Managerial confidence and initial public offerings

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Managerial confidence and initial public offerings"

Transcription

1 Managerial confidence and initial public offerings Thomas J. Boulton a, T. Colin Campbell b,* May, 2014 Abstract Initial public offering (IPO) underpricing is positively correlated with managerial confidence. We hypothesize that highly overconfident managers, who tend to overvalue their own firm, use underpricing to signal their beliefs to the market in an effort to receive greater value for their shares in follow-on offerings. Evidence from the subsequent capital raising activities of IPO firms supports this conjecture. However, firms with highly overconfident managers do not consistently outperform firms with less confident managers following their IPO, which suggests that overconfidence is not a proxy for firm quality. Running Head: Managerial confidence and initial public offerings JEL classification: D21; D22; G24; G30 Keywords: Initial public offering (IPO); Managerial confidence; Signaling; Underpricing For valuable comments, the authors express their thanks to Joanna Campbell, Alex Petkevich, Heather Rhodes, Jordan Schoenfeld, Scott Smart, and seminar participants at the 2013 Midwest Finance Association Meetings (Chicago) and Miami University. Research funding was provided by the Lindmor Professorship (Boulton) and the ARMCO Alumni Professorship (Campbell). Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. a Miami University, Farmer School of Business, Oxford, OH 45056, USA b Miami University, Farmer School of Business, Oxford, OH 45056, USA * Corresponding author at: Miami University, Farmer School of Business, Oxford, OH 45056, USA. Tel.: ; Fax: ; address: campbet7@miamioh.edu (T.C. Campbell).

2 Managerial confidence and initial public offerings Abstract Initial public offering (IPO) underpricing is positively correlated with managerial confidence. We hypothesize that highly overconfident managers, who tend to overvalue their own firm, use underpricing to signal their beliefs to the market in an effort to receive greater value for their shares in follow-on offerings. Evidence from the subsequent capital raising activities of IPO firms supports this conjecture. However, firms with highly overconfident managers do not consistently outperform firms with less confident managers following their IPO, which suggests that overconfidence is not a proxy for firm quality. JEL classification: D21; D22; G24; G30 Keywords: Initial public offering (IPO); Managerial confidence; Signaling; Underpricing

3 Managerial confidence and initial public offerings 1. Introduction IPO underpricing, which refers to firms apparent willingness to sell their IPO shares at a discount relative to the market s equilibrium price, has puzzled researchers for decades. One well-known explanation suggests that information asymmetry between issuing firms and potential investors leads IPO firms to attempt to signal their quality to market participants. For example, Welch (1989) proposes a model in which high-quality firms use underpricing to signal their quality to the market and to differentiate themselves from low-quality firms. High-quality firms benefit from the costly signal by receiving better terms in follow-on offerings. Because firm quality is likely to be revealed in the aftermarket, low-quality firms do not mimic the signal, allowing for a separating equilibrium. 3 The empirical evidence regarding underpricing and signaling is mixed. Consistent with the predictions of Welch (1989), Jegadeesh, Weinstein, and Welch (1993) report a positive relation between underpricing and the probability and size of follow-on offerings. However, Michaely and Shaw (1994) reject signaling when using a simultaneous equation framework modeling both underpricing and the decision to issue equity in the future. More recently, Francis, Hasan, Lothian, and Sun (2010) conclude that signaling plays a role in the underpricing of foreign firms from financially segmented capital markets, and Boulton, Smart, and Zutter (2013) find evidence that focused IPO firms signal in order to differentiate themselves from diversified issuers. We revisit the signaling hypothesis and study the impact of managerial overconfidence on IPO underpricing and firms subsequent capital raising activities. Managerial overconfidence 3 Other prominent IPO signaling models include Allen and Faulhaber (1989), Grinblatt and Hwang (1989), and Chemmanur (1993). 1

4 refers to managers biased beliefs in their own ability, which lead them to overvalue their firm and its investments. We use this terminology similarly to Malemendier and Tate s (2005) overconfidence in means rather than optimism which has been used at times interchangeably in the literature, but may be interpreted as representing the manager s external outlook. Prior research demonstrates a link between managerial overconfidence and corporate policies (e.g., Malmendier and Tate, 2005 and 2008; Campbell, Gallmeyer, Johnson, Rutherford, and Stanley, 2011; Gervais, Heaton, and Odean, 2011). However, little is known about how managerial overconfidence impacts IPO outcomes. For example, do highly overconfident managers use underpricing to signal their beliefs about firm value to potential investors? If so, this should lead to predictable relations between managerial overconfidence, IPO underpricing, and firms seasoned equity offering (SEO) activities. We first show that simple adjustments to incorporate managerial overconfidence into Welch s (1989) model do not violate the conditions needed for a signaling equilibrium under reasonable assumptions. The model predicts that a high-quality firm could underprice to signal quality in order to receive a higher total value for the firm s equity through follow-on offerings. Because highly overconfident managers tend to overvalue their firm, we predict that they are more likely to strategically underprice their IPO to signal their valuation in an attempt to raise capital on more favorable terms in follow-on offerings. If highly overconfident managers use underpricing as a signaling strategy, they should also be more likely to perform a follow-on offering, return to the equity market more quickly and more frequently, and raise a larger percentage of their equity capital through SEOs, relative to less overconfident or unbiased managers. Finally, because highly overconfident managers tend to incorrectly value their firm 2

5 and its prospects, we do not expect them to outperform other managers over the long-run. We test these predictions using a large sample of IPOs from We construct three measures of managerial overconfidence for our tests. The first measure is based on an IPO firm s investments in the two year period ending with the IPO year. This measure is motivated by Malmendier and Tate (2005) and Campbell et al. (2011), which suggest that high overconfidence should lead managers to invest more aggressively, resulting in greater levels of firm investments. We calculate this measure as the match-adjusted ratio of capital expenditures to beginning of year property, plant, and equipment. The matching procedure controls for the impact of the firm s size, age, and industry. Additionally, this measure is a ratio rather than a dollar amount, helping to address potential concerns that firms with larger cash financing requirements are misclassified as having highly overconfident managers. The second measure is based on managerial decisions around the IPO. Specifically, we focus on three characteristics that are likely to be associated with managerial overconfidence: firm age, share overhang, and recent market returns. The expectation is that, compared to less confident managers, highly overconfident managers will take their firms public sooner, retain a greater fraction of the firm s post-ipo shares, and be less influenced by current market conditions when going public. The third measure is based on an analysis of the wording used in the Risk Factors section of the Form S-1 filed closest to the IPO offer date ( registration statement ). Managers are classified as highly overconfident when the text analysis suggests greater tenacity, insistence, assurance, collectives or plurality, and less hesitation or ambivalence specificity, the avoidance of overstatement, or acknowledgement of the speakers limited vision. Importantly, these measures provide three distinct proxies for managerial overconfidence that are unlikely to be subject to the same empirical concerns. 3

6 We find strong evidence that IPOs backed by highly overconfident managers are underpriced significantly more than other IPOs. On average, highly overconfident managers underprice by 33.8 percent. This compares to underpricing of 18.7 percent and 16.9 percent for IPOs with managers exhibiting moderate and low overconfidence, respectively. The relation between managerial overconfidence and underpricing remains strong in multivariate analysis that controls for other factors thought to affect underpricing. Having established a link between managerial overconfidence and IPO underpricing, our tests turn to Welch s (1989) prediction that signaling through underpricing is designed to improve firms subsequent capital raising outcomes. We follow Francis et al. (2010) and explore the probability, speed, size, and frequency of IPO firms follow-on offerings. Taken together, the evidence is consistent with the notion that highly overconfident managers strategically engage in IPO signaling in an effort to raise capital on more favorable terms in follow-on offerings. Specifically, compared to managers with moderate or low levels of overconfidence, we find that highly overconfident managers are: (i) more likely to raise additional capital through an SEO; (ii) issue SEOs more quickly following their IPO; (iii) raise a larger fraction of their equity capital in SEOs; and (iv) access the equity market for additional capital more often. Our results are evident for each of the three measures of managerial overconfidence and robustness tests reasonably rule out alternative explanations, including those based on misclassification of high-quality or highgrowth firms as having managers with high overconfidence. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we expand the Welch (1989) model to consider managerial overconfidence. In Section 3 we describe our empirical approach, sample selection, and descriptive statistics. In Section 4 we present our empirical results and in Section 5 we offer our conclusions. 4

7 2. Background and signaling model Welch s (1989) signaling model shows that when both high- and low-quality firms exist, and there is a positive cost to a low-quality firm imitating a high-quality firm coupled with a chance that imitation is discovered, a signaling equilibrium can exist where high-quality firms underprice to signal their quality. In the model, three possible equilibria exist: (1) the pooling equilibrium where there is no benefit to signaling quality through underpricing and all firms issue stock, (2) the underpricing equilibrium where high-quality firms underprice as a signal of quality, but low-quality firms do not imitate, and (3) the announcement equilibrium where no signal of quality is needed, high-quality firms do not underprice, and low-quality firms do not issue. Importantly, the equilibrium is determined by the likelihood that investors learn of the firm s quality between the IPO and subsequent follow-on offerings (denoted by r in the model). If this probability is sufficiently low (below approximately 0.2 in Welch s calibration), the cost of imitating a high-quality firm is sufficiently low and low-quality firms will imitate, distorting signals of firm quality through IPO underpricing. As a result, a pooling equilibrium results where firms do not intentionally underprice to signal quality. On the other hand, if this probability is sufficiently high (above approximately 0.6 in Welch s calibration), the cost of underpricing outweighs the expected benefits for both high-quality and low-quality firms. In effect, highquality firms do not need to signal when the probability of investors learning the true firm value is sufficiently high. However, when the probability of reveal (r) is moderate (between 0.2 and 0.6 in Welch s calibration), the high-quality firms can increase aggregate proceeds raised from their IPO and subsequent follow-on offerings by using IPO underpricing as a signal of quality. Low-quality 5

8 firms will not imitate this behavior due to the cost of the signal and a sufficiently high probability that a false signal will be discovered before the SEO. In this equilibrium, underpricing represents a credible signal of quality because low-quality firms will not benefit from imitating high-quality firms, allowing for a separating equilibrium. In this equilibrium, high-quality firms signal their quality by intentionally underpricing their IPO and expect to benefit from their signal through higher issue prices in follow-on offerings. This condition is necessary for the signaling equilibrium to hold. Specifically, in the model highquality firms do not deviate from the signaling equilibrium when the total payoff from signaling (the total amount raised in the IPO and SEO) is greater than the payoff from deviating. Welch (1989) shows that this requirement amounts to: ( ) { ( ) ( ( ) ( ) ( ) ) } (1) where α 1 is the proportion of funds raised at IPO, P 1 is the IPO proceeds, V H is the value of a high-quality firm, V L is the value of a low-quality firm, C is the cost of a low-quality firm imitating a high-quality firm, and r is the probability that the true value of the firm is revealed to the market (irrespective of signaling). Welch (1989) shows that the first part of this condition is equivalent to: ( ) ( )[ ( ) ( ) ] (2) which is true by the requirements in the model that (V L C) > 0, V H > 0, and r is a probability between 0 and 1. The second part of this condition is equivalent to: ( ) [ ( ) ( )] ( ) ( ) (3) which is also true because 2V L 3C > 0. Thus, both conditions will be met, allowing for a signaling equilibrium. 6

9 In the Welch (1989) model, the manager correctly values the firm and has complete information about firm quality. The manager decides whether to underprice to signal quality based on the expected costs and benefits of the signal. Because the potential benefits of signaling increase with the value of the high-quality firm (V H ), a result of the signaling equilibrium is that underpricing is expected to increase with V H. While the Welch (1989) model assumes that the manager correctly values his/her own firm, it is straightforward to predict that, because underpricing will increase as V H increases, underpricing will also increase as the manager s estimate (whether correct or overly confident) of V H increases. This prediction is conditional on the assumption that the signaling equilibrium may hold even if managers have biased valuations of their own firms. However, this will depend on the payoff to a high-quality firm from signaling. We start with the assumption that the market understands that some managers are overconfident. However, due to asymmetric information, the market is not certain whether the underpricing signal of firm value is affected by managerial bias. In this case, the market should adjust the price paid for follow-on offerings to account for the possibility that an underpricing signal represents managerial overconfidence rather than high firm quality. Therefore, we expect the market to pay a weighted average of V H and the value of a low-quality firm, V L C, where each value is weighted based on the proportion of highly overconfident managers, which we denote as HO. This would lead the market to pay V H (1 HO) + (V L C)HO at the SEO rather than V H in response to the underpricing signal. For the equilibrium to hold, managers who believe their firm to be high quality must not have reason to deviate from the signaling equilibrium. Thus, we show that the condition outlined in Eq. (1) is still met under reasonable conditions. We update the first part of this condition as follows: 7

10 2( )( ( ) ( ) ) ( )[ ( ) ( ) ] (4) which can be simplified to:. (5) Thus, this part of the equilibrium condition is satisfied whenever the proportion of highly overconfident managers is less than the probability that the true value of the firm is naturally revealed to the market. As noted above, Welch (1989) finds that, under certain assumptions, an r of between about 0.2 and 0.6 would lead to the signaling equilibrium. As we note in the next section, we find that roughly 10% of firms have highly overconfident managers, which is likely to be less than the probability of reveal for which a signaling equilibrium could exist. Thus, if a signaling equilibrium is possible, it is also unlikely that the observed proportion of highly overconfident managers would cause the equilibrium to fail. The second part of the condition for the signaling equilibrium in the Welch (1989) model also changes when the market updates its estimate of firm value based on the proportion of highly overconfident managers as we have proposed. Similar to the first condition above, we update the second condition as follows: ( )[ ( ) ( ) ][ ( ) ( )] ( ) ( ) (6) which must be true by the requirements set forth in Welch s (1989) model for any HO between 0 and 1. Because the proportion of highly overconfident managers must take a value between 0 and 1 by definition, this second condition is also met, meaning that managers who believe their firm to be high quality would not have a reason to deviate, and the signaling equilibrium could exist. Implicit in our additions to the Welch (1989) model are the assumptions that all participants are aware of the proportion of highly overconfident managers, the market cannot determine managerial overconfidence at the IPO, and no managers believe they are overconfident. If 8

11 managers fail to adjust their expectations for SEO payoffs to account for the proportion of overconfident managers, they would continue to (incorrectly) expect total proceeds from IPO and subsequent follow-on offerings to be V H, the payoff from the original Welch (1989) model. In this case, the conditions for the signaling equilibrium in Eqs. (5) and (6) would revert to the conditions in the Welch (1989) model. The second assumption, that the market cannot determine the manager s overconfidence at the IPO, is similar to Welch s (1989) assumption that the market cannot perfectly determine firm value. Asymmetric information prevents the market from fully realizing the firm s true quality, and thus the market cannot determine whether the manager s estimate deviates from the firm s true value. Finally, the third assumption is typically implicit in the models used in the literature on managerial biases (Malmendier and Tate, 2005; Goel and Thakor, 2008; Campbell et al., 2011). If managers realize that they are overconfident, they would lower their estimate of firm value accordingly, correcting their overconfident beliefs. Thus, the possibility that managers may be overconfident requires the assumption that they do not realize their overconfidence level. To the extent that underpricing can be used to signal firm quality, we predict that highly overconfident managers are more likely to believe their firm is high-quality and, therefore, more likely to use underpricing as a signal, all else equal. This leads us to a number of specific predictions. First, underpricing should increase as managerial overconfidence increases. Formally: H1: IPO underpricing will increase with managerial overconfidence If highly overconfident managers underprice to signal their belief about firm quality, with the goal of raising capital on more favorable terms in follow-on offerings, they should take additional actions consistent with IPO signaling. Based on prior works, this means that 9

12 managerial overconfidence should be positively correlated with the likelihood of an SEO, the number of SEOs, and the fraction of total funds raised in SEOs, and negatively correlated with the time elapsed between the IPO and SEO (e.g., Jegadeesh et al., 1993; Francis et al., 2010) Formally stated: H2: The likelihood of raising capital through a follow-on offering will increase with managerial overconfidence H3: The time between IPO and subsequent follow-on offerings will decrease with managerial overconfidence H4: The number of follow-on offerings by the firm will increase with managerial overconfidence H5: The percentage of total equity capital (IPO plus SEO proceeds) raised through SEOs will increase with managerial overconfidence We use the empirical measures of managerial overconfidence described in the following section to test these predictions on a large sample of IPOs issued between 1982 and Empirical approach 3.1. Managerial overconfidence The empirical literature on managerial overconfidence considers several proxies for this bias, which cannot generally be measured directly. For example, Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008) and Campbell et al. (2011) use proxies for CEO overconfidence based on the CEO s decisions regarding the exercise of stock options granted as a part of compensation and personal trading in the firm s stock. Malmendier and Tate (2008) also measure CEO overconfidence based on the media s portrayal of the CEO. The main shortcoming of these measures is the data required for 10

13 estimation. Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008) use proprietary and hand collected data, while Campbell et al. (2011) use Execucomp data for CEOs at S&P 1500 companies. Because similar data is not readily available for newly public firms, and because CEO option and stock transaction decisions are likely to be highly endogenous with IPO performance, we consider two alternative measures of overconfidence that are available for a large sample of IPO firms. These measures are described in detail below Managerial overconfidence - firm investment Our first measure of managerial overconfidence is motivated by Campbell et al. (2011), who theoretically link overconfidence to firm investment and use firm investment levels as an empirical proxy for managerial overconfidence. Specifically, the authors classify managers as highly overconfident if they chose very high levels of industry-adjusted investment for their firm (as measured by capital expenditures) for two consecutive years. We adapt their measure for the study of IPO firms. Specifically, we measure overconfidence at the IPO based on a firm s level of investment in the two years ending with the IPO year. Similar to the more general setting studied by Campbell et al. (2011), high managerial overconfidence in our sample firms should lead the managers to invest more aggressively, resulting in greater levels of firm investments. One possible concern is that firms in particular industries or during particular periods of time may be expected to invest more heavily, and thus add noise to our measure of managerial overconfidence. Many IPO firms are young and growing firms that require more investment to optimize firm value compared to older and more established firms. We take a number of steps to address this concern. First, we control for industry and firm size by matching each IPO firm to a non-ipo firm in the same three-digit SIC industry based on market capitalization and IPO issue 11

14 year, using a similar procedure to Ritter (1991). We require that each match candidate is publicly traded for at least 3 years to prevent matching IPO firms with other firms pursuing IPOs during the same period. Additionally, all matching firms are required to have non-missing data for capital expenditures and plant, property, and equipment (PP&E) in Compustat. By matching our sample firms to control firms during the same time period on the basis of size and industry, we hope to control for other factors that could influence a firm s capital expenditure needs. We also scale capital expenditures by beginning of year PP&E, which helps to control for the nature of the firm (i.e., whether the firm has largely tangible or intangible assets; whether the firm is likely to require small or large amounts of capital expenditures). We then calculate the match-adjusted firm investment, measured as the IPO firm s capital expenditures to PP&E ratio minus the matching firm s capital expenditures to PP&E ratio for the IPO year and the year immediately prior to IPO. We classify a firm as having highly overconfident managers if the firm has match-adjusted firm investment above the 80 th percentile in-sample during the IPO year and the year prior to IPO. We classify managers as having low overconfidence if the firm has match-adjusted firm investment below the 20 th percentile insample for the IPO year and the year prior to IPO. The remaining firms are classified as having moderately overconfident managers. 4 One potential concern is that this measure of overconfidence is based on a single firm-level variable, while prior studies have used multiple measures of managerial overconfidence. As an alternative, we consider a second measure that 4 The 20 th and 80 th percentiles break-points for low and high overconfidence, respectively, and the use of two consecutive years of firm investment data to measure managerial confidence are similar to Campbell et al. (2011). Our results are substantively unchanged if we use the firm s match-adjusted investment only during the IPO year. 12

15 incorporates multiple characteristics that may proxy for managerial overconfidence, and offers a valuable robustness check for our first overconfidence measure Managerial overconfidence - IPO characteristics As a second measure of managerial overconfidence, we consider an alternative based on multiple managerial decisions related to the IPO. A common measure of overconfidence previously used in the literature is the manager s personal portfolio investment decisions, specifically the purchases and sales of stock in his or her own firm (Malmendier and Tate, 2005, 2008; Campbell et al., 2011). However, constructing a similar measure for IPO firms is difficult because post-ipo stock sales could be largely endogenous to post-ipo stock performance. In addition, most managers commit to post-ipo lock-up periods during which they agree not to sell stock. A possible alternative is share overhang, which represents the ratio of shares retained to shares sold at the IPO. An overconfident manager should overvalue his/her firm s stock, leading to the prediction in prior works that such a manager will hold too large a personal position in the firm s stock. It is straightforward to argue that such a manager would also seek to retain a larger portion of the firm s post-ipo stock as the manager would expect the stock to be worth more in the future when the market realizes its true value. As this is a less direct measure of overconfidence and may also represent other factors, we include it as one part of a multi-faceted overconfidence measure. The second variable used to calculate the multi-faceted overconfidence measure is the state of the broader market when the firm goes public. Baker and Wurgler (2002) find that many firms time their capital raising activities to coincide with favorable stock market conditions. A rational manager should avoid selling stock during a poor market when the firm would receive a lower 13

16 value for newly issued shares, while an overconfident manager might ignore market conditions and issue in a bad market believing that their firm s prospects and their ability as a manager can offset any shortcomings that the firm will suffer due to market conditions. To capture market conditions, we include the return on the CRSP value-weighted index over the 22 trading days immediately prior to the IPO issue date as the second facet of managerial overconfidence. The third variable in our multi-faceted measure is the age of the IPO firm. Fink, Fink, Grullon, and Weston (2010) link younger IPO firms to higher idiosyncratic risk. Thus, we include the difference between the IPO year and the firm founding year as the third facet of our second managerial overconfidence measure. The intuition for including firm age is that highly overconfident managers will tend to take their firms public sooner than managers with moderate or low overconfidence. We use these three IPO characteristics to form our multi-faceted measure of managerial overconfidence. To construct the measure, we sort all sample firms into deciles based on each of the three measures so that the highest decile represents the most overconfident behavior (greatest percentage of shares retained, lowest recent market performance, youngest firms), and calculate the average decile ranking across the three measures for each IPO firm. We then classify a firm as having highly overconfident managers if the average decile ranking is above the 80 th percentile in-sample, and classify managers as having low overconfidence if the average decile ranking is below the 20 th percentile in-sample. The remaining firms are classified as having moderately overconfident managers. An added benefit of this multi-faceted measure is that the data required to construct the measure is available for a larger sample of IPOs than the investment-based measure. 14

17 A potential shortcoming of this measure is that managers might hesitate to go public during a poor market if they expect their firm to suffer from greater undervaluation, or early in the firm s existence if they are less concerned with diversification. However, it is important to note that overconfidence reflects not simply the manager s valuation of the firm, but their view of their ability to control firm outcomes. Based on this, we argue that a highly overconfident manager, despite the belief that the firm is undervalued by the market, will believe that they can overcome this shortcoming by underpricing to signal firm quality. Additionally, our measure requires that a manager must choose to issue public equity early in the firm s existence, in poor market conditions, and retain a large percentage of equity (share overhang) to be classified as highly overconfident. Thus, highly confident managers not only choose to issue public equity during a poor market and early in the firm s existence, but also retain a large fraction of the firm s equity post-ipo. Recognizing that each of these measures are imperfect proxies for managerial overconfidence, we consider a third measure of confidence that does not rely on characteristics of the firm or IPO Managerial overconfidence text-based measure As an alternative to the two measures above, we consider a third measure of managerial confidence based on a textual analysis of the wording used in the Risk Factors section of the registration statement. 5 If managers are more overconfident, this should be reflected in their word choice. Moreover, this should not represent conscious signaling of firm quality through word choice, as the cost of imitation (using more confident wording) would essentially be zero. 5 Malmendier and Tate (2008) and Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012) also use textual analysis to measure CEO overconfidence. 15

18 To analyze the text, we employ a standard text-analysis software Diction that measures the word choice in the text on a number of facets. Specifically, we use Diction s measure of certainty as a proxy for managerial confidence. Texts with more words indicative of tenacity, insistence, assurance, collectives or plurality, and fewer words that suggest hesitation or ambivalence specificity, the avoidance of overstatement, or acknowledging the speakers limited vision receive a higher value of this measure of confidence. 6 We use Diction s measure of certainty standardized by the number of different words used in the text to represent the managerial confidence displayed by word choice. We calculate this for all observations in the sample with the full text registration statement available on the SEC s web database (EDGAR). Similar to the other measures presented above, we then calculate the 80 th and 20 th percentiles of this variable within our sample, and classify managers as highly overconfident if their value is above the 80 th percentile in sample. We classify managers as having low overconfidence if their value is below the 20 th percentile in sample. The remaining managers are classified as moderately overconfident Data and descriptive statistics To calculate our measures of overconfidence and conduct our tests, we use data from a number of sources. Thomson Financial s SDC New Issues database is the basis for our IPO sample. From SDC, we extract all firm-commitment new issues by U.S. firms that are listed in the U.S. between January 1982 and December 2010 with an offer price of at least five dollars. As 6 Our results are similar if we use text measures that place greater weight on insistence and tenacity, exclude measures of plurality and/or specificity, or allow the number of words used to reflect the confidence of the manager. 16

19 is customary in the literature, we exclude limited partnerships, closed-end funds, units, real estate investment trusts, and firms in financial and regulated industries. We retrieve aftermarket prices from the CRSP database and eliminate firms that do not have stock price data available within two weeks of the issue date. Additional accounting data is retrieved from Compustat. These data requirements result in a final sample of 6,243 IPOs. In Table 1, we report the number of IPOs by issue year that fall into the high, moderate, and low overconfidence classifications based on the investment-based measure. The final two columns report the percentage of IPOs in a given calendar year that are brought to market by high and low overconfidence managers, respectively. By construction, the majority of our sample managers are classified as moderately overconfident. The largest annual concentration of highly overconfident managers is found at the height of the technology bubble. Specifically, and percent of IPO firms are taken public by highly overconfident managers in 1999 and 2000, respectively. This pattern quickly reverses when, in 2002, percent of IPO firms are brought to market by low overconfidence managers. Across the entire sample, 7.69 percent (7.32 percent) of the IPO-firm managers are classified as highly overconfident (low overconfidence). << TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE >> In Table 2, we report descriptive statistics (mean values) for the high, moderate, and low overconfidence subsamples. In the final two columns we report differences between the high and moderate overconfidence samples and the high and low overconfidence subsamples, respectively. Underpricing is the percentage difference between the IPO offer price and the closing price on the first day of trading. Underpricing for the moderate and low overconfidence subsamples, 18.7 percent and 16.9 percent, respectively, compares favorably to the 18.5 percent 17

20 average underpricing reported by Boulton, Smart, and Zutter (2010). The average high overconfidence IPO, however, experiences underpricing that is substantially greater (33.8 percent). << TABLE 2 ABOUT HERE >> Table 2 reports other significant differences between IPO firms taken public by highly overconfident managers compared to those brought to market by managers with moderate or low overconfidence. Age indicates that highly overconfident managers tend to take their companies public much sooner than other managers. Highly overconfident managers typically wait about 7 years before going public. This compares to nearly 16 years for moderately overconfident managers and 14 years for managers with low overconfidence. Heaton (2002) suggests that overconfident CEOs, who believe the market undervalues their firm s stock, may be reluctant to issue risky securities. Partially consistent with that notion, share overhang indicates that highly overconfident managers tend to retain a greater fraction of the firm post-ipo than do managers with moderate or low overconfidence. Hanley (1993) documents a tendency for IPO firms to revise their offer price from the initial filing range prior to going public. We find that the typical manager with moderate or low overconfidence tends to revise the offer price very little from the midpoint of the initial filing range (0.2 percent and 0.6 percent, respectively). However, IPOs brought to market by highly overconfident managers tend to experience large positive price revisions prior to the issue date (6.6 percent, on average). Loughran and Ritter (2004) report that just over 39 percent of firms receive venture capital backing for their sample of IPOs issued from We find that venture capital backing is more common for our sample, especially among firms taken public by highly overconfident managers, where 61.6 percent of firms receive venture funding. Highly overconfident managers 18

21 are less likely than managers with moderate or low overconfidence to be associated with equity carve-outs, and more likely to work in a high tech industry. Prior evidence suggests that firms go public when overall stock market conditions are favorable (e.g., Baker and Wurgler, 2002). However, recent market conditions appear to be less important to highly overconfident managers. On average, returns on the CRSP value-weighted index over the month leading up to the IPO are 1.0, 1.5, and 1.6 percent for managers with high, moderate, and low overconfidence, respectively. Debt ratios are significantly lower for high overconfidence firms (11.3 percent) compared to moderate and low overconfidence firms (27.2 percent and 28.8 percent, respectively). 4. Results In this section we provide a motive for highly overconfident managers to engage in IPO signaling. Subsequent tests establish a link between managerial overconfidence and underpricing and explore the relation between managerial overconfidence, underpricing, and the subsequent capital raising activities of IPO firms. The weight of the evidence is consistent with the conjecture that highly overconfident managers use underpricing to signal their beliefs to outside investors. Robustness tests reasonably rule out alternative explanations Managerial overconfidence and offer price revisions IPO signaling models are based on the premise that signaling helps to alleviate information asymmetry between issuing firms and potential investors. This suggests that the value of signaling, and consequently the likelihood that an issuer signals, is positively correlated with the level of information asymmetry. One potential proxy for the level of information asymmetry 19

22 between issuing firms and investors is the offer price revision, which reflects information generated during the bookbuilding process. Prior to bookbuilding, issuing firms indicate a range of prices indicative of where they expect to price their IPO. During the bookbuilding process, issuing firms exchange information with potential investors, which assists the firm in setting a final offer price that is often above or below the firm s initial expectations. For example, Hanley (1993) reports that the typical firm revises their final price downward by 4.3% during the period, while Cliff and Denis (2004) report that the average firm revises their final price upward by 3.1% between 1993 and We posit that issues with greater information asymmetry will exhibit larger offer price revisions. In Table 3, we follow Hanley (1993) and report ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions where the dependent variable is the offer price revision, measured as the percent change from the midpoint of the initial filing range to the actual offer price. In addition to our proxies for managerial overconfidence, we control for the width of the preliminary filing range relative to the midpoint of the filing range, the natural log of the inflation-adjusted offer size, the percent change in the Nasdaq index from the IPO filing date to the offer date, the ratio of overallotment shares offered to the total shares offered, underwriter reputation, and controls for issue year and industry. If firms with highly overconfident managers suffer from greater information asymmetry and thus are likely to benefit more from IPO signaling, we expect to observe a positive relation between managerial overconfidence and offer price revisions. << TABLE 3 ABOUT HERE >> The Table 3 results indicate that offer price revisions tend to be percentage points greater for IPO firms with highly overconfident managers. These results suggest that information asymmetry and the amount of information generated during the bookbuilding process are greater 20

23 for IPOs associated with highly overconfident managers. The implication is that these firms stand to benefit more from signaling due to greater information asymmetry between the firm and potential investors Managerial overconfidence and IPO underpricing We argue that highly overconfident managers underprice more when going public to signal their valuation of their firm to the broader market. Our main hypothesis predicts that underpricing will be positively correlated with managerial overconfidence. Table 4 details the results of six regressions that examine the relation between managerial overconfidence and IPO underpricing. Models 1 and 2, 3 and 4, and 5 and 6 report the results using the investment-based, multi-faceted, and text-based overconfidence measures, respectively. << TABLE 4 ABOUT HERE >> In addition to managerial overconfidence, we control for other factors thought to affect underpricing. Prior research finds a positive relation between uncertainty and underpricing. Common proxies for uncertainty include firm size and age (e.g., Ritter, 1984; Beatty and Ritter, 1986). We include the log of the inflation-adjusted offer value to control for size. Our control for age is the log of 1 plus the difference between the IPO issue year and the firm founding year. Studies find that underpricing is negatively correlated with the fraction of the firm that managers sell at the IPO (e.g., Bradley and Jordan, 2002). Share overhang is included to control for this effect. Hanley (1993) finds that underpricing is positively correlated with the offer price revision. To control for this relation, we include the variable offer price revision. The presence of financial intermediaries is also thought to impact underpricing. For example, Barry, Muscarella, Peavy, and Vetsuypens (1990) and Loughran and Ritter (2004) find a relation 21

24 between venture capital backing and underpricing, while Carter and Manaster (1990) and Megginson and Weiss (1991) report that underwriter reputation impacts underpricing. To control for these effects, we include indicator variables set equal to 1 for venture capital backed firms and firms brought to market by top tier investment banks, and zero otherwise. Top tier investment banks are those with Carter and Manaster (1990) rankings equal to 8 or 9. 7 We also include indicator variables for equity carve-outs, high tech firms, and Nasdaq-listed firms. We include the return on the CRSP value-weighted index over the 22 trading days leading up to a firm s IPO to control for hot markets effects. 8 The gross underwriter spread controls for the documented positive relation between underpricing and underwriter spreads (e.g., Cliff and Denis, 2004). Debt ratio is included to control for firms with capital needs and/or financing constraints. All regressions also include industry and issue year indicator variables. In four of the six Table 4 regressions, including all three regressions (1, 3, 5) when comparing high-overconfidence to low-overconfidence managers, we find a positive and significant relation between high managerial overconfidence and underpricing. The coefficient on the high overconfidence measure in the first results column implies that a highly overconfident manager is associated with an additional 5.7 percentage points of underpricing. Given that the mean underpricing across the entire IPO sample is approximately 19.7 percentage points, a highly overconfident manager is associated with an economically significant 29 percent greater underpricing. Furthermore, we find evidence of a significant positive relation between 7 The authors thank Jay Ritter for providing data on IPO firm founding dates and updated Carter and Manaster (1990) rankings. 8 We exclude the controls for age, share overhang, and recent market returns in the regressions that use the multifaceted overconfidence measure. 22

25 managerial overconfidence and underpricing for all three measures of overconfidence, suggesting that this result is not specific to any particular measure. The coefficients on the control variables in Table 4 are generally consistent with expectations. Consistent with the notion that larger offerings pose fewer information asymmetry problems, underpricing is negatively related to the offer size. We also find that underpricing is positively correlated with share overhang, offer price revision, venture capital backing, underwriter reputation, recent market return, and Nasdaq-listing. The negative coefficient on the debt ratio suggests that IPO firms with greater immediate capital needs or debt financing constraints typically underprice less Managerial overconfidence and seasoned equity offerings In the previous section, we document a positive relation between managerial overconfidence and IPO underpricing. In this section, we explore the possibility that this association is motivated by highly overconfident managers desire to signal their beliefs to the broader market to enable their firms to raise subsequent equity capital on more favorable terms. To do so, we explore the relation between managerial overconfidence and the SEO activities of IPO firms. If the observed positive relation between managerial overconfidence and underpricing is the result of signaling, we should also find that the likelihood of an SEO, the speed at which the firm returns to the equity market, and the percentage of the total equity capital raised through SEOs should increase with managerial overconfidence. In Table 5, we report multivariate analyses that examine the relation between managerial overconfidence and the probability, speed, size, and frequency of IPO firms follow-on offerings. The primary variables of interest in these tests are our proxies for managerial overconfidence. Panels A, B, and C report the results for the 23

26 investment-based, multi-faceted, and text-based confidence measures, respectively. Control variables are motivated by Jegadeesh et al. (1993) and Francis et al. (2010). Underpricing is the first day return on the IPO. Aftermarket return 1 (aftermarket return 2) is the market model abnormal return over the window [+1, +20] ([+21, +40]) following the IPO. Assets is the book value of assets. Fraction sold is the number of shares sold at the IPO divided by the total number of shares outstanding after the IPO. All regressions also include unreported controls for industry and IPO issue year. << TABLE 5 ABOUT HERE >> We first test the hypothesis that managerial overconfidence is correlated with the probability that a firm holds a follow-on offering. In the first two columns of Table 5, we report logistic regressions where the dependent variable is set equal to 1 for firms that issue an SEO within 3 years of the IPO and zero otherwise. Because our SEO sample extends through 2010, in these and subsequent SEO tests we exclude IPOs issued after 2007 to allow for a full 3-year post-ipo window. 9 The results are consistent with signaling by highly overconfident managers. Specifically, firms led by high-overconfidence managers are significantly more likely to issue an SEO within 3 years of their IPO than firms with less overconfident managers. In the next two columns of Table 5, we consider the impact of managerial overconfidence on the time that elapses between a firm s IPO and its first follow-on offering. The intuition for this test is that, if high-overconfidence managers underprice because they plan to raise additional capital on more favorable terms in an SEO, they should return to the capital markets sooner than less overconfident managers. We report Tobit regressions where the dependent variable is the natural log of the number of days between the IPO and the first SEO issued within 3 years. For 9 The results reported in prior tables are similar when we exclude IPOs issued after 2007 from the analysis. 24

27 firms that do not issue an SEO within 3 years of their IPO, the dependent variable equals the natural log of 1,095 days (3 years). The results indicate that high-overconfidence managers tend to return to the equity markets sooner than moderate- and low-overconfidence managers. In columns 5 and 6, we consider the possibility that managerial confidence is correlated with the size of firms follow-on offerings. Firms that expect to raise capital on better terms in followon offerings should raise a greater portion of their capital at the more favorable SEO price, rather than the less favorable IPO price. We report OLS regressions where the dependent variable is the natural log of the ratio of the proceeds from a firm s first SEO to the total equity capital raised (IPO plus first SEO). 10 The results indicate a positive relation between managerial overconfidence and the amount of capital raised through follow-on offerings, which is consistent with the conjecture that high-overconfidence managers raise less capital at the IPO, instead choosing to wait to raise capital during the SEO on more favorable terms. In the final two columns of Table 5, we study the relation between managerial overconfidence and the frequency of a firm s follow-on offerings. Although prior studies do not address SEO frequency in a signaling context, there may be reason to expect a positive relation between managerial overconfidence and the number of times a firm returns to the equity markets. If high-overconfidence managers underprice because they plan to raise additional capital at a more favorable price later, they may return to the capital markets more often than less overconfident managers. We report OLS regressions where the dependent variable is equal to the log of 1 plus the number of SEOs that a firm issues within 3 years of the IPO. The results suggest that high-overconfidence managers tend to issue follow-on offerings more frequently than lowoverconfidence managers. 10 The results are qualitatively similar when we use the aggregate proceeds from all SEOs within 3 years of the IPO. 25

The Changing Influence of Underwriter Prestige on Initial Public Offerings

The Changing Influence of Underwriter Prestige on Initial Public Offerings Journal of Finance and Economics Volume 3, Issue 3 (2015), 26-37 ISSN 2291-4951 E-ISSN 2291-496X Published by Science and Education Centre of North America The Changing Influence of Underwriter Prestige

More information

RESEARCH ARTICLE. Change in Capital Gains Tax Rates and IPO Underpricing

RESEARCH ARTICLE. Change in Capital Gains Tax Rates and IPO Underpricing RESEARCH ARTICLE Business and Economics Journal, Vol. 2013: BEJ-72 Change in Capital Gains Tax Rates and IPO Underpricing 1 Change in Capital Gains Tax Rates and IPO Underpricing Chien-Chih Peng Department

More information

The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information. Production, and Initial Public Offerings. December 7, 2016

The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information. Production, and Initial Public Offerings. December 7, 2016 The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information Production, and Initial Public Offerings December 7, 2016 The Geography of Institutional Investors, Information Production, and Initial Public Offerings

More information

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 9 Issue 3 Fall 2004 Article 7 December 2004 Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets Nobuhiko Hibara University of Saskatchewan

More information

Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy. Richard Walton

Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy. Richard Walton Optimism, Attribution and Corporate Investment Policy by Richard Walton A Dissertation Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy Approved April 2016 by the

More information

The Role of Demand-Side Uncertainty in IPO Underpricing

The Role of Demand-Side Uncertainty in IPO Underpricing The Role of Demand-Side Uncertainty in IPO Underpricing Philip Drake Thunderbird, The American Graduate School of International Management 15249 N 59 th Avenue Glendale, AZ 85306 USA drakep@t-bird.edu

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Underpricing of private equity backed, venture capital backed and non-sponsored IPOs

Underpricing of private equity backed, venture capital backed and non-sponsored IPOs Underpricing of private equity backed, venture capital backed and non-sponsored IPOs AUTHORS ARTICLE INFO JOURNAL FOUNDER Vlad Mogilevsky Zoltan Murgulov Vlad Mogilevsky and Zoltan Murgulov (2012). Underpricing

More information

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior By Jackson Mills Abstract The retention of deep in-the-money exercisable stock options by CEOs has generally been attributed to managers

More information

Do VCs Provide More Than Money? Venture Capital Backing & Future Access to Capital

Do VCs Provide More Than Money? Venture Capital Backing & Future Access to Capital LV11066 Do VCs Provide More Than Money? Venture Capital Backing & Future Access to Capital Donald Flagg University of Tampa John H. Sykes College of Business Speros Margetis University of Tampa John H.

More information

The Signaling Hypothesis Revisited: Evidence from Foreign IPOs

The Signaling Hypothesis Revisited: Evidence from Foreign IPOs The Signaling Hypothesis Revisited: Evidence from Foreign IPOs Bill B. Francis Lally School of Management and Technology Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute 110 8 th Street, Pittsburgh Building Troy, NY 12180-3590

More information

The Role of Venture Capital Backing. in Initial Public Offerings: Certification, Screening, or Market Power?

The Role of Venture Capital Backing. in Initial Public Offerings: Certification, Screening, or Market Power? The Role of Venture Capital Backing in Initial Public Offerings: Certification, Screening, or Market Power? Thomas J. Chemmanur * and Elena Loutskina ** First Version: November, 2003 Current Version: February,

More information

Leaders and Followers in a Hot IPO Market

Leaders and Followers in a Hot IPO Market Leaders and Followers in a Hot IPO Market Shantanu Banerjee İsmail Ufuk Güçbilmez Grzegorz Pawlina December 1, 2011 Abstract We model IPO timing decisions of firms. Our model s outcome suggests that leaders

More information

SUBSTANCE, SYMBOLISM AND THE SIGNAL STRENGTH OF VENTURE CAPITALIST PRESTIGE

SUBSTANCE, SYMBOLISM AND THE SIGNAL STRENGTH OF VENTURE CAPITALIST PRESTIGE SUBSTANCE, SYMBOLISM AND THE SIGNAL STRENGTH OF VENTURE CAPITALIST PRESTIGE PEGGY M. LEE W.P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University Tempe, AZ 85287-4006 TIMOTHY G. POLLOCK Pennsylvania State

More information

Institutional Allocation in Initial Public Offerings: Empirical Evidence

Institutional Allocation in Initial Public Offerings: Empirical Evidence Institutional Allocation in Initial Public Offerings: Empirical Evidence Reena Aggarwal McDonough School of Business Georgetown University Washington, D.C., 20057 Tel: (202) 687-3784 Fax: (202) 687-4031

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Cross Border Carve-out Initial Returns and Long-term Performance

Cross Border Carve-out Initial Returns and Long-term Performance Financial Decisions, Winter 2012, Article 3 Abstract Cross Border Carve-out Initial Returns and Long-term Performance Thomas H. Thompson Lamar University This study examines initial period and three-year

More information

Biases in the IPO Pricing Process

Biases in the IPO Pricing Process University of Rochester William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration The Bradley Policy Research Center Financial Research and Policy Working Paper No. FR 01-02 February, 2001 Biases in

More information

Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing

Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing Michelle Lowry Penn State University Email: mlowry@psu.edu Phone: (814) 863-6372 Fax: (814) 865-3362 Susan Shu Boston College Email: shus@bc.edu Phone: (617) 552-1759

More information

FIRM TRANSPARENCY AND THE COSTS OF GOING PUBLIC. Abstract. I. Introduction

FIRM TRANSPARENCY AND THE COSTS OF GOING PUBLIC. Abstract. I. Introduction The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXV, No. 1 Pages 1 17 Spring 2002 FIRM TRANSPARENCY AND THE COSTS OF GOING PUBLIC James S. Ang Florida State University James C. Brau Brigham Young University Abstract

More information

Heterogeneous Beliefs, IPO Valuation, and the Economic Role of the Underwriter in IPOs

Heterogeneous Beliefs, IPO Valuation, and the Economic Role of the Underwriter in IPOs Heterogeneous Beliefs, IPO Valuation, and the Economic Role of the Underwriter in IPOs Thomas J. Chemmanur and Karthik Krishnan We empirically analyze the economic role of the underwriter in initial public

More information

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? *

Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Prior target valuations and acquirer returns: risk or perception? * Thomas Moeller Neeley School of Business Texas Christian University Abstract In a large sample of public-public acquisitions, target

More information

Demand uncertainty, Bayesian update, and IPO pricing. The 2011 China International Conference in Finance, Wuhan, China, 4-7 July 2011.

Demand uncertainty, Bayesian update, and IPO pricing. The 2011 China International Conference in Finance, Wuhan, China, 4-7 July 2011. Title Demand uncertainty, Bayesian update, and IPO pricing Author(s) Qi, R; Zhou, X Citation The 211 China International Conference in Finance, Wuhan, China, 4-7 July 211. Issued Date 211 URL http://hdl.handle.net/1722/141188

More information

Parent Firm Characteristics and the Abnormal Return of Equity Carve-outs

Parent Firm Characteristics and the Abnormal Return of Equity Carve-outs Parent Firm Characteristics and the Abnormal Return of Equity Carve-outs Feng Huang ANR: 313834 MSc. Finance Supervisor: Fabio Braggion Second reader: Lieven Baele - 2014 - Parent firm characteristics

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

Winner s Curse in Initial Public Offering Subscriptions with Investors Withdrawal Options

Winner s Curse in Initial Public Offering Subscriptions with Investors Withdrawal Options Asia-Pacific Journal of Financial Studies (2010) 39, 3 27 doi:10.1111/j.2041-6156.2009.00001.x Winner s Curse in Initial Public Offering Subscriptions with Investors Withdrawal Options Dennis K. J. Lin

More information

The Macrotheme Review A multidisciplinary journal of global macro trends

The Macrotheme Review A multidisciplinary journal of global macro trends The Macrotheme Review A multidisciplinary journal of global macro trends Signal models and the initial undervaluation of the French IPOs Afef AYADI*, Hatem MANSALI**, and Mohamed Tahar RAJHI*** * Faculté

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INSTITUTIONAL ALLOCATION IN INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE. Reena Aggarwal Nagpurnanand R. Prabhala Manju Puri

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INSTITUTIONAL ALLOCATION IN INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE. Reena Aggarwal Nagpurnanand R. Prabhala Manju Puri NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INSTITUTIONAL ALLOCATION IN INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Reena Aggarwal Nagpurnanand R. Prabhala Manju Puri Working Paper 9070 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9070

More information

BANK REPUTATION AND IPO UNDERPRICING: EVIDENCE FROM THE ISTANBUL STOCK EXCHANGE

BANK REPUTATION AND IPO UNDERPRICING: EVIDENCE FROM THE ISTANBUL STOCK EXCHANGE BANK REPUTATION AND IPO UNDERPRICING: EVIDENCE FROM THE ISTANBUL STOCK EXCHANGE Abstract This study examines the effect of underwriter reputation on the initial-day and long-term IPO returns in an emerging

More information

Tie-In Agreements and First-Day Trading in Initial Public Offerings

Tie-In Agreements and First-Day Trading in Initial Public Offerings Tie-In Agreements and First-Day Trading in Initial Public Offerings Hsuan-Chi Chen 1 Robin K. Chou 2 Grace C.H. Kuan 3 Abstract When stock returns in certain industrial sectors are rising, shares of initial

More information

Do Venture Capitalists Certify New Issues in the IPO Market? Yan Gao

Do Venture Capitalists Certify New Issues in the IPO Market? Yan Gao Do Venture Capitalists Certify New Issues in the IPO Market? Yan Gao Northwestern University Baruch College, City University of New York, New York, NY 10010 Current version: 6 Novermber 2002 Abstract In

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Who Receives IPO Allocations? An Analysis of Regular Investors

Who Receives IPO Allocations? An Analysis of Regular Investors Who Receives IPO Allocations? An Analysis of Regular Investors Ekkehart Boehmer New York Stock Exchange eboehmer@nyse.com 212-656-5486 Raymond P. H. Fishe University of Miami pfishe@miami.edu 305-284-4397

More information

Investor Demand in Bookbuilding IPOs: The US Evidence

Investor Demand in Bookbuilding IPOs: The US Evidence Investor Demand in Bookbuilding IPOs: The US Evidence Yiming Qian University of Iowa Jay Ritter University of Florida An Yan Fordham University August, 2014 Abstract Existing studies of auctioned IPOs

More information

Are Initial Returns and Underwriting Spreads in Equity Issues Complements or Substitutes?

Are Initial Returns and Underwriting Spreads in Equity Issues Complements or Substitutes? Are Initial Returns and Underwriting Spreads in Equity Issues Complements or Substitutes? Dongcheol Kim, Darius Palia, and Anthony Saunders The objective of this paper is to analyze the joint behavior

More information

Completely predictable and fully anticipated? Step ups in warrant exercise prices

Completely predictable and fully anticipated? Step ups in warrant exercise prices Applied Economics Letters, 2005, 12, 561 565 Completely predictable and fully anticipated? Step ups in warrant exercise prices Luis Garcia-Feijo o a, *, John S. Howe b and Tie Su c a Department of Finance,

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

CONFLICTS OF INTEREST AND THE PERFORMANCE OF VENTURE- CAPITAL-BACKED IPOs: A PRELIMINARY LOOK AT THE UK

CONFLICTS OF INTEREST AND THE PERFORMANCE OF VENTURE- CAPITAL-BACKED IPOs: A PRELIMINARY LOOK AT THE UK CONFLICTS OF INTEREST AND THE PERFORMANCE OF VENTURE- CAPITAL-BACKED IPOs: A PRELIMINARY LOOK AT THE UK by Susanne Espenlaub Ian Garrett Wei Peng Mun First draft: August 1998 This version: 18 March 1999

More information

The Puzzle of Frequent and Large Issues of Debt and Equity

The Puzzle of Frequent and Large Issues of Debt and Equity The Puzzle of Frequent and Large Issues of Debt and Equity Rongbing Huang and Jay R. Ritter This Draft: October 23, 2018 ABSTRACT More frequent, larger, and more recent debt and equity issues in the prior

More information

A Comparison of the Characteristics Affecting the Pricing of Equity Carve-Outs and Initial Public Offerings

A Comparison of the Characteristics Affecting the Pricing of Equity Carve-Outs and Initial Public Offerings A Comparison of the Characteristics Affecting the Pricing of Equity Carve-Outs and Initial Public Offerings Abstract Karen M. Hogan and Gerard T. Olson * * Saint Joseph s University and Villanova University,

More information

The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs

The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs Bryan Henrick ABSTRACT: Haverford College Department of Economics Spring 2012 This paper examines the significance of a firm s industry

More information

Underwriting relationships, analysts earnings forecasts and investment recommendations

Underwriting relationships, analysts earnings forecasts and investment recommendations Journal of Accounting and Economics 25 (1998) 101 127 Underwriting relationships, analysts earnings forecasts and investment recommendations Hsiou-wei Lin, Maureen F. McNichols * Department of International

More information

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts We replicate Tables 1-4 of the paper relating quarterly earnings forecasts (QEFs) and long-term growth forecasts (LTGFs)

More information

Multiple Bookrunners, Bargaining Power, and the Pricing of IPOs

Multiple Bookrunners, Bargaining Power, and the Pricing of IPOs Multiple Bookrunners, Bargaining Power, and the Pricing of IPOs Craig Dunbar a * and Michael R. King a a Ivey Business School, Western University, 1255 Western Road, London Ontario, N6G 0N1, Canada This

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

The IPO Derby: Are there Consistent Losers and Winners on this Track?

The IPO Derby: Are there Consistent Losers and Winners on this Track? The IPO Derby: Are there Consistent Losers and Winners on this Track? Konan Chan *, John W. Cooney, Jr. **, Joonghyuk Kim ***, and Ajai K. Singh **** This version: June, 2007 Abstract We examine the individual

More information

Auditor s Reputation, Equity Offerings, and Firm Size: The Case of Arthur Andersen

Auditor s Reputation, Equity Offerings, and Firm Size: The Case of Arthur Andersen Auditor s Reputation, Equity Offerings, and Firm Size: The Case of Arthur Andersen Stephanie Yates Rauterkus Louisiana State University Kyojik Roy Song University of Louisiana at Lafayette First Draft:

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Do Pre-IPO Shareholders Determine Underpricing? Evidence from Germany in Different Market Cycles

Do Pre-IPO Shareholders Determine Underpricing? Evidence from Germany in Different Market Cycles Do Pre-IPO Shareholders Determine Underpricing? Evidence from Germany in Different Market Cycles Susanna Holzschneider* 19. December 2008 Abstract This paper analyzes shareholder ownership of IPO firms

More information

Does Venture Capital Reputation Matter? Evidence from Subsequent IPOs.

Does Venture Capital Reputation Matter? Evidence from Subsequent IPOs. Does Venture Capital Reputation Matter? Evidence from Subsequent IPOs. C.N.V. Krishnan Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University 216.368.2116 cnk2@cwru.edu Ronald W. Masulis Owen

More information

Initial Public Offering. Corporate Equity Financing Decisions. Venture Capital. Topics Venture Capital IPO

Initial Public Offering. Corporate Equity Financing Decisions. Venture Capital. Topics Venture Capital IPO Initial Public Offering Topics Venture Capital IPO Corporate Equity Financing Decisions Venture Capital Initial Public Offering Seasoned Offering Venture Capital Venture capital is money provided by professionals

More information

Discounting and Underpricing of REIT Seasoned Equity Offers

Discounting and Underpricing of REIT Seasoned Equity Offers Discounting and Underpricing of REIT Seasoned Equity Offers Author Kimberly R. Goodwin Abstract For seasoned equity offerings, the discounting of the offer price from the closing price on the previous

More information

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns The Variability of IPO Initial Returns Michelle Lowry Penn State University, University Park, PA 16082, Micah S. Officer University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA 90089, G. William Schwert University

More information

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE (forthcoming) The Variability of IPO Initial Returns MICHELLE LOWRY, MICAH S. OFFICER, and G. WILLIAM SCHWERT * ABSTRACT The monthly volatility of IPO initial returns is substantial,

More information

The New Game in Town Competitive Effects of IPOs. Scott Hsu Adam Reed Jorg Rocholl Univ. of Wisconsin UNC-Chapel Hill ESMT Milwaukee

The New Game in Town Competitive Effects of IPOs. Scott Hsu Adam Reed Jorg Rocholl Univ. of Wisconsin UNC-Chapel Hill ESMT Milwaukee The New Game in Town Competitive Effects of IPOs Scott Hsu Adam Reed Jorg Rocholl Univ. of Wisconsin UNC-Chapel Hill ESMT Milwaukee Motivation An extensive literature studies the performance of IPO firms

More information

Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation

Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation 1 Managerial Optimism, Investment Efficiency, and Firm Valuation I-Ju Chen* Yuan Ze University, Taiwan Shin-Hung Lin Yuan Ze University, Taiwan This study investigates the relationship between managerial

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

Does Managerial Optimism Lead to Long-Run Underperformance? Evidence from Venture Capital-Backed IPOs. Jean-Sébastien Michel

Does Managerial Optimism Lead to Long-Run Underperformance? Evidence from Venture Capital-Backed IPOs. Jean-Sébastien Michel Does Managerial Optimism Lead to Long-Run Underperformance? Evidence from Venture Capital-Backed IPOs Jean-Sébastien Michel Current Version: February 27, 2009 Abstract In a sample of 340 venture capital-backed

More information

Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing

Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing Litigation Risk and IPO Underpricing Presentation by Gennaro Bernile Michelle Lowry Penn State University Susan Shu Boston College Problem in hand and related literature Model proposed and problems with

More information

Managerial Ability and Firm Performance: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis

Managerial Ability and Firm Performance: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis Managerial Ability and Firm Performance: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis Panayiotis C. Andreou, Daphna Ehrlich and Christodoulos Louca January 2013 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Very Welcome

More information

The Design of IPO Lockups *

The Design of IPO Lockups * he Design of IPO Lockups * Chris Yung Leeds School of Business University of Colorado Jaime F. Zender Leeds School of Business University of Colorado First Draft: 8/26/04 Current Draft: 11/8/05 * We thank

More information

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. 5/2014 April 2014 ISSN: 2239-2734 This Working Paper is published under

More information

The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour

The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour The relationship between share repurchase announcement and share price behaviour Name: P.G.J. van Erp Submission date: 18/12/2014 Supervisor: B. Melenberg Second reader: F. Castiglionesi Master Thesis

More information

Investor Preferences, Mutual Fund Flows, and the Timing of IPOs

Investor Preferences, Mutual Fund Flows, and the Timing of IPOs Investor Preferences, Mutual Fund Flows, and the Timing of IPOs by Hsin-Hui Chiu 1 EFM Classification Code: 230, 330 1 Chapman University, Argyros School of Business, One University Drive, Orange, CA 92866,

More information

Earnings Management in Initial Public Offering. and Post-Issue Stock Performance

Earnings Management in Initial Public Offering. and Post-Issue Stock Performance Erasmus School of Economics Earnings Management in Initial Public Offering and Post-Issue Stock Performance Author: Sha Xu, 424970 424970sx@student.eur.nl Supervisor: Dr. Yun Dai dai@ese.eur.nl Program:

More information

Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings

Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings Biljana Seistrajkova 1 Swiss Finance Institute and Università della Svizzera Italiana August 2017 Abstract This paper examines short

More information

The Dotcom Bubble and Underpricing: Conjectures and Evidence

The Dotcom Bubble and Underpricing: Conjectures and Evidence w o r k i n g p a p e r 16 33 The Dotcom Bubble and Underpricing: Conjectures and Evidence Antonio Gledson de Carvalho, Roberto B. Pinheiro, and Joelson Oliveira Sampaio FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

More information

Syndicate Size In Global IPO Underwriting Demissew Diro Ejara, ( University of New Haven

Syndicate Size In Global IPO Underwriting Demissew Diro Ejara, (  University of New Haven Syndicate Size In Global IPO Underwriting Demissew Diro Ejara, (E-mail: dejara@newhaven.edu), University of New Haven ABSTRACT This study analyzes factors that determine syndicate size in ADR IPO underwriting.

More information

Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation?

Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation? Internet Appendix for: Does Going Public Affect Innovation? July 3, 2014 I Variable Definitions Innovation Measures 1. Citations - Number of citations a patent receives in its grant year and the following

More information

IPO s Long-Run Performance: Hot Market vs. Earnings Management

IPO s Long-Run Performance: Hot Market vs. Earnings Management IPO s Long-Run Performance: Hot Market vs. Earnings Management Tsai-Yin Lin Department of Financial Management National Kaohsiung First University of Science and Technology Jerry Yu * Department of Finance

More information

Key Investors in IPOs: Information, Value-Add, Laddering or Cronyism?

Key Investors in IPOs: Information, Value-Add, Laddering or Cronyism? Key Investors in IPOs: Information, Value-Add, Laddering or Cronyism? David C. Brown Sergei Kovbasyuk June 26, 2015 Abstract We identify a group of institutional investors who persistently report holdings

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

How Important Are Relationships for IPO Underwriters and Institutional Investors? *

How Important Are Relationships for IPO Underwriters and Institutional Investors? * How Important Are Relationships for IPO Underwriters and Institutional Investors? * Murat M. Binay Peter F. Drucker and Masatoshi Ito Graduate School of Management Claremont Graduate University 1021 North

More information

Why Don t Issuers Get Upset about IPO Underpricing: Evidence from the Loan Market

Why Don t Issuers Get Upset about IPO Underpricing: Evidence from the Loan Market Why Don t Issuers Get Upset about IPO Underpricing: Evidence from the Loan Market Xunhua Su Xiaoyu Zhang Abstract This paper links IPO underpricing with the benefit of going public from the loan market.

More information

Why Are Stock Exchange IPOs So Underpriced and Yet Outperform in The Long Run? A Test of the Signaling Hypothesis

Why Are Stock Exchange IPOs So Underpriced and Yet Outperform in The Long Run? A Test of the Signaling Hypothesis Why Are Stock Exchange IPOs So Underpriced and Yet Outperform in The Long Run? A Test of the Signaling Hypothesis Abstract: Isaac Otchere Sprott School of Business Carleton University Ottawa, Canada [This

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Are Mergers Driven by Overvaluation? Evidence from Managerial Insider Trading Around Merger Announcements

Are Mergers Driven by Overvaluation? Evidence from Managerial Insider Trading Around Merger Announcements Paper 1 of 2 USC FBE FINANCE SEMINAR presented by Mehmet Akbulut FRIDAY, September 16, 2005 10:00 am 11:30 am, Room: JKP-104 Are Mergers Driven by Overvaluation? Evidence from Managerial Insider Trading

More information

CEO Reputation and Dividend Payouts

CEO Reputation and Dividend Payouts 2011 2 nd International Conference on Economics, Business and Management IPEDR vol.22 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore CEO Reputation and Dividend Payouts Danai Likitratcharoen 1 + 1 National Institute

More information

Advanced Corporate Finance. 8. Raising Equity Capital

Advanced Corporate Finance. 8. Raising Equity Capital Advanced Corporate Finance 8. Raising Equity Capital Objectives of the session 1. Explain the mechanism related to Equity Financing 2. Understand how IPOs and SEOs work 3. See the stylized facts related

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

The Effect of Issuer Conservatism on IPO Pricing and Performance. Stephen P. Ferris Trulaske College of Business University of Missouri

The Effect of Issuer Conservatism on IPO Pricing and Performance. Stephen P. Ferris Trulaske College of Business University of Missouri The Effect of Issuer Conservatism on IPO Pricing and Performance by Stephen P. Ferris Trulaske College of Business University of Missouri (Grace) Qing Hao Trulaske College of Business University of Missouri

More information

Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings?

Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings? Do CEO Beliefs Affect Corporate Cash Holdings? Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe February 17, 2015 Abstract We examine the effect of CEO optimism on corporate cash holdings by developing

More information

The Influence of Underpricing to IPO Aftermarket Performance: Comparison between Fixed Price and Book Building System on the Indonesia Stock Exchange

The Influence of Underpricing to IPO Aftermarket Performance: Comparison between Fixed Price and Book Building System on the Indonesia Stock Exchange International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues ISSN: 2146-4138 available at http: www.econjournals.com International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, 2017, 7(4), 157-161. The Influence

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 5 Number 1 2011 DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN Ming-Hui Wang, Taiwan University of Science and Technology

More information

HOW DO IPO ISSUERS PAY FOR ANALYST COVERAGE?

HOW DO IPO ISSUERS PAY FOR ANALYST COVERAGE? JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, Vol. 4, No. 2, (2006), pp. 1 13 JOIM JOIM 2006 www.joim.com HOW DO IPO ISSUERS PAY FOR ANALYST COVERAGE? 1 Michael T. Cliff a, and David J. Denis b This article reports

More information

Underpricing, explained by ex-ante uncertainty

Underpricing, explained by ex-ante uncertainty Underpricing, explained by ex-ante uncertainty By, Thijs van Rijn Master Thesis 11-10-2016 Supervisor: Drs. Siraj Zubair Radboud Universiteit Nijmegen Nijmegen 1 Abstract This paper examines the influence

More information

Underwriter Compensation and the Returns to Reputation*

Underwriter Compensation and the Returns to Reputation* Underwriter Compensation and the Returns to Reputation* Chitru S. Fernando University of Oklahoma cfernando@ou.edu Vladimir A. Gatchev University of Central Florida vgatchev@bus.ucf.edu Anthony D. May

More information

CEO Overconfidence and Agency Cost of Debt

CEO Overconfidence and Agency Cost of Debt CEO Overconfidence and Agency Cost of Debt : Evidence from Voluntary Turnovers Subramanian. R. Iyer Anderson School of Management University of New Mexico Albuquerque, New Mexico 87131 Ph: (505) 277-3207

More information

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy Keng-Yu Ho Department of Finance National Taiwan University Chia-Wei Yeh Department of Finance National Taiwan University December 3, 2014 Corresponding

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

The Distribution of Fees Within the IPO Syndicate

The Distribution of Fees Within the IPO Syndicate The Distribution of Fees Within the IPO Syndicate Sami Torstila* This paper examines the division of fees within the IPO underwriting syndicate using data on 4,186 US IPOs in the 1990s. Like the 7% gross

More information

Key words: Incentive fees; Underwriter compensation; Hong Kong; Underwriter reputation; Initial Public offerings.

Key words: Incentive fees; Underwriter compensation; Hong Kong; Underwriter reputation; Initial Public offerings. Incentive Fees: Do they bond underwriters and IPO issuers? Abdulkadir Mohamed Cranfield University Brahim Saadouni The University of Manchester This paper examines the impact of incentive fees in mitigating

More information

Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions

Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions Corporate cash shortfalls and financing decisions Rongbing Huang and Jay R. Ritter December 5, 2015 Abstract Immediate cash needs are the primary motive for debt issuances and a highly important motive

More information

Information Asymmetry, Signaling, and Share Repurchase. Jin Wang Lewis D. Johnson. School of Business Queen s University Kingston, ON K7L 3N6 Canada

Information Asymmetry, Signaling, and Share Repurchase. Jin Wang Lewis D. Johnson. School of Business Queen s University Kingston, ON K7L 3N6 Canada Information Asymmetry, Signaling, and Share Repurchase Jin Wang Lewis D. Johnson School of Business Queen s University Kingston, ON K7L 3N6 Canada Email: jwang@business.queensu.ca ljohnson@business.queensu.ca

More information

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University.

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University. Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited Hendrik Bessembinder W.P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University Feng Zhang David Eccles School of Business University of Utah May 2017

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

The performance of initial public offerings in the biotechnology industry

The performance of initial public offerings in the biotechnology industry Gonzaga University From the SelectedWorks of Todd A Finkle 1998 The performance of initial public offerings in the biotechnology industry Todd A Finkle, Gonzaga University Dan French, University of Missouri

More information