, we describe the different income types we account for, the characterization of tax liabilities and tax benefits, and the computation of effective average tax rates. Regarding the income categories, our definition is threefold. First, gross income is the sum of labor income, capital income, and self-employment income. Labor income comprises benefits in cash 8

9 and in kind granted to individuals as employees. Capital income includes both financial income (interests, dividends, capital gains, etc.) and real-estate income (excluding the main residence). Self-employment income corresponds to the earnings of the self-employed associated to their business. It is worth noting that the data report self-employment income and part of capital income already net of some deductible expenses and tax deductions. This feature is specially relevant for the self-employed, as deductible expenses and other deductions can be relatively high, which may lead to an underestimation of their income. For this reason, we account for a second definition of income, named adjusted gross income, where all income categories are net of deductible expenses, such as employee s social security contributions, a deduction for labor-income earners, and business expenses. Nevertheless, we favor the first definition of income when it comes to computing average tax rates and total tax deductions, since doing so prevents an underestimation of these variables. The third income category is taxable income, which is income subject to the application of the (general and saving) tax scales. Note that we define also a general and saving taxable incomes, to which the corresponding general and saving tax scales are applied. Tax liabilities correspond to the amount that the taxpayer effectively has to pay, taking into account all the tax credits, including those refundable. For this reason, they can be a negative amount. Tax benefits can be of two types: tax deductions and tax credits. Tax deductions are amounts subtracted from the tax base, that is, before the application of the tax scales. Therefore, total tax deductions are defined as gross income minus taxable income. Tax credits are amounts subtracted from the tax liabilities resulting from the application of the tax scale. Hence, total tax credits can be computed as the difference between this amount and final tax liabilities. Lastly, average effective tax rates are computed as tax liabilities over gross income if the former are greater than or equal to zero, and zero otherwise. Note also that taxpayers with negative gross income are excluded from the sample, as we explain below. We also define the average effective general tax rate as tax liabilities resulting from the application of the general tax scale net of the family allowance (the box Intermediate Tax Liabilities 1 in Figure I) over general taxable income, provided that the latter is positive. We subtract the family allowance because for many (low income) taxpayers, this is equal to the general taxable income, hence by subtracting it from the numerator we avoid an artificial overestimation of the general tax rate (for these taxpayers the resulting average general tax rate is zero). Average saving tax rates are computed similarly, except for the fact the family allowance is a tax deduction regarding saving income, and then it is not subtracted from the numerator. 4 Hence, according to Figure I, the average effective saving tax rate is defined as Intermediate Tax Liabilities 2 over saving income. 5 4 In 2015, the family allowance regarding saving income was recoded as tax credit, as in general income. 5 According to the 2013 tax code, the cells (in Modelo 100 ) corresponding to each definition are the following. Gross income: 9 (labor) (capital) (self-employment). Adjusted gross income: 20 (labor)

10 Regarding the sample, we restrict it to taxpayers with positive total gross income, non-negative gross income sources (labor, capital and self-employment) and average tax rates below the maximum statutory marginal tax rate. Note also that we exclude taxpayers spared from the obligation to fill in the tax return and who decide not to do so, despite earning low income and hence, being likely entitled to obtain a tax refund from the taxes withheld at source. Our final sample leaves us with around 96% of tax filers and 85% of taxpayers. 3.3 Survey of Household Finances As mentioned above, we compare the estimated household income distribution from the tax return data with that obtained from the Survey of Household Finances (Encuesta Financiera de las Familias or EFF). This is a survey conducted by the Banco de España that collects information on income, assets, debts and spending of around 6,000 households each wave, several of the variables being reported for each household member, such as labor income and employment status. Moreover, the survey oversamples high-wealth households, in order to allow for a sufficient number of observations to study the financial behavior at the top of the wealth distribution and to accurately measure aggregate wealth. The EFF is undertaken every three years, the last wave corresponding to Each wave accounts for annual income pertaining to the previous year. A detailed description of the survey can be found in Bover et al. (2017b). Note that households in the tax data are defined as the taxpayer and his/her spouse. Therefore, we apply this definition to the EFF, by adding the gross income of the household s reference person and his/her spouse. Note that the EFF provides information on most of the labor and self-employment income items for each household member. On the contrary, the capital income items are mainly reported for the whole household. When this happens, we make the assumption that the item pertains to the household s reference person. 6 Note also that we classify the income sources provided by the EFF so as to mimic the labor, capital and self-employment groups defined in the tax data. 7 As with the tax data, we restrict the sample to households earning positive gross income and non-negative gross income sources (labor, capital and self-employment). This amounts to dropping (capital) ( ) (self-employment). Taxable income: 415 (general) + 2 (saving). General income: Saving income: Tax liabilities: Average effective general tax rate: general income. Average effective saving tax rate: saving income. 6 Note that since we focus on aggregate household income, it is irrelevant for two-person households to assign capital income to the reference person, his/her partner, or to split it between the two. 7 According to the 2014 wave of the EFF, we define gross income as: (p6 64 i + p6 66 i + p6 68 i p p6 74b i + p6 74 i) + p6 75d1 + p6 75d3 + p6 75d4 (labor) + ip6 72 i (self-employment) + p7 2 + p p p7 12a + p p7 4a + p7 4b + p7 6a + p7 6b + p7 8a + p7 8b + p6 76b + p6 75f (capital), where i indexes each household member (the reference person and his/her spouse in two-person households and the former in one-person households). 10 i

11 around 2% of the observations. 4 Basic Facts of the and Tax Distributions In this section we report basic facts of income, tax liabilities and tax benefits for both our sample of 2013 individuals and households. Moreover, we compare the results of the latter with survey data from the Survey of Household Finances. 4.1 Distribution Individuals Table II summarizes the distribution of taxpayers income and income sources in The data show a fair degree of income concentration at the top. For example, the top 20% of taxpayers earns about 46% of income, whereas the richest 10%, 5% and 1% earns about 30.2%, 20.0% and 8.1%, respectively. Nevertheless, this income concentration is substantially lower than that documented in the US by Guner et al. (2014), where the top 20% earns 61.4% of total income and the top 1% accumulates as much as 20.9%. Regarding the different concepts of income, the share of income accruing to the well-off increases once deductible expenses and tax deductions are subtracted from the gross measure, and taxpayers with zero income are excluded from the sample. For example, the share of income accounted for the top 20% increases from 46% of gross income, to 49.6% of adjusted gross income and taxable income. Likewise, the income share of the top 1% shows an increasing pattern across the different concepts of income. The Gini coefficients reveal that, conditional on positive income, taxable income inequality is larger than gross income inequality, while the levels are still substantially lower than in the US, compare the last two rows of Table II with Table 2 of Guner et al. (2014). With respect to the distribution of the different income sources, columns (4) to (6) of Table II show that capital income renders a higher degree of concentration at the bottom and top quintiles, when compared to gross income. For example, the bottom 20% accounts for just 4.8% of gross income, while it accumulates 6.6% of capital income; the top 1% accumulating 8.1% and 24.3%, respectively. Self-employment income is also concentrated at the very top, but the lower end of the income distribution accumulates a substantial amount. For instance, the first three quintiles earn more than 40% of this income source. In Table III we decompose the sources of income across the income distribution. Labor income is by far the largest source of income, its importance increasing monotonically from quintiles 1 to 4, where it represents between 80 and 90% of total income. In the top decile income from labor is less important, although even for the top 1% the share of labor income is very high, being close to 70%. In the lowest end of the distribution, specially in the bottom 1%, capital income appears very 11

12 Table II Distribution of Individuals and Sources Quantiles Share of Gross Sources Bottom Gross Adjusted Gross Taxable Labor Capital Selfemployment (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 1-5% 0.3% 0.1% 0.2% 0.2% 1.1% 1.0% 5-10% 1.1% 0.5% 0.6% 0.9% 1.7% 2.4% Quintiles 1st (bottom 20%) 4.8% 2.9% 3.0% 4.2% 6.6% 10.1% 2nd (20-40%) 10.5% 9.0% 8.9% 10.2% 9.5% 15.9% 3rd (40-60%) 15.8% 15.3% 15.2% 16.2% 11.4% 16.4% 4th (60-80%) 23.0% 23.3% 23.3% 24.5% 15.1% 14.0% 5th (80-100%) 46.0% 49.6% 49.6% 44.9% 57.4% 43.6% Top 90-95% 10.2% 10.8% 10.8% 10.4% 9.3% 7.8% 95-99% 11.9% 13.0% 12.9% 11.6% 13.6% 12.0% 1% 8.1% 9.3% 9.4% 5.8% 24.3% 15.7% Other Statistics Gini Coefficient Var - Log Notes: This table displays the distribution of gross income, adjusted gross income and taxable income, as well as the distribution of gross income sources (labor, capital, and self-employment) for the sample of 2013 individuals. Note that observations with non-positive income values in columns (1) to (3) are excluded. The Gini coefficient in columns (4) to (6) are computed including the observations with zero income. significant. However, this is explained by the very low income levels of this group, see Table A.1 in the appendix. Excluding the lowest quintile, capital income accounts for around 6 to 9%, reaching 20.8% for the richest taxpayers. Self-employment income explains 8.6% of income in the second quintile, while it drops to around 4 to 6% for richer individuals. At the top of the distribution it accounts for slightly more than 10% of total income Households In Table IV we compare the household distribution of income estimated from the tax data with that obtained from the Survey of Household Finances (EFF). We do so for the two latest EFF waves, i.e and We can see that both sources provide a similar estimate of the income distribution. For example, in 2010 income accounted by the top 20% amounted to around 50%, the top 1% accumulating more than 9% of total income; while the bottom 20% received less than 5% of earnings. With respect to the most recent wave, estimates of the income distribution are also similar, although the differences at the right-end of the distribution are larger. For example, the EFF seems to under predict the share of income accruing to the top 1% by 1.7 percentage 12

13 Table III Individuals Gross Sources Quantiles Labor Capital Selfemployment (1) (2) (3) Bottom 1% 12.4% 79.3% 8.4% 1-5% 46.5% 36.5% 17.0% 5-10% 72.1% 15.3% 12.7% Quintiles 1st (bottom 20%) 66.8% 20.6% 12.6% 2nd (20-40%) 82.8% 8.7% 8.6% 3rd (40-60%) 87.3% 6.9% 5.9% 4th (60-80%) 90.4% 6.2% 3.4% 5th (80-100%) 87.5% 8.4% 4.1% Top 90-95% 87.2% 8.7% 4.2% 95-99% 83.8% 10.8% 5.4% 1% 68.8% 20.8% 10.4% Notes: This table shows the decomposition of gross income over income sources across the gross income distribution for the sample of 2013 taxpayers. Columns (1) to (3) add up to 100. points. 4.2 Tax Rates and Tax Liabilities In Table V we summarize the distribution of tax liabilities and tax rates of the 2013 taxpayers. In columns (1) and (2) we also depict the corresponding distributions of gross income and taxable income (already shown in Table II), in order to illustrate the progressivity of the tax code. Indeed, this feature of the tax becomes apparent. If the top quintile accumulates 46% of gross income, it shoulders more than 70% of tax liabilities, while the top 1% accounts for close to 20% of revenues. As a matter of fact, more than 90% of tax payments are concentrated in the top 40%, while the bottom two deciles account for only 1.3% of the tax. The high concentration of tax liabilities is reflected in small average tax rates at the lower end of the income distribution and larger rates for richer individuals, which average 20.2% in the top quintile and 33.1% in the top 1%. Average statutory marginal tax rates are also highest for the well-off, reaching 45% for the top 1%, while they are significantly lower as we move leftwards across the income distribution. Note that for each individual we computed the statutory marginal tax rate as the weighted average of the corresponding marginal rates of general income and saving income. These averages hide a substantial degree of heterogeneity across individuals. Panel A of Figure 13

14 Table IV Household Distribution: Tax Data Compared to EFF Quantiles Bottom Tax Data EFF Difference Tax Data EFF Difference (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 1% 0.0% 0.1% % 0.0% % 0.3% 0.7% % 0.5% % 1.0% 1.2% % 1.1% -0.1 Quintiles 1st (bottom 20%) 4.4% 4.9% % 4.7% nd (20-40%) 9.6% 9.4% % 9.1% 0.3 3rd (40-60%) 14.5% 14.5% % 14.3% 0.0 4th (60-80%) 21.7% 22.7% % 22.2% th (80-100%) 49.9% 48.5% % 49.6% 0.8 Top 90-95% 11.0% 11.1% % 10.8% % 13.2% 13.0% % 13.4% 0.2 1% 9.7% 8.0% % 9.1% 0.5 Other Statistics Gini coefficient Var - log income Notes: This table provides a summary of the household distribution of income according to the tax return data aggregated at the household level and the Survey of Household Financies (EFF). It compares the results from two waves: 2013 and III depicts the average effective tax rates across different multiples of mean gross income, alongside 2 standard error bands. 8 As can be seen, there is wide variation of tax rates even for individuals with the same gross income, being this the result of different family characteristics and tax benefit entitlements. The shape of this curve is what the parametric estimates of Section 5 are meant to approximate. In panel B we represent the corresponding curves of statutory and effective marginal tax rates. Statutory rates are again computed as the weighed average of the general and saving marginal rates. The effective rates are computed as in Guner et al. (2014), see Section 6 thereof, where we set the minimum (maximum) income level to 0.2 (10.4) times mean income and the increment to 0.4 times mean income. The findings shows that marginal rates increase rapidly with income, becoming flat at around 3 times mean income. The set of tax benefits renders the effective curve below the statutory one, being the difference roughly about 5 percentage points on average. It is worth noting one feature of the tax code which will be important in the parametric estimates later on, namely the large percentage of individuals facing zero tax rates, around 32% 8 Note that mean individual gross income in 2013 was e23.354, while household mean income in 2012 amounted to e

15 Table V Distribution of Individuals Tax Liabilities and Tax Rates Quantiles Gross Taxable Tax Liabilities Average Tax Rate Statutory Marginal Tax Rate (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Bottom 1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 5.5% 1-5% 0.3% 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 9.2% 5-10% 1.1% 0.6% 0.0% 0.0% 18.6% Quintiles 1st (bottom 20%) 4.8% 3.0% 0.0% 0.1% 18.4% 2nd (20-40%) 10.5% 8.9% 1.3% 2.0% 24.5% 3rd (40-60%) 15.8% 15.2% 7.9% 7.5% 24.8% 4th (60-80%) 23.0% 23.3% 19.9% 12.8% 28.9% 5th (80-100%) 46.0% 49.6% 70.9% 20.2% 36.4% Top 90-95% 10.2% 10.8% 13.8% 20.2% 38.0% 95-99% 11.9% 12.9% 20.4% 25.3% 42.7% 1% 8.1% 9.4% 18.7% 33.1% 45.0% Notes: This table shows the distribution of individuals tax liabilities (column 3), average effective tax rates (column 4) and statutory marginal tax rates (column 5) across the gross income distribution. In columns (1) and (2) the distribution of gross income and taxable income are summarized in order to illustrate the progressivity of the tax code. Figure III Individuals Effective Average and Marginal Tax Rates Panel A: Effective Average Tax Rates Panel B: Marginal Tax Rates Average Tax Rates Marginal Tax Rates Multiples of Mean Multiples of Mean Statutory Effective Notes: Panel A depicts the effective average tax rate (± 2 standard deviations) across different multiples of mean income. Note that each data point corresponds to the mean average tax rate of taxpayers with mean income within the corresponding point in the x-axis and the very next (excluding the right end point). For instance, the data point of mean income 1.4 is the mean average tax rate of taxpayers earning income within the interval [1.4,1.8). Panel B shows the statutory and effective marginal tax rates. Statutory rates are computed as the weighted average of general and saving marginal rates, while effective rates are described in Section 6 of Guner et al. (2014), where we set the minimum (maximum) income level to 0.2 (10.4) times mean income and the increment to 0.4 times mean income. 15

16 in Figure IV shows that until about 35% of mean income the percentage of taxpayers facing positive rates is below 10%. This share increases steeply, so that by 70% of mean income around 90% of taxpayers contributes to revenue, this number gradually converging towards 100% as income increases. Figure IV Share of Positive Effective Tax Rates (Individuals) Share of Positive Average Tax Rates Multiples of Mean Notes: Each data point corresponds to the share of taxpayers facing strictly positive average tax rates and earning income within the corresponding point in the x-axis and the very next (excluding the right end point). 4.3 Tax Benefits In Table VI we describe the distribution of the most relevant tax deductions, which, as mentioned in Section 3.2, correspond to tax benefits reducing the tax base. Also, in Table A.2 in the appendix we account for their relative weight across income groups. The biggest tax deduction is that granted to labor income earners, followed by Social Security contributions paid by the employees, the tax benefit associated to joint tax returns and the contributions to private pension plans. On the whole, the top quintile benefits from more than 25% of the total tax deductions, while the bottom quintile receives less than 15%, see the first column of Table VI. This feature of the tax system suggests that these benefits are overall regressive, being specially so in regard to benefits associated to private pension plan and Social Security contributors, where the top quintile represents 72% and 41% of the total amount, respectively. However, note that part of the regressive nature of tax deductions stems from the fact that the tax base of many low income earners goes to zero after making use of some tax benefits, exhausting the possibility of further deductions later on in the tax code. 16

17 Table VI Distribution of Individuals Tax Deductions Bottom Labor Joint Filing Quantiles Total Social Security Contributions Contributions to Private Pensions Other (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.2% 1-5% 1.2% 0.3% 1.4% 1.0% 0.1% 3.5% 5-10% 3.8% 0.7% 5.5% 1.7% 0.5% 5.0% Quintiles 1st (bottom 20%) 14.1% 3.7% 19.6% 8.2% 2.0% 20.0% 2nd (20-40%) 19.2% 10.5% 23.2% 19.5% 4.6% 21.2% 3rd (40-60%) 18.9% 18.6% 18.9% 25.7% 8.2% 14.0% 4th (60-80%) 20.4% 26.1% 19.2% 24.2% 13.2% 12.7% 5th (80-100%) 27.4% 41.1% 19.1% 22.4% 72.0% 32.0% Top 90-95% 6.8% 11.6% 4.8% 5.3% 16.7% 5.4% 95-99% 6.5% 10.1% 3.8% 4.2% 26.8% 7.1% 1% 2.8% 2.6% 0.9% 1.1% 15.3% 11.9% Notes: This table depicts the distribution of tax deductions over the gross income distribution. Tax deductions are amounts subtracted from the tax base. Total tax deductions are computed as gross income minus taxable income, where the latter refers to income to which the tax schedule applies. Tax credits, as mentioned in Section 3.2, correspond to tax benefits applied to the tax liabilities that result from the application of the tax schedule. Table VII depicts their distribution across income groups and Table A.3 in the appendix shows the relative weight of the most relevant ones. By far the family allowance is the largest tax credit, representing more than 95% of these benefits for the bottom 20% and more than 80% for the top 20%. Following in magnitude is the tax credit associated to house purchases, that granted to employed mothers and a battery of region-specific tax credits. 9 Finally, it is worth highlighting a tax credit granted to low labor income earners, which is a relevant tax benefit for the second quintile. As of the distribution of these benefits, the family allowance is roughly evenly distributed since it depends solely on family characteristics. Note that the smaller share accruing to the lower end of the income distribution is explained by the exhaustion of tax liabilities as a result of the application of (part of) this allowance. On the contrary, the tax credit associated to house purchases benefits more the well-off, where benefits granted to employed mothers, low labor income earners and the set of region-specific benefits goes mainly to the middle or the lower end of the income distribution. 9 The tax credit associated to house purchases was stopped in 2013, so that it only benefits transactions carried out before that year. 17

18 Quantiles Total Family Allowance Bottom Table VII Distribution of Individuals Tax Credits House Purchases Working Mothers Regional Labor (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 1-5% 0.3% 0.3% 0.0% 0.8% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 5-10% 0.9% 1.1% 0.1% 1.8% 0.0% 0.3% -0.3% Quintiles 1st (bottom 20%) 6.2% 7.1% 0.7% 9.4% 0.6% 9.0% -1.0% 2nd (20-40%) 19.1% 19.9% 10.5% 21.7% 16.0% 87.1% -0.5% 3rd (40-60%) 23.8% 24.0% 23.0% 24.5% 35.0% 3.8% 24.0% 4th (60-80%) 24.7% 24.6% 28.7% 26.3% 31.1% 0.0% 18.1% 5th (80-100%) 26.2% 24.5% 37.1% 18.1% 17.3% 0.0% 59.3% Top 90-95% 6.4% 6.0% 9.3% 5.0% 3.3% 0.0% 10.7% 95-99% 5.4% 4.9% 8.9% 3.6% 4.6% 0.0% 13.1% 1% 1.9% 1.3% 2.2% 0.5% 1.3% 0.0% 24.3% Other Notes: This table characterizes the distribution of tax credits across income groups. Tax credits are amounts that directly reduce tax liabilities. Total tax credits are computed as the difference between tax liabilities following the application of the tax schedule and final tax liabilities. 5 Parametric Estimates In this section we provide estimates of effective average tax functions for applied use. Specifically, we estimate different parametric functions for our samples of individuals and households in 2013, differentiating by marital status for the latter. We also estimate separate parametric functions for the different components of the Spanish tax returns, namely the general tax rates, the savings tax rates and the tax credits. In addition, we provide estimates for the different cross-sections of individuals between 2002 and Finally, we estimate the effective average tax function under the 2015 legislation using the BdE-PIT microsimulation model. 5.1 Taxes in Individuals A significant number of Spanish taxpayers face zero tax rates, therefore we opt for estimating the following function: 0 if ỹ < t(ỹ) = Ī, (1) f(ỹ) if ỹ Ī, where t is the average tax rate, ỹ stands for multiples of mean gross income, Ī is chosen so as to minimize the mean squared error and f(ỹ) is a parsimonious non-linear function that takes one of 18

19 the following four specifications: The log specification which was used by Guner et al (2012a, 2012b) f(ỹ) = α + βlog(ỹ) (2) The HSV specification, used by Benabou (2002) and Heathcote et al. (2011) The Power specification, used by Guvenen et al. (2014) f(ỹ) = 1 λ(ỹ) τ (3) f(ỹ) = δ + γỹ ɛ (4) And the GS specification: Gouveia and Strauss (1994), in which ỹ is replaced by y, i.e. the income level. f(y) = b [ ] 1 (sy p + 1) 1 p Table VIII column (1) shows the parameter estimates for individuals in 2013 for the four specifications. Other columns of the table show the parameter estimates for other samples defined in the next subsections. We estimate the log and HSV functions by OLS and the Power and GS by NLS. Figure V illustrates the average tax rates predicted by the estimated parametric functions alongside the the data averages for each bin. Figure V Effective Average Tax Rates 2013: Functions (Individuals) (5) Average Tax Rates Multiples of Mean Data Log HSV Power GS Figure VI shows the mean squared error (MSE) under the four different specification, with the minimum of each function determining the corresponding threshold Ī. 19

20 Table VIII Parameter Estimates Functions Individuals 2013 Households 2013 Individuals 2015 (1) (2) (3) Log α (0.0000) (0.0001) (0.0000) β (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) Ī 44% 34% 47% MSE HSV λ (0.0000) (0.0001) (0.0000) τ (0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001) Ī 47% 36% 49% MSE Power δ (0.0000) (0.0001) (0.0000) γ (.) (.) (.) ɛ (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) Ī 44% 33% 47% MSE GS b (0.0004) (0.0007) (0.0004) s (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) p (0.0059) (0.0085) (0.0068) Ī 53% 42% 57% MSE Notes: Households For households we follow the same estimation approach as for individuals. Table VIII shows the parameter estimates and Figure VII plots our preferred tax functions (HSV and GS) for all households (Panel A) and distinguishing between single and married households (Panel B) Three-function Approach An alternative to the one-function approach is to estimate the three different tax functions that lead to final tax liabilities (c.f. Figure I): the general tax rates, applied to general taxable income (base liquidable general); the savings tax rates, applied to savings taxable income (base liquidable 20

21 Figure VI Evaluation of Tax Functions: Mean Squared Error Mean Squared Error Multiples of Mean Log Power HSV GS Figure VII Households Average Tax Rates 2013: Functions Panel A: All households Panel B: Single and married households Average Tax Rates Multiples of Mean Average Tax Rates Multiples of Mean Data HSV GS Singles Married Notes: del ahorro); and the tax credits (deducciones sobre la cuota). This approach allows to simulate more detailed reforms such as changes in capital taxes. Functional forms For the general taxable income we estimate the same functional form (1) as for the effective average tax function under our preferred specifications GS and HSV. For the savings income, we estimate the following parametric function 21

22 c + ζỹ s t s (ỹ s ) = κ if ỹ s < S, if ỹ s S, (6) where κ is the sample mean of the average savings tax rate if ỹ s S and S is chosen so as to minimize the MSE. Note that S = And for the tax credits we estimate the Ricker Model: t tc (ỹ) = β 0 + e β 1 e β 2ỹỹ β 3 (7) Table IX shows the estimated parameters for all these functions for individuals in Figure VIII plots the general income tax functions estimated, Figure IX shows the estimated function for savings income tax rates, and Figure X shows the Tax Credit function. Figure VIII Parametric Functions for the General Tax Rates General Average Tax Rates Multiples of Mean General Data HSV GS Notes: Evaluation of Tax Functions To evaluate the fit of different specifications across the tax liabilities distribution we calculate the percentage difference of the predicted total tax liabilities with respect to the data under the onefunction and three-function approaches for the HSV and GS specifications. The result is shown in Table X. Table XI shows a similar comparison but in terms of the distribution of tax liabilities. 22

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations Online Appendix of Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality By ANDREAS FAGERENG, LUIGI GUISO, DAVIDE MALACRINO AND LUIGI PISTAFERRI This appendix complements the evidence

More information

The redistributive effects of Personal Income Tax reforms during the Great Recession in Spain

The redistributive effects of Personal Income Tax reforms during the Great Recession in Spain Universidad de Alcalá The redistributive effects of Personal Income Tax reforms during the Great Recession in Spain M. Adiego (IEF), O. Cantó (UAH), M. Paniagua (IEF) and T. Pérez (IEF) Brussels, 21st

More information

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Andreas Fagereng (Statistics Norway) Luigi Guiso (EIEF) Davide Malacrino (Stanford University) Luigi Pistaferri (Stanford University

More information

Income Taxation of U.S. Households: Facts and Parametric Estimates

Income Taxation of U.S. Households: Facts and Parametric Estimates Income Taxation of U.S. Households: Facts and Parametric Estimates Nezih Guner, Remzi Kaygusuz and Gustavo Ventura October 2013 Abstract We use micro data from the U.S. Internal Revenue Service to document

More information

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013 Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak November 2013 Well known that policymakers face important tradeoffs between equity and efficiency in the design of the tax system The issue we address in this paper informs

More information

UNIVERSITAT JAUME I INCOME INEQUALITY OF THE SPANISH FAMILIES; AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

UNIVERSITAT JAUME I INCOME INEQUALITY OF THE SPANISH FAMILIES; AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS UNIVERSITAT JAUME I JEL: E25 JEL: E01 INCOME INEQUALITY OF THE SPANISH FAMILIES; AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS Marta Martinez Monterroso Grado de Economía, group C al185378@uji.es Tutor: Simone Alfarano Castellón

More information

Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes

Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes Guyonne Kalb, Hsein Kew and Rosanna Scutella Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic

More information

EstimatingFederalIncomeTaxBurdens. (PSID)FamiliesUsingtheNationalBureau of EconomicResearchTAXSIMModel

EstimatingFederalIncomeTaxBurdens. (PSID)FamiliesUsingtheNationalBureau of EconomicResearchTAXSIMModel ISSN1084-1695 Aging Studies Program Paper No. 12 EstimatingFederalIncomeTaxBurdens forpanelstudyofincomedynamics (PSID)FamiliesUsingtheNationalBureau of EconomicResearchTAXSIMModel Barbara A. Butrica and

More information

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany Modern Economy, 2016, 7, 1198-1222 http://www.scirp.org/journal/me ISSN Online: 2152-7261 ISSN Print: 2152-7245 Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction

More information

Regional convergence in Spain:

Regional convergence in Spain: ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/2017 ANALYTICAL ARTIES Regional convergence in Spain: 1980 2015 Sergio Puente 19 September 2017 This article aims to analyse the process of per capita income convergence between the

More information

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries May 2017 Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries May 2017 The concept of a Basic Income (BI), an unconditional

More information

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany Contents Appendix I: Data... 2 I.1 Earnings concept... 2 I.2 Imputation of top-coded earnings... 5 I.3 Correction of

More information

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., 1987 2010 Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner Cross-sectional Census data, survey data or income tax returns (Saez 2003) generally

More information

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM Revenue Summit 17 October 2018 The Australia Institute Patricia Apps The University of Sydney Law School, ANU, UTS and IZA ABSTRACT

More information

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

Online Appendix (Not For Publication) A Online Appendix (Not For Publication) Contents of the Appendix 1. The Village Democracy Survey (VDS) sample Figure A1: A map of counties where sample villages are located 2. Robustness checks for the

More information

PWBM WORKING PAPER SERIES MATCHING IRS STATISTICS OF INCOME TAX FILER RETURNS WITH PWBM SIMULATOR MICRO-DATA OUTPUT.

PWBM WORKING PAPER SERIES MATCHING IRS STATISTICS OF INCOME TAX FILER RETURNS WITH PWBM SIMULATOR MICRO-DATA OUTPUT. PWBM WORKING PAPER SERIES MATCHING IRS STATISTICS OF INCOME TAX FILER RETURNS WITH PWBM SIMULATOR MICRO-DATA OUTPUT Jagadeesh Gokhale Director of Special Projects, PWBM jgokhale@wharton.upenn.edu Working

More information

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES,

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES, INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES, 1995-2013 by Conchita d Ambrosio and Marta Barazzetta, University of Luxembourg * The opinions expressed and arguments employed

More information

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly www.taxpolicycenter.org The Distribution of Federal Taxes, 2008 11 Jeffrey Rohaly Overall, the federal tax system is highly progressive. On average, households with higher incomes pay taxes that are a

More information

Online Appendix for On the Asset Allocation of a Default Pension Fund

Online Appendix for On the Asset Allocation of a Default Pension Fund Online Appendix for On the Asset Allocation of a Default Pension Fund Magnus Dahlquist Ofer Setty Roine Vestman January 6, 26 Dahlquist: Stockholm School of Economics and CEPR; e-mail: magnus.dahlquist@hhs.se.

More information

An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland

An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland An Analysis of Public and Private Sector Earnings in Ireland 2008-2013 Prepared in collaboration with publicpolicy.ie by: Justin Doran, Nóirín McCarthy, Marie O Connor; School of Economics, University

More information

Personal Income Tax Reforms and Effective Tax Functions in China

Personal Income Tax Reforms and Effective Tax Functions in China Personal Income Tax Reforms and Effective Tax Functions in China Rong Li and Guangrong Ma August 2015 Abstract We use household-level data to estimate the effective income tax function for China, i.e.

More information

TABLE I SUMMARY STATISTICS Panel A: Loan-level Variables (22,176 loans) Variable Mean S.D. Pre-nuclear Test Total Lending (000) 16,479 60,768 Change in Log Lending -0.0028 1.23 Post-nuclear Test Default

More information

STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS

STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS Juan F. Martínez S.* Daniel A. Oda Z.** I. INTRODUCTION Stress tests, applied to the banking system, have

More information

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality Economics 448: Measures of Inequality 6 March 2014 1 2 The context Economic inequality: Preliminary observations 3 Inequality Economic growth affects the level of income, wealth, well being. Also want

More information

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? Massimiliano Marzo and Paolo Zagaglia This version: January 6, 29 Preliminary: comments

More information

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model By Ana Buisán, Juan Carlos Caballero and Noelia Jiménez, Directorate General Economics, Statistics and Research

More information

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey Data Appendix A.1. The 2007 survey The survey data used draw on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey was conducted between June and September 2007 and elicited detailed financial

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

SPAIN According to the Centre for Tax and Policy and Administration, the 2007 AW level is EUR

SPAIN According to the Centre for Tax and Policy and Administration, the 2007 AW level is EUR SPAIN 2007 1. Overview of the tax-benefit system Unemployed persons are covered by two successive benefits: a contributory unemployment insurance benefit for 120-to-720 days depending on contributions,

More information

Firm Manipulation and Take-up Rate of a 30 Percent. Temporary Corporate Income Tax Cut in Vietnam

Firm Manipulation and Take-up Rate of a 30 Percent. Temporary Corporate Income Tax Cut in Vietnam Firm Manipulation and Take-up Rate of a 30 Percent Temporary Corporate Income Tax Cut in Vietnam Anh Pham June 3, 2015 Abstract This paper documents firm take-up rates and manipulation around the eligibility

More information

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal Forecasting Federal Individual Income Tax Receipts Challenges and Uncertainties in Forecasting Federal Individual Income Tax Receipts Abstract - Forecasting individual income receipts has been greatly

More information

ARC Centre of Excellence in Population Ageing Research. Working Paper 2019/1

ARC Centre of Excellence in Population Ageing Research. Working Paper 2019/1 ARC Centre of Excellence in Population Ageing Research Working Paper 2019/1 Tax Progressivity in Australia: Facts, Measurements and Estimates Chung Tran and Nabeeh Zakariyya This paper can be downloaded

More information

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey, Internet Appendix A1. The 2007 survey The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey, conducted between June and September 2007, provides detailed financial and

More information

CLARA MARTÍNEZ-TOLEDANO TOLEDANO WEALTH INEQUALITY IN SPAIN ( )

CLARA MARTÍNEZ-TOLEDANO TOLEDANO WEALTH INEQUALITY IN SPAIN ( ) CLARA MARTÍNEZ-TOLEDANO TOLEDANO WEALTH INEQUALITY IN SPAIN (1984-2013) Abstract. This paper combines different sources (tax records, national accounts, wealth surveys) and the capitalization method in

More information

Status of the Social Security and Medicare Programs

Status of the Social Security and Medicare Programs Social Security Online Actuarial Publications Status of the Social Security and Medicare Programs A SUMMARY OF THE 2011 ANNUAL REPORTS Social Security and Medicare Boards of Trustees A MESSAGE TO THE PUBLIC:

More information

Appendix A. Additional Results

Appendix A. Additional Results Appendix A Additional Results for Intergenerational Transfers and the Prospects for Increasing Wealth Inequality Stephen L. Morgan Cornell University John C. Scott Cornell University Descriptive Results

More information

Global Mobility Services: Taxation of International Assignees - Spain

Global Mobility Services: Taxation of International Assignees - Spain www.pwc.es/en Global Mobility Services: Taxation of International Assignees - Spain People and Organisation Global Mobility Country Guide (Folio) Last updated: February 2017 This document was not intended

More information

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data The Distributions of Income and Consumption Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data Elin Halvorsen Hans A. Holter Serdar Ozkan Kjetil Storesletten February 15, 217 Preliminary Extended Abstract Version

More information

Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings

Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings Raj Chetty, Harvard and NBER John N. Friedman, Harvard and NBER Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley and NBER April

More information

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Summer 22, Vol. 26, No. 3, pp. 2 35 Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of,, and Wealth Santiago Budría Rodríguez Teaching Associate Department

More information

Assessing the Benefits Reform in Slovenia Using a Microsimulation Approach

Assessing the Benefits Reform in Slovenia Using a Microsimulation Approach Assessing the Benefits Reform in Slovenia Using a Microsimulation Approach Nataša Kump Institute for Economic Research Kardeljeva pl. 17, 1000 Ljubljana natasa.kump@ier.si Tel: +386(0)15303824 Boris Majcen

More information

Federal Taxation of Earnings versus Investment Income in 2004

Federal Taxation of Earnings versus Investment Income in 2004 Federal Taxation of Earnings versus Investment in 2004 Institute on Taxation & Economic Policy May 2004 1311 L Street, NW, Washington, DC! 202-737-4315! www.itepnet.org Federal Taxation of Earnings versus

More information

Tax Incidence Analysis First & Second Omnibus Tax Bills

Tax Incidence Analysis First & Second Omnibus Tax Bills Tax Incidence Analysis Prepared by the Tax Research Division, Minnesota Department of Revenue June 18, 2014 2014 First & Second Omnibus Tax Bills Chapter 150 (H.F. 1777 as enacted on March 21, 2014) and

More information

Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand?

Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand? HCSF/217/1-2-1 15 e séance Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand? The French private non-financial sector (households and firms) indebtedness registered a steady increase since the

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Properties of the estimated five-factor model Informationin(andnotin)thetermstructure Appendix. Additional results Greg Duffee Johns Hopkins This draft: October 8, Properties of the estimated five-factor model No stationary term structure model is

More information

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan Open Journal of Social Sciences, 2016, 4, 13-26 http://www.scirp.org/journal/jss ISSN Online: 2327-5960 ISSN Print: 2327-5952 Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan Tetsuo Fukawa 1,2,3

More information

Income Inequality in Korea,

Income Inequality in Korea, Income Inequality in Korea, 1958-2013. Minki Hong Korea Labor Institute 1. Introduction This paper studies the top income shares from 1958 to 2013 in Korea using tax return. 2. Data and Methodology In

More information

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $ CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $ Joyce Jacobsen a, Melanie Khamis b and Mutlu Yuksel c a Wesleyan University b Wesleyan

More information

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take?

Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take? Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Halving Poverty in Russia by 2024: What will it take? September 2018 Prepared by the

More information

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations IFS Briefing Note BN192 Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Copy-edited by Judith Payne Published by The Institute for Fiscal Studies

More information

Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality:

Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality: Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality: Evidence from Large Predetermined Payments Lorenz Kueng Northwestern University and NBER Motivation: understanding consumption is important

More information

2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study 2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study (Using November 2008 Forecast) An analysis of Minnesota s household and business taxes. March 2009 For document links go to: Table of Contents 2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence

More information

Window Width Selection for L 2 Adjusted Quantile Regression

Window Width Selection for L 2 Adjusted Quantile Regression Window Width Selection for L 2 Adjusted Quantile Regression Yoonsuh Jung, The Ohio State University Steven N. MacEachern, The Ohio State University Yoonkyung Lee, The Ohio State University Technical Report

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Economic Impact Report

Economic Impact Report Economic Impact Report Idaho Tax Reform Proposal by the Idaho Association of Commerce and Industry Prepared By: Dr. Geoffrey Black Professor, Department of Economics Boise State University Dr. Donald Holley

More information

Income Inequality in Canada: Trends in the Census

Income Inequality in Canada: Trends in the Census Income Inequality in Canada: Trends in the Census 1980-2005 Kevin Milligan Vancouver School of Economics University of British Columbia kevin.milligan@ubc.ca May, 2013 1 The focus of this paper: Analysis

More information

Tax Progressivity in Australia:

Tax Progressivity in Australia: Tax Progressivity in Australia: Facts, Measurements and Estimates (In Progress) Chung Tran Australian National University Nabeeh Zakariyya Australian National University Australian-Korean Tax and Welfare

More information

Potential Output in Denmark

Potential Output in Denmark 43 Potential Output in Denmark Asger Lau Andersen and Morten Hedegaard Rasmussen, Economics 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY The concepts of potential output and output gap are among the most widely used concepts

More information

The elasticity of taxable income and the optimal taxation of top incomes: Evidence from an exhaustive panel of the wealthiest taxpayers

The elasticity of taxable income and the optimal taxation of top incomes: Evidence from an exhaustive panel of the wealthiest taxpayers The elasticity of taxable income and the optimal taxation of top incomes: Evidence from an exhaustive panel of the wealthiest taxpayers Pierre-Yves Cabannes (PSE) & Camille Landais (PSE) 1 Preliminary

More information

Income Mobility: The Recent American Experience

Income Mobility: The Recent American Experience International Studies Program Working Paper 06-20 July 2006 Income Mobility: The Recent American Experience Robert Carroll David Joulfaian Mark Rider International Studies Program Working Paper 06-20

More information

INCOME DISTRIBUTION DATA REVIEW PORTUGAL

INCOME DISTRIBUTION DATA REVIEW PORTUGAL INCOME DISTRIBUTION DATA REVIEW PORTUGAL 1. Available data sources used for reporting on income inequality and poverty 1.1. OECD reporting: OECD income data currently available for Portugal refer to income

More information

2 TRENDS IN THE DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLD INCOME BETWEEN 1979 AND 27 Summary Figure 1. Growth in Real After-Tax Income from 1979 to L

2 TRENDS IN THE DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLD INCOME BETWEEN 1979 AND 27 Summary Figure 1. Growth in Real After-Tax Income from 1979 to L Congressional Summary Budget Office Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 27 From 1979 to 27, real (inflation-adjusted) average household income, measured after government transfers

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS Alan L. Gustman Thomas Steinmeier Nahid Tabatabai Working

More information

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230 Taxes and the High Income Population New Tax Responsiveness Literature Started by Feldstein [JPE The Effect of MTR on Taxable Income: A Panel Study of 1986 TRA ]. Hugely important

More information

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN Olympia Bover 1 Introduction and summary Dierences in wealth distribution across developed countries are large (eg share held by top 1%: 15 to 35%)

More information

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS PPI PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS I S S U E B R I E F Introduction President George W. Bush fulfilled a 2000 campaign promise by signing the $1.35

More information

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence ISSN 2029-4581. ORGANIZATIONS AND MARKETS IN EMERGING ECONOMIES, 2012, VOL. 3, No. 1(5) Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence from and the Euro Area Jolanta

More information

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction,

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction, Understanding the Drivers of Poverty Reduction To understand the drivers of poverty reduction, we decompose the distributional changes in consumption and income over the 7 to 1 period, and examine the

More information

INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT

INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT INEQUALITY UNDER THE LABOUR GOVERNMENT Andrew Shephard THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 33 Income Inequality under the Labour Government Andrew Shephard a.shephard@ifs.org.uk Institute

More information

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto alex.edwards@rotman.utoronto.ca Adrian Kubata University of Münster, Germany adrian.kubata@wiwi.uni-muenster.de

More information

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4691 How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment Jan C. van Ours Sander Tuit January 2010 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure Christian Dustmann Johannes Ludsteck Uta Schönberg This Version: July 2008 This appendix consists of three parts. Section 1 compares alternative methods

More information

The Child and Dependent Care Credit: Impact of Selected Policy Options

The Child and Dependent Care Credit: Impact of Selected Policy Options The Child and Dependent Care Credit: Impact of Selected Policy Options Margot L. Crandall-Hollick Specialist in Public Finance Gene Falk Specialist in Social Policy December 5, 2017 Congressional Research

More information

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, NBER, PIER March 2018 Pushing the Frontier of Central Bank s Macro Modeling Preliminaries This paper

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DISTRIBUTION OF PAYROLL AND INCOME TAX BURDENS, Andrew Mitrusi James Poterba

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DISTRIBUTION OF PAYROLL AND INCOME TAX BURDENS, Andrew Mitrusi James Poterba NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DISTRIBUTION OF PAYROLL AND INCOME TAX BURDENS, 1979-1999 Andrew Mitrusi James Poterba Working Paper 7707 http://www.nber.org/papers/w7707 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Distributional National Accounts DINA

Distributional National Accounts DINA Distributional National Accounts DINA Facundo Alvaredo Anthony B. Atkinson Thomas Piketty Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman Meeting of Providers of OECD IDD Data OECD, Paris, February 18-19, 2016 Envision a

More information

The distribution of wealth between households

The distribution of wealth between households The distribution of wealth between households Research note 11/2013 1 SOCIAL SITUATION MONITOR APPLICA (BE), ATHENS UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS (EL), EUROPEAN CENTRE FOR SOCIAL WELFARE POLICY

More information

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect The Rise of the Added Worker Effect Jochen Mankart Rigas Oikonomou February 9, 2016 Abstract We document that the added worker effect (AWE) has increased over the last three decades. We develop a search

More information

Online Appendix. income and saving-consumption preferences in the context of dividend and interest income).

Online Appendix. income and saving-consumption preferences in the context of dividend and interest income). Online Appendix 1 Bunching A classical model predicts bunching at tax kinks when the budget set is convex, because individuals above the tax kink wish to decrease their income as the tax rate above the

More information

Internet Appendix to Do the Rich Get Richer in the Stock Market? Evidence from India

Internet Appendix to Do the Rich Get Richer in the Stock Market? Evidence from India Internet Appendix to Do the Rich Get Richer in the Stock Market? Evidence from India John Y. Campbell, Tarun Ramadorai, and Benjamin Ranish 1 First draft: March 2018 1 Campbell: Department of Economics,

More information

APPENDIX FOR FIVE FACTS ABOUT BELIEFS AND PORTFOLIOS

APPENDIX FOR FIVE FACTS ABOUT BELIEFS AND PORTFOLIOS APPENDIX FOR FIVE FACTS ABOUT BELIEFS AND PORTFOLIOS Stefano Giglio Matteo Maggiori Johannes Stroebel Steve Utkus A.1 RESPONSE RATES We next provide more details on the response rates to the GMS-Vanguard

More information

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Social Situation Monitor - Glossary Active labour market policies Measures aimed at improving recipients prospects of finding gainful employment or increasing their earnings capacity or, in the case of

More information

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK Dita Eckardt London School of Economics Nattavudh Powdthavee CEP, London School of Economics and MIASER, University

More information

Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England

Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England Using the British Household Panel Survey to explore changes in housing tenure in England Tom Sefton Contents Data...1 Results...2 Tables...6 CASE/117 February 2007 Centre for Analysis of Exclusion London

More information

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM August 2015 151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H3 Tel: 613-233-8891 Fax: 613-233-8250 csls@csls.ca CENTRE FOR THE STUDY OF LIVING STANDARDS SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Emmanuel Saez March 2, 2012 What s new for recent years? Great Recession 2007-2009 During the

More information

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE I. Introduction Income disparities between males and females have been identified as one major issue in the process

More information

Linking a Dynamic CGE Model and a Microsimulation Model: Climate Change Mitigation Policies and Income Distribution in Australia*

Linking a Dynamic CGE Model and a Microsimulation Model: Climate Change Mitigation Policies and Income Distribution in Australia* Linking a Dynamic CGE Model and a Microsimulation Model: Climate Change Mitigation Policies and Income Distribution in Australia* Hielke Buddelmeyer, Nicolas Hérault, Guyonne Kalb and Mark van Zijll de

More information

Ireland's Income Distribution

Ireland's Income Distribution Ireland's Income Distribution Micheál L. Collins Introduction Judged in an international context, Ireland is a high income country. The 2014 United Nations Human Development Report ranks Ireland as having

More information

How Do Public Pensions Affect Retirement Incomes and Expenditures? Evidence over Five Decades from Canada. January 2014

How Do Public Pensions Affect Retirement Incomes and Expenditures? Evidence over Five Decades from Canada. January 2014 How Do Public Pensions Affect Retirement Incomes and Expenditures? Evidence over Five Decades from Canada January 2014 Kevin Milligan Vancouver School of Economics and NBER kevin.milligan@ubc.ca David

More information

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot Online Theory Appendix Not for Publication) Equilibrium in the Complements-Pareto Case

More information

Comparing Estimates of Family Income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the March Current Population Survey,

Comparing Estimates of Family Income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the March Current Population Survey, Comparing Estimates of Family Income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the March Current Population Survey, 1968-1999. Elena Gouskova and Robert F. Schoeni Institute for Social Research University

More information

Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk

Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk 17 June 2013 Stephen Gray and Jason Hall, SFG Consulting Contents 1. PREPARATION OF THIS REPORT... 1 2. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 2 3. INTRODUCTION...

More information

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013 Percent 70 60 50 Shares of Before-Tax Income and Federal Taxes, by Before-Tax Income

More information

Introducing Family Tax Splitting in Germany: How Would It Affect the Income Distribution, Work Incentives and Household Welfare?

Introducing Family Tax Splitting in Germany: How Would It Affect the Income Distribution, Work Incentives and Household Welfare? Introducing Family Tax Splitting in Germany: How Would It Affect the Income Distribution, Work Incentives and Household Welfare? Viktor Steiner and Katharina Wrohlich DIW Berlin Motivation In Germany,

More information

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK Fiscal Studies (1996) vol. 17, no. 2, pp. 1-36 The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK SUSAN HARKNESS 1 I. INTRODUCTION Rising female labour-force participation has been one of the most striking

More information

Regression Discontinuity and. the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing

Regression Discontinuity and. the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing Regression Discontinuity and the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing Internet Appendix Yen-Cheng Chang Harrison Hong Inessa Liskovich In this Appendix we show results which were left out of the paper

More information