Leveling Playing Field or Obfuscation: The Informational Role of Overconfident CEOs*

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Leveling Playing Field or Obfuscation: The Informational Role of Overconfident CEOs*"

Transcription

1 Leveling Playing Field or Obfuscation: The Informational Role of Overconfident CEOs* Chishen Wei Nanyang Technological University Lei Zhang Nanyang Technological University October 12, 2016 Abstract We study the informational role of overconfident CEOs. We find that stocks led by overconfident CEOs have lower analyst forecast dispersion, higher breadth of ownership, and lower informed trading intensity. These results are consistent around CEO turnovers. We also show that overconfident CEOs level the playing field between short sellers and other investors, as the (good) news in short interest (Boehmer, Huszar and Jordan, 2010) exists only among stocks with non-overconfident CEOs and disappears among stocks with overconfident CEOs. These findings suggest that overconfident CEOs can help increase information efficiency and lower the mispricing of their company shares. Keywords: Overconfident CEOs, Differences of Opinion, Informed Trading, Short Interest, Information Efficiency JEL Classification: D80, G14, G32, G34 * We thank Zhanhui Chen, Stephen Dimmock, Chuan Yang Hwang, Oguzhan Karakas, Jun-koo Kang, Andy Kim, Neng Wang, Xiaoyun Yu and seminar participants at Nanyang Business School for helpful comments. Both authors are at Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore Chishen Wei cswei@ntu.edu.sg; phone: (+65) Lei Zhang zhangl@ntu.edu.sg; phone: (+65) All errors and omissions are our own.

2 Leveling Playing Field or Obfuscation: The Informational Role of Overconfident CEOs Abstract We study the informational role of overconfident CEOs. We find that stocks led by overconfident CEOs have lower analyst forecast dispersion, higher breadth of ownership, and lower informed trading intensity. These results are consistent around CEO turnovers. We also show that overconfident CEOs level the playing field between short sellers and other investors, as the (good) news in short interest (Boehmer, Huszar and Jordan, 2010) exists only among stocks with non-overconfident CEOs and disappears among stocks with overconfident CEOs. These findings suggest that overconfident CEOs can help increase information efficiency and lower the mispricing of their company shares. Keywords: Overconfident CEOs, Differences of Opinion, Informed Trading, Short Interest, Information Efficiency JEL Classification: D80, G14, G32, G34

3 1. Introduction Recent research in finance shows that managerial traits such as managers prior experience, personal characteristics, and cognitive biases affect corporate decisions (e.g., Bertrand and Schoar, 2003). Of the cognitive biases, CEO overconfidence has received perhaps the most attention (Malmendier and Tate, 2015). The extant literature examines the effect of overconfident CEOs on corporate policies such as investments, financing decisions, and innovation, 1 but their impact on a firm s information environment has gone unexplored. This is an important consideration because the information environment affects the firm s cost of capital, investor base, and price efficiency (e.g., Diamond and Verrechia, 1991). In this paper, we provide the first direct evidence on the overall impact of CEO overconfidence on investor disagreement, informed trading, and the information efficiency of stock prices. There are two competing views on the informational role of overconfident CEOs. First, extant literature shows that because overconfident CEOs view their company shares as undervalued, they tend to release more voluntary managerial disclosure and earnings guidance (Hribar and Yang, 2015), exhibit less asymmetric timeliness in the recognition of good news versus bad news 2 (Ahmed and Duellman, 2013), and are more likely to repurchase shares from the market (Banerjee, Humphery-Jenner, and Nanda, 2013). This increase in information disclosure may facilitate more timely incorporation of information into stock prices and lower information asymmetry between informed and uninformed investors. As a result, firms led by overconfident CEOs will have lower investor disagreement, lower informed trading intensity, and higher information efficiency of stock prices. We refer to this hypothesis as the leveling playing field hypothesis. Alternatively, studies also show that overconfident CEOs have a tendency to misstate earnings in corporate financial reporting (Schrand and Zechman, 2011), issue overly optimistic estimates (Hribar and Yang, 2015), pursue less conservative accounting practices (Ahmed and Duellman, 2013), and are more 1 See, among others: Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008); Graham, Harvey, and Puri (2009); Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012). 2 Barth, Landsman, Raval and Wang (2015) find that higher asymmetric timeliness in news recognition decreases the speed with which equity investor disagreement and uncertainty resolve at earnings announcements. 1

4 likely to be involved in securities class action litigations (Banerjee, Humphrey-Jenner, Nanda, and Tham, 2015). From this perspective, overconfident CEOs may obfuscate information quality, potentially creating a more opaque information environment and increasing information asymmetry between informed and uninformed investors. This information obfuscation hypothesis predicts that firms with overconfident CEOs will have higher investor disagreement, higher informed trading intensity, and lower information efficiency of stock prices. To test these two competing hypotheses, we use a comprehensive sample of 30,149 firm-year observations in the S&P Execucomp database between 1992 and We identify overconfident CEOs by their willingness to hold deep in-the-money vested stock options. 3 In the first half of our analysis, we directly examine the informational role of overconfident CEOs by linking CEO overconfidence with measures of investor disagreement and informed trading intensity. Also, we examine how these measures change around CEO turnovers. In the second half our analysis, we analyze the effect of CEO overconfidence on the information efficiency of stock prices by focusing on a particular form of informed trading, short selling. Overconfident CEOs may marginalize the information advantages of short sellers if their actions level the playing field between informed and uninformed investors. On the other hand, short sellers may stand to benefit if the actions of overconfident CEOs obfuscates the information environment. We briefly summarize our main results. We find that overconfident CEOs are associated with lower analyst forecast dispersion, higher breadth of ownership, and lower informed trading intensity. Investor disagreement and informed trading increase when an overconfident CEO is replaced by a nonoverconfident CEO and decrease when a non-overconfident CEO is replaced by an overconfident CEO. These findings unambiguously support the leveling playing field hypothesis. Consistent with this evidence, our second set of results show that overconfident CEOs marginalize the information advantages of short sellers, as the relation between short interest and future returns disappears among stocks with 3 Specifically, we define a CEO as overconfident once he or she postpones the exercise of vested stock options that are at least 67% in the money. Once a CEO is identified as overconfident, he or she remains overconfident for the rest of the sample period. This commonly used option-based measure is based on the idea that managers who are overconfident in their firm s future prospects will voluntarily maintain excessive exposure to the idiosyncratic risk of the firm (e.g., Malmendier and Tate, 2005; Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh, 2012; Ahmed and Duellman, 2013). 2

5 overconfident CEOs. Further supporting the leveling playing field hypothesis, these results suggest that CEO overconfidence helps to correct mispricing and improves the information efficiency of stock prices. We start by examining the effect of overconfident CEOs on investor disagreement among investors using two commonly used measures of differences of opinion. The results indicate that the stocks of overconfident CEOs have significantly lower analyst forecast dispersion (e.g., Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina, 2002). Stocks with overconfident CEOs display a 21% lower analyst forecast dispersion relative to the sample average. 4 One concern with examining analyst forecast dispersion is that analysts are not buy-side investors in the stock market. To address this concern, we use an alternative measure based on the breadth of ownership by active U.S. equity mutual funds (e.g., Chen, Hong, and Stein, 2002). We find that the stocks of overconfident CEOs display a 6% higher breath of ownership relative to the sample average compared to the ones with non-overconfident CEOs. We also examine two trading-based measures that capture the intensity of informed trading in the market. The evidence indicates that the stocks of overconfident CEOs have 5% lower probability of informed trading (PIN) relative to the sample average (e.g., Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O Hara, 2002; Brown and Hillegest, 2007). A potential concern with the PIN measure is that it is less applicable in highly automated markets. Therefore, we construct an alternative informed trading measure, C2, based on the return autocorrelation conditional on trading volume (e.g., Llorente, Michaely, Saar, and Wang, 2002). We find stocks of overconfident CEOs exhibit a significant reduction in C2 of 40% relative to the sample average. The strong association between CEO overconfidence and the firm s information environment supports the leveling the playing field hypothesis. However, simultaneity and reverse causality are potential sources of concern for the interpretation of our findings. These issues are partially attenuated because we examine aspects of the information environment that are formed by investor beliefs and trading behavior, not direct managerial actions. Concerns of unobserved firm characteristics are further 4 Our tests control for firm size, leverage, profitability, institutional ownership, stock volatility, past stock return and trading volume in our empirical analyses. The results remain robust with the inclusion of industry fixed effects or firm fixed effects. 3

6 alleviated by the use of firm fixed effects in our earlier tests. Nonetheless, we recognize the possibility that overconfident CEOs may self-select or are hired into firms with higher transparency and lower information asymmetry. To rule out this explanation, we follow the literature (e.g., Ahmed and Duellman, 2013) and examine changes in the information environment around CEO turnover. If the previous results are due to CEO-firm matching, we expect no change in our set of information asymmetry measures after the new CEO takes over. However, we find that investor disagreement and informed trading increase after an overconfident CEO is replaced by another non-overconfident new CEO and decrease after a nonoverconfident CEO is replaced by another overconfident new CEO. These patterns are consistent for both voluntary and forced CEO turnovers, which alleviates the simultaneity concern that poor recent performance worsens the information environment and causes the overconfident CEO to be fired. Overall, the evidence supports the leveling playing field hypothesis of the informational role of overconfident CEOs. Building on the overconfidence/transparency relation, we conduct a market based test on whether overconfident CEOs level the playing field between short sellers and other investors. This is an ideal setting for our research question because: 1) short sellers are generally viewed as more sophisticated and more informed; 2) short interest data is public information; 3) market participants directly observe short sellers action as revealed by short interest; 4) short interest predicts future returns (e.g., Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang, 2008; Boehmer, Huszar, and Jordan, 2010). Perhaps surprisingly, Boehmer, Huszar, and Jordan (2010) show that short interest predicts high future returns of lightly shorted stocks suggesting that the information content of short interest is not hindered by short sell constraints. To test the effect of overconfident CEOs on information efficiency, we compare the return predictability of short interest between stocks with and without overconfident CEOs. We find that the (good) news in short interest only exists within stocks with non-overconfident CEOs and disappears among stocks with overconfident CEOs. Results from independent sorts show that the long-short portfolio (sorted by short interest in the previous month) based on the 3-4

7 factor plus momentum factor model yields an insignificant alpha of 0.26% per month for stocks led by overconfident CEOs, compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.72% per month for stocks with nonoverconfident CEOs. The results are similar using a 5-factor plus momentum factor model, with the long-short portfolio yielding an insignificant alpha of 0.27% per month for overconfident CEOs compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.76% per month for non-overconfident CEOs. Moreover, we find that this difference in return predictability in short interest between overconfident CEOs and nonoverconfident CEOs is largely driven by the lowest short interest portfolio. This suggests that our findings are not explained by short sell constraints. Using a 5-factor plus momentum factor model, the lowest short interest portfolio yields an insignificant alpha of 0.18% per month for overconfident CEOs, compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.46% per month for non-overconfident CEOs. These results are similar using dependent sorts and matching approach based on firm characteristics. These results are important for two reasons. First, it provides direct market based evidence that CEO overconfidence levels the playing field among informed and uninformed investors. Second, from an information efficiency standpoint, it implies that CEO overconfidence is associated with less mispricing. For companies led by overconfident CEOs, the non-relation between short interest and future returns implies that the positive information in lightly shorted stocks has already been incorporated into the stock price. This suggests that overconfident CEOs play a role in correcting mispricing and improving the information efficiency of their stock. 5 We perform additional tests to ensure that our results are robust. First, our results are similar using alternative cutoffs for the identification of overconfident CEOs or alternative measures of short interest. Second, it is possible that firms tend to hire overconfident CEOs in good times and fire overconfident CEOs in bad times, creating additional firm-ceo matching issues when the CEO is first identified as overconfident. Following Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012), we address this concern by dropping the 5 It is important to note that the leveling playing field hypothesis does not predict the level of short interest in stocks with overconfident CEOs because lower level of short interest does not imply less informed trading. Rather, low short interest suggests that short sellers, being more informed and sophisticated, do not short the stocks that they have positive private information. Overconfident CEOs, by leveling the playing field, reduce the information advantage of informed vis-à-vis uninformed investors, which leads to less return predictability of short interest. 5

8 initial three years after a CEO is first identified as overconfident. Our results are not sensitive to this alternative specification. Our paper contributes to the literature on CEO overconfidence. Studies show that overconfident CEOs affect information disclosure but these channels often generate mixed implications on the overall informational role of overconfident CEOs. On the one hand, overconfident CEOs release more managerial earnings guidance (Hribar and Yang, 2015), exhibit less asymmetric earnings timeliness (Ahmed and Duellman, 2013), and are more likely to repurchase shares (Banerjee, Humphery-Jenner, and Nanda, 2013). On the other hand, overconfident CEOs are more likely to misstate earnings (Schrand and Zechman, 2011), issue overly optimistic estimates (Hribar and Yang, 2015), and attract class action litigation (Banerjee, Humphrey-Jenner, Nanda, and Tham, 2015). Our findings are unique in that we examine the overall informational role of overconfident CEOs and its consequence on the information efficiency of stock prices. We find that CEO overconfidence has a bright side in terms of improving information efficiency and lowering mispricing (underpricing). These results shed new light to our understanding of the puzzle on why firms are willing to hire or keep overconfident managers (e.g., Goel and Thakor, 2008; Gervais, Heaton, and Odean, 2011). Our results also add to the asset pricing literature on corporate transparency, informed trading, and short selling (e.g., Chen, Hong, and Stein, 2002; Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina, 2002; Zhang, 2006). Prior studies find evidence that stocks with high short interest subsequently underperform (e.g., Senchack and Starks, 1993; Asquith and Meulbroek, 1995; Desai, Ramesh, Thiagarajan, and Balachandran, 2002; Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang, 2008). More recently, Boehmer, Huszar, and Jordan (2010) show that lightly shorted stocks experience positive future abnormal returns. This raises a broader issues regarding market efficiency because it implies that information is slow to incorporate into prices, even for a long only strategy. Our evidence shows that the good news in short interest exist only within stocks with nonoverconfident CEOs and disappear among stocks led by overconfident CEOs. This suggests that overconfident CEOs help to level the playing field between informed and uninformed investors and increase the timeliness of (positive) information incorporation into stock prices. 6

9 Third, our results contribute to a broad literature on behavioral finance and market efficiency. A large body of evidence suggests that behavioral biases of investors affect asset prices and reduce market efficiency (e.g., Barberis and Thaler, 2003). We depart from this literature by examining the effect of managerial biases on asset prices with the existence of information frictions. To our knowledge, we are among the first to show that overconfident CEOs may help the market to correct mispricing, particularly undervaluation. This is important from a welfare perspective because undervaluation may increase the cost of capital and waste valuable investment opportunities. Our findings imply that a behavioral bias of CEO can actually reduce the barriers to arbitrage and improve informational efficiency. 2. Data and Variables This section describes the data sources and variable construction. We also provide summary statistics of our sample. 2.1 Data and variables The data on CEO option holdings and other CEO characteristics are obtained from S&P Execucomp database during the period of 1992 to We collect data on daily and monthly stock returns, monthly short interest, trading volumes and shares outstanding are from CRSP. The data on annual accounting information are from Compustat. The data on stock holdings of mutual funds and institutional investors are from Thomson Reuters. The data on analyst earnings forecasts are from IBES. To identify CEO overconfidence, we follow the most commonly used approach in the literature based on the exercise of vested CEO stock options. As we do not have the dataset used in Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008), we estimate CEO overconfidence following the approach of Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012) and Campbell et al. (2011). 6 Specifically, we use the Execucomp data to construct the 6 Similar to Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012), we do not require that the CEO holds a 67% in the money option at least twice and define the CEO as overconfident after the first time he or she exhibits such a behavior. The reason is that this requires the use of forward-looking information, which is not appropriate for us to examine the return predictability of short interest. 7

10 overconfidence measure. First, we divide the value of exercisable unexercised options (Execucomp item: opt_unex_exer_est_val) by the number of exercisable unexercised options (Execucomp item: opt_unex_exer_num) and subtract this value from the stock price at the fiscal year end (Compustat item: PRCC_F) to obtain the average strike price per option. Second, we divide the value of exercisable unexercised options per option by the average strike price per option to calculate the average moneyness of the options. We define a CEO as overconfident once he or she postpones the exercise of vested stock options that are at least 67% in the money, following the cut-off in Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008). The Options67 variable takes the value of 1 if the CEO is identified as overconfident and 0 otherwise. We only include the vested options held by the CEO because we are interested in options that the CEO can exercise. Once a CEO is identified as overconfident, he or she remains overconfident for the rest of the sample period. We construct Options100 following the same methodology as Options67, except that we identify a CEO as overconfident once he or she postpones the exercise of vested options that are at least 100% in the money. Similarly, once a CEO is identified as overconfident, he or she remains overconfident for the rest of the sample period. We construct two measures of investor disagreement. The first measure is analyst forecast dispersion. For a given firm-month, we define analyst forecast dispersion as the ratio between the standard deviation of analyst one-year EPS forecasts divided by the absolute mean forecast. We require at least five analysts to calculate the measure. Then, we calculate the yearly average across the monthly observations. The second measure is based on the breadth of ownership by active U.S. equity mutual funds. 7 For each firm-quarter, we define the breadth of ownership as the number of mutual funds holding the stock divided by the total number of mutual funds in that quarter. Then, we calculate the yearly 7 We only focus on U.S. domestic equity mutual funds. For data from 1993 to 1999, we select funds with IOC fund objective codes (available until 1999 in the Thomson data) 2, 3, 4, and 7: Aggressive growth, Growth, Growth & Income, and Balanced. For data from 2000 to 2013, we select funds with the Lipper objective codes that pertain to domestic equity funds from the CRSP Mutual Fund database: G, SG, MC, SP, I, B, GI, FX, EI, TK, H, S, CS, UT, TL, CA, DSB, LSE, ID, BM, and CG. We use the MFLinks data to match the Thompson data with the CRSP Mutual Fund data. 8

11 average across four quarters. Our two measures of informed trading intensity are PIN and C2. The probability of informed trading (PIN) measures the unconditional probability of information-based trading for a given stock based on the observed order flow. We follow the construction procedure detailed in Brown and Hillegeist (2007). 8 The second measure is the C2 coefficient based on stock return autocorrelation conditional on trading volume developed in Llorente et al. (2002). 9 For a given firm-month, we define Short Interest as the amount of shorted shares divided by the trading volume of the month or, alternatively, divided by the total shares outstanding. We control for the following firm characteristics. Firm Size is the log value of book assets. Marketto-book is market value of assets divided by book assets. Book Leverage is total debt divided by book assets. Profitability is operating income before depreciation divided by book assets. Sales Growth is current year sales less prior year sales scaled by prior year sales. Institutional Ownership is the number of shares held by all of the institutional investors divided by the total number of shares outstanding. Yearly Return is the cumulative stock return in a year. Return Volatility is the standard deviation of monthly stock returns in a year. Trading Volume is the average monthly trading volume in a year. We estimate monthly trading volume as the number of shares traded in the month divided by the total shares outstanding. The detailed definitions of each variable together with Compustat item symbols are available in the appendix. We also control for important CEO characteristics. CEO Tenure is the logarithm of the number of years since the CEO resumes office. CEO Age is the logarithm of the CEO s age. CEO Ownership is the number of stocks held by the CEO divided by the number of shares outstanding. Initial CEO is a dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the CEO is the same CEO when the firm first appears in the Execucomp database and 0 otherwise. Chairman CEO is a dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the CEO is also the 8 The quarterly data on the PIN measure from 1993 to 2010 are obtained from Stephen Brown s website at 9 Specifically, for each firm-year, we estimate the coefficient C2 in the time-series regression:, 0 1, 2,,,, where, is the daily stock return of firm i on day t+1, is the value-weighted market return,, is the detrended logarithm of stock turnover on day t, by subtracting a 100 trading day moving average. We calculate daily stock turnover as the number of shares traded on that day divided by the total number of shares outstanding. 9

12 chairman of the board and 0 otherwise. 2.2 Summary Statistics In Table I, we report the summary statistics of the main variables used in the subsequent analyses. The overall sample includes 30,149 firm-year observations during the period of 1992 to The mean value of Options67 is 0.58, meaning that 58% of CEOs are identified as overconfident. This figure is comparable to the sample average reported in Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012). The alternative measure Options100 has a mean of 0.46, implying that 46% of CEOs are identified as overconfident. After merging with firm characteristics and other CEO characteristics, the combined sample includes 28,086 firm-year observations. The mean and median size of book assets is $13.8 billion and $1.7 billion respectively, consistent with the fact that firms covered in Execucomp are relatively large firms. The average CEO tenure is 7.8 years and the average CEO age is 56 years. Around 56% of the CEOs serve as the chairman of the board, 2% are female CEOs, and the average CEO stock ownership is 1.8% of the firm s shares outstanding. Table II reports the percentage of overconfident CEOs year by year. In each year from 1992 to 2012, we report the mean and standard deviation of two CEO overconfidence measures, Options67 and Options100. The time-series pattern shows that CEOs tend to become more overconfident during market booming period and tend to be less so during market downturns. This pattern is also consistent with the one reported in Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012) Overconfident CEOs and the Information Environment The extant literature shows that CEO overconfidence affects information disclosure, but the implications on the informational role of overconfident CEOs are mixed. 11 For example, Hribar and Yang (2015) show 10 This may raise some firm-ceo matching issues that CEO overconfidence can be spuriously correlated with market conditions. It could be that firms tend to hire overconfident CEOs in good times and fire overconfident CEOs in bad times. Following Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012), we address this concern by dropping the first three years since a CEO starts to be identified as overconfident. We report these results in later analyses. 11 Confirming prior studies, we verify that overconfident CEOs are more likely to provide voluntary earnings 10

13 that overconfident CEOs are more likely to provide company-issued earnings guidance, but their managerial forecasts tend to be overly optimistic. Ahmed and Duellman (2013) find that overconfident CEOs use less conservative accounting in the form of both conditional and unconditional conservatism. The informational implications are unclear because less asymmetric timeliness in the recognition of good versus bad news may quicken the resolution of investor disagreement and uncertainty at earnings announcements (Barth, Landsman, Raval, and Wang, 2015). On the other hand, less accounting conservatism may be associated with higher earnings management (Beaver and Ryan 2005), resulting in a greater likelihood that overconfident CEOs misstate earnings (Schrand and Zechman, 2011). These findings raise the important question of the overall informational role of overconfident CEOs. The leveling playing field hypothesis suggests that the disclosure provided by overconfident CEOs improves the transparency of the information environment. In contrast, the information obfuscation hypothesis implies that information environment becomes more opaque as a result of the type of disclosure overconfident CEOs release. To analyze these two competing hypotheses, we examine two broad dimensions of the information environment: 1) investor disagreement and 2) informed trading intensity. We analyze issues associated with CEO-firm matching by studying the changes in information environment around CEO turnover. 3.1 Overconfident CEOs and investor disagreement We begin by examining the effect of overconfident CEOs on the investor disagreement by estimating regressions following equation (1): Investor Disagreementit, Overconfident CEOit, 1 X it, 1 it,. (1) Our main CEO overconfidence measure is Options67. Investor Disagreement is measured using either analyst forecast dispersion (e.g., Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina, 2002) or breadth of mutual fund ownership (e.g., Hong, Kubik, and Stein, 2002). We control for firm characteristics including book size, guidance, announce stock repurchases and use less conservative accounting in terms of asymmetric timeliness of earnings in our sample. The results are available in the Internet Appendix. 11

14 market-to-book, book leverage, profitability, sales growth, institutional ownership, return volatility, and trading volume. We also control for past stock returns following Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012) and Malmendier and Tate (2015). Our regressions include year fixed effects to capture time-varying macroeconomic shocks and industry fixed effects to capture industry factors. We also consider a specification with firm fixed effects to alleviate concerns that certain unobserved firm characteristics are behind our results. Standard errors are clustered by firm. Panel A of Table III shows a negative and significant effect of CEO overconfidence on analyst forecast dispersion. Relative to the sample average, the parameter estimate in Column (1) shows that an overconfident CEO is associated with a decrease in analyst forecast dispersion by 22% (t=-5.82). In Column (2) the results are unchanged (21%, t=-5.83) with the inclusion of industry fixed effects. As analyst dispersion may be related to other CEO characteristics, we include CEO tenure, age, ownership, founder, chairman, and female indicators. Column (3) shows the results are similar with the inclusion of these characteristics. We also estimate a specification with firm fixed effects to capture unobserved firm heterogeneity. The results remains similar (20%, t=-4.61) in Column (4), suggesting that unobserved firm heterogeneity is not behind our findings. The results also show a positive relation between analyst forecast dispersion and trading volume. This is consistent with the view that forecast dispersion measures investor disagreement because disagreement generates greater trading volume. Analyst forecast dispersion is also associated with higher return volatility and firm leverage, and smaller firm size, lower profitability and low past stock returns, consistent with the view that larger and more profitable companies have more transparent information environment. One concern with using analyst forecast dispersion to measure investor disagreement is that analysts are not buy-side investors in the stock market. We address this concern using an investor-based measure that captures the breadth of ownership by active U.S. equity mutual funds (e.g., Chen, Hong, and Stein, 2002). Diamond and Verrecchia (1991) show that a reduction of information asymmetry increases demand from many investors which leads to a higher breadth of ownership. 12

15 The results in Panel B of Table III show a significant positive effect of CEO overconfidence on the breadth of ownership. The results are consistent across different specifications. For example, with year and industry fixed effects in Column (3), firms with overconfident CEOs display a 4% higher breadth of ownership relative to the sample average with a t-statistic of We note that the effects are stronger in the specification with firm fixed effects in Column (4). Firms with overconfident CEOs display a 6% higher breadth of ownership relative to the sample average with a t-statistic of This shows that the effect of CEO overconfidence is unlikely to be driven by certain unobserved firm characteristics. Among the control variables, firm size, market-to-book, profitability, institutional ownership, and past stock return are positively related to breadth of ownership, while trading volume, book leverage, and CEO ownership are negatively related to breadth of ownership. In sum, these results support the leveling playing field hypothesis and refute the information obfuscation hypothesis. Another implication of the leveling playing field hypothesis is that stocks with overconfident CEOs should display a lower level of informed trading intensity because of a decrease in the information advantage of informed investors over uninformed investors. We next examine the effect of overconfident CEOs on informed trading intensity. 3.2 Overconfident CEOs and informed trading intensity To examine the relation between CEO overconfidence and informed trading intensity, we estimate regressions following equation (2): Informed Trading Intensityi,t Overconfident CEOi,t-1 X it, (2) 1 it, We focus on the main CEO overconfidence measure Options67. We consider two general measures of informed trading intensity: 1) the probability of informed trades (PIN) based on observed order flow, 2) the return-volume coefficient C2 based on autocorrelation of stock returns conditional on trading volume. In Panel A of Table IV, the dependent variable is the probability of information-based trading (PIN) based on the observed order flow. The procedures to construct PIN are detailed in Brown and Hillegeist 13

16 (2007). We calculate the yearly average across 4 quarters for a given firm-year. Column (1) reports the base-line specification. Column (2) includes industry fixed effects at the two-digit SIC level. Column (3) further controls for CEO characteristics. In column (4), we include firm fixed effects. The standard errors are always clustered at the firm level. The results show a significantly negative relation between CEO overconfidence and the probability of informed trading. The results are consistent across different specifications. Under the most complete specification with year and industry fixed effects, firms with overconfident CEOs display a 3% lower intensity of informed trades relative to the sample average with a t-statistic of This result is consistent in the specification with firm fixed effects. In this case, firms with overconfident CEOs display a 5% lower intensity of informed trades relative to the sample average with a t-statistic of Among the control variables, firm size, market-to-book, profitability, sales growth, institutional ownership, past stock return and trading volume are negatively related to PIN, while book leverage, CEO age and CEO ownership are positively related to PIN. In Panel B, Table IV, the dependent variable is the return-volume coefficient C2 based on autocorrelation of stock returns conditional on trading volume (Llorente et al., 2002). They show that a correspondence exists between the cross-sectional variation in return-volume dynamics and the relative importance of informed trading in stock returns. The higher the C2 coefficient, the higher the intensity of information based trading. Panel B follows the same layout as in Panel A. The results show a significantly negative relation between CEO overconfidence and the C2 coefficient. The results are consistent across different specifications. In the specification with year and industry fixed effects, firms with overconfident CEOs display a 70% lower C2 relative to the sample average 12 with a t-statistic of This effect remains significant in the specification with firm fixed effects, in which firms with overconfident CEOs display a 40% lower C2 relative to the sample average with a t-statistic of Among the control variables, market-to-book, sales growth, past stock return and trading volume are negatively related to C2 across different specifications. 12 The average C2 is 0.01 in our sample, consistent with Llorente et al. (2002). 14

17 3.3 Changes in the information environment around CEO turnover The previous results indicate a strong association between overconfident CEOs and a firm s information environment. However, simultaneity and reverse causality are potential sources of concern for the interpretation of these findings. The endogeneity concerns are alleviated by the use of firm fixed effects in our tests. Still, we recognize that an alternative explanation is that overconfident CEOs may self-select or are hired into firms with more transparency and lower information asymmetry. To rule out this explanation, we examine changes in the information environment around CEO turnover. If our previous findings are explained by CEO-firm matching, we expect no change in the information environment measures after the new CEO takes over. We obtain the data on CEO turnover including both voluntary turnover and forced turnover for all firms in the S&P Execucomp database during the period of 1993 to 2010 from Jenter and Kanaan (2015). We focus on the five-year period both around turnover from an overconfident incumbent CEO to a nonoverconfident new CEO, and around turnover from a non-overconfident incumbent CEO to an overconfident new CEO. For example, in terms of analyst forecast dispersion, we report the average forecast dispersion in the two years before the turnover year, the average forecast dispersion in the two years after the turnover year, and we use a t-test to test the statistical differences. The results on breadth of ownership, PIN and C2 are reported accordingly. The number of observations and t-statistics are given in parentheses. Table V presents the results. In Panel A, we include all of the CEO turnover events. We find evidence of significant changes in the information measures around CEO turnovers, even in a significantly reduced sample. We find that investor disagreement and informed trading increase after an overconfident CEO is replaced by another non-overconfident new CEO, and decrease after a nonoverconfident CEO is replaced by another overconfident new CEO. For example, we find that when an overconfident incumbent CEO is replaced by another non-overconfident new CEO, analyst forecast dispersion increases from to 0.198, breadth of ownership decreases from 6.96% to 6.72%, PIN 15

18 remains relatively stable from to 0.127, and C2 increases from to When a nonoverconfident incumbent CEO is replaced by another overconfident new CEO, analyst forecast dispersion decreases from to 0.125, breadth of ownership increases from 6.31% to 6.93%, PIN decreases from to 0.128, and C2 decreases from to One remaining concern is that poor recent stock performance may simultaneously worsens the information environment and causes overconfident CEOs to be fired. Therefore, we examine voluntary CEO turnovers and forced CEO turnovers separately. In Panel B, we only consider voluntary CEO turnovers, and in Panel C, we focus on forced CEO turnovers. We find similar patterns for both voluntary and forced CEO turnovers. Overall, we conclude that the evidence supports the leveling playing field hypothesis of the informational role of overconfident CEOs. 4. Overconfident CEOs and the News in Short Interest Our second set of tests builds upon the overconfidence/transparency relation in Section 3. We examine the effect of overconfident CEOs on the information efficiency of their stock price by testing whether overconfident CEOs level the playing field among short sellers and other investors. Short sellers are an ideal investor group to examine this research question for the following reasons. First, it is a common view that short sellers are sophisticated and informed. Short-selling is risky and costly and requires superior information. Second, the data on short interest are publicly available information and observable by market participants. This is particularly important in our setting because it provides a direct measure of the informed traders in a stock. Third, evidence suggests that short interest predicts future abnormal returns (e.g., Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang, 2008; Boehmer, Huszar and Jordan, 2010), confirming the perception that short-sellers are informed. Fourth, Boehmer, Huszar, and Jordan (2010) show that lightly shorted stocks experience higher future returns. The undervaluation of low short interest stocks implies that positive information is slow to incorporate into prices. This is a surprising result because short interest is a publicly available signal and only requires a long position investment to capture the abnormal returns. 16

19 Using the short interest setting developed in Boehmer, Huszar, and Jordan (2010), we examine the effect of overconfident CEOs on the undervaluation of low short interest stocks. We expect no undervaluation among these stocks if overconfident CEOs are able to level the playing field between informed and uninformed investors. Before we begin our main analysis, we first examine the overall relation between short interest and future return in our sample. 4.1 The overall relation between short interest and future returns At each month-beginning from January 1993 to December 2013, stocks are sorted into quintiles based on the previous month-end short interest. We use the main measure on short interest defined as the amount of shorted shares divided by the trading volume of the month. Portfolio 1 has the lowest short interest. Portfolio 5 has the highest short interest. Equally-weighted returns for the five portfolios are calculated over the month. Panel A1 of Table VI reports the mean and standard deviation of short interest in each portfolio. We also report the percentage of overconfident CEOs in each portfolio. We focus on our main overconfidence measure Options67 throughout the table. The results show that the average short interest in Portfolio 1 is with a standard deviation of 0.029, while the average short interest in Portfolio 5 is with a standard deviation of The average percentage of firms with overconfident CEOs is similar across the five portfolios, being 54.1% in Portfolio 1 and 56.7% in Portfolio 5. In Panel A2, for each portfolio, we report the raw average portfolio return, the abnormal return (i.e., alpha) from the 3-factor (market factor, SMB, HML) model, and the alpha from the Fama- French 3-factor and the Carhart momentum factor model, and the alpha from the 5-factor (market factor, SMB, HML, RMW, CMA) and the Carhart momentum factor model. Long Portfolio 1 & Short Portfolio 5 is the difference in the returns between the lowest and highest short interest portfolios. We report the raw return and the alphas for the long-short portfolio accordingly. We find that short interest predicts future returns, consistent with Boehmer, Huszar, and Jordan (2010). Our sample extends their original time period by 8 years (until 2013) and only focus on the stocks 17

20 covered in the S&P Execucomp database. Using a 3-factor plus momentum factor model, the long-short portfolio yields a significant alpha of 0.48% per month, driven mostly by the positive alpha of 0.46% per month in the lowest short interest portfolio. Based on the 5-factor plus momentum factor model, the long-short portfolio yields a significant alpha of 0.51% per month, contributed both from a significant positive alpha of 0.31% in the lowest short interest portfolio and a marginally significant negative alpha of -0.20% in the highest short interest portfolio. 4.2 CEO overconfidence and the relation between short interest and future returns We perform our main test by separating firms with overconfident CEOs and firms with non-overconfident CEOs. We use Options67 throughout this analysis. A CEO is identified to be overconfident if the indicator variable Options67 is equal to one in the previous year. We examine raw and risk-adjusted returns of stock portfolios sorted by short interest, both independently and dependently conditioning on firms with overconfident and non-overconfident CEOs. We report the results in Panel B and C of Table VI. Panel B reports the results of independent sorting, in which we first sort stocks into five portfolios independently, without conditioning on whether the stock has an overconfident CEO. Then, we calculate portfolio returns separately for stocks with overconfident CEOs and stocks with non-overconfident CEOs. For each portfolio, we report the average short interest, the raw average portfolio return, the abnormal return (i.e., alpha) from the 3- factor model, and the alpha from the 3-factor plus the Carhart momentum factor model, and the alpha from the 5-factor plus the Carhart momentum factor model. Long Portfolio 1 & Short Portfolio 5 is the difference in the returns between the lowest and highest short interest portfolios. The evidence shows that the return predictability in short interest is nearly non-existent among stocks with overconfident CEOs, and strongly evident among stocks with non-overconfident CEOs. Panel B2 shows that for the non-overconfident sample of firms, the long-short portfolio is positive and statistically significant across all four alpha measures. For example, in the second to last column in Panel B2 (the 3-factor plus momentum factor model), the long-short portfolio earns an average 18

21 alpha of 0.72% (t=4.11) per month. In comparison, Panel B1 shows that the long-short portfolio alpha is statistically insignificant in three out of four specifications, and is notably weaker after controlling for momentum. This is consistent with the argument in Malmendier and Tate (2015) that it is important to control for past returns when using the Options67 measure. In the second to last column in Panel B1, the long-short portfolio earns an average of 0.26% (t=1.48) per month. The results are similar if using a 5-factor plus momentum factor model, where the long-short portfolio yields an insignificant alpha of 0.27% per month (t=1.43) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a significant alpha of 0.76% per month (t=3.99) for non-overconfident CEOs. Dependent sorts generate similar result as shown in Panel C of Table VI. The long-short portfolio based on the 3-factor plus momentum factor model yields an insignificant alpha of 0.26% per month (t=1.52) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a significant 0.75% per month (t=4.12) for nonoverconfident CEOs. The results are also similar if using a 5-factor plus momentum factor model, where the long-short portfolio yields an insignificant alpha of 0.30% per month (t=1.60) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a significant 0.79% per month (t=4.04) for non-overconfident CEOs. In Panel D, we test the statistical differences of raw and risk-adjusted returns between the long-short portfolio sorted among stocks with overconfident CEOs and the long-short portfolio sorted among stocks with non-overconfident CEOs. We report the results for both the independent sorting and the dependent sorting (as in Panel B and Panel C). The results show that the differences in raw and risk-adjusted returns between the long-short portfolio sorted from stocks with overconfident CEOs and the one sorted from stocks with non-overconfident CEOs are always statistically significant. Importantly, we find that this difference in the return predictability of short interest between overconfident CEOs and non-overconfident CEOs is largely driven by the lowest short interest portfolio. Using a 5-factor plus momentum factor model, in the case of independent sorting (Panel B), the lowest short interest portfolio yields an insignificant alpha of 0.18% per month (t=1.19) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.46% per month (t=3.10) for nonoverconfident CEOs. Similarly, in the case of dependent sorting (Panel C), the lowest short interest 19

22 portfolio yields an insignificant alpha of 0.18% per month (t= 1.19) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.49% (t=3.23) per month for non-overconfident CEOs. 4.3 Robustness tests Our results are also robust to scaling short interest by total shares outstanding. Panel A of Table VII shows that the independently sorted long-short portfolio yields an alpha of 0.36% per month (t=1.80) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.69% per month (t=3.53) for nonoverconfident CEOs based on 5-factor plus momentum factor model. Similarly, Panel B shows that in the case of dependent sorting, the long-short portfolio yields an insignificant alpha of 0.28% per month (t=1.41) for overconfident CEOs, compared to a highly significant alpha of 0.80% (t=4.13) per month for non-overconfident CEOs. One potential concern is that the identification of overconfident CEO may be driven by other major firm characteristics. To deal with this concern, we perform matching sample analyses to examine the return predictability of short interest for the sample of firms with overconfident CEOs and for a matching sample matched by major firm characteristics but without overconfident CEOs. Specifically, we separately perform 1-on-1 propensity score matching (with replacement) by firm characteristics such as firm size, market-to-book, past stock return, stock volatility, trading volume, institutional ownership, CEO ownership and a combination of qualitative CEO characteristics (CEO tenure, CEO age, initial CEO, female CEO and chairman CEO). To ensure the quality of the matching, we calculate the absolute difference in the matching characteristics (propensity scores) between the overconfident CEO stocks and the matched non-overconfident CEO stocks. We drop those observations with the absolute differences above the sample top decile. We report the results in Table VIII. Panel A reports the average matching characteristics for the overconfident CEO stocks and the matched non-overconfident CEO stocks. For each matching sample, we report the average absolute difference in the firm characteristics used as a matching variable and we test the statistical differences with a t-test respectively. The results show that the overconfident CEO 20

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior By Jackson Mills Abstract The retention of deep in-the-money exercisable stock options by CEOs has generally been attributed to managers

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Badrinath Kottimukkalur * January 2018 Abstract This paper provides an arbitrage based explanation for the puzzling negative

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Disagreement, Underreaction, and Stock Returns

Disagreement, Underreaction, and Stock Returns Disagreement, Underreaction, and Stock Returns Ling Cen University of Toronto ling.cen@rotman.utoronto.ca K. C. John Wei HKUST johnwei@ust.hk Liyan Yang University of Toronto liyan.yang@rotman.utoronto.ca

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

Overconfidence and Incentive Compensation

Overconfidence and Incentive Compensation Overconfidence and Incentive Compensation Mark Humphery-Jenner Australian School of Business University of New South Wales mlhj@unsw.edu.au Ling Lei Lisic School of Management George Mason University llisic@gmu.edu

More information

Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings

Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings Biljana Seistrajkova 1 Swiss Finance Institute and Università della Svizzera Italiana August 2017 Abstract This paper examines short

More information

Conservatism and stock return skewness

Conservatism and stock return skewness Conservatism and stock return skewness DEVENDRA KALE*, SURESH RADHAKRISHNAN, and FENG ZHAO Naveen Jindal School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, 800 West Campbell Road, Richardson, Texas 75080

More information

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy Keng-Yu Ho Department of Finance National Taiwan University Chia-Wei Yeh Department of Finance National Taiwan University December 3, 2014 Corresponding

More information

High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk. Alexander Barinov. Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013

High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk. Alexander Barinov. Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013 High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk Alexander Barinov Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013 We propose a risk-based firm-type explanation on why stocks of firms with high relative

More information

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Abstract Several previous studies show that consensus analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts are excessively influenced by past firm

More information

Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs

Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs VERONIQUE BESSIERE and PATRICK SENTIS CR2M University

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage and Costly Arbitrage Badrinath Kottimukkalur * December 2018 Abstract This paper explores the relationship between the variation in liquidity and arbitrage activity. A model shows that arbitrageurs will

More information

Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy. Richard Walton

Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy. Richard Walton Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy by Richard Walton A Dissertation Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy Approved April 2016 by the

More information

CEO Tenure and Earnings Quality

CEO Tenure and Earnings Quality CEO Tenure and Earnings Quality Weining Zhang School of Management University of Texas at Dallas Email: wxz041000@utdallas.edu December 30 th, 2009 Abstract This study investigates the relation between

More information

Trading Behavior around Earnings Announcements

Trading Behavior around Earnings Announcements Trading Behavior around Earnings Announcements Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence supporting the hypothesis that individual investors news-contrarian trading behavior drives post-earnings-announcement

More information

Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation

Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation 1 Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation I-Ju Chen* Yuan Ze University, Taiwan Shin-Hung Lin Yuan Ze University, Taiwan This study investigates the relationship between managerial

More information

The good news in short interest

The good news in short interest The good news in short interest Ekkehart Boehmer Lundquist College of Business University of Oregon & Mays Business School Texas A&M University Zsuzsa R. Huszár College of Business Administration California

More information

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University, Deptartment of Economics, USA. KEYWORDS Capital structure, tax rates, cost of capital. ABSTRACT The main purpose

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings?

Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings? Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings? Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe February 17, 2015 Abstract We examine the effect of CEO optimism on corporate cash holdings by developing

More information

Managements' Overconfident Tone and Corporate Policies

Managements' Overconfident Tone and Corporate Policies University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Summer Program for Undergraduate Research (SPUR) Wharton Undergraduate Research 2017 Managements' Overconfident Tone and Corporate Policies Sin Tae Kim University

More information

Accruals, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Stock Returns

Accruals, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Stock Returns Accruals, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Stock Returns Emma Y. Peng An Yan* and Meng Yan Fordham University 1790 Broadway, 13 th Floor New York, NY 10019 Feburary 2012 *Corresponding author. Tel: (212)636-7401

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Does the Board of Directors Learn from Short Sellers? Evidence from CEO Turnovers 1 Anja Kunzmann 2, Kristina M. Meier 3 December 31, 2016

Does the Board of Directors Learn from Short Sellers? Evidence from CEO Turnovers 1 Anja Kunzmann 2, Kristina M. Meier 3 December 31, 2016 Does the Board of Directors Learn from Short Sellers? Evidence from CEO Turnovers 1 Anja Kunzmann 2, Kristina M. Meier 3 December 31, 2016 Abstract We provide evidence that the board of directors learns

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Doron Avramov Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland Tarun Chordia Department of Finance Goizueta Business

More information

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models INTERNET APPENDIX 1. Logit and Linear Probability Models Table 1 Leverage and the Likelihood of a Union Strike (Logit Models) This table presents estimation results of logit models of union strikes during

More information

Internet Appendix for Do General Managerial Skills Spur Innovation?

Internet Appendix for Do General Managerial Skills Spur Innovation? Internet Appendix for Do General Managerial Skills Spur Innovation? Cláudia Custódio Imperial College Business School Miguel A. Ferreira Nova School of Business and Economics, ECGI Pedro Matos University

More information

Investment and Firm Value under High Economic Uncertainty: The Beneficial Effect of Overconfident CEOs

Investment and Firm Value under High Economic Uncertainty: The Beneficial Effect of Overconfident CEOs Investment and Firm Value under High Economic Uncertainty: The Beneficial Effect of Overconfident CEOs Jingoo Kang, Jun-Koo Kang, Minwook Kang, and Jungmin Kim This version: November 2017 Jingoo Kang is

More information

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded?

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded? Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded? Xiaoting Hao *, Natalia Piqueira ABSTRACT Although the literature provides strong evidence supporting the presence of informed trading in

More information

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation Tao Wang Queens College and the Graduate Center of the City University of New York Abstract Stock return volatilities are related to firms' financial

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Does perceived information in short sales cause institutional herding? July 13, Chune Young Chung. Luke DeVault. Kainan Wang 1 ABSTRACT

Does perceived information in short sales cause institutional herding? July 13, Chune Young Chung. Luke DeVault. Kainan Wang 1 ABSTRACT Does perceived information in short sales cause institutional herding? July 13, 2016 Chune Young Chung Luke DeVault Kainan Wang 1 ABSTRACT The institutional herding literature demonstrates, that institutional

More information

CEO Overconfidence and Agency Cost of Debt

CEO Overconfidence and Agency Cost of Debt CEO Overconfidence and Agency Cost of Debt : Evidence from Voluntary Turnovers Subramanian. R. Iyer Anderson School of Management University of New Mexico Albuquerque, New Mexico 87131 Ph: (505) 277-3207

More information

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal*

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal* Su Han Chan Department of Finance, California State University-Fullerton Wai-Kin Leung Faculty of Business Administration, Chinese University of Hong Kong Ko Wang Department of Finance, California State

More information

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey.

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey. Size, Book to Market Ratio and Momentum Strategies: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange Ersan ERSOY* Assistant Professor, Faculty of Economics and Administrative Sciences, Department of Business Administration,

More information

Short Selling, Limits of Arbitrage and Stock Returns ±

Short Selling, Limits of Arbitrage and Stock Returns ± Short Selling, Limits of Arbitrage and Stock Returns ± Jitendra Tayal * Abstract Previous studies document (i) negative abnormal returns for high relative short interest (RSI) stocks, and (ii) positive

More information

Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers?

Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers? Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers? Liang Xu * This version: September 2016 Abstract This paper investigates whether short selling activities affect corporate decisions through an information channel.

More information

Heterogeneous Beliefs and Momentum Profits

Heterogeneous Beliefs and Momentum Profits JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS Vol. 44, No. 4, Aug. 2009, pp. 795 822 COPYRIGHT 2009, MICHAEL G. FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195 doi:10.1017/s0022109009990214

More information

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Jia Chen, Kewei Hou, and René M. Stulz* January 2015 Abstract Using theories from the behavioral finance literature to predict that investors are attracted to

More information

Mutual Funds and the Sentiment-Related. Mispricing of Stocks

Mutual Funds and the Sentiment-Related. Mispricing of Stocks Mutual Funds and the Sentiment-Related Mispricing of Stocks Jiang Luo January 14, 2015 Abstract Baker and Wurgler (2006) show that when sentiment is high (low), difficult-tovalue stocks, including young

More information

Insider Purchases after Short Interest Spikes: a False Signaling Device?

Insider Purchases after Short Interest Spikes: a False Signaling Device? Insider Purchases after Short Interest Spikes: a False Signaling Device? Abstract We study the information contents of the purchases by corporate insiders when their firms experience sharp increases in

More information

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Kotaro Miwa Tokio Marine Asset Management Co., Ltd 1-3-1, Marunouchi, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo, Japan Email: miwa_tfk@cs.c.u-tokyo.ac.jp Tel 813-3212-8186

More information

Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings?

Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings? Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings? Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe December 20, 2015 Abstract We examine the effect of CEO optimism on corporate cash holdings by developing

More information

Asubstantial portion of the academic

Asubstantial portion of the academic The Decline of Informed Trading in the Equity and Options Markets Charles Cao, David Gempesaw, and Timothy Simin Charles Cao is the Smeal Chair Professor of Finance in the Smeal College of Business at

More information

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US *

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US * DOI 10.7603/s40570-014-0007-1 66 2014 年 6 月第 16 卷第 2 期 中国会计与财务研究 C h i n a A c c o u n t i n g a n d F i n a n c e R e v i e w Volume 16, Number 2 June 2014 A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968):

More information

Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions

Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions Richard W. Sias * March 15, 2005 * Department of Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate, College of Business and Economics, Washington State University,

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

The Good News in Short Interest: Ekkehart Boehmer, Zsuzsa R. Huszar, Bradford D. Jordan 2009 Revisited

The Good News in Short Interest: Ekkehart Boehmer, Zsuzsa R. Huszar, Bradford D. Jordan 2009 Revisited Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2014 The Good News in Short Interest: Ekkehart Boehmer, Zsuzsa R. Huszar, Bradford D. Jordan 2009 Revisited

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato Abstract Both rating agencies and stock analysts valuate publicly traded companies and communicate their opinions to investors. Empirical evidence

More information

Investment and Firm Value under High Economic Uncertainty: The Beneficial Effect of Overconfident CEOs

Investment and Firm Value under High Economic Uncertainty: The Beneficial Effect of Overconfident CEOs Investment and Firm Value under High Economic Uncertainty: The Beneficial Effect of Overconfident CEOs Jingoo Kang, Jun-Koo Kang, Minwook Kang, and Jungmin Kim This version: December 2017 Jingoo Kang is

More information

OFFSETTING DISAGREEMENT AND SECURITY PRICES

OFFSETTING DISAGREEMENT AND SECURITY PRICES OFFSETTING DISAGREEMENT AND SECURITY PRICES Byoung-Hyoun Hwang, Dong Lou, and Chengxi Yin * This Draft: March 2013 Portfolios often trade at a substantial discount relative to the sum of its components

More information

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners A Model: Who Gains and Who Loses When Divergence-of-Opinion is Resolved? In the baseline model, the pessimist s gain or loss is equal to her shorting demand times

More information

Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability?

Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability? Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability? Finance Working Paper N 570/2018 July 2018 Lifeng Gu University of Hong Kong Dirk Hackbarth Boston University, CEPR and ECGI Lifeng Gu and Dirk Hackbarth

More information

Choosing the Precision of Performance Metrics

Choosing the Precision of Performance Metrics Choosing the Precision of Performance Metrics Alan D. Crane Jones Graduate School of Business Rice University Chishen Wei Nanyang Business School Nanyang Technological University Andrew Koch Katz Graduate

More information

Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns *

Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns * Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns * Fangjian Fu Singapore Management University Wenjin Kang National University of Singapore Yuping Shao National University of Singapore Abstract

More information

Stock Returns And Disagreement Among Sell-Side Analysts

Stock Returns And Disagreement Among Sell-Side Analysts Archived version from NCDOCKS Institutional Repository http://libres.uncg.edu/ir/asu/ Stock Returns And Disagreement Among Sell-Side Analysts By: Jeffrey Hobbs, David L. Kaufman, Hei-Wai Lee, and Vivek

More information

Short Selling and Attention around the Business Cycle

Short Selling and Attention around the Business Cycle Short Selling and Attention around the Business Cycle PETER N. DIXON AND ERIC K. KELLEY * July 11, 2017 ABSTRACT We show that firm-level short interest predicts negative returns for individual stocks during

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Managerial confidence and initial public offerings

Managerial confidence and initial public offerings Managerial confidence and initial public offerings Thomas J. Boulton a, T. Colin Campbell b,* May, 2014 Abstract Initial public offering (IPO) underpricing is positively correlated with managerial confidence.

More information

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. 5/2014 April 2014 ISSN: 2239-2734 This Working Paper is published under

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium?

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? Hae mi Choi Loyola University Chicago This study investigates what drives the earnings announcement premium. Prior studies have offered various explanations

More information

Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior

Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior Research on the Relationship between CEO's Overconfidence and Corporate Investment Financing Behavior Yan-liang Zhang*, Zi-wei Yang Shandong University of Finance and Economics. Jinan P.R.China E-mail:zhyanliang@sina.com

More information

Are banks more opaque? Evidence from Insider Trading 1

Are banks more opaque? Evidence from Insider Trading 1 Are banks more opaque? Evidence from Insider Trading 1 Fabrizio Spargoli a and Christian Upper b a Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University b Bank for International Settlements Abstract We investigate

More information

Heterogeneous Institutional Investors and Earnings Smoothing

Heterogeneous Institutional Investors and Earnings Smoothing Heterogeneous Institutional Investors and Earnings Smoothing Yudan Zheng Long Island University This paper examines the relationship between institutional ownership and earnings smoothing by taking into

More information

Appendix. A. Firm-Specific DeterminantsofPIN, PIN_G, and PIN_B

Appendix. A. Firm-Specific DeterminantsofPIN, PIN_G, and PIN_B Appendix A. Firm-Specific DeterminantsofPIN, PIN_G, and PIN_B We consider how PIN and its good and bad information components depend on the following firm-specific characteristics, several of which have

More information

CEO Reputation and Dividend Payouts

CEO Reputation and Dividend Payouts 2011 2 nd International Conference on Economics, Business and Management IPEDR vol.22 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore CEO Reputation and Dividend Payouts Danai Likitratcharoen 1 + 1 National Institute

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS? NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO ACQUIRERS WITH MORE UNCERTAIN GROWTH PROSPECTS GAIN LESS FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M. Stulz Working Paper 10773 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10773

More information

Accepted Manuscript. New product strategies and firm performance: CEO optimism. Sheng-Syan Chen, Chih-Yen Lin, Yun-Ching Tsai

Accepted Manuscript. New product strategies and firm performance: CEO optimism. Sheng-Syan Chen, Chih-Yen Lin, Yun-Ching Tsai Accepted Manuscript New product strategies and firm performance: CEO optimism Sheng-Syan Chen, Chih-Yen Lin, Yun-Ching Tsai PII: S1059-0560(16)30259-3 DOI: 10.1016/j.iref.2018.01.021 Reference: REVECO

More information

The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information. Production, and Initial Public Offerings. December 7, 2016

The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information. Production, and Initial Public Offerings. December 7, 2016 The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information Production, and Initial Public Offerings December 7, 2016 The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information Production, and Initial Public Offerings

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

Recency Bias and Post-Earnings Announcement Drift * Qingzhong Ma California State University, Chico. David A. Whidbee Washington State University

Recency Bias and Post-Earnings Announcement Drift * Qingzhong Ma California State University, Chico. David A. Whidbee Washington State University The Journal of Behavioral Finance & Economics Volume 5, Issues 1&2, 2015-2016, 69-97 Copyright 2015-2016 Academy of Behavioral Finance & Economics, All rights reserved. ISSN: 1551-9570 Recency Bias and

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): 2222-6737/ISSN(p): 2305-2147 journal homepage: http://www.aessweb.com/journals/5002 THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS Jung Fang Liu 1 --- Nicholas

More information

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection of Stock Returns Cameron Truong Monash University, Melbourne, Australia February 2015 Abstract We document a significant positive relation

More information

What kind of trading drives return autocorrelation?

What kind of trading drives return autocorrelation? What kind of trading drives return autocorrelation? Chun-Kuei Hsieh and Shing-yang Hu* Department of Finance, National Taiwan University March 2008 This paper proposes new tests for the prediction of Llorente,

More information

Geographic Diffusion of Information and Stock Returns

Geographic Diffusion of Information and Stock Returns Geographic Diffusion of Information and Stock Returns Jawad M. Addoum * University of Miami Alok Kumar University of Miami Kelvin Law Tilburg University October 21, 2013 Abstract This study shows that

More information

Does Book-to-Market Equity Proxy for Distress Risk or Overreaction? John M. Griffin and Michael L. Lemmon *

Does Book-to-Market Equity Proxy for Distress Risk or Overreaction? John M. Griffin and Michael L. Lemmon * Does Book-to-Market Equity Proxy for Distress Risk or Overreaction? by John M. Griffin and Michael L. Lemmon * December 2000. * Assistant Professors of Finance, Department of Finance- ASU, PO Box 873906,

More information

Volatility and the Buyback Anomaly

Volatility and the Buyback Anomaly Volatility and the Buyback Anomaly Theodoros Evgeniou, Enric Junqué de Fortuny, Nick Nassuphis, and Theo Vermaelen August 16, 2016 Abstract We find that, inconsistent with the low volatility anomaly, post-buyback

More information

Short Arbitrage, Return Asymmetry and the Accrual Anomaly

Short Arbitrage, Return Asymmetry and the Accrual Anomaly MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Short Arbitrage, Return Asymmetry and the Accrual Anomaly David Hirshleifer and Siew Hong Teoh and Jeff Jiewei Yu University of California Irvine, Southern Methodist

More information

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Yelena Larkin, Mark T. Leary, and Roni Michaely April 2016 Table I.A-I In table I.A-I we perform a simple non-parametric analysis

More information

Is Information Risk Priced for NASDAQ-listed Stocks?

Is Information Risk Priced for NASDAQ-listed Stocks? Is Information Risk Priced for NASDAQ-listed Stocks? Kathleen P. Fuller School of Business Administration University of Mississippi kfuller@bus.olemiss.edu Bonnie F. Van Ness School of Business Administration

More information

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage Badrinath Kottimukkalur George Washington University Discussed by Fang Qiao PBCSF, TSinghua University EMF, 15 December 2018 Puzzle The level of liquidity affects

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions

When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions When do banks listen to their analysts? Evidence from mergers and acquisitions David Haushalter Penn State University E-mail: gdh12@psu.edu Phone: (814) 865-7969 Michelle Lowry Penn State University E-mail:

More information

The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods. Ata Torabi. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business

The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods. Ata Torabi. A Thesis. The John Molson School of Business The Role of Management Incentives in the Choice of Stock Repurchase Methods Ata Torabi A Thesis In The John Molson School of Business Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree

More information

Analyst Disagreement and Aggregate Volatility Risk

Analyst Disagreement and Aggregate Volatility Risk Analyst Disagreement and Aggregate Volatility Risk Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia April 15, 2010 Alexander Barinov (Terry College) Disagreement and Volatility Risk April

More information

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Doron Avramov Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland davramov@rhsmith.umd.edu Tarun Chordia Department

More information

The Free Cash Flow and Corporate Returns

The Free Cash Flow and Corporate Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 12-2018 The Free Cash Flow and Corporate Returns Sen Na Utah State University Follow this and additional

More information

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty?

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia E-mail: abarinov@terry.uga.edu http://abarinov.myweb.uga.edu/ This version: July 2009 Abstract The

More information

SHORT ARBITRAGE, RETURN ASYMMETRY AND THE ACCRUAL ANOMALY

SHORT ARBITRAGE, RETURN ASYMMETRY AND THE ACCRUAL ANOMALY MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive SHORT ARBITRAGE, RETURN ASYMMETRY AND THE ACCRUAL ANOMALY David Hirshleifer and Siew Hong Teoh and Jeff Jiewei Yu University of California Irvine, Southern Methodist

More information

Investor Trading and Return Patterns around Earnings Announcements

Investor Trading and Return Patterns around Earnings Announcements Investor Trading and Return Patterns around Earnings Announcements Ron Kaniel, Shuming Liu, Gideon Saar, and Sheridan Titman This version: September 2007 Ron Kaniel is from the Fuqua School of Business,

More information

Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices?

Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices? Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices? Narasimhan Jegadeesh Dean s Distinguished Professor Goizueta Business School Emory

More information