Best Practice in Smoothing the Tax Burden: The New Zealand experience

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Best Practice in Smoothing the Tax Burden: The New Zealand experience"

Transcription

1 International Seminar on Social Security Employees Provident Fund, Malaysia Best Practice in Smoothing the Tax Burden: The New Zealand experience 13 July 2010 Michael Littlewood 1 Retirement Policy and Research Centre Economics Department Business School The University of Auckland Private Bag Auckland, New Zealand 1 Michael Littlewood is a co-director of the Retirement Policy and Research Centre, the University of Auckland. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author and not necessarily of the RPRC.

2 Table of Contents Abstract Introduction New Zealand Superannuation New Zealand Superannuation Fund Outline of this paper The background to the NZSF s establishment Ageing population Change to funding of NZS Governance of the NZSF Investment processes Investment performance to date Regular reviews The 2009 Budget announcements The NZSF s impact on the government s balance sheet: the hurdle rate Best of class but The investment decision The hurdle rate Actual return vs. the hurdle rate Borrowing to invest The economics of an ageing population Economic strength matters How do we support the growing elderly population? Where does the money come from? Current workers pay twice Long-term costs probably higher Partial pre-funding or PAYG? Where is the money invested? The investment process The lessons of history The impact on saving decisions Politicising the problem Conclusion partial pre-funding an ineffective distraction

3 Abstract In 2001, the government established the New Zealand Superannuation Fund. This is intended to partially pre-fund the future costs of New Zealand Superannuation (NZS), the universal Tier 1 pension payable to all New Zealanders over age 65. The current National-led government suspended contributions in 2009 and has said it intends to resume those when economic conditions allow. That will probably not be before The legislation governing the Fund required the total cost of NZS, including current pensions, to be calculated on a smoothed basis so that more was contributed in the early years and less in the later. The excess was invested in financial markets on an arms-length basis by Guardians. An analysis in a total accounting context would probably have precluded the Fund s introduction in 2001 because the Fund is effectively 100% leveraged and taxpayers are unlikely to be adequately compensated for assuming that risk. Over the six years to 30 June 2009, the Fund diminished the net worth of the government by about $2.6 billion and, even if it fully recovers those losses, is unlikely to make any significant future contribution to the security of payments of New Zealand Superannuation. In fact, it raises financial risks for taxpayers and may increase the long-term cost of New Zealand Superannuation. Note: the analysis in sections 3 and 4 of this paper draws on Littlewood (2010). 3

4 1. Introduction 1.1 New Zealand Superannuation New Zealand Superannuation (NZS) is a universal taxable pension, funded largely on a pay-as-you-go (PAYG) basis from general taxation. The gross married couple s rate is set in section 16 of the New Zealand Superannuation and Retirement Income Act 2001 (the NZS Act) to be between % of average ordinary time earnings. Following a side agreement between the Labour and New Zealand First parties in 2005, the floor for after-tax NZS was raised to 66% of the after-tax average wage. Despite a change of government in 2008, that 66% floor remains. Rates of NZS vary depending on whether the person is married, single or living alone. From 1 April 2010, NZS at the married rate is $14,229 p.a. before tax for each of a couple, or $28,458 in total for the couple. NZS is taxed on an individual basis and is paid without regard for other income or assets. 1.2 New Zealand Superannuation Fund Section 37 of the NZS Act established the New Zealand Superannuation Fund (NZSF). It is the property of the Crown (section 40) and section 43 sets out the basis on which the Crown must contribute each year. In summary, the formula requires the annual payment to be the net total of all current pension payments (section 45) plus an amount that is derived from a rolling 40 year calculation, intended to partially smooth the amounts that future governments will need to meet the expected NZS outgo. The effect of this calculation is that the NZSF, in the years to 2009, received more than the net cost of current pensions. The excess has been invested by the Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation (the Guardians) a Crown Entity, established under section 48 of the NZS Act. 1.3 Outline of this paper This paper describes the establishment of the NZSF and its governance structure. It then discusses the issues connected with the partial pre-funding of NZS, or indeed any long-term government expenditure, in the context of the government s overall budget and risk management. It concludes that pure PAYG funding is more appropriate for this type of benefit payment. 4

5 2. The background to the NZSF s establishment 2.1 Ageing population New Zealand has an ageing population. By traditional measures, the number of retired New Zealanders will increase over the next 50 years while those working reduce. This is expected to lead to an approximate doubling of the retired dependency ratio (the number of retired who are supported by each working person 2 ). As with many developed countries, the net cost of NZS will about double from its current 4.3% of GDP to about 8% by 2050 (The New Zealand Treasury, 2009a). 2.2 Change to funding of NZS When the NZSF was established, the government described the change to the financing of NZS as a "smoothed pay as you go" way of providing for NZS rather than the pure PAYG system that has been used to support the elderly for more than 100 years (see for example Cullen, 2000a). At establishment, the NZSF was expected to build and to reach, at its peak, 50% of GDP (about $89 billion in 2009 dollars). The smoothed PAYG model sees the government saving money for the future retirement needs of its citizens in much the same way as households do that for themselves. The question is whether this decision might be based on a fallacy of composition. It may be a good idea for a household to save specifically for its retirement income needs but it may not be a good idea either for all households to do that (the paradox of thrift ); nor even for the government to do that on behalf of all New Zealand households. Later sections of this paper examine this possibility. When the NZSF was established, the funding objective was to build up the assets while the annual contributions exceeded the benefit outgo and then to gradually run those down over the period to the year Since then, the long-term objective seems to have changed as Figure 1 illustrates: Figure 1 (Source: The New Zealand Treasury, 2004) 2 The traditional definitions of the working and the retired are entirely age-based and are therefore unsatisfactory. Many between the internationally used ages of for the working population do not work while an increasing number over age 65 do. All those receiving income pay income tax, even the retired. NZS is supported by all government revenue, including income and expenditure taxes from the retired. 5

6 Figure 2 tracks the expected capital flows to and from the NZSF starting, again in 2005: Figure 2 (Source:The New Zealand Treasury, 2004) In the early years from the NZSF s start effectively in 2002, assets would accumulate from the excess of contributions over benefits paid until It seems that the NZSF has become, effectively, an in perpetuity fund. As with the NZSF s establishment legislation in 2001, there was no public discussion as to why the NZSF needed to exist after the last of the baby boomers had died. Figure 3 shows how, in 2002, the total expected cost of NZSF was to be met: Figure Governance of the NZSF (Source:Treasury, 2003) The NZSF is a Crown entity (part of the State sector) that is managed in accordance with the requirements of the Crown Entities Act Its official title is the Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation but is commonly called, 6

7 simply, the Guardians in recognition of the body responsible for its governance, the Board of the Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation. The Board (established under the NZS Act) comprises at least five, but no more than seven members appointed by the head of state on the recommendations of the Minister of Finance. The NZSF s annual accounts are prepared and audited annually in accordance with generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP), as are the entire accounts of the government itself. 2.4 Investment processes When the NZSF was established, the government went to some trouble to distance the Guardians from the political process. It was recognised that a large pool of assets in a relatively small market carried with it a considerable potential for political interference. The Guardians will run the Fund at arms-length from the government. The selection process will begin with a nominating committee. The Minister of Finance will make recommendations from the nominations provided. The Governor General will make the appointments. "Guardians will have to have a background in managing financial investments and will be required to manage the Fund independently of government and on a prudent, commercial basis in line with best practice portfolio management. "They will be subject to independent performance reviews at least every five years, with the first review to be conducted as soon as possible after 1 July, "This elaborate system of checks and balances has been inserted to protect the integrity and independence of the Fund. (Cullen, 2001) In the nine years of the NZSF s existence, the arms-length process has worked reasonably well. That has not, however, prevented politicians from making helpful suggestions as to what the Guardians should, or should not be doing with the money. It is almost inevitable that political pressures will influence the NZSF's investment strategy. For example, it seems that the NZSF will not be permitted by the current government to invest unlimited amounts overseas (see below). It is also constrained by government policy to invest in a manner consistent with avoiding prejudice to New Zealand's reputation as a responsible member of the world community. 3 The government has, under section 64(1) of the NZS Act the right to give directions to the Guardians regarding the Government's expectations as to the Fund's performance, including the Government's expectations as to risk and return. However, any such direction must not be... inconsistent with the Guardians' duty to invest the Fund on a prudent, commercial basis, in accordance with section 58. This requires the Guardians to adopt a prudent commercial basis consistent with best practice and maximising return without undue risk. 3 The NZS Act, section 58(2)(c). 7

8 Despite the apparent independence of the Guardians, there is significant potential for the politicisation of the investment process. The current government s inexplicable pressure to require the NZSF to increase its exposure to New Zealand investments is a case in point. The announcements by the National Party in opposition were less constrained than those now being made in government. For example, National suggested the following as part of its 2008 election policy: National will: Amend the New Zealand Superannuation and Retirement Income Act 2001 to allow the Minister of Finance to give a direction to the Guardians of the Fund in relation to the proportion of the fund which is to be allocated to New Zealand. Set the target of at least 40% of the Super Fund to be invested in New Zealand. Maintain the independence of the Guardians of the Fund in every other regard. The Guardians will continue to invest on a prudent, commercial basis, by making their own decisions about what asset classes to invest in, in line with best-practice portfolio management. In particular, the Guardians will determine the appropriate rate at which to increase their investment in New Zealand to 40%, taking into account their need to manage their overall risk profile, the availability of quality investments, and the impact of increased investment on local markets. (National Party of New Zealand, 2008) The 2009 National-led government has drawn back from that commitment: The Guardians will actively consider New Zealand-based investments as part of their role of managing the Fund prudently and commercially. (English, 2009, page 26) But National could, as it promised in 2008, change the NZS Act to give the government a more direct involvement in the investment process. 2.5 Investment performance to date Most of the NZSF s assets (72.2% at 31 May 2010) are invested overseas and most (55.3% of all assets at 31 May 2010) are in international shares. Figure 4 shows how the NZSF itself has presented its performance against its self-chosen benchmarks. 8

9 Figure 4 (New Zealand Superannuation Fund, 2009) Figure 4 gives the impression that performance that is something akin to the NZ-T Bills (New Zealand Government Treasury Bills) would be acceptable 4. Section 3 suggests that neither this, nor the alternative NZ T-Bills + 2.5% expectation shown in Figure 4 is an acceptable return, relative to the risks assumed by New Zealand s taxpayers. 2.5 Regular reviews Section 71 of the NZS Act requires the Minister of Finance to direct a review of the performance of the Guardians at least every five years. The objective of the review is an assessment as to how effectively and efficiently the Guardians are performing their duties. An independent person, appointed by the Minister must conduct the review and the subsequent report must be presented to the New Zealand Parliament. The latest such review was carried out in (Mercer, 2009) In the 210 page report, the reviewers made a total of 31 recommendations: This review has covered the performance of the Guardians generally but has emphasised two specific areas its performance in relation to achieving its investment objectives and its performance in relation to investment operations. These emphases were agreed by the Minister of Finance via the Treasury prior to the commencement of the review. The governance arrangements put in place by the Guardians had been covered by the Office of the Auditor General (OAG) Review 2008, and the Guardians have implemented most of the OAG s Recommendations. Mercer took these relative emphases on board. Nonetheless, all aspects of the Guardians activities remained part of the Review. (Mercer, 2009, p. 3) Most of the review s recommendations touched on investment targets, processes, strategy, reporting and governance. In general, the review found the NZSF to be...implementing appropriate investment strategies, 4 Section 3.2 details these targets as expressed by the NZSF s Guardians. 9

10 governance arrangements and operational activities to position itself to meet its long-term objectives. (Mercer, 2009, p. 1) With particular respect to the NZSF s investment performance, the review noted that its comparative performance by sector has been mixed: The global large cap equities sector performed moderately well against their benchmark before the sector capitulated to the global financial crisis. The emerging market sector is a little more interesting, performing below their benchmark in the financial years 2005 and 2006, recovering in 2007 and 2008, before falling back against their benchmark in The multi-sector strategy started off strongly in the year ended But it has gone downhill since then with the performance against benchmark getting progressively worse each year. The New Zealand equities, global property and commodity sectors all performed relatively well against their benchmarks since inception. (Mercer, 2009, p. 154) Despite this, Mercer thinks that the performance of the Guardians was broadly consistent with other funds of the same type through the same period. (Mercer, 2009, p. 142) 2.6 The 2009 Budget announcements As part of the government s response to the 2008 economic downturn, the 2009 Budget announced that contributions to the NZSF would be suspended for about ten years: When it was set up, the idea of the Super Fund was to invest Budget surpluses. The Government was then in surplus and expected to remain so for the foreseeable future. Those Budget surpluses have disappeared. Had contributions continued at the previous rate, the Government would have had to borrow an additional $1.5 billion a year, rising to over $2 billion a year during the next decade. It makes little economic sense to burden future generations with debt incurred financing investments that were intended to reduce their need to borrow. We will resume contributions when the operating balance is sufficient in terms of cash flow to meet contributions and other capital spending. On current projections this will be from 2020/21, and will continue for a decade until withdrawals from the Fund begin in around (English, 2009) After the 2009 Budget, the projected peak will now be 23% of GDP in 2056 (about $43 billion in today s money) when today s 18 year olds reach the present state pension age of 65 (The New Zealand Treasury, 2009c) 5. Figure 5 shows the impact of this contribution holiday on the total and net payments in respect of NZS. 5 The reduction from 50% of GDP described in section 2.2 to 23% is caused by the combined effect of the 10 year contribution suspension and the rolling 40 year calculation resuming 10 years after the first baby boomers have started to receive their pensions. 10

11 Figure 5 (Source:The New Zealand Treasury, 2010a) The net cost of NZS in Figure 5, by comparison with the equivalent track in Figure 1 (carried out in 2005) has been updated by later long-term Treasury estimates. Generally, the expected net cost of NZS has fallen in comparison with projections of GDP, mostly because of expected improvements in the latter. This track was unaffected by the 2009 Budget announcement because the NZS benefits were unchanged. What have changed in Figure 5 are: - the net outgo track shows the effect of the contribution holiday that cuts off the new contributions until 2020; - the ensuing tracks between the net cost of NZS and the net outgo after 2030 are now closer, reflecting the now smaller contribution the NZS is expected to make in the future to the NZS payments. For the reasons described below, the past presence of Budget surpluses was an illusory justification for starting the NZSF; the expected return of Budget surpluses will therefore be no ground for resuming contributions in

12 3. The NZSF s impact on the government s balance sheet: the hurdle rate 3.1 Best of class but... While the structure and governance of the NZSF may well be amongst the best of class, the question addressed in sections 3 to 4 is whether the government should have the NZSF at all. There seem to be a number of objections to this particular piece of public policy: this section deals with the most obvious of these the investment risk. If the government eventually resumes contributions to the NZSF from 2020, it will effectively be making an investment decision with each contribution. However, even maintaining the existing assets, as now, requires the government to make that same key investment decision: whether to hold financial assets (in the NZSF) or repay debt in other parts of its balance sheet. Chart 1 summarises the government s overall financial position at 30 June Chart 1 Summary from the government s 30 June 2009 accounts Assets Liabilities Includes $13.7 bn. from the NZSF $93.4 billion (Financial) $14.6 billion (Current) $123.8 billion (Other) $62.0 billion (Debt) Total $217.2 billion $41.1 billion (Other) Total $117.6 billion Net worth $99.5 billion Source: author s calculations based on the financial statements for the year ended 30 June 2009 (The New Zealand Treasury, 2009b). When the accounts for New Zealand Limited are consolidated for accounting purposes (as in Chart 1), the NZSF provides nearly $14 billion 6 on the assets side of the balance sheet. However, whether the presence of the NZSF can be justified depends on looking at the government s overall financial position in a total accounting context. 6 Now, at 31 May 2010, $15.86 billion (New Zealand Superannuation Fund, 2010). 12

13 3.2 The investment decision By maintaining the NZSF s assets as financial investments (and even resuming contributions in 2020 as is intended), the government must assume that the return on the NZSF will exceed the cost of new borrowings it will be making in other parts of its financial activities. The interest payable on that debt is the hurdle rate in this regard. The NZSF usually has a statement in its annual reports about its investment return objective over the long term. Here, for example, is the 2009 version: Our reference point for [the long-term return] is benchmarking the Fund performance against the 90-day Treasury bill rate (i.e. a proxy for the Government s risk-free rate or its opportunity cost of raising debt). Based on our investment blueprint our Strategic Asset Allocation (SAA) our internal expectation is to deliver a rate of return averaging at least 2.5% per annum above the 90-day Treasury bill (T-Bill) rate over rolling 20-year periods.it is important to note that this outperformance is not our target, which is to maximise return without undue risk. In fact we aspire to outperforming the +2.5% whenever we have opportunities to do so. (Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation, 2009a pp 8-9) Phrased in these terms, the reference point (the T-Bill rate) is characterised as one of the two separate return targets. That is the minimum the Guardians aim for; however, the internal expectation is to exceed that by at least 2.5% a year The hurdle rate When the NZSF describes the T-Bill rate as the reference point the NZSF considerably understates its significance to the government. Re-characterising it as a hurdle rate is a more accurate depiction. In a total accounting context, it is a target the NZSF must achieve. For the reasons explained below, to the extent the Guardians miss the hurdle rate in any year, the government is losing money overall. Further, the 2.5% a year that the Guardians aspire to is probably an inadequate margin to compensate taxpayers for the investment risks undertaken by the NZSF. It should be more than an aspirational target. It should be a prerequisite to justify the portfolio s existence in the government s overall balance sheet. The T-Bill rate over the long-term should be the cheapest money the government expects to borrow. It is equivalent to a short-term cash rate. Of greater significance to taxpayers in the context of the NZSF should be the cost of long-term borrowings by the government. In New Zealand, the longestterm government securities are 10 year bonds and the cost of those was 6.35% per annum at 1 July 2009 (the start of the financial year just ended). In order for the government to justify the existence of the NZSF as part of its overall activities in the 2009/10 financial year, the NZSF s Guardians must have achieved at least that hurdle rate of 6.35% in that year before the government as a whole is better off financially 8. As the government s cost of debt changes, so too does the hurdle rate. 7 The 2009 Review of the NZSF s operations concluded that...under our modelling assumptions we consider that the Guardians is expected to achieve its expectations over rolling 20 year periods. (Mercer, 2009, p. 20) 8 The hurdle rate could also be the cost of interest on the most expensive debt currently held as that is the debt that the government should repay first. 13

14 There is a case to suggest that the hurdle rate should be after-tax; at present 4.45% a year for a 30% taxpayer. Although the government pays interest of 6.35%, it collects tax from the lender so the net cost is after-tax. There seem to be three difficulties with this: First, if the lender is overseas, the government collects only 15% in Non-resident Withholding Tax leaving a net cost of 5.40%. Secondly, if the lender is a charity, the government would collect no tax. Lastly, for a domestic lender, if the government had not borrowed the money, the lender would have invested it elsewhere and still paid tax. So the government would receive the tax regardless. Using gross interest as the hurdle rate seems a better assumption. 3.4 Actual return vs. the hurdle rate Table 1 shows a year-by-year comparison for the last six financial years (the most recent one ended on 30 June 2010 and the audited accounts will not be available for some months). In each year, the hurdle rate is the cost of ten year bonds at the start of the financial year 1 July in each case. It is appropriate to fix the rate in this way for the then following 12 months as the government should effectively be making its decisions in this regard on an annual, in advance, basis. Table 1 New Zealand Superannuation Fund s returns vs. hurdle rate Year ending 30 June NZSF s return (Note 2) Hurdle rate (Note 3) 2004 (Note 1) 7.69% 6.15% % 6.31% % 5.72% % 5.85% % 6.71% % 6.35% Notes: 1. The Guardians received the first tranche of money in October 2003 so the first period is effectively eight months. 2. The returns are as reported in the NZSF s annual reports. It seems they are before tax but after expenses. 3. The hurdle rate is the yield on 10 year government stock at the beginning of each year (except for 2004 when it is as of 30 October 2003). Over the nearly 6 years , the average hurdle rate was 6.18%. The average rate of return earned by the NZSF over the same period was 3.91% p.a. (allowing for the initial short year). Looking at just the NZSF s return is, however, only part of the story. Chart 2 illustrates the impact of the hurdle rate by showing the net return to the government in each year, after deducting the hurdle rate. In a total accounting context, this net return is the only one that matters. 14

15 Chart % 15.0% 10.0% m 5.0% u n 0.0% a -5.0% e r p -10.0% % -15.0% -20.0% -25.0% -30.0% Impact of 'net' return (NZSF return less hurdle rate) (part year) NZSF return Hurdle rate Net return However, even Table 1 and Chart 2 together do not show the full story. Table 2 shows an approximate calculation of the accumulated notional deficit in the government s overall balance sheet that the NZSF has produced in relation to the hurdle rate from October 2003 to 30 June Table 2 New Zealand Superannuation Fund s accumulations - actual returns vs. hurdle rates Year ended 30 June At NZS Fund s return At hurdle rate Accumulated difference 2004 $3,956 m $3,861 m $94 m 2005 $6,555 m $6,067 m $488 m 2006 $9,864 m $8,515 m $1,350 m 2007 $12,992 m $10,507 m $2,485 m 2008 $14,212 m $12,963 m $1,249 m 2009 $13,688 m $16,267 m ($2,579 m) Sources: The NZSF s actual accumulation is from the NZSF s annual reports; the accumulations at the hurdle rate 9 assume the Crown s contributions are received evenly through each year; also that all amounts shown in the financial statements as tax paid (including GST) were in fact paid to the New Zealand government evenly through the year in question. In other words, holding all else the same, if the government had not established the NZSF but rather had reduced debt (that would otherwise have cost it the hurdle rate of interest over each of the six years measured), the overall balance sheet for the government would have been better off by about $2.6 billion at 30 June The investment recovery in the 2009/10 financial year reduced that deficit by about half as the NZSF increased to $15.86 billion (New Zealand Superannuation Fund, 2010). However, the accumulated difference in Table 2 as of 31 May 2010 will still be a deficit of about $1.14 billion Hurdle rate calculations are by Michael Chamberlain, MCA NZ Limited, actuaries. 10 Using the NZSF s aspirational T-Bill + 2.5% as the hurdle rate in Table 2 means the government is even further behind. The 30 June 2009 shortfall would have been about $3.5 billion. 11 The calculation for the 2009/10 year is only approximate as it is based on the cited news release from the NZSF, rather than the full, audited accounts. 15

16 To retrieve this position financially, the NZSF will need to exceed the hurdle rate over the coming years by an accumulated $2.6 billion ($1.14 billion from 31 May) but that will only restore the government to its starting position in In other words, having restored the $2.6 billion ($1.14 billion), it would be as though the government had done nothing in 2001 about partially prefunding NZS but had instead reduced debt by the net amounts paid to the NZSF. The key issue, however, is whether over the period to 30 June 2009, the government would have had the fiscal discipline to apply the net NZSF contributions to debt reduction. That is a political, not a financial issue: see section 4.11 below. 3.5 Borrowing to invest By maintaining the NZSF the government is effectively in the business of portfolio investing., arguably not a natural function of a government. There seem to be three problems with this. First, the scale of the government s portfolio investment activities does not add natural value. Next, Table 1 shows that the government has actually been worse off over the last six years to 30 June 2009 by an average of 2.27% a year (6.18% less 3.91%). Thirdly, the total accounting context, illustrated by Chart 1, shows that the government is effectively borrowing to invest 12. Leverage magnifies both positive and negative returns on investments. In this respect, the government is much like households. Borrowing to buy shares is inherently risky because the borrowing increases the volatility of the investment s returns. For the government in a total accounting context, a negative result is a return that is less than the hurdle rate; a positive result is one that exceeds the hurdle rate. The net return over the hurdle rate should be the only one that matters. On average, the NZSF has failed to achieve that minimum target over the last six years. It is correct that this is too short a period for such a comparison to be made. Looking back further, however, is still not comforting. New Zealand s recent history suggests that, if the NZSF had existed since the early 1990s, it would have also failed the basic test by missing the hurdle rate. From a 2009 perspective, this analysis cannot extend beyond 1992 because, although interest rates have been relatively free in New Zealand since 1985, inflation was not brought under control until the early 1990s. Using 1991/92 as a starting point, the hurdle rate to 2009 has averaged 6.98% p.a. Had all the assets been invested in unhedged overseas shares over the same period, the average return would have been 4.91% p.a. To show the 18 year cumulative effect of that difference, using 1991/92 as the base (1991/92 = 100), the hurdle rate would have accumulated to by 30 June An unhedged overseas share portfolio would have accumulated to (hedged, ) Grimes (2001) suggested (in contemplation of the NZSF s establishment) that the government can run its various financial activities as individual entities as long as a recommended Asset- Liability Management Office (ALMO) manage[d] Crown-wide risk, taking into account the portfolios adopted by individual entities. In the presence of the NZSF, it is not apparent how the recommended ALMO might have counteracted that effect except by borrowing further amounts. Grimes does conclude that the Crown should act as a risk-averse investor. An NZSF portfolio that, in a total accounting context is effectively 100% leveraged does not seem to fit a normal investment management understanding of that description. 13 Before tax and expenses. Data supplied by MCA NZ Limited, actuaries. 16

17 That average annual return margin over the 18 years of 2.07% a year, the difference between 6.98% and 4.91%, is not very different to the gap over the last six years since the NZSF started (2.27% a year). That said, looking back is probably unhelpful. The recent past has seen an unprecedented three periods of significant falls in international share prices. However, looking forward does not help either. Using the NZSF s own aspirational target (T-Bill + 2.5%), the Reserve Bank of New Zealand expects long term nominal cash rates of about 6% p.a. 14 Adding 2.5% to that gives a total of 8.5% p.a. Overseas shares might be expected to earn a long-term return of about 9% p.a. with a volatility of 18% a year 15. Expecting a return of at least 8.5% a year from a portfolio that returns between -27% to +45% in any year (with two-thirds of those returns expected to be in the range -9% to +27%) seems inherently risky. According to the NZSF s current Strategic Asset Allocation (Hayward, Dyer, & Frogley, 2007), 17% of the portfolio is to be invested in fixed interest securities of all kinds. Borrowing to buy bonds is probably even riskier than borrowing to buy shares because of the small or even non-existent margin between the cost of borrowing (in other parts of the government s balance sheet) and the expected return to the NZSF. At 30 June 2009, the NZSF actually held 18.5% of its portfolio in fixed interest securities, 93% of that in overseas holdings (Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation, 2009b). Given that 18.5% of the portfolio will probably fail to earn more than the hurdle rate, it means that the remaining 81.5% has to earn 3.1% a year more than the T- Bill rate to achieve what the NZSF describes as its aspirational target but what this paper suggests is a prerequisite in a total accounting context. Borrowing to invest is not necessarily a bad idea. Borrowing helps households and businesses pay over time for lumpy investments. A household takes on a mortgage to pay for the home and then repays that over a long period while living in the home. A business might need to take on debt to expand or buy new equipment if it cannot pay for those directly from cash but can from future profits. Even governments might need to do this to pay for expensive motorway networks or other infrastructure. In this case, borrowing to invest has the added advantage of sharing the costs between generations of users of that infrastructure. An investor who borrows to buy portfolio investments (shares, bonds etc) is engaging in speculation again, not necessarily a bad thing. The borrower takes on the risk that the returns from those investments will be at least as great as the cost of the debt used to acquire them. Borrowing to invest magnifies positive yields and also the losses. It turns a good return into an excellent result; and a bad return into a potential disaster. While a private investor may be willing to speculate in this way, it seems questionable for a government to do that with public money. In a total accounting context, it is clear that amounts added by way of contributions to the NZSF are, as illustrated in Chart 1, effectively (not actually) borrowed money The Reserve Bank notes that the current model includes an assumed equilibrium nominal 90- day interest rate at 6%. This is based on what the Reserve Bank calls a long term neutral real return of 4% p.a. (+/- 0.75%) plus expected inflation. See Björksten & Karagedikli (2003). 15 Using the MSCI World Index - information supplied by MCA NZ Limited, actuaries. 16 The same logic also applies to other investments the government makes, such as in stateowned businesses like New Zealand Post, KiwiRail etc. It also applies to the assets of the stateowned Accident Compensation Corporation: see Littlewood (2009). 17

18 The same applies to assets already held in the NZSF even if the current contribution holiday continues: new borrowing by the government in the presence of the assets held by the NZSF is effectively the same as borrowing to invest. That is because the government has a choice with respect to all new borrowings: it can borrow, say, $1 million and maintain that amount of invested assets in the NZSF or it can sell $1 million of those investments and not borrow. The suggested total accounting context makes clear that a decision to borrow in the presence of the NZSF s current assets is also a borrow to invest decision. In a total accounting context, the NZSF s portfolio is effectively 100% leveraged. 18

19 4. The economics of an ageing population The NZSF sets aside financial assets to help meet the pension outgoings of tomorrow s retirees. Sections 4.1 to 4.11 analyse the implications of doing this: might the presence of the NZSF actually help New Zealand withstand the fiscal pressures of an ageing population? 4.1 Economic strength matters The material living standards of people in retirement are largely determined by their ability to consume goods and services. Retirees cannot directly consume the money represented by public or private savings. Those savings must be used to buy goods and services that are produced by New Zealand's future working-age population or by workers of other countries (imports). The British economist, Nicholas Barr, expressed this point memorably: "Pensioners do not eat pound note 'butties' [sandwiches] they use the pound notes to purchase consumption, and it is consumption that matters." (Barr, 1979) 17 With respect to the growing future number of pensioners, it is New Zealand s future capacity to create wealth that matters. The ability to produce goods and services and to buy imports is the key to the living standards of present and future retirees (and everyone else). Savings by the government or by individuals will not help by themselves. What matters is how those savings are applied (investment and then growth). It is not apparent how the presence of the NZSF will help increase the capacity of tomorrow's New Zealand workers to produce more for tomorrow s retirees to consume. 4.2 How do we support the growing elderly population? An increasing elderly population can only continue to be supported at current real income levels broadly by either increasing output today and tomorrow, restricting consumption today and tomorrow or by improving the productivity of the relatively smaller workforce we expect to have. In a retirement income context, this means, specifically: Raising future output by increasing the working-age population relative to the dependent population of all ages: the young, the infirm and the old, but particularly the last group because it will become relatively much larger. Changing the working population can be done in a number of ways such as: Bringing new workers into New Zealand through immigration 18 ; Lowering the impact on the retirement/work decisions of NZS by having an income test or by allowing a more flexible state pension age. This might have the effect of extending retirement ages on a voluntary basis but may also reduce them as people leave the workforce to take up NZS 19 ; Increasing the state pension age (currently age 65) so that the age from which the future old start receiving NZS is deferred; Increasing the labour force participation rate, such as by reducing unemployment, persuading more people to work 17 The analysis in paragraphs 7.1 and 7.2 draws on Barr (1979). 18 However, immigration tends to import other countries' demographic problems. 19 There is some evidence of this effect amongst men (but not women) in Australia: see Warren & Oguzoglu (2007). 19

20 (including by increasing the state pension age), lowering the unemployment benefit or making that benefit more difficult to get Restricting current consumption and investing overseas with a view to paying for retirees future imports. At 30 June 2009, 76.2% of the NZSF is in fact invested overseas (Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation, 2009a). On this ground alone, there is a case to make that 100% Constraining the consumption of the working-age population in future, for example through higher taxes on wages, to make proportionately more goods and services available to retirees. A compulsory, private savings scheme that reduces current consumption, as long as it has no impact on other savings, can have this effect Improving productivity through investment in education and training. In the debate about the introduction of the NZSF, the last government argued that as productivity rises so do wages (and, therefore, NZS because of its link to wages). On that view, increasing the size of the cake does not help to make NZS more affordable (see, for example Cullen, 2000b). There are two possible answers to this: First, increases in the productivity of capital employed and also innovations can raise total factor productivity and let GDP increase without increasing wages and, therefore, NZS (see below) 20. Secondly, the link between real wages and NZS could change as relative incomes increase Increasing the capital stock and its quality to compensate for the potential labour shortage. That can make a relatively smaller workforce more productive. Also, robots have the advantage of not needing pensions. In order for the government to support the presence of the NZSF as a way of helping to address the problem of the sustainability of NZS with an ageing population, it would have to show how the NZSF will increase output, raise productivity or might possibly constrain the consumption of future workers, as the retired population increases. Of the above list, the only possible contribution the NZSF might make is to constrain current, in favour of future consumption: paragraph above. The NZSF could also, by smoothing tax receipts, reduce the impact of the deadweight costs associated with higher expected taxes: see paragraph below. 4.3 Where does the money come from? The NZSF is used as an accounting device to pass through all the money that is paid to existing and future superannuitants. Total payments by the government to the NZSF for the year ended 30 June 2009 were $9.99 billion but of that, $7.74 billion was immediately paid out to superannuitants, leaving $2.24 billion (about 1.3% of GDP) for investment purposes (Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation, 2009b, p. 63). So, what is not needed to pay for pensions today is left behind to build up into a fund. 20 In fact, employees compensation as a proportion of GDP has fallen from about 55% in the early 1980s to less than 45% in the 2000s: 44% in 2008 (Statistics New Zealand, 2008). 20

21 The transfer to the NZSF of a dollar of tax revenue to pay a dollar of NZS to an existing pensioner is accounting housework. It is like putting a dollar of wages directly into the housekeeping jar instead of the tin for general spending. The partial pre-funding of NZS has been necessarily matched in past years by an equal reduction in money available to fund other activities. For instance, general government debt may have increased; health or capital spending may have reduced or there may have been less available for education. Again there was no change of substance but, for the reasons described in paragraph 4.11, limiting cash resources to fund other activities may in fact have been the main (political) reason for the NZSF s establishment. The recent arrival of potentially long-term fiscal deficits 21 has changed the past justification for the NZSF s existence. They have brought into focus more sharply the substance of what was previously happening: the government s borrowing to invest. However, that difficulty existed even without the deficits. Had the true nature of the NZSF s arrangements been properly debated at the outset in a total accounting context, the risks of borrowing to invest that section 3 has quantified might have been more clearly understood. 4.4 Current workers pay twice A change from the previous pure PAYG approach to a partially pre-funded basis requires workers during the transition to pay twice. Those workers must meet, through their taxes, the costs of NZS for current retirees as at present. In addition, they must pay the capital contributions to the NZSF that, together with related investment income, will provide partly for their own NZS when they retire. It is not possible to change to a partly pre-funded NZS without increasing taxes and/or reducing spending on NZS or other goods and services or transfers like education, health and welfare. If capital contributions resume from 2020 as the government intends, it will be effectively asking today's workers to pay twice (at least partially) for NZS. 4.5 Long-term costs probably higher The cost of any superannuation scheme (public or private; pre-funded or PAYG; defined benefit or defined contribution; lump sum or pension) is the benefits that the scheme pays (plus administration costs). In that regard, it does not matter how the scheme is paid for: whether from current taxes, contributions paid in earlier years or from investment income. Investment risks aside, what matters is the type of structure that is the cheapest to administer. NZS, in the presence of the NZSF, will probably be more expensive than in its absence. 4.6 Partial pre-funding or PAYG? When the NZSF was established, the economic substance of the smoothed, PAYG method of paying for the future costs of NZS received little public examination. In fact, adding a pre-funded component to the process raises a number of issues: No reduction in cost: The establishment of a partly pre-funded scheme does not reduce the cost of NZS, other things being equal. A 21 The government s accounts are expected to remain in deficit until the 2015/16 year (The New Zealand Treasury, 2010b, p. 37). 21

22 transfer to the NZSF of a dollar today that increases in value with net investment income of, say, 5% a year (before adjusting for inflation) to $7 in 40 years' time is exactly equivalent to a PAYG payment of $7 (plus an adjustment for inflation) in 40 years' time. In the latter case the taxpayer can invest a dollar today and earn the same investment income as the NZSF to pay his or her tax bill in 40 years' time. Similarly, the transfer of a dollar of personal income tax to the NZSF which increases to $7 in 40 years' time is matched by a dollar plus related forgone earnings elsewhere in the government sector which, other things being equal, can be expected to have an opportunity cost of $7 in 40 years' time. Contrary to the then government's claim, adding the NZSF to the mix provides no additional security about where the money for NZS will come from. It will effectively continue to come from tax revenue. There is no separate source of funding for NZS. The best that can be argued in support of partial pre-funding is that it affects the timing of tax receipts by increasing today s tax in favour of a possible (not promised) reduction in tomorrow s tax. Neither the last nor this government has promised that tomorrow s tax take will be reduced by the draw-downs from the NZSF that help pay for NZS The strength of the economy matters: There seem to be no grounds for partly pre-funding NZS over similar non-contributory public programmes, such as the invalid's benefit or health-spending, that are presently funded on a PAYG basis. The future funding of these schemes primarily depends on the prosperity of the economy and the government's power to tax 22. Private superannuation schemes are not analogous to state pensions as their sponsors are unable to tax citizens. This is the main reason they seek to provide security for contributors by fully pre-funding their schemes. Governments face no such problem because of their ability to tax and the fact that they do not go out of business. As Nicholas Barr explains it: I know that I will need to buy food for the rest of my life; but I do not accumulate a food fund but intend to pay my grocery bills out of future earnings. The reason for making a pension accumulation is a different one namely that I intend to retire, that is to stop producing goods which I can exchange for other goods; no such accumulation is needed in a world without retirement, where people are immortal, or remain healthy and active in the labour force until their death. Such a world is mythical for the individual but is exactly the case for a country, which does not have to take action to anticipate a time when production will cease. The fact that countries are immortal is central: from an economic perspective, it makes prefunding unnecessary unless it has a positive effect on output... (Barr, 2000) Re-arranging claims on the economy: It is a good idea for individuals or employers to put aside money for future retirement payments. However, it does not follow that what is right for an individual is necessarily right for the country. Building up the NZSF will 22 The Ministry of Health suggests that healthcare costs will rise from 6.2% of GDP to 9.2% by 2051 (Ministry of Health, 2004). If a government were concerned about the future affordability of health care, why is there no proposal for a similar "smoothed pay as you go" approach to rising health costs? There seems to be no economic distinction between these two demographically influenced programmes. 22

23 re-arrange claims on today's economy between earners and nonearners and also, through overseas investment, as between New Zealand and other countries. However, that does not necessarily increase the security of the claims by both tomorrow s earners and non-earners. Only a stronger economy can do that. There is an even more significant political issue in this connection. The NZSF is founded on the principle that, when a future government looks at the amount to be spent on NZS, it will have regard for only the net amount, after allowing for the receipts from the NZSF. This seems unrealistic politically. The government is more likely to make compensating adjustments in other parts of its spending to allow for the NZSF s contributions. In other words, the existence of the NZSF and the expected future draw-downs can give no assurance that total spending is likely to be less in the presence of those draw-downs. The contrary view seems just as likely: that total government spending would be higher in the presence of the NZSF draw-downs than in their absence (with a pure PAYG pension). In fact, NZS is (and should continue to be) part of an annual balancing by governments of spending priorities against income. In any year, the annual amount of NZS is effectively the total amount the government decides to spend on NZS divided by the number of people then eligible to receive it. The presence (or absence) of the NZSF does not affect that fundamental process. It may affect the pocket from which amounts come but is unlikely to affect the process itself. In that way, the NZSF might obscure a political safety valve. Given that the country s capacity to meet the economic obligations to superannuitants (both public and private) depends on the strength of the contemporary economy, the NZSF will partly disguise one of the safety valves that will be required to regulate the relative equities of competing claims on that economy. The annual budget process is the most practical example of the way in which those relative equities are resolved year by year. The NZSF creates a partial barrier for that ongoing, self-balancing process Increases retirement income costs: The presence of the NZSF may mean that NZS costs more than the past pure PAYG arrangements. First, there are the risks of investment losses, both direct and indirect, that, as at 30 June 2009, effectively amount to about $2.6 billion (see section 3 above). Then there are the potential losses that the New Zealand government might suffer if the NZSF fails in the future to achieve returns at least equal to the hurdle rate. Finally, there are the administration costs of running the NZSF. According to the NZSF, these amounted to $96.8 million for the 2008/09 year (Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation, 2009b at page 74) or 0.69% of average assets for the 2008/09 year Deadweight costs of higher tax: If, as suggested in paragraph 4.6.4, NZS costs more over the long term than the pure PAYG alternative, taxes must also be higher unless other spending is constrained. Higher taxes involve indirect costs, such as the deadweight costs on the economy. Collecting taxes is not costless. Not only are there the direct administrative costs but there are more subtle, but real costs to the economy as people change their behaviour as a result of the structure of taxation. These are the deadweight costs or sometimes known as the social costs of the tax system s design See, for example, Becker (1985). The deadweight costs in the present case do not apply to the higher taxes collected during the build-up of the NZSF as these should be matched by the 23

How much will New Zealand Superannuation really cost?

How much will New Zealand Superannuation really cost? How much will New Zealand Superannuation really cost? RPRC PensionBriefing 2010-4 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- This PensionBriefing

More information

The NZ Super Fund and the partial prefunding of universal superannuation

The NZ Super Fund and the partial prefunding of universal superannuation The NZ Super Fund and the partial prefunding of universal superannuation Prepared by the Guardians of New Zealand Superannuation at the request of the Commission for Financial Capability, July 2016 For

More information

Why does the Accident Compensation Corporation have a fund?

Why does the Accident Compensation Corporation have a fund? Why does the Accident Compensation Corporation have a fund? Michael Littlewood PensionCommentary 2009-1 1 19 August 2009 (revised 12 October 2009) -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

TITLE: Guardians of NZ Superannuation and New Zealand Superannuation Fund Review AUTHOR:

TITLE: Guardians of NZ Superannuation and New Zealand Superannuation Fund Review AUTHOR: TITLE: Guardians of NZ Superannuation and New Zealand Superannuation Fund 2017-18 Review AUTHOR: Catherine Savage CHAIR Matt Whineray CEO EVENT PRESENTATION: Finance & Expenditure Select Committee, 20

More information

Guardians of NZ Superannuation and New Zealand Superannuation Fund

Guardians of NZ Superannuation and New Zealand Superannuation Fund TITLE: Guardians of NZ Superannuation and New Zealand Superannuation Fund 2013/14 Review AUTHOR: Gavin Walker CHAIRMAN Adrian Orr CEO EVENT PRESENTATION: Commerce Select Committee, 26 February 2015 Agenda

More information

New Zealand Superannuation Bill. Government Bill 2000 No Explanatory Note

New Zealand Superannuation Bill. Government Bill 2000 No Explanatory Note New Zealand Superannuation Bill Government Bill 2000 No 89-1 Explanatory Note General policy statement This proposed legislation seeks to establish a New Zealand Superannuation Fund to be administered

More information

B.20 SPE (2017) Statement of Performance Expectations

B.20 SPE (2017) Statement of Performance Expectations B.20 SPE (2017) Statement of Performance Expectations 1 July 2017 Contents Statement from the Board 1 The Authority 3 Investment 5 Schemes 11 Forecast Financial Statements 15 Government Superannuation

More information

B.20 SPE (2018) Statement of Performance Expectations

B.20 SPE (2018) Statement of Performance Expectations B.20 SPE (2018) Statement of Performance Expectations 1 July 2018 Contents Statement from the Board 1 The Authority 3 Investment 5 Schemes 10 Forecast Financial Statements 15 Government Superannuation

More information

Long-Term Fiscal External Panel

Long-Term Fiscal External Panel Long-Term Fiscal External Panel Summary: Session One Fiscal Framework and Projections 30 August 2012 (9:30am-3:30pm), Victoria Business School, Level 12 Rutherford House The first session of the Long-Term

More information

STATEMENT OF PERFORMANCE EXPECTATIONS

STATEMENT OF PERFORMANCE EXPECTATIONS B.21 STATEMENT OF PERFORMANCE EXPECTATIONS FOR THE PERIOD 01 JULY 2016 TO 30 JUNE 2017 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION Contents SECTION 1 Introduction... 1 SECTION 2 Our Mandate... 2 SECTION 3

More information

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2014

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2014 B.20a Report on the ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2014 2014 Presented to the House of Representatives pursuant to section 94 of the Government Superannuation Fund Act 1956 Contents 1. INTRODUCTION

More information

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2015

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2015 B.20a Report on the ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2015 2015 Presented to the House of Representatives pursuant to section 94 of the Government Superannuation Fund Act 1956 Contents 1. INTRODUCTION

More information

Report on the Public Service Pension Plan. for the Fiscal Year Ended March 31, nnual report

Report on the Public Service Pension Plan. for the Fiscal Year Ended March 31, nnual report A N N UA L R E P O R T T O PA R L I A M E N T Report on the Public Service Pension Plan for the Fiscal Year Ended March 31, 2009 nnual report Report on the Public Service Pension Plan for the Fiscal Year

More information

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2017

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2017 B.20a Report on the ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2017 Presented to the House of Representatives pursuant to section 94 of the Government Superannuation Fund Act 1956 Contents 1. Introduction 1 2.

More information

CHAPTER 3 - NON-CONCESSIONARY OPTIONS. 3.1 Taxed/Taxed/Exempt

CHAPTER 3 - NON-CONCESSIONARY OPTIONS. 3.1 Taxed/Taxed/Exempt - 17 - CHAPTER 3 - NON-CONCESSIONARY OPTIONS 3.1 Taxed/Taxed/Exempt The Consultative Document proposed that contributions to superannuation schemes should be from tax paid income, rather than being deductible

More information

Government of the Northwest Territories Budget Cuts: A Review

Government of the Northwest Territories Budget Cuts: A Review Government of the Northwest Territories 2008-2009 Budget Cuts: A Review Prepared by Alternatives North June 11, 2008 GNWT 2008-2009 Budget Cuts: A Review Contents Introduction... 1 The cuts announcements...

More information

NEW ZEALAND Overview of the tax-benefit system

NEW ZEALAND Overview of the tax-benefit system NEW ZEALAND 2005 1. Overview of the tax-benefit system The provision of social security benefits in New Zealand is funded from general taxation and not specific social security contributions. For example,

More information

6. WHO GETS WHAT - Recommendations: Change Today

6. WHO GETS WHAT - Recommendations: Change Today 6. WHO GETS WHAT - Recommendations: Change Today 6.1. Increase the age of eligibility to 67 years for New Zealand Superannuation. 6.2. Increase the length of residence required for New Zealand Superannuation

More information

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2016

ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2016 B.20a Report on the ACTUARIAL VALUATION as at 30 June 2016 2016 Presented to the House of Representatives pursuant to section 94 of the Government Superannuation Fund Act 1956 Contents 1. INTRODUCTION

More information

A way forward for NZ Superannuation. Peter Cosseboom

A way forward for NZ Superannuation. Peter Cosseboom A way forward for NZ Superannuation Peter Cosseboom Welfare Cashflow based Look through variations Most unaffected by population changes Exceptions are health and retirement National Party Keep age 65

More information

What are the next steps?

What are the next steps? KiwiSaver and the ageing population: What are the next steps? Susan St John RPRC Business School The University of Auckland KiwiSaver is here to stay But how stable and sensible are our policies looking

More information

Scrutiny Unit Briefing Note

Scrutiny Unit Briefing Note Scrutiny Unit Briefing Note Public Sector Pensions This note provides background and briefing to help you understand the key figures in the accounts of public sector pension schemes. It sets out the main

More information

Reforming Public Service Pensions

Reforming Public Service Pensions elete this text box to isplay the color squar; you ay also insert an image or lient logo in this space. o delete the text box, click within ext, hit the Esc key and then the elete key 4 December 2008 Reforming

More information

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard SLAS 16. Retirement Benefit Costs

Sri Lanka Accounting Standard SLAS 16. Retirement Benefit Costs Sri Lanka Accounting Standard SLAS 16 Retirement Benefit Costs Contents Sri Lanka Accounting Standard SLAS 16 Retirement Benefit Costs paragraphs OBJECTIVE SCOPE 1-3 DEFINITIONS 4-14 Retirement Benefit

More information

Exemplar for Internal Assessment Resource Economics Level 2

Exemplar for Internal Assessment Resource Economics Level 2 Exemplar for internal assessment resource Economics 2.6A for Achievement Standard 91227 Exemplar for Internal Assessment Resource Economics Level 2 Resource title: Government policies that could lift the

More information

Challenger Guaranteed Annuity

Challenger Guaranteed Annuity Challenger Guaranteed Annuity Product Disclosure Statement (PDS) Dated 13 June 2014 Challenger Guaranteed Annuity (SPIN CHG0005AU) Issuer Challenger Life Company Limited (ABN 44 072 486 938) (AFSL 234670)

More information

Superannuation System

Superannuation System Making a fairer and more sustainable Superannuation System Fact sheets and Q&As Superannuation fact sheets Contents Fact sheet 01: A superannuation system that is sustainable, flexible and has integrity

More information

Ensuring a Sustainable Pension Plan. for the. University of Toronto

Ensuring a Sustainable Pension Plan. for the. University of Toronto Ensuring a Sustainable Pension Plan for the University of Toronto January 2011 58714 Table of Contents Executive Summary...3 Introduction......5 Background..5 The Problem.8 Projections for Dealing with

More information

Outlook for Scotland s Public Finances and the Opportunities of Independence. May 2014

Outlook for Scotland s Public Finances and the Opportunities of Independence. May 2014 Outlook for Scotland s Public Finances and the Opportunities of Independence May 2014 1 Table of Contents Executive Summary... 3 Introduction and Overview... 5 Scotland s Public Finances 2008-09 to 2012-13...

More information

Social assistance integrity: defining family income

Social assistance integrity: defining family income Social assistance integrity: defining family income An officials issues paper August 2010 Prepared by the Policy Advice Division of the Inland Revenue Department and by the New Zealand Treasury First published

More information

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group Tax and fairness Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group This paper contains advice that has been prepared by the Tax Working Group Secretariat for consideration by the Tax Working Group.

More information

Chair, Cabinet Economic Growth and Infrastructure Committee

Chair, Cabinet Economic Growth and Infrastructure Committee In Confidence Office of the Minister for Workplace Relations and Safety Chair, Cabinet Economic Growth and Infrastructure Committee Annual Minimum Wage Review 2016 Proposal 1. This paper proposes: 1.1

More information

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments Address by Mr Ric Battellino, Deputy Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, at the Annual Stockbrokers Conference, Sydney, 26 May 2011. * * * Introduction

More information

B.21 STATEMENT OF PERFORMANCE EXPECTATIONS FOR THE PERIOD 1 JULY 2017 TO 30 JUNE 2018 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION

B.21 STATEMENT OF PERFORMANCE EXPECTATIONS FOR THE PERIOD 1 JULY 2017 TO 30 JUNE 2018 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION B.21 STATEMENT OF PERFORMANCE EXPECTATIONS FOR THE PERIOD 1 JULY 2017 TO 30 JUNE 2018 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION Contents 1. Introduction... 1 2. Our ultimate goal (outcome) and strategic

More information

The Report must not be used for any commercial purposes unless Hymans Robertson LLP agrees in advance.

The Report must not be used for any commercial purposes unless Hymans Robertson LLP agrees in advance. Hymans Robertson LLP has carried out an actuarial valuation of the Lincolnshire County Council Pension Fund ( the Fund ) as at 31 March 2010, details of which are set out in the report dated 23 ( the Report

More information

B.21 STATEMENT OF INTENT FOR THE PERIOD COMMENCING 01 JULY 2016 TO 30 JUNE 2021 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION

B.21 STATEMENT OF INTENT FOR THE PERIOD COMMENCING 01 JULY 2016 TO 30 JUNE 2021 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION B.21 STATEMENT OF INTENT FOR THE PERIOD COMMENCING 01 JULY 2016 TO 30 JUNE 2021 GUARDIANS OF NEW ZEALAND SUPERANNUATION Contents SECTION 1 Foreword from the Board Chair... 1 SECTION 2 Introduction to the

More information

Issues linked to Settlement and population. The UK s ageing population; a contemporary geographical issue

Issues linked to Settlement and population. The UK s ageing population; a contemporary geographical issue Issues linked to Settlement and population The UK s ageing population; a contemporary geographical issue We are healthier, living longer and doing more than ever before. What is the problem? What is the

More information

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy 1 Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy At the end of Class 26, you will be able to answer the following: 1. How is the government purchases multiplier calculated? (Review) How is the taxation multiplier

More information

CHAPTER 03. A Modern and. Pensions System

CHAPTER 03. A Modern and. Pensions System CHAPTER 03 A Modern and Sustainable Pensions System 24 Introduction 3.1 A key objective of pension policy design is to ensure the sustainability of the system over the longer term. Financial sustainability

More information

Susan St John, Co-director, Retirement Policy and Research centre introduced the session:

Susan St John, Co-director, Retirement Policy and Research centre introduced the session: Breakfast Briefing, Wednesday 3 November KiwiSaver turns 3: are we celebrating? Proceedings of a breakfast seminar at The University of Auckland Business School, Decima Glenn Room, Level 3, Owen G Glenn

More information

Your AVC Scheme & Public Sector PRSA. Member Guide

Your AVC Scheme & Public Sector PRSA. Member Guide Your AVC Scheme & Public Sector PRSA Member Guide 2 AVC and PRSA Member Guide Your AVC Scheme & Public Sector PRSA Contents How an AVC Plan works 6 Why an AVC Plan may be right for you 8 Setting up an

More information

KiwiSaver advice. 7 March This guidance note is for advisers and. financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products.

KiwiSaver advice. 7 March This guidance note is for advisers and. financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products. 7 March 2017 KiwiSaver advice This guidance note is for advisers and financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products. It gives guidance on when advice is class advice, personalised advice or just information.

More information

Annual report. KiwiSaver evaluation. July 2011 to June 2012

Annual report. KiwiSaver evaluation. July 2011 to June 2012 KiwiSaver evaluation Annual report July 2011 to June 2012 Prepared by: National Research and Evaluation Unit, Inland Revenue for the KiwiSaver Evaluation Steering Group Date: September 2012 1 Contents

More information

New Zealand Superannuation Fund Case Study Latest Asset Allocation Review. 8 July Tore Hayward General Manager Portfolio Research

New Zealand Superannuation Fund Case Study Latest Asset Allocation Review. 8 July Tore Hayward General Manager Portfolio Research New Zealand Superannuation Fund Case Study Latest Asset Allocation Review 8 July 2008 Tore Hayward General Manager Portfolio Research Outline Context Purpose of Fund and where we re at Focus on two key

More information

10 YEARS OF WORKING FOR THE FUTURE OF NEW ZEALANDERS...

10 YEARS OF WORKING FOR THE FUTURE OF NEW ZEALANDERS... 10 YEARS OF WORKING FOR THE FUTURE OF NEW ZEALANDERS... THE FIRST DECADE OF MANY THE GUARDIANS MISSION IS TO MAXIMISE THE FUND S RETURNS OVER THE LONG TERM, WITHOUT UNDUE RISK, SO AS TO REDUCE FUTURE

More information

BBC Pension Scheme. Actuarial valuation as at 1 April June willistowerswatson.com

BBC Pension Scheme. Actuarial valuation as at 1 April June willistowerswatson.com BBC Pension Scheme Actuarial valuation as at 1 April 2016 30 June 2017 willistowerswatson.com 1 Summary The main results of the Scheme s actuarial valuation are as follows: Technical provisions funding

More information

PRINT. MEDIA. ENTERTAINMENT. ARTS. OURCOMMUNITY PLUS. Product Disclosure Statement

PRINT. MEDIA. ENTERTAINMENT. ARTS. OURCOMMUNITY PLUS. Product Disclosure Statement PRINT. MEDIA. ENTERTAINMENT. ARTS. OURCOMMUNITY PLUS Product Disclosure Statement Issued 1 October 2018 CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCING LIFETIMEPLUS 4 How LifetimePlus works 4 2. WHO CAN INVEST? 5 What this means

More information

KiwiSaver advice. 7 November This guidance note is for advisers and. financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products.

KiwiSaver advice. 7 November This guidance note is for advisers and. financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products. 7 November 2016 KiwiSaver advice This guidance note is for advisers and financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products. It gives guidance on when advice is class advice, personalised advice or just information.

More information

NATIONAL PENSION STRATEGY

NATIONAL PENSION STRATEGY FEBRUARY 2016 NATIONAL PENSION STRATEGY An Ireland for all. MICHAEL McGRATH FIANNA FÁIL SPOKESPERSON ON FINANCE Executive summary Pension provision is an issue which should concern everyone in society,

More information

REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013

REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013 REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013 CONTENTS 1. Introduction... 1 2. Approach and methodology... 8 3. Current priority order...

More information

The Swedish old-age pension system. How the income pension, premium pension and guarantee pension work

The Swedish old-age pension system. How the income pension, premium pension and guarantee pension work The Swedish old-age pension system How the income pension, premium pension and guarantee pension work The Swedish old-age pension system How the income pension, premium pension and guarantee pension work

More information

Modelling the distributional aspects of KiwiSaver: methodology and results

Modelling the distributional aspects of KiwiSaver: methodology and results Modelling the distributional aspects of KiwiSaver: methodology and results RPRC PensionBriefing 2009-6 The taxpayer-funded subsidies to KiwiSaver are distributed to members based on the contributions made

More information

The equity and sustainability of government assistance for retirement income in Australia

The equity and sustainability of government assistance for retirement income in Australia The equity and sustainability of government assistance for retirement income in Australia Ross Clare Director of Research July 2014 1 of 15 The Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia Limited

More information

International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly

International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly RPRC PensionBriefing 2009-1 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- This PensionBriefing

More information

RETIREMENT INCOME STREAMS PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT

RETIREMENT INCOME STREAMS PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT IAG & NRMA S U P E R A N N U AT I O N P L A N RETIREMENT INCOME STREAMS PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT Allocated Pensions Transition to Retirement Income Streams Issue No. 3 dated 15 September 2010 IAG &

More information

Multiple generations in one SMSF a great idea or a disaster waiting to happen?

Multiple generations in one SMSF a great idea or a disaster waiting to happen? Multiple generations in one SMSF a great idea or a disaster waiting a great idea or a disaster waiting 1 / Introduction Most SMSFs have just one or two members (typically a couple). However, the law allows

More information

Superannuation account balances by age and gender

Superannuation account balances by age and gender Superannuation account balances by age and gender October 2017 Ross Clare, Director of Research ASFA Research and Resource Centre The Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia Limited (ASFA) PO

More information

Pension Schemes Bill Impact Assessment. Summary of Impacts

Pension Schemes Bill Impact Assessment. Summary of Impacts Pension Schemes Bill Impact Assessment Summary of Impacts June 2014 Contents 1 Introduction... 3 Background... 4 Categories of Pension Scheme... 4 General Changes to Pensions Legislation... 4 Collective

More information

Submission to the Commonwealth Government on the Objective of Superannuation

Submission to the Commonwealth Government on the Objective of Superannuation Division Head Retirement Income Policy Division The Treasury Langton Crescent PARKES ACT 2600 6 th April, 2016 Dear Sir/Madam, Submission to the Commonwealth Government on the Objective of Superannuation

More information

ACTUARIAL REPORT 25 th. on the

ACTUARIAL REPORT 25 th. on the 25 th on the CANADA PENSION PLAN Office of the Chief Actuary Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions Canada 16 th Floor, Kent Square Building 255 Albert Street Ottawa, Ontario K1A 0H2 Facsimile:

More information

B.20 SOI (2017) Statement Of Intent

B.20 SOI (2017) Statement Of Intent B.20 SOI (2017) Statement Of Intent 1 July 2017 to 30 June 2021 Contents Statement from the Board 1 The Authority 3 Investment 6 Schemes 17 Organisational Health and Capability 21 Consultation and Reporting

More information

HEALTH SUPER DB FUND REPORT TO THE TRUSTEE ON THE ACTUARIAL INVESTIGATION AS AT 30 JUNE 2016 STATEMENT OF ADVICE

HEALTH SUPER DB FUND REPORT TO THE TRUSTEE ON THE ACTUARIAL INVESTIGATION AS AT 30 JUNE 2016 STATEMENT OF ADVICE 19 August 2016 HEALTH SUPER DB FUND (A SUB-FUND OF THE FIRST STATE SUPERANNUATION SCHEME) STATEMENT OF ADVICE REPORT TO THE TRUSTEE ON THE ACTUARIAL INVESTIGATION AS AT 30 JUNE 2016 Contents 1. Key results

More information

2.2 Superannuation and Life Insurance in the New Zealand Financial System

2.2 Superannuation and Life Insurance in the New Zealand Financial System 15 CHAPTER 2 - SUPERANNUATION AND LIFE INSURANCE 2.1 Introduction As both repositories for savings, and as sources of loanable funds, superannuation schemes and life offices play a significant role in

More information

State pension reform: A Summary

State pension reform: A Summary State pension reform: A Summary November 2004 www.pensionspolicyinstitute.org.uk PPI 2004 State Pension Reform: A Summary The following summarises the PPI s current view on pension reform. 1. The problems

More information

Thank you for the opportunity to make a submission on your three yearly review.

Thank you for the opportunity to make a submission on your three yearly review. Martin Poulsen Head of Wealth Management First NZ Capital PO Box 5333 Auckland Dr Malcolm Menzies Research Manager Commission for Financial Literacy and Retirement Income PO Box 12-148 Wellington 6144

More information

REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA

REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA DEMOGRAPHY AND SOCIOLOGY PROGRAM RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA Peter McDonald Rebecca Kippen Working Papers in Demography No. 95 March 2005 Working

More information

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects.

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects. 74 The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028 April 2018 continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects. Tax Many exclusions, deductions, preferential rates, and credits

More information

The evolving retirement landscape

The evolving retirement landscape The evolving retirement landscape This report has been sponsored by A Research Report by Lauren Wilkinson and Tim Pike Published by the Pensions Policy Institute May 2018 978-1-906284-52-23 www.pensionspolicyinstitute.org.uk

More information

Testimony by. Alan Greenspan. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Senate Finance Committee. United States Senate

Testimony by. Alan Greenspan. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Senate Finance Committee. United States Senate For release on delivery 9:30 A M EST February 27, 1990 Testimony by Alan Greenspan Chairman Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System before the Senate Finance Committee United States Senate February

More information

The CPI purpose and definition - the Australasian Debate

The CPI purpose and definition - the Australasian Debate The CPI purpose and definition - the Australasian Debate Helen Stott 1 A Paper for the International Working Group on Price Indices Washington, April 1998 1 Statistics New Zealand, PO Box 2922, Wellington,

More information

Methodology and Inputs for the 2017 Valuation: Initial assessment. Technical discussion document for sponsoring employers

Methodology and Inputs for the 2017 Valuation: Initial assessment. Technical discussion document for sponsoring employers NOTE: This document was first circulated to stakeholders in February 2017 as part of the Trustee's preparations for the 2017 valuation. In December 2017, a formal actuarial report was submitted to the

More information

New Zealand Superannuation and KiwiSaver

New Zealand Superannuation and KiwiSaver New Zealand Superannuation and KiwiSaver Dr Brian McCulloch Green Paper on Pensions Learning from International Experience Conference Dublin, May 29 th, 2008 1 The New Zealand policy framework is built

More information

ASSET SALES, THE GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTS, AND THE NEW ZEALAND ECONOMY

ASSET SALES, THE GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTS, AND THE NEW ZEALAND ECONOMY Discussion Paper prepared for: ASSET SALES, THE GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTS, AND THE NEW ZEALAND ECONOMY Prepared by Dr Ganesh Nana Fiona Stokes Kelly Dustow Copyright BERL BERL ref #5260 Asset sales, the Government

More information

KiwiSaver and Superannuation policy

KiwiSaver and Superannuation policy 1 of 7 KiwiSaver and Superannuation policy National is committed to keeping the KiwiSaver scheme and making it an enduring and affordable scheme for members, employers, and taxpayers. National is committed

More information

The Martikainen Employment Model

The Martikainen Employment Model The Martikainen Employment Model Full employment in Finland Full employment is possible if, unlike at present, employers can also employ people at significantly lower labour costs. If this were so, the

More information

Taxing securities lending transactions: substance over form

Taxing securities lending transactions: substance over form Taxing securities lending transactions: substance over form A government discussion document Hon Dr Michael Cullen Minister of Finance Minister of Revenue First published in November 2004 by the Policy

More information

The Business of Ageing Update 2015

The Business of Ageing Update 2015 INTRODUCTION i The Business of Ageing Update 2015 This report provides an update to the report: Realising the Economic Potential of Older People in New Zealand: 2051 ii THE BUSINESS OF AGEING UPDATE 2015

More information

WELCOME TO THE NEW ZEALAND UNIVERSITIES SUPERANNUATION SCHEME YOUR SUPER GUIDE

WELCOME TO THE NEW ZEALAND UNIVERSITIES SUPERANNUATION SCHEME YOUR SUPER GUIDE WELCOME TO THE NEW ZEALAND UNIVERSITIES SUPERANNUATION SCHEME YOUR SUPER GUIDE 30 June 2014 CONTENTS 1. Advantages of Scheme membership 4 2. How your Scheme works 5 3. Your benefits 9 4. Investment choice

More information

Peter Whiteford. University of NSW

Peter Whiteford. University of NSW New Zealand and the KiwiSaver scheme Presentation for Conference on The Potential for Matching Defined Contributions (MDC) Design Features in Pension Systems to Increase Coverage in Low and Middle Income

More information

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit Order Code RL31235 The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit Updated January 24, 2007 Brian W. Cashell Specialist in Quantitative Economics Government and Finance Division The Economics of the Federal

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RL33519 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Why Is Household Income Falling While GDP Is Rising? July 7, 2006 Marc Labonte Specialist in Macroeconomics Government and Finance

More information

1 The Terrace, PO Box 3724, Wellington 6140 Tel: (04)

1 The Terrace, PO Box 3724, Wellington 6140 Tel: (04) 1 The Terrace, PO Box 3724, Wellington 6140 Tel: (04) 472-2733 Email: savingsworkinggroup@treasury.govt.nz Document: PAYGO vs SAYGO: Prefunding Government-provided Pensions Author: Andrew Coleman, Motu

More information

RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS

RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS Preface By Brian Donaghue 1 This paper addresses the recognition of obligations arising from retirement pension schemes, other than those relating to employee

More information

CHAPTER 6 - HOW SUPERANNUATION AND LIFE INSURANCE SAVINGS ARE TO BE TAXED

CHAPTER 6 - HOW SUPERANNUATION AND LIFE INSURANCE SAVINGS ARE TO BE TAXED 87 CHAPTER 6 - HOW SUPERANNUATION AND LIFE INSURANCE SAVINGS ARE TO BE TAXED 6.1 Introduction For the reasons given in Chapter 5, the preferential tax treatment of superannuation cannot be justified on

More information

Zurich Investments Equity Income Fund

Zurich Investments Equity Income Fund Zurich Investments Equity Income Fund APIR ZUR0538AU Product Disclosure Statement (PDS) Issue date 1 July 2015 Strategic investment partner: Denning Pryce Pty Ltd 1. About Zurich Investments Zurich Investment

More information

Establishing the right price for electricity in South Africa. Brian Kantor with assistance from Andrew Kenny and Graham Barr

Establishing the right price for electricity in South Africa. Brian Kantor with assistance from Andrew Kenny and Graham Barr Establishing the right price for electricity in South Africa Brian Kantor with assistance from Andrew Kenny and Graham Barr This exercise is designed to answer the essential question of relevance for consumers

More information

Zurich Superannuation Plan and Zurich Account-Based Pension

Zurich Superannuation Plan and Zurich Account-Based Pension Issue date: 1 January 2017 Preparation date: 25 November 2016 Zurich Superannuation Plan and Zurich Account-Based Pension Product Disclosure Statement This Product Disclosure Statement (PDS) is a summary

More information

December Perkins Staff Section

December Perkins Staff Section December 2007 Perkins Staff Section Any questions? We have tried to keep the explanation of the benefits as simple as possible, so you should consider this booklet as only a guide to the Perkins Staff

More information

Recent Amendments to Canada's Retirement Income Security System

Recent Amendments to Canada's Retirement Income Security System Recent Amendments to Canada's Retirement Income Security System 5.1 Introduction In less than a year the government (including the provincial governments in the case of amendments to the Canada Pension

More information

NEW ZEALAND. 1. Overview of the tax-benefit system

NEW ZEALAND. 1. Overview of the tax-benefit system NEW ZEALAND 2006 1. Overview of the tax-benefit system The provision of social security benefits in New Zealand is funded from general taxation and not specific social security contributions. Social security

More information

Analysing Australia s Ageing Population: A Demographic Picture

Analysing Australia s Ageing Population: A Demographic Picture National Centre for Social and Economic Modelling University of Canberra Analysing Australia s Ageing Population: A Demographic Picture Ann Harding Paper presented to Australia s Ageing Population Summit

More information

Res HD C2C b. Pension Reform: Improvements in Tax Assistance for Retirement Saving

Res HD C2C b. Pension Reform: Improvements in Tax Assistance for Retirement Saving Res HD7105.45 C2C362 1989b Pension Reform: Improvements in Tax Assistance for Retirement Saving 3 0145 00082077 6 Pension Reform: Improvements in Tax Assistance for Retirement Saving December 1989 FINANCE

More information

Submission on the Discussion Document: Flexible Superannuation

Submission on the Discussion Document: Flexible Superannuation Submission on the Discussion Document: Flexible Superannuation Contact address This submission is from: Retirement Policy and Research Centre University of Auckland Business School Level 6, Owen G Glenn

More information

Selecting your investments

Selecting your investments Selecting your investments Whether you are putting aside $2,000 to use in three months or saving for your retirement, the things you need to consider before investing are the same. These are outlined over

More information

Res HD C2C A Better Pension System. Saving for Retirement: A Guide to the Tax Legislation. March Lud. CanadU

Res HD C2C A Better Pension System. Saving for Retirement: A Guide to the Tax Legislation. March Lud. CanadU Res HD7105.45 C2C38 1988 A Better Pension System Saving for Retirement: A Guide to the Tax Legislation March 1988 Lud CanadU A Better Pension System 11 #1[1:14b5r111111 FOR Saving for Retirement: A Guide

More information

INCREASING INVESTMENT IN SOCIAL HOUSING Analysis of public sector expenditure on housing in England and social housebuilding scenarios

INCREASING INVESTMENT IN SOCIAL HOUSING Analysis of public sector expenditure on housing in England and social housebuilding scenarios INCREASING INVESTMENT IN SOCIAL HOUSING Analysis of public sector expenditure on housing in England and social housebuilding scenarios January 219 A report by Capital Economics for submission to Shelter

More information

TAX LAWS AMENDMENT (CROSS BORDER TRANSFER PRICING) BILL 2013: MODERNISATION OF TRANSFER PRICING RULES EXPOSURE DRAFT - EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM

TAX LAWS AMENDMENT (CROSS BORDER TRANSFER PRICING) BILL 2013: MODERNISATION OF TRANSFER PRICING RULES EXPOSURE DRAFT - EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM 2012 TAX LAWS AMENDMENT (CROSS BORDER TRANSFER PRICING) BILL 2013: MODERNISATION OF TRANSFER PRICING RULES EXPOSURE DRAFT - EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM (Circulated by the authority of the Deputy Prime Minister

More information

SECURING RETIREMENT INCOMES. TAX & SUPERANNUATION: THE SHORTCOMINGS OF the SUPERANNUATION TAXATION EXPENDITURES

SECURING RETIREMENT INCOMES. TAX & SUPERANNUATION: THE SHORTCOMINGS OF the SUPERANNUATION TAXATION EXPENDITURES SECURING RETIREMENT INCOMES TAX & SUPERANNUATION: THE SHORTCOMINGS OF the SUPERANNUATION TAXATION EXPENDITURES April 2013 february 2013 CONTENTS 1 Executive Summary 2 Background 3 Proving the point 7 Additional

More information

ENGLISH SUMMARY. Chapter I: Economic Outlook and Public Finances

ENGLISH SUMMARY. Chapter I: Economic Outlook and Public Finances ENGLISH SUMMARY This report from the chairmanship of the Danish Economic Councils contains three chapters. Chapter I presents the outlook for the Danish economy and discusses the state of the public finances.

More information

PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT

PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT PRODUCT DISCLOSURE STATEMENT Munich Holdings of Australasia Pty Ltd Superannuation Scheme Inside About the Munich Holdings of Australasia Pty Ltd Superannuation Scheme (the Scheme) How super works 2 Benefits

More information