Regularities. December 2006

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Regularities. December 2006"

Transcription

1 Preliminary and incomplete Not for quotation Comments welcome Regularities Laura X. L. Liu School of Business and Management Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Toni M. Whited School of Business University of Wisconsin Madison Lu Zhang Stephen M. Ross School of Business University of Michigan and NBER December 2006 Abstract The q theory of investment implies a purely characteristic-based expected-return model. Under constant return to scale, stock return equals investment return, which is tied directly with firm characteristics. We use a two-period example to show analytically that the investment-return equation is consistent with the relations of average returns with book-to-market, investment-toasset, and earnings surprises. Using GMM, we estimate the q-theoretic expected return model by minimizing the differences between average stock returns in the data and average unlevered investment returns. Our model captures quantitatively the average returns of portfolios sorted on investment-to-asset and on size and book-to-market, including the small-stock value premium. The model is also partially successful in matching the post-earnings-announcement drift and its higher magnitude in small firms. Finance Department, School of Business and Management, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Kowloon, Hong Kong, tel: (852) , and fnliu@ust.hk. Department of Finance, School of Business, University of Wisconsin at Madison, 975 University Avenue, Madison WI 53706; tel: (608) , fax: (608) , and twhited@bus.wisc.edu. Finance Department, Stephen M. Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, 701 Tappan Street, E 7605 Bus Ad, Ann Arbor MI ; and NBER, tel: (734) , and zhanglu@bus.umich.edu. For helpful comments, we thank Nick Barberis, David Brown, V. V. Chari, Rick Green, Burton Hollifield, Patrick Kehoe, Narayana Kocherlakota, Leonid Kogan, Owen Lamont, Ellen McGrattan, Antonio Mello, Mark Ready, Bryan Routledge, Martin Schneider, Masako Ueda, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, the Yale School of Management, the University of Wisconsin, Madison, Carnegie-Mellon University, the Society of Economic Dynamics Annual Meetings in 2006, and the 2006 UBC Summer Finance Conference. Some of the theoretical results have previously been circulated in NBER working paper #11322 entitled Anomalies. All remaining errors are our own.

2 1 Introduction The empirical finance literature has documented tantalizing relations between future stock returns and firm characteristics. As surveyed, for example, in Fama (1998) and Schwert (2003), traditional asset pricing models have failed to explain many of these relations, which have therefore been dubbed anomalies. Several prominent studies, such as Shleifer (2000) and Barberis and Thaler (2003), have interpreted this failure as prima facia evidence against the efficient markets hypothesis. We use the neoclassical q theory of investment to provide the microfoundation for time-varying expected returns in the cross section, thus providing a structural framework for understanding these anomalies and for capturing them empirically. As first shown by Cochrane (1991), under constant return to scale, stock returns equal investment returns, which are tied to firm characteristics through the first-order conditions for optimal investment. We use these optimality conditions to show how expected returns vary in the cross section with firm characteristics, corporate policies, and events. In particular, we show that q theory can give rise to the following anomalies. The first is the investment anomaly, that is, the negative correlation between the investment-to-assets ratio and average returns, especially for firms with higher operating income-to-asset ratios. The second is the value anomaly, that is, value stocks (with high book-to-market ratios) earn higher average returns than growth stocks (with low book-to-market ratios), especially for small firms. The third is the post-earnings-announcement drift anomaly, that is, firms with positive earnings surprises earn higher average returns than firms with negative earnings surprises, especially for small firms. The intuition behind the way in which q theory generates these anomalies is most transparent in a simple two-period example. The investment return from time t to t+1 equals the ratio of the marginal profit of investment at t+1 divided by the marginal cost of investment at t. This definition implies two potential explanations for observed asset pricing anomalies. First, optimal investment implied by q theory produces a negative relation between investment and expected returns. The ratio of investment to assets increases with the net present value of capital, and the net present value 2

3 decreases with the cost of capital; that is, the expected return. The investment anomaly occurs because a low cost of capital implies high net present value, which in turn implies high investment. The value anomaly results from the same driving force because investment is an increasing function of marginal q, which is closely linked to the market-to-book ratio. The negative investment-return relation then implies a negative relation between market-to-book and expected returns. Whereas the first explanation operates through the denominator of the investment return, the second operates through the numerator. The marginal product of capital at time t + 1 in the numerator of the investment return equation drives the post-earnings-announcement drift in our model. Under constant return to scale, the marginal product of capital equals the average product of capital, which in turn equals profitability plus the rate of capital depreciation. This link suggests a positive relation between expected profitability and expected returns, all else equal. Because profitability is highly persistent and because earnings surprises and profitability are highly correlated, our model therefore predicts that earnings surprises are positively correlated with expected returns. Intriguingly, our economic explanations of anomalies do not involve risk directly, even though we do not assume over- or under-reaction, as in Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998). Because we derive expected returns from the optimality conditions of the firm, the stochastic discount factor and its covariances with stock returns do not enter the expected-return determination. Characteristics are sufficient statistics for expected returns, even in efficient markets. This result clearly helps interpret the debate on covariances versus characteristics in empirical finance in, for example, Daniel and Titman (1997) and Davis, Fama, and French (2000). More importantly, we test empirically whether q theory can quantitatively capture asset pricing anomalies. We test a purely characteristic-based, structural expected return model derived from the value maximization problem underlying q theory. To facilitate empirical tests of the theory, we derive new analytical relations between stock and investment returns after incorporating flow operating costs, leverage, and financing costs of external equity. We then use GMM to minimize the differences between the average stock returns observed in the data and the expected stock returns 3

4 implied by the model. Our data comprise several sets of testing portfolios designed to capture cross sectional variations induced by the anomalies. We examine the value anomaly in the Fama- French (1993) 25 size and book-to-market portfolios, the post-earnings-announcement drift in ten portfolios sorted by Standardized Unexpected Earnings (SUE), and the negative relation between expected returns and investment in ten portfolios sorted by the ratio of investment to assets. The q-theoretic mechanisms are empirically important. Average stock returns in the data and model-implied expected returns track each other closely across portfolios sorted by investment-toassets, and across portfolios sorted by size and book-to-market. Specifically, when we apply the benchmark model with only physical adjustment costs to the Fama-French (1993) 25 portfolios (a task comparable to that in Fama and French, 1996, Table I), the average absolute pricing error is only 0.07% per month. The overidentification test fails to reject the null hypothesis that the average pricing error is zero. Further, none of the 25 alphas are significantly different from zero. The small-stock value strategy, in particular, carries an insignificant alpha of 0.04% per month. The model is less successful in matching average returns across the SUE portfolios. When we only use the SUE portfolios in the moment conditions, the benchmark model generates an average difference of 0.81% per month between the returns of the low and high SUE portfolios, but both extreme deciles have significant alphas of 0.21% and 0.36% per month, respectively. The model performs well for the nine double-sorted size and SUE portfolios, in which only three out of nine estimated alphas are significant. More importantly, the model-implied average return spread between the low SUE and high SUE terciles is 0.80% per month in small firms, a difference noticeably higher than the 0.14% per month difference in big firms. Unfortunately, the difference in model-implied average returns between extreme SUE portfolios largely disappears in joint estimation, in which we also ask the model to price the Fama-French (1993) 25 size and book-to-market portfolios, ten investment-to-assets portfolios, and the market portfolio. Our asset pricing tests represent a fundamental departure from traditional tests in the cross section of returns. Derived from optimality conditions, our approach differs from empirically mo- 4

5 tivated factor models, as in Fama and French (1993, 1996). In contrast to tests derived from consumption-based asset pricing (e.g., Hansen and Singleton, 1982; Lettau and Ludvigson, 2001; Bansal, Dittmar, and Lundblad, 2005), we do not use information on preferences or the stochastic discount factor. Our expected return model is based entirely on firm characteristics. In view of the empirical difficulty in estimating risk and risk premia documented in, for example, Fama and French (1997), it is perhaps not surprising that our model outperforms traditional asset pricing models in capturing anomalies. Our theoretical approach is built on Cochrane (1991), who first establishes the link between stock and investment returns. (See also Restoy and Rockinger, 1994). Cochrane (1996) uses the aggregate investment return to price the cross section of returns. Cochrane (1997) also uses the investment-return equation to explain the magnitude of the equity premium. Our contribution consists of employing the q model to address anomalies in the cross section. We also add to studies of the cross section of returns based on intertemporal models of optimal firm behavior, as in Berk, Green, and Naik (1999), Carlson, Fischer, and Giammarino (2004), and Zhang (2005). Our work differs because we do structural estimation on closed-form estimating equations. Our work is also related to the q theory of investment originated by Brainard and Tobin (1968) and Tobin (1969). On a theoretical level the equivalence between stock and investment returns is an algebraic restatement of the equivalence between marginal q and average q, demonstrated in Lucas and Prescott (1971) and Hayashi (1982). Empirically, our work is connected with the investment Euler equation tests designed to understand the investment behavior (e.g., Shapiro, 1986; Whited, 1992). Our extention of this approch consists of restating the investment Euler equation in terms of stock returns and of testing it using data on the cross section of returns. 2 A Two-Period Example We follow Cochrane (1991, 1996) to link expected returns to characteristics using the q theory. 5

6 2.1 The Setup Firms use capital and a vector of costlessly adjustable inputs to produce a perishable output good. Firms choose the levels of these inputs each period to maximize their operating profits, defined as revenues minus the expenditures on these inputs. Taking the operating profits as given, firms then choose optimal investment to maximize their market value. There are only two periods, t and t+1. Firm j starts with capital stock k jt, invests in period t, and produces in both t and t+1. The firm exits at the end of period t+1 with a liquidation value of (1 δ j )k jt+1, in which δ j is the firm-specific rate of capital depreciation. Let π jt =π(k jt,x jt ) denote the operating profit at time t, in which x jt is a vector of exogenous shocks including aggregate and firm-specific productivity shocks. We assume that operating profits exhibit constant return to scale, that is, π(k jt,x jt )=π 1 (k jt,x jt )k jt, in which numerical subscripts denote partial derivatives. The expression π 1 (k jt,x jt ) therefore denotes the marginal product of capital.. The law of motion for capital is k jt+1 = i jt + (1 δ j )k jt, in which i jt denotes capital investment. We use the one-period time-to-build convention: capital goods invested today only become productive at the beginning of next period. Investment incurs quadratic adjustment costs given by θ(i jt,k jt ) = (a/2)(i jt /k jt ) 2 k jt, in which a > 0 is a constant parameter. The function θ (i jt,k jt ) is increasing and convex in i jt, decreasing in k jt, and exhibits constant return to scale, that is, θ(i jt,k jt )=θ 1 (i jt,k jt )i jt + θ 2 (i jt,k jt )k jt. Let m t+1 be the stochastic discount factor from time t to t+1, which is correlated with the aggregate component of x jt+1. Firm j choose i jt to maximize the market value of equity: Payout/external equity at period t {}}{ max π(k jt,x jt ) i jt a [ ] Cash flow at period t+1 2 ijt {}}{ k jt + E t m t+1 π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j )k jt+1 {i jt } 2 k jt } {{ } Cum dividend market value of equity at period t+1 (1) The market value contains two parts. The first is net cash flow over period t, which is denoted by π(k jt,x jt ) i jt (a/2)(i jt /k jt ) 2 k jt. Firms use operating profits π(k jt,x jt ) to pay investment costs, 6

7 which include both purchase costs, i jt, and adjustment costs, (a/2)(i jt /k jt ) 2 k jt. If net cash flow is positive, firms distribute it to shareholders (payout). Otherwise, negative net cash flows consist of cash inflows from shareholders (external equity). The second part of the market value contains the discounted value of cash flow from period t+1, given by the sum of operating profits π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) and the liquidation value of the capital stock at the end of t+1. Taking the partial derivative of equation (1) with respect to i jt yields the first-order condition: Marginal cost of investment at period t {}} [ ]{ ijt 1 + a k jt = E t m t+1 Marginal benefit of investment at period t+1 {}}{ π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j ) } {{ } marginal q at period t (2) Equation (2) says that the marginal cost of investment must equal the marginal benefit (commonly dubbed marginal q). To generate one additional unit of capital at the beginning of next period, k jt+1, firms must pay the unit price of capital (normalized to be one) and the marginal adjustment cost, a(i jt /k jt ). The next-period marginal benefit of this additional unit of capital includes the marginal product of capital, π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ), and the liquidation value (net of depreciation), 1 δ j. Discounting this next-period benefit using the pricing kernel m t+1 yields the marginal q at time t. To derive asset pricing implications of the two-period q-theoretic model, we follow Cochrane (1991) and divide both sides of equation (2) by the marginal cost of investment to obtain: E t [m t+1 r I jt+1 ] = 1 (3) in which r I jt+1 denotes the investment return, defined as: r I jt+1 }{{} Investment return from period t to t+1 Marginal benefit of investment at period t+1 {}}{ π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j ) 1 + a(i jt /k jt ) }{{} Marginal cost of investment at period t (4) The investment return, rjt+1 I, is therefore the ratio of the marginal benefit of investment at period t+1 divided by the marginal cost of investment at period t. 7

8 Under constant return to scale, stock returns equal investment returns. To derive this result, we note from equation (1) that we can define the ex-dividend equity value at period t, denoted p jt, as: p jt }{{} Ex dividend equity value at period t = E t m t+1 Cash flow at period t+1 {}}{ π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j )k jt+1, (5) that is, p jt equals the cum-dividend equity value the maximum in equation (1) minus the net cash flow over period t. We can now define stock returns as follows: rjt+1 S = }{{} Stock return from period t to t+1 Cash flow at period t+1 {}}{ π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j )k jt+1, (6) E t [m t+1 [π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j )k jt+1 ]] }{{} Ex dividend equity value at period t in which the numerator is the cash flow at period t+1 (the ex-dividend market value of equity is zero). Dividing both the numerator and the denominator of equation (6) by k jt+1 yields: r S jt+1 = π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j ) E t [m t+1 [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j )]] = π 1(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) + (1 δ j ) = r I 1 + a(i jt /k jt ) jt+1, (7) in which the second equation follows from the first-order condition given by equation (2). Because of this equivalence, in what follows, we use r jt+1 to denote both stock and investment returns. 2.2 Economic Mechanisms Admittedly, the prediction in equation (7) that stock returns equal investment returns in realizations is restrictive; for example, Cochrane (1991) shows that aggregate investment returns are much less volatile than aggregate stock returns. However, to provide economic intuition on the driving forces of expected returns, we only use the restriction in expectations: E t [r jt+1 ] = }{{} Expected return Expected marginal product of capital {}}{ E t [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 )] + 1 δ j. (8) 1 + a(i jt /k jt ) }{{} Marginal cost of investment In this regard, we follow Cochrane (1997), who shows that average aggregate equity returns are well within the range of plausible parameters for average aggregate investment returns. 8

9 Equation (8) is useful for interpreting anomalies because it ties expected returns directly to characteristics. The equation implies that there are three firm-specific determinants of expected returns: the investment-to-assets ratio, i jt /k jt, the expected marginal product of capital, E t [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 )], and the depreciation rate, δ j. We discuss each below The Value Anomaly Holding constant the expected marginal product of capital and the rate of capital depreciation, equation (8) implies the negative relation between expected returns and investment-to-assets in Cochrane (1991). In the capital budgeting language of Brealey, Myers, and Allen (2006, Chapter 6), investment-to-assets increases with the net present value of capital. All else equal, the net present value decreases with the cost of capital, which is precisely the expected return. Given expected cash flows, high costs of capital imply low net present value, which in turn implies low investment-to-assets ratios. Further, a low cost of capital implies high net present value, which in turn implies high investment-to-assets ratios. Adjustment costs are a crucial ingredient for our model. From equation (8), the partial derivative of expected returns with respect to the investment-to-assets ratio is: 1 E t [r jt+1 ] (i jt /k jt ) = a(e t[π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 )] + 1 δ j ) [1 + a(i jt /k jt )] 2 < 0. (9) The negative sign generates the negative relation between investment and expected returns, as illustrated in Figure 1. However, without adjustment costs, a = 0, and expected returns are independent of investment, E t [r jt+1 ]/ (i jt /k jt ) = 0. More importantly, Figure 1 shows that similar to high investment-to-asset firms, growth firms have low expected returns; and similar to low investment-to-asset firms, value firms have high 1 Because of the law of motion for capital, k jt+1 = [i jt/k jt + (1 δ j)]k jt, we should also worry about the effect of investment at period t on the capital at the beginning of period t+1. Let π 11(k jt+1, x jt+1) denote the second order partial derivative of π(k jt+1, x jt+1) with respect to k jt+1. We have: E t[r jt+1] (i jt/k jt) xjt+1)] + 1 δj) Et[π11(kjt+1, xjt+1)kjt] a (Et[π1(kjt+1, xjt+1)] + 1 δj) = a(et[π1(kjt+1, + = [1 + a(i jt/k jt)] a(i jt/k jt) [1 + a(i jt/k jt)] 2 The term involving π 11(k jt+1, x jt+1) drops out because π 11(k jt+1, x jt+1) = 0 (constant returns to scale). 9

10 expected returns. This pattern follows directly from a one-to-one mapping between investment-toassets and market-to-book. Equations (2) and (5) imply that [ ] ijt q jt = 1 + a }{{} k jt Marginal q = Average Q {}}{ p jt k jt+1 Q jt, (10) that is, marginal q = average Q. It follows that growth firms invest more and earn lower expected returns, and that value firms invest less and earn higher expected returns. Formally, equation (10) implies that (i jt /k jt )/ Q jt = 1/a > 0. The value anomaly follows because the chain rule of partial derivative implies that E t [r jt+1 ]/ Q jt = [ E t [rjt+1 S ]/ (i jt/k jt )][ (i jt /k jt )/ Q jt ] < 0. To show that the value anomaly is stronger in small firms, we need a few more lines of algebra. The main driving force is the convexity of the investment-return relation. From equation (9): 2 E t [r jt+1 ] (i jt /k jt ) 2 = 2a2 [E t [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 )] + 1 δ j ] [1 + a(i jt /k jt )] 3 > 0. (11) We also need (i jt /k jt )/ p jt > 0. However, equation (10) implies that p jt = [1+a(i jt /k jt )](i jt /k jt + 1 δ)k jt and p jt / (i jt /k jt ) = q jt k jt +ak jt+1 > 0. The interpretation of p jt / (i jt /k jt ) > 0 is that high q firms invest more than low q firms (e.g., Fama and French 1995; Xing 2006). 2 The stronger value anomaly in small firms says that E t [r jt+1 ]/ Q jt / p jt < 0. In our model: E t [r jt+1 ] Q jt / p jt = 2 E t [r jt+1 ] Q jt p jt = 1 2 E t [r jt+1 ] (i jt /k jt ) a (i jt /k jt ) 2 < 0, (12) p jt in which the second equality follows from the chain rule and the inequality follows from the convexity of the investment-return relation and p jt / (i jt /k jt ) > 0 (high q firms invest more than low q firms). 2 p jt/ (i jt/k jt) > 0 does not imply that big firms invest more than small firms. Although firm size means market capitalization in empirical finance (e.g., Fama and French 1993), firm size means physical size in macroeconomics and in our model. For example, Evans (1987) and Hall (1987) show that small firms invest more and grow faster than big firms, using the logarithm of employment as the measure of firm size. The measure corresponds to log(k jt) in our model. More important, from equation (2). i jt/k jt is independent of k jt in our model (constant return to scale). 10

11 2.2.2 Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift The relation between earnings and average returns arises naturally in our neoclassical model. Intuitively, the marginal product of capital in the numerator of the expected-return equation (8) is closely related to earnings. Accordingly, expected returns increase with earnings. The earnings-return relation persists even without capital adjustment costs. In this sense, the earnings-return relation is more fundamental than the investment-return relation (and the valuereturn relation). Specifically, when a = 0, equation (8) reduces to: E t [r jt+1 ] = }{{} Expected return Expected marginal product of capital {}}{ E t [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 )] + (1 δ j ) (13) i.e., expected (net) returns equal the expected marginal product of capital minus the depreciation rate. Earnings equals operating cash flows minus the capital depreciation (the only accruals in our model). 3 Let e jt denotes earnings, then: e jt }{{} Earnings Operating cash flows {}}{ π(k jt,x jt ) δ j k jt }{{} Capital depreciation (14) We can now link expected returns to expected accounting profitability. Because constant return to scale, equation (13) becomes: E t [r jt+1 ] = }{{} Expected return Average product of capital { [ }} ]{ πjt+1 E t k jt+1 i.e., expected returns equal expected profitability. [ ] ejt δ j = E t k jt+1 }{{} Expected profitability + 1 (15) To link expected returns further to earnings surprises, we note that profitability is highly per- 3 We assume implicitly that accruals are only used to mitigate the accounting timing and matching problems that deviate operating cash flows from earnings (e.g., Dechow 1994). In particular, we do not model earnings management. 11

12 sistent. 4 In particular, we assume that profitability follows an autoregressive process: e jt+1 [ ejt = ē(1 ρ k e ) + ρ e jt+1 k jt }{{} Expected profitability ] + Earnings surprise {}}{ ε e jt+1 (16) in which ē and 0 < ρ e < 1 are the long-run average and the persistence of profitability, respectively. ε e jt+1 denotes the earnings surprise. Combining equations (15) and (16) yields: E t [r jt+1 ] }{{} Expected return Profitability {[ }} ]{ ejt = ē(1 ρ e ) + ρ e k jt }{{} Expected profitability + 1 (17) Expected returns thus increase with the current-period profitability. This insight only depends on the persistence in profitability, not the specific functional form in equation (16). Plugging the one-period-lagged equation (16) into equation (17) yields: E t [r jt+1 ] }{{} Expected return [ ] Earnings surprise = ē(1 ρ e )(1 + ρ e ) + ρ 2 ejt 1 {}}{ e + ρ k e ε e t jt 1 }{{} Expected profitability + 1 (18) Expected returns therefore have a positive loading, ρ e, on earnings surprises, ε e t. The model thus predicts that the magnitude of the post-earnings-announcement drift should increase with the average persistence in firm-level profitability in the sample. But equation (18) predicts that the loading of expected returns on earnings surprises is constant across different market capitalization groups. To generate the stronger post-earnings-announcement drift in small firms, we need to introduce adjustment costs. We go back to equation (8) for this purpose. Combining equations (8) and (14), we have: E t [r jt+1 ] }{{} Expected return = Expected profitability {}}{ E t [e jt+1 /k jt+1 ] a(i jt /k jt ) }{{} Marginal cost of investment (19) 4 There is much evidence on the persistence in profitability at the portfolio level and at the firm level (e.g., Fama and French 1995, 2000). For example, Fama and French (2006) document that the current-period profitability is the strongest predictor of profitability one to three years ahead. 12

13 Therefore, controlling for the denominator that is equivalent to market-to-book, 1 + a(i jt /k jt ) = q jt = Q jt, expected returns increase with expected profitability. Empirically, Haugen and Baker (1996) and Fama and French (2006) show that, controlling for market valuation ratios, firms with high expected profitability earn higher average returns than firms with low expected profitability. More important, equation (19) implies that the loading of expected returns on the expected profitability equals 1/Q jt = k jt+1 /p jt that is inversely related to the market capitalization, p jt. 5 This prediction is consistent with Cohen, Gompers, and Vuolteenaho s (2002) evidence that the relation between expected profitability and future returns is stronger in small firms. Moreover, combining equations (14) and (8), we have: E t [r jt+1 ] }{{} Expected return = Expected profitability [ ] ejt 1 {}}{ ē(1 ρ e )(1 + ρ e ) + ρ 2 e k jt a(i jt /k jt ) }{{} Marginal cost of investment + ρ e ε e t + 1 }{{} Earnings surprise (20) Therefore, controlling for market-to-book, expected returns increase with earnings surprises, and the loading of expected returns on earnings surprises equals ρ e k jt+1 /p jt, which is inversely related to the market capitalization, p jt. This prediction is consistent with Bernard s (1993) evidence that the magnitude of the post-earnings-announcement drift is stronger in small firms The Depreciation-Return Relation Equation (8) shows that, all else equal, firms that have higher rates of capital depreciation earn lower expected returns than firms that have lower rates of capital depreciation. Our prediction on the depreciation-return relation is consistent with the theoretical results of Tuzel (2005). Using a two-sector model, Tuzel shows that firms with more structure earn higher average returns than firms with more equipment. The reason is that structure depreciates more slowly than equipment. 5 Fama and French (1992) document that the average cross-sectional correlation between book-to-market and market capitalization is

14 2.3 Characteristics-Based Asset Pricing As a fundamental departure from traditional asset pricing theory, our q-theoretic model determines expected returns entirely from firm characteristics via the first principle of investment without any information about the pricing kernel. The reason is that, m t+1, and its covariances with returns do not enter the expected-return equation (8). This insight carries over to the dynamic setting (see Proposition 1 below). Characteristics are sufficient statistics for expected returns, and investmentbased asset pricing can be developed independently from consumption-based asset pricing. 6 This practice only means that the effect of m t+1 is indirect, not irrelevant. If m t+1 is a constant, m, then equation (26) implies that the expected return E t [r jt+1 ] = 1/m, a constant uncorrelated with firm characteristics. If the correlation between m t+1 and x jt+1 is zero, i.e., the operating profits of firms are unaffected by aggregate shocks, then equation (3) implies that E t [r jt+1 ]= r ft, in which r ft 1/E t [m t+1 ] is the risk free rate. In this case, there is no cross-sectional variation in expected returns, and our results only provide time-series correlations between the risk free rate and firm characteristics. Because we study expected returns instead of expected excess returns, we do not need to specify m t+1 necessary for determining the risk free rate, and we do not need to restrict the correlation between m t+1 and x jt+1 as necessary for determining expected excess returns. More important, the characteristic-based approach is internally consistent with the traditional risk-based approach. From equation (3) and equivalence between stock and investment returns, E t [m t+1 r jt+1 ] = 1. Following Cochrane (2001, p. 19), we rewrite this equation as the beta-pricing form, E t [r jt+1 ] = r ft +β jt λ mt, in which β jt Cov t [r jt+1,m t+1 ]/Var t [m t+1 ] is the amount of risk, and λ mt Var t [m t+1 ]/E t [m t+1 ] is the price of risk, but from E t [r I jt+1 ] = E t[r S jt+1 ] = r ft +β jt λ mt, we have β jt = E t [r I jt+1 ] r ft/λ mt, which provides a one-to-one mapping between covariances and characteristics. However, apart from this mechanical link, risk only plays a secondary role in our characteristic-based determination of expected returns. 6 This approach is foretold by Rubinstein (2001, p. 23): For the most part, financial economists take the stochastic process of stock prices, the value of the firms, or dividend payments as primitive. However, to explain some anomalies, we may need to look deeper into the guts of corporate decision making to derive what the processes are. 14

15 3 The Dynamic Model We first describe the model with all equity financing. Then we add more realistic ingredients such as leverage and costly external equity. 3.1 All Equity Financing Firms use capital and a vector of costlessly adjustable inputs to produce a homogeneous output. The levels of these inputs are chosen each period to maximize operating profits, defined as revenues minus the expenditures on these inputs. Taking the operating profits as given, firms then choose optimal investment to maximize their market value. Investment involves physical costs of adjustment. Let π jt π(k jt,x jt ) denote the maximized operating profits of firm j at time t, in which k jt is the capital stock and x jt is a vector of exogenous shocks such as aggregate and firm-specific shocks to the production technology and the prices of costlessly adjusted inputs and industry- and firm-specific shocks to the demand for firm output. π(k jt,x jt ) exhibits constant return to scale. Firms that stay in production each period must incur a flow operating cost proportional to capital stock, ck jt, in which the parameter c>0 is a constant common to all firms. End-of-period capital equals investment plus beginning-of-period capital net of depreciation: k jt+1 = i jt + (1 δ jt )k jt (21) We assume that capital depreciates at an exogenous proportional rate of δ jt. This rate is firmspecific and time-varying because later we use data on capital depreciation divided by capital stock to measure the rate of depreciation in our tests. When firms invest, they incur purchase/sales costs and convex costs of physical adjustment. Purchase/sales costs are incurred when firms buy or sell uninstalled capital. When firms disinvest, the sales costs are negative, representing revenues. Convex costs of physical adjustment are nonnegative costs that are zero when i jt = 0. These costs are continuous, strictly convex in i jt, non-increasing in k jt, and differentiable with respect to i jt and k jt everywhere; and the second-order 15

16 partial derivative of the convex-cost function with respect to k jt is nonnegative. We let φ(i jt,k jt ) denote the total cost of investment that represents the sum of purchase/sale costs and convex costs of physical adjustment, and we refer to it as the augmented adjustment-cost function. φ(i jt,k jt ) satisfies φ 1 0,φ 2 0, and φ 11 >0, in which the subscript i denotes the first-order partial derivative with respect to the i th argument, and multiple subscripts denote high-order derivatives. Let q jt be the present-value multiplier associated with equation (21). We can formulate the market value of firm j, denoted v(k jt,x jt ), as follows: v(k jt,x jt ) = [ max E t {i jt+s, k jt+1+s } s=0 s=0 m t+s (π(k jt+s,x jt+s ) ck jt+s φ(i jt+s,k jt+s ) q jt+s [k jt+s+1 (1 δ jt+s )k jt+s i jt+s ]) ] (22) The first-order conditions with respect to i jt and k jt+1 are, respectively, q jt = φ 1 (i jt,k jt ) (23) q jt = E t [m t+1 [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) + (1 δ jt+1 )q jt+1 ]] (24) Combining equations (23) and (24) yields: φ 1 (i jt,k jt ) = E t [m t+1 [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) + (1 δ jt+1 )φ 1 (i jt+1,k jt+1 )]] (25) Dividing both sides by φ 1 (i jt,k jt ) yields: E t [m t+1 r I jt+1 ] = 1 (26) in which r I t+1 denotes the investment return, defined as: r I jt+1 π 1(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) + (1 δ jt+1 )φ 1 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) φ 1 (i jt,k jt ) (27) Intuitively, equation (27) says that the investment return is the ratio of the marginal benefit of investment at time t+1 divided by the marginal cost of investment at time t. The denominator, φ 1 (i jt,k jt ), is the marginal cost of investment. By optimality, it equals marginal q jt the shadow value of capital, or the expected present value of the marginal profits from investing in capital 16

17 goods. In the numerator of equation (27), π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c is the extra operating profits, net of the flow operating costs generated by the extra capital at t+1; the effect of extra capital on the augmented adjustment cost is captured by φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ); and (1 δ jt+1 )φ 1 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) is the expected present value of marginal profits evaluated at time t+1, net of depreciation. Proposition 1 (Cochrane 1991) Define the ex-dividend firm value, p jt, as p jt p(k jt,k jt+1,x jt ) = v(k jt,x jt ) π(k jt,x jt ) + ck jt + φ(i jt,k jt ) and stock return as: r S jt+1 p jt+1 + π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) ck jt+1 φ(i jt+1,k jt+1 ) p jt (28) Under constant return to scale, we have p jt = q jt k jt+1 and r S jt+1 = ri jt+1. Proof. See Appendix A. The result is first derived by Cochrane (1991) (see also Restoy and Rockinger 1994). The equivalence between stock and investment returns is an algebraic restatement of the equivalence between marginal q and average Q (e.g., Hayashi 1982). 3.2 Leverage The benchmark model assumes that all firms are entirely equity financed. If firms finance investment using both equity and debt, the investment return is the leverage-weighted average of equity return and corporate bond return. 7 For simplicity, we follow Hennessy and Whited (2005) and model only one-period debt. At the beginning of period t, firm j can choose to issue a certain amount of one-period debt, denoted b jt+1, that must be repaid at the beginning of next period. Negative b jt+1 represents cash holdings. The interest rate on b jt is r(x jt ), and is a function of the exogenous state variable, x jt, and can be stochastic. r(x jt ) can also be firm-specific because x jt contains both aggregate and firm-specific shocks. 7 This result was first established by Gomes, Yaron, and Zhang (2006) but not reported in the published paper. 17

18 We can now formulate the cum-dividend market value of equity as: v(k jt,b jt,x jt ) = max {i jt+s,k jt+s+1,b jt+s+1 } s=0 E t s=0 m t+s[π(k jt+s,x jt+s ) ck jt+s φ(i jt+s,k jt+s ) + b jt+s+1 r (x jt+s ) b jt+s q jt+s (k jt+s+1 (1 δ jt+s )k jt+s i jt+s )] The optimality conditions with respect to i jt, k jt+1, and b jt+1 are, respectively: (29) q jt = φ 1 (i jt,k jt ) (30) q jt = E t [m t+1 [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) + (1 δ jt+1 )q jt+1 ]] (31) 1 = E t [m t+1 r (x jt+1 )] (32) It follows that E t [m t+1 rjt+1 I ]=1, and E t[m t+1 rjt+1 B ]=1, in which the investment return is defined as: r I jt+1 π 1(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) + (1 δ jt+1 )φ 1 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ) φ 1 (i jt,k jt ) (33) and the corporate bond return is defined as: r B jt+1 r (x jt+1 ) (34) Proposition 2 (Gomes, Yaron, and Zhang 2006) Define the ex-dividend equity value as: p(k jt,b jt,x jt ) v(k jt,b jt,x jt ) π(k jt,x jt ) + ck jt + φ(i jt,k jt ) b jt+1 + r (x jt )b jt and r S jt+1 [p jt+1 + π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) ck jt+1 φ(i jt+1,k jt+1 ) + b jt+2 r(x jt+1 )b jt+1 ]/p jt as stock returns. Under constant return to scale, q jt k jt+1 = p(k jt,b jt,x jt ) + b jt+1 (35) More important, the investment return is the leverage-weighted average of stock and bond returns: r I jt+1 = ν jt r B jt+1 + (1 ν jt )r S jt+1 (36) in which ν jt is the market leverage ratio: ν jt b jt+1 /[p(k jt,b jt,x jt ) + b jt+1 ]. 18

19 Proof. See Appendix A. Equation (36) says that the investment return is the leverage-weighted average of stock returns and bond returns. Although we make some simplifying assumptions to derive this equation, it is likely to hold under more general conditions given its well-known application in capital budgeting (e.g., Grinblatt and Titman 2001, p. 381). 3.3 Costly External Equity The benchmark framework assumes that firms can finance capital investment using external equity costlessly. In reality, issuing equity is often costly (e.g., Smith 1977; Altinkilic and Hansen 2000; Hennessy and Whited 2006). To capture the equity financing costs, we let ψ(o jt,k jt ) denote the financing-cost function of issuing equity, in which o jt is the amount of financing, o jt [φ(i jt,k jt ) + ck jt π(k jt,x jt )]1 o jt (37) and in which 1 o jt 1 {φ(i jt,k jt )+ck jt π(k jt,x jt ) 0} is the indicator function that takes the value of one if the firm uses outside equity and zero otherwise. We assume that the financing-cost function is increasing, ψ 1 >0, convex, ψ 11 >0, exhibits economies of scale, ψ 2 0 and constant return to scale: ψ(o jt,k jt ) = ψ 1 (o jt,k jt )o jt + ψ 2 (o jt,k jt )k jt (38) v(k jt,x jt ) = We can now formulate the cum-dividend market value of equity as: max {i jt+s, k jt+s+1 } s=0 E t [ s=0 m t+s[π(k jt+s,x jt+s ) ck jt+s φ(i jt+s,k jt+s ) ψ(o jt+s,k jt+s ) q jt+s [k jt+s+1 (1 δ jt+s )k jt+s i jt+s ]] ] (39) The optimality conditions with respect to i jt and k jt+1 are, respectively: q jt = φ 1 (i jt,k jt )[1 + ψ 1 (o jt,k jt )1 o jt] [ [ (π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ q jt = E t m 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ))(1 + ψ 1 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1 ) t+1 ψ 2 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1 + (1 δ jt+1)q jt+1 ]] 19

20 Combining the two equations yields E t [m t+1 rjt+1 I ]=1, in which the investment return is: r I jt+1 = [ (π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ))(1 + ψ 1 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1 ) ψ 2 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o t+1 + (1 δ jt+1)φ 1 (i jt+1,k jt+1 )(1 + ψ 1 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1 ) φ 1 (i jt,k jt )[1 + ψ 1 (o jt,k jt )1 o jt ] (40) ] The investment return in equation (40) is still the ratio of the marginal benefits of investment evaluated at period t + 1 divided by the marginal costs of investment at period t. Increasing one unit of capital entails marginal purchase/sales and physical adjustment costs that sum up to φ 1 (i jt,k jt ). If this investment is partially financed by external equity, its marginal financing cost is then ψ 1 (o jt,k jt ) o jt / i jt = ψ 1 (o jt,k jt )φ 1 (i jt,k jt ). Adding all three parts of the marginal cost yields the denominator in equation (40). The numerator of equation (40) contains three terms. The interpretation of the first term, π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 ), is the same as that in the benchmark model. If the firm issues external equity at t+1, then the marginal effect of the extra unit of capital on the amount of financing costs is ψ 1 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1 o jt+1/ k jt+1 = [π 1 (k jt+1,x jt+1 ) c φ 2 (i jt+1,k jt+1 )]ψ 1 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1. The extra unit of capital also lowers financing costs because of economies of scale. This benefit is captured by ψ 2 (o jt+1,k jt+1 )1 o jt+1. At the end of period t+1, the firm is left with 1 δ jt+1 units of capital net of depreciation. This capital is worth marginal q evaluated at time t+1, which equals the marginal costs of investment at that time. Proposition 3 Define the ex-dividend market value of equity, p jt, as p jt p(k jt,k jt+1,x jt ) = v(k jt,x jt ) π(k jt,x jt ) + ck jt + φ(i jt,k jt ) + ψ(o jt,k jt ) and stock return as r S jt+1 [p jt+1 + π(k jt+1,x jt+1 ) ck jt+1 φ(i jt+1,k jt+1 ) ψ(o jt+1,k jt+1 )]/p jt. If the operating-profit, the adjustment-cost, and the financing-cost functions all exhibit constant return to scale, then p jt = q jt k jt+1 and r S jt+1 =ri jt+1, in which ri jt+1 is given by equation (40). Proof. See Appendix A. It is tempting to incorporate time-to-build into the model. Time-to-build says that multiple periods are required to build new capital projects, instead of the one-period convention embedded 20

21 in the standard capital accumulation equation (21). Theoretically, several studies have demonstrated the importance of time-to-build in driving business cycle fluctuations (e.g., Kydland and Prescott 1982). Empirically, Lamont (2000) shows that investment plans can predict excess stock returns better than actual aggregate investment, probably because of investment lags. However, the analytical link between the stock and investment returns breaks down under time-to-build. The reason is that the investment return measures the trade-off between the marginal benefits and the marginal costs of new investment projects. In contrast, the stock return is the return to the entire firm that derives its market value not only from the new but also from the old incomplete projects. Detailed derivations are not reported but are available upon request. 4 Empirical Methodology Our chief goal in this section is to evaluate how well the economic mechanisms developed in Section 2 can quantitatively explain the anomalies in the data. Section 4.1 outlines the design of the benchmark test, and Section 4.2 discusses its various perturbations. 4.1 The Benchmark Specification Proposition 2 shows that the investment return is the leverage-weighted average of the stock return and the corporate bond return. We unlever the investment return in equation (36) as: r S jt+1 = ri jt+1 ν jtr B jt+1 1 ν jt. (41) Because anomalies primarily concern first moments, we therefore test the ex-ante restriction implied by equation (41): expected stock returns equal expected unlevered investment returns, that is, E t [r S jt+1 ] = E t [ r I jt+1 ν jt r B jt+1 1 ν jt We test this restriction using GMM on the following moment conditions: E [[ r S jt+1 ri jt+1 ν jtr B jt+1 1 ν jt ] ] Z t ]. (42) = 0, (43) 21

22 in which denotes the Kronecker product, and Z t is a vector of portfolio-specific and aggregate instrumental variables known at time t. Our test differs from investment-based asset pricing tests in Cochrane (1991, 1996), Balvers and Huang (2006), Gomes, Yaron, and Zhang (2006), and Whited and Wu (2006). Cochrane (1991, 1996) and Gomes et al. (2006) parameterize the pricing kernel as a linear function of aggregate investment returns constructed from macroeconomic variables. Similarly, Balvers and Huang parameterize the pricing kernel as a linear function of the Solow residual. However, firm characteristics are absent in these papers. Whited and Wu (2006) test equation (26) by assuming m t+1 is a linear combination of the Fama-French (1993) factors and by constructing firm-level investment returns. However, stock returns are absent. Our test has its roots in Cochrane (1991), who compares the time series properties of aggregate stock and investment returns. We add more ingredients into the q-theoretic framework, and use it to understand the anomalies in the cross section of returns. Although based on the same investment Euler equation, our test differs from the Euler equation tests in the investment literature (e.g., Shapiro, 1986; Whited, 1992; Love, 2003). These tests assume a constant pricing kernel, m t+1, which in turn implies that all stocks earn the risk-free rate ex ante. We do not include the quantity moment condition from equation (25) into our set of return moment conditions. Doing so requires us to make strong parametric assumptions about m t Testing Portfolios We use GMM to implement the test given by equation (46) on portfolios sorted on anomaly-related characteristics. We use portfolio-level data two reasons. First, as pointed out in Whited (1998), simple versions of investment Euler equations are almost always strongly rejected at the firm level. The reason is that real investment is lumpy at the firm level, especially in small firms. To capture lumpy investment, we can incorporate fixed costs, but we lose the differentiability of the adjustment-cost function, φ(i jt,k jt ), at the point where the investment, i jt, equals zero. Second, and more importantly, asset pricing anomalies are often documented at the portfolio level, so it is 22

23 natural to conduct our tests using portfolios. We use 55 testing portfolios: the Fama-French 25 size and book-to-market portfolios; ten portfolios sorted on the investment-to-assets ratio; ten portfolios sorted on Standardized Unexpected Earnings, or SUE; nine portfolios sorted on size and SUE; and the aggregate stock-market portfolio. Our choice of testing portfolios captures a wide array of anomalies. We include book-to-market and SUE portfolios because the value anomaly and post-earnings-announcement drift are arguably two of the most celebrated anomalies (e.g., Fama and French 1992, 1993; Bernard and Thomas 1989, 1990). We include the investment-to-assets portfolios because the q-theory explanation of the value anomaly works primarily though capital investment. We also include the aggregate market portfolio to facilitate comparison with Cochrane (1991), who essentially tests the implication that the aggregate stock return equals the aggregate investment return Bond Yields Because firm-level corporate bond data are rather limited, and because few or none of the firms in several portfolios have corporate bond ratings, we use the Baa-rated bond yield as rjt+1 B in equation (43) for all portfolios. Although simplistic, this strategy avoids the use of firm-level bond return data that have a sample size much smaller than that for firm-level stock return data. Moreover, asset pricing anomalies are mostly documented for equity returns. Assuming no cross-sectional variations in average bond returns across anomaly-related portfolios therefore serves as a natural first cut Instrumental Variables Our list of instrumental variables includes a vector of ones and three portfolio-specific variables: investment-to-assets, sales-to-capital, and book-to-market. To construct portfolio-level investmentto-assets ratios, we divide the sum of investments for all the firms in the portfolio by the sum of their capital stocks. We use similar procedures to construct all portfolio-level characteristics. We also use in the list of instrumental variables a vector of macroeconomic variables that include the dividend yield, the default premium, the term premium, and the short-term interest rate. 23

24 These conditioning variables are commonly used to predict future stock market returns (e.g., Fama and French 1989; Ferson and Harvey 1991) Functional Forms We follow the empirical investment Euler equation literature in specifying the marginal product of capital, π 1 (k jt,x jt ), and the adjustment-cost function, φ(i jt,k jt ). We first need to relate the unobservable marginal product of capital to observables. As shown in Love (2003), if firms have a Cobb-Douglas production function with constant returns to scale, the marginal product of capital of portfolio j is given by: π 1 (k jt,x jt ) = κ y jt k jt, (44) in which y jt denotes sales, and κ denotes the capital share. Equation (44) assumes that the shocks to the operating profits, x jt, are reflected in the realizations of sales. To parameterize the adjustment-cost function, we follow Whited (1998) and Whited and Wu (2006) and use a flexible functional form that is linearly homogeneous but allows for nonlinearity in the marginal adjustment-cost function: N φ ( ) φ(i jt,k jt ) = i jt + 1 n n a ijt n k jt, (45) k jt n=2 in which a n,n=2,...,n φ are coefficients to be estimated, and N φ is a truncation parameter that sets the highest power of i jt /k jt in the expansion. If N φ = 2, then equation (45) reduces to the standard quadratic adjustment-cost function. To determine N φ, we follow Whited and Wu (2006) and use the test developed by Newey and West (1987). First, we choose a high starting value for N φ and estimate the model. Next, using the same optimal weighting matrix, we estimate a sequence of restricted models for progressively lower values of N φ, in which the corresponding coefficient, a Nφ +1, is set to zero. The final value for N φ is then the highest one for which the exclusion restriction on the parameter a Nφ +1 is not 24

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES REGULARITIES. Laura X. L. Liu Toni Whited Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES REGULARITIES. Laura X. L. Liu Toni Whited Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES REGULARITIES Laura X. L. Liu Toni Whited Lu Zhang Working Paper 13024 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13024 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Testing the q-theory of Anomalies

Testing the q-theory of Anomalies Testing the q-theory of Anomalies Toni M. Whited 1 Lu Zhang 2 1 University of Wisconsin at Madison 2 University of Rochester, University of Michigan, and NBER Carnegie Mellon University, May 2006 Whited

More information

Testing the q-theory of Anomalies

Testing the q-theory of Anomalies Testing the q-theory of Anomalies Toni M. Whited School of Business University of Wisconsin-Madison Lu Zhang William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration University of Rochester and NBER

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ANOMALIES. Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ANOMALIES. Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ANOMALIES Lu Zhang Working Paper 11322 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11322 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May 2005 I acknowledge

More information

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: Working Paper Costly External Equity: Implications for Asset Pricing Anomalies Dongmei Li Assistant Professor of Finance Rady School of Management University of California at San Diego Erica X. N. Li Assistant

More information

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern. , JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 13, 2009 Outline 1 Motivation Production-Based Asset Pricing Framework 2 Assumptions Firm s Problem Equilibrium 3 Main Findings Mechanism Testable

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1

Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Anomalies and Time-Varying Betas: A New Specification Test for Conditional Factor Models 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick January 2006 address

More information

Asset Pricing Implications of Firms Financing Constraints

Asset Pricing Implications of Firms Financing Constraints University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Finance Papers Wharton Faculty Research 2006 Asset Pricing Implications of Firms Financing Constraints Joao F. Gomes University of Pennsylvania Amir Yaron University

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters

The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters The CAPM Strikes Back? An Investment Model with Disasters Hang Bai 1 Kewei Hou 1 Howard Kung 2 Lu Zhang 3 1 The Ohio State University 2 London Business School 3 The Ohio State University and NBER Federal

More information

Investment-Based Underperformance Following Seasoned Equity Offering. Evgeny Lyandres. Lu Zhang University of Rochester and NBER

Investment-Based Underperformance Following Seasoned Equity Offering. Evgeny Lyandres. Lu Zhang University of Rochester and NBER Investment-Based Underperformance Following Seasoned Equity Offering Evgeny Lyandres Rice University Le Sun University of Rochester Lu Zhang University of Rochester and NBER University of Texas at Austin

More information

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: = = = = = = = Working Paper Financially Constrained Stock Returns Dmitry Livdan Mays Business School Texas A&M University Horacio Sapriza Rutgers Business School Rutgers University Lu Zhang Stephen M.

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Does the Investment-Based Model Explain the Value Premium? Evidence from Investment Euler Equations

Does the Investment-Based Model Explain the Value Premium? Evidence from Investment Euler Equations Does the Investment-Based Model Explain the Value Premium? Evidence from Investment Euler Equations Stefanos Delikouras Robert F. Dittmar March 20 Abstract We empirically investigate the ability of stochastic

More information

Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM

Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM Andrei S. Gonçalves 1 Chen Xue 2 Lu Zhang 3 1 UNC 2 University of Cincinnati 3 Ohio State and NBER PBCSF November 21, 218 Introduction Theme

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation

Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation Erica X.N. Li and Laura X.L. Liu March 15, 2010 Abstract We augment a q-theory model with intangible assets where

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information

Lecture Notes. Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 920: Theory of Finance The Ohio State University Autumn and NBER. 1 The Ohio State University

Lecture Notes. Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 920: Theory of Finance The Ohio State University Autumn and NBER. 1 The Ohio State University Lecture Notes Li and Zhang (2010, J. of Financial Economics): Does Q-Theory with Investment Frictions Explain Anomalies in the Cross-Section of Returns? Lu Zhang 1 1 The Ohio State University and NBER

More information

Department of Finance Working Paper Series

Department of Finance Working Paper Series NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LEONARD N. STERN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Department of Finance Working Paper Series FIN-03-005 Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch, Jessica Wachter

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation. November 1, 2010

Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation. November 1, 2010 Intangible Assets and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns: Evidence from Structural Estimation November 1, 2010 1 Abstract The relation between a firm s stock return and its intangible investment ratio and asset

More information

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption Problem Set 3 Thomas Philippon April 19, 2002 1 Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption The goal of the question is to derive the formulas on p13 of Topic 2. This is a partial equilibrium analysis

More information

A Labor-Augmented Investment-Based Asset Pricing Model

A Labor-Augmented Investment-Based Asset Pricing Model A Labor-Augmented Investment-Based Asset Pricing Model Frederico Belo Carlson School of Management University of Minnesota Lu Zhang Stephen M. Ross School of Business University of Michigan and NBER September

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle?

Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch New York University and NBER Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania and NBER First Version: 15 November 2002 Current Version:

More information

Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM

Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM Andrei S. Gonçalves 1 Chen Xue 2 Lu Zhang 3 1 UNC 2 University of Cincinnati 3 Ohio State and NBER BUSFIN 82 Ohio State, Autumn 218 Introduction

More information

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Leonid Kogan 1 Dimitris Papanikolaou 2 1 MIT and NBER 2 Northwestern University Boston, June 5, 2009 Kogan,

More information

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Tolga Cenesizoglu March 1, 2016 Cenesizoglu Return Decomposition & the Business Cycle March 1, 2016 1 / 54 Introduction Stock prices depend on investors expectations

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MARKET TIMING. Erica X. N. Li Dmitry Livdan Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MARKET TIMING. Erica X. N. Li Dmitry Livdan Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPTIMAL MARKET TIMING Erica X. N. Li Dmitry Livdan Lu Zhang Working Paper 12014 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12014 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics Ian Dew-Becker and Stefano Giglio Duke Fuqua and Chicago Booth 11/27/13 Dew-Becker and Giglio (Duke and Chicago) Frequency-domain asset pricing

More information

Does the Investment Model Explain Value and Momentum Simultaneously?

Does the Investment Model Explain Value and Momentum Simultaneously? Does the Investment Model Explain Value and Momentum Simultaneously? Andrei S. Gonçalves 1 Chen Xue 2 Lu Zhang 3 1 The Ohio State University 2 University of Cincinnati 3 The Ohio State University and NBER

More information

The Value Premium. Lu Zhang ABSTRACT. Costly reversibility and countercyclical price of risk cause assets in place to be harder to

The Value Premium. Lu Zhang ABSTRACT. Costly reversibility and countercyclical price of risk cause assets in place to be harder to Forthcoming in the Journal of Finance. The Value Premium Lu Zhang ABSTRACT The value anomaly arises naturally in the neoclassical framework with rational expectations. Costly reversibility and countercyclical

More information

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis A. Buss B. Dumas R. Uppal G. Vilkov INSEAD INSEAD, CEPR, NBER Edhec, CEPR Goethe U. Frankfurt

More information

What do frictions mean for Q-theory?

What do frictions mean for Q-theory? What do frictions mean for Q-theory? by Maria Cecilia Bustamante London School of Economics LSE September 2011 (LSE) 09/11 1 / 37 Good Q, Bad Q The empirical evidence on neoclassical investment models

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 353 January 2005 Sudden Stops and Output Drops V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Patrick J.

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM?

CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? WORKING PAPERS SERIES WP05-04 CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? Devraj Basu and Alexander Stremme CAY Revisited: Can Optimal Scaling Resurrect the (C)CAPM? 1 Devraj Basu Alexander

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits

Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits Laura X.L. Liu, Jerold B. Warner, and Lu Zhang September 2003 Abstract We study empirically the changes in economic fundamentals for firms with recent

More information

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods Prepared by Kevin Pei for The Fund @ Sprott Abstract: In this document, I will model and back test our portfolio with various proposed models. It goes without

More information

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns

Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Risk Premia and the Conditional Tails of Stock Returns Bryan Kelly NYU Stern and Chicago Booth Outline Introduction An Economic Framework Econometric Methodology Empirical Findings Conclusions Tail Risk

More information

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: = = = = = = = Working Paper Neoclassical Factors Lu Zhang Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan and NBER Long Chen Eli Broad College of Business Michigan State University Ross

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios

Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Interpreting Risk Premia Across Size, Value, and Industry Portfolios Ravi Bansal Fuqua School of Business, Duke University Robert F. Dittmar Kelley School of Business, Indiana University Christian T. Lundblad

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT. Long Chen Lu Zhang. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE STOCK MARKET AND AGGREGATE EMPLOYMENT Long Chen Lu Zhang Working Paper 15219 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15219 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue

More information

The Predictability Characteristics and Profitability of Price Momentum Strategies: A New Approach

The Predictability Characteristics and Profitability of Price Momentum Strategies: A New Approach The Predictability Characteristics and Profitability of Price Momentum Strategies: A ew Approach Prodosh Eugene Simlai University of orth Dakota We suggest a flexible method to study the dynamic effect

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Niklas Engbom June 16, 2016 Christian Moser World Bank-Bank of Spain Conference This project Shed light on drivers of earnings inequality

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Production and Inventory Behavior of Capital *

Production and Inventory Behavior of Capital * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 8-1, 95 112 (2007) Production and Inventory Behavior of Capital * Yi Wen Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis E-mail: yi.wen@stls.frb.org This paper provides

More information

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM

TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM TIME-VARYING CONDITIONAL SKEWNESS AND THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM Campbell R. Harvey and Akhtar Siddique ABSTRACT Single factor asset pricing models face two major hurdles: the problematic time-series properties

More information

Does Corporate Governance Affect the Cost of Equity Capital? Erica X. N. Li. October 11, 2010

Does Corporate Governance Affect the Cost of Equity Capital? Erica X. N. Li. October 11, 2010 Does Corporate Governance Affect the Cost of Equity Capital? Erica X. N. Li October 11, 2010 Abstract Using a dynamic asset pricing model with managerial empire-building incentives, this paper shows that

More information

Can Investment Shocks Explain Value Premium and Momentum Profits?

Can Investment Shocks Explain Value Premium and Momentum Profits? Can Investment Shocks Explain Value Premium and Momentum Profits? Lorenzo Garlappi University of British Columbia Zhongzhi Song Cheung Kong GSB First draft: April 15, 2012 This draft: December 15, 2014

More information

Introduction to Asset Pricing: Overview, Motivation, Structure

Introduction to Asset Pricing: Overview, Motivation, Structure Introduction to Asset Pricing: Overview, Motivation, Structure Lecture Notes Part H Zimmermann 1a Prof. Dr. Heinz Zimmermann Universität Basel WWZ Advanced Asset Pricing Spring 2016 2 Asset Pricing: Valuation

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

OUT OF ORDER Bolton and Scharfstein

OUT OF ORDER Bolton and Scharfstein OUT OF ORDER Bolton and Scharfstein Borrowers are disciplined by the threat of losing access to further credit. Generates Investment cash flow correlation Suppose there is a one period model where an entrepreneur

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Consumption and Asset Pricing Consumption and Asset Pricing Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Williamson s lecture notes (2006) ch5 and ch 6 Further references: Stochastic dynamic programming:

More information

Estimation and Test of a Simple Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model

Estimation and Test of a Simple Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model Estimation and Test of a Simple Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model Byoung-Kyu Min This version: January 2013 Abstract We derive and test a consumption-based intertemporal asset pricing model in which

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Carl E. Walsh March 8, 017 Contents 1 Policy Coordination 1 1.1 The Basic Model..................................... 1. Equilibrium with Coordination.............................

More information

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? Andrea Gamba Alexander J. Triantis Corporate Finance Symposium Cambridge Judge Business School September 20, 2014 What do we know

More information

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation Joel M. David Lukas Schmid David Zeke USC Duke & CEPR USC Summer 2018 1 / 18 Introduction In an ideal world, all capital should be deployed to its most

More information

Real Investment, Risk and Risk Dynamics

Real Investment, Risk and Risk Dynamics Real Investment, Risk and Risk Dynamics Ilan Cooper and Richard Priestley y February 15, 2009 Abstract The spread in average returns between low and high asset growth and investment portfolios is largely

More information

Financial Distress and the Cross Section of Equity Returns

Financial Distress and the Cross Section of Equity Returns Financial Distress and the Cross Section of Equity Returns Lorenzo Garlappi University of Texas Austin Hong Yan University of South Carolina National University of Singapore May 20, 2009 Motivation Empirical

More information

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics

Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Investment-Based Momentum Profits Laura Xiaolei Liu, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology

More information

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth The Fisher Equation and Output Growth A B S T R A C T Although the Fisher equation applies for the case of no output growth, I show that it requires an adjustment to account for non-zero output growth.

More information

Labor-Technology Substitution: Implications for Asset Pricing. Miao Ben Zhang University of Southern California

Labor-Technology Substitution: Implications for Asset Pricing. Miao Ben Zhang University of Southern California Labor-Technology Substitution: Implications for Asset Pricing Miao Ben Zhang University of Southern California Background Routine-task labor: workers performing procedural and rule-based tasks. Tax preparers

More information

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006 How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006 The Effects of Costly External Finance on Investment Still, after all of these years,

More information

What is the Expected Return on a Stock?

What is the Expected Return on a Stock? What is the Expected Return on a Stock? Ian Martin Christian Wagner November, 2017 Martin & Wagner (LSE & CBS) What is the Expected Return on a Stock? November, 2017 1 / 38 What is the expected return

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops NEW PERSPECTIVES ON REPUTATION AND DEBT Sudden Stops and Output Drops By V. V. CHARI, PATRICK J. KEHOE, AND ELLEN R. MCGRATTAN* Discussants: Andrew Atkeson, University of California; Olivier Jeanne, International

More information

The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates

The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates Adrien Verdelhan MIT Sloan and NBER March 2013 This Paper (I/II) Two variables account for 20% to 90% of the monthly exchange rate movements

More information

Long Run Labor Income Risk

Long Run Labor Income Risk Long Run Labor Income Risk Robert F. Dittmar Francisco Palomino November 00 Department of Finance, Stephen Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 4809, email: rdittmar@umich.edu

More information

The Accrual Anomaly: Exploring the Optimal Investment Hypothesis

The Accrual Anomaly: Exploring the Optimal Investment Hypothesis Working Paper The Accrual Anomaly: Exploring the Optimal Investment Hypothesis Lu Zhang Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan Jin Ginger Wu University of Georgia X. Frank Zhang

More information

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007 Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert February 15, 2007 Abstract In this paper we use a simple model with a single Cobb Douglas firm and a consumer with

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Alberto Bisin Corporate Finance: Lecture Notes Class 1: Valuation updated November 17th, 2002 1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Consider an economy with two states of nature {s 1, s 2 } and with

More information

Introduction Some Stylized Facts Model Estimation Counterfactuals Conclusion Equity Market Misvaluation, Financing, and Investment

Introduction Some Stylized Facts Model Estimation Counterfactuals Conclusion Equity Market Misvaluation, Financing, and Investment Equity Market, Financing, and Investment Missaka Warusawitharana Toni M. Whited North America meetings of the Econometric Society, June 2014 Question Do managers react to perceived equity mispricing? How

More information

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

One-Period Valuation Theory

One-Period Valuation Theory One-Period Valuation Theory Part 2: Chris Telmer March, 2013 1 / 44 1. Pricing kernel and financial risk 2. Linking state prices to portfolio choice Euler equation 3. Application: Corporate financial leverage

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 8: From factor models to asset pricing Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Solution to exercise 1 of problem

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Asset Prices and Finance Max Gillman Cardi Business School 0 December 200 Gillman (Cardi Business School) Chapter 7 0 December 200 / 38 Chapter 7: Asset Prices and Finance

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Asset Prices Spring 2015 1 / 43 A New Topic We are now going to switch

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Theory Appendix to. Idiosyncratic Volatility, Growth Options, and the Cross-Section of Returns. Alexander Barinov

Theory Appendix to. Idiosyncratic Volatility, Growth Options, and the Cross-Section of Returns. Alexander Barinov Theory Appendix to Idiosyncratic Volatility, Growth Options, and the Cross-Section of Returns Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia This version: June 2010 Abstract This document

More information