Female Relative Wages, Household Specialization and Fertility

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Female Relative Wages, Household Specialization and Fertility"

Transcription

1 Female Relative Wages, Household Specialization and Fertility Christian Siegel January 31, 2017 Abstract Falling ertility rates have oten been linked to rising emale wages. However, over the last 40 years the US total ertility rate has been rather stable while emale wages have continued to grow. Over the same period, women s hours spent on housework have declined, but men s have increased. I propose a model in which households are not perectly specialized, but both men and women contribute to home production. As the gender wage gap narrows, the time allocations o men and women converge, and while ertility alls at irst, the decline stops when emale wages are close to male s. Rising relative wages increase women s labor supply and due to higher opportunity cost lower ertility at irst, but they also lead to a reallocation o home production and child care rom women to men, and a marketization. I ind that both are important in understanding why ertility did not decline urther. In a urther quantitative exercise I show that the model perorms well in matching ertility over the entire 20th century, including the overall decline, the baby boom, and the recent stabilization. JEL codes: D13, E24, J13, J22 Keywords: Fertility, Female Labor Supply, Household Production, Intrahousehold Allocations University o Kent, School o Economics, Canterbury, Kent, CT2 7NP, UK; C.Siegel@kent.ac.uk. This is a substantially revised version o a chapter o my PhD thesis at the London School o Economics entitled Female Employment and Fertility: The Eects o Rising Female Wages. I am grateul to Francesco Caselli or his advise on this project. I would also like to thank two anonymous reerees, the editor Matthias Doepke, Zsóia Bárány, Wouter den Haan, Monique Ebell, Paula Gobbi, Moshe Hazan, Ethan Ilzetzki, Winried Koeniger, John Knowles, Rigas Oikonomou, Albert Marcet, Michael McMahon, Rachel Ngai, Silvana Tenreyro, as well as seminar and conerence participants at Bonn, Cologne, Exeter, LSE, Uppsala, the SED 2013 meeting in Seoul and the Demographic Economics Conerence at the University o Iowa or many comments and suggestions. 1

2 1 Introduction Between the 1960s and today, we have seen enormous changes to the economic and demographic structure in all Western countries. There has been a decline in total ertility rates 1 and an increase in women s market hours (see igures 1 and 2 or US data). Many authors explain both with a rise in emale wages (e.g. Galor and Weil (1996), Doepke, Hazan, and Maoz (2015)). An apparent puzzle, however, is that while emale wages and market hours have continued to grow, since the early 1970s ertility has stopped alling. 2 Understanding the underlying ertility decisions is important since they aect population growth, labor orce composition and social security systems, and thereby economic outcomes. In this paper I argue that the common driving orce behind the trends in ertility and in emale employment is the narrowing o the gender wage gap (shown in igure 3), rather than the level o emale wages per se, since it changes the division o labor within the amily. The explanation I propose is based on imperect specialization o households, such that both men and women contribute to home and market production, implying that a reallocation has a nonlinear eect. My explanation is based on the observation that men s home hours have increased, allowing women s home hours to all. In the 1960s, when the wage gap was large, the catching up o emale wages increased women s labor supply. The associated increase in the opportunity cost o women s time, who shouldered most o child care, lowered ertility, as argued by Becker (1960) or Galor and Weil (1996). But as relative wages become more equal over time, specialization in the household decreases. Consequently, male home hours increase, a ather s time at home becomes more important or raising children, and the allocation o time between home and market work becomes more evenly balanced or men and women. I show that when the complementarity between mother s and ather s time working at home is suiciently large, the marginal utility cost o having an additional child can become constant, or even all, despite women working more hours in the market. Circumstantial evidence in avor o this mechanism is provided by data on non-market hours. Using data rom Aguiar and Hurst (2007), based on the American Time Use Survey since 1965, I show the trends in hours spent working at home in igure 4. I ocus on the sum o time spent non-market work, deined by Aguiar and Hurst as home production plus obtaining goods, and basic child care. 3 The data displays a shit in household production 1 The total ertility rate (TFR) is the average number o children that would be born i all women lived to the end o their childbearing years and bore children according to the current age-speciic birth rates. 2 Most o the recent rise in the oicial total ertility rate is driven by the eects o immigration. For US-born women the increase is much less and ertility virtually lat since the late 1970s. The details on the decomposition o TFR by mothers birthplace are given in the online appendix, section A.1. 3 The measure is constructed as weekly hours spent on home production in a narrow sense, on obtaining goods, and on basic child care. Arguably, or many people child care is an activity that is more enjoyable than other orms o housework. Excluding child care rom the measure o market work does not change the qualitative trends. This can be seen in the regression results o table A-1 in the online appendix. 2

3 All Men and Women Married Single Year Year Year Male Female Male Female Male Female Figure 1: Male and emale market hours This graph shows average (per capita) yearly market hours worked or men and women aged 20 to 60. The data is taken rom the PSID and reers to sel-reported hours worked in the previous year. In the panel on the let, all individuals o age 20 to 60 are included. The panels to the right restrict the sample to married and to single individuals respectively. Per capita hours worked are computed as the simple average o the average hours worked in 5-year age bins, in order to take out a potential composition eect due to changing cohort sizes. Total Fertility Rate Children Ever Born Year Year TFR US Born Women Oicial TFR all ever married never married Total Fertility Rate Children Ever Born Figure 2: Total ertility rate and children ever born In the let panel, the red dashed line shows the oicial total ertility rate (TFR) or the United States, taken rom the World Bank (based on national statistics and the United Nations Demographic Yearbook), and the blue solid line the author s computation o TFR or US-born women, based on the Vital Statistics o the United States combined with population estimates rom the US Census; see online appendix or details. The right panel shows children ever born to women o age 40 to 44; the blue dashed line or all women o age 40 to 44, the red solid line and the green dot-dashed line the breakdown or ever married and never married women respectively. The data is taken rom the United States Census Bureau s Fertility Data Historical Time Series and based on the CPS. 3

4 Ratio Year Figure 3: Female Relative Wages Ratio o median emale to male hourly wages, computed in a PSID subsample o men and women aged 20 to 60 who work at least one hour in paid employment and report positive earnings. rom women to men, with an overall reduction o hours worked at home. As a consequence, the ratio o married men s to married women s hours devoted to working at home rose rom 0.25 to 4 over There has also been a shit in time investments into children. Sayer, Bianchi, and Robinson (2004) ind in time diary data that the ratio o married mothers to married athers time in child care declined in all primary child care activities since mid-1960s. This is consistent with the acts documented by Robinson and Godbey (2008), who ind in time use data over evidence or convergence in activities across gender. 4 The tendencies or men and women s time spent on home production to converge have been at work throughout the last century, as documented by Ramey (2009). The importance o considering intrahousehold allocations can be seen in the right panels o igure 4. While home hours o married men have increased over time, single men s hours o home production are constant, ater an initial change between 1965 and This is consistent with the explanation I propose. Single men, who are without a emale partner, are not aected by rising emale wages, whereas married men spend more hours working at home a trend in US data that has not received much attention by researchers yet, with the notable exception o Knowles (2013). 5 Single women, on the other hand, spend less time working at home, but the decline is not as pronounced as or 4 They also report that average parental hours spent on child-care per child has been roughly constant. Ramey and Ramey (2010), on the other hand, include time spent teaching children and document a rise since the mid 1990s, especially or college educated parents. 5 Burda, Hamermesh, and Weil (2007) study time use data across various developed countries, and ind that total work, the sum o home and market work, is virtually the same or men and women. For the US, Ramey and Francis (2009) report that total work o men and women has been constant throughout the 20th century. 4

5 All Men and Women Married Single Year Year Year Male Female Male Female Male Female Figure 4: Male and emale home hours worked This graph shows average (per capita) weekly hours spent on nonmarket work and basic child care or men and women aged 20 to 60. The data is taken rom Aguiar and Hurst (2007). Per capita hours worked are computed as the simple average o the average hours worked in 5-year age bins, in order to take out a potential composition eect due to changing cohort sizes. married women, whose husbands devote more o their time to home production. 6 Distinguishing household types is also important in the ertility data. Figure 2 shows that the total ertility rate (let panel) has been rather stable over the last orty years (and even increased slightly) and that the number children ever born (CEB) or women o age (right panel) has been lat or the last 25 years. 7 However, the trends in CEB or ever-married and never-married women dier substantially. While overall ertility has been lat, there has been an increase in the ertility o never married women. However, the rise in single women s ertility is not the sole driver o the lattening out in aggregate data. To the contrary, the total igure o children ever born ollows more closely the number or ever-married women, which has been stable or the last 25 years. Understanding the evolution o married ertility is the ocus o this paper. I present a model matching the observed patterns o married ertility and hours worked through an exogenous decrease in the gender wage gap. As the main interest o this paper 6 In the Aguiar and Hurst (2007) data marital status is deined in a legal sense, and it is not possible to disentangle cohabiting rom other singles. In igure A-4 o the online appendix I show that home hours have changed more or singles with children (who are more likely to be cohabiting) than or singles without children. 7 CEB has lattened out only rom 1990 on, since it shows lie-time ertility o women aged 40-44, whereas TFR is a measure o ertility across women o all ages at a point in time. Since TFR is computed by adding up the age-speciic ertility rates o all women (in their child-bearing years), it is potentially subject to a tempo eect, which is that an increase in the age o childbearing mechanically lowers the computed total ertility rate. CEB is not aected by changes in the timing o ertility, as it measures actually completed ertility. In general, TFR and CEB ollow similar trends though. 5

6 is in understanding the recent time series o ertility, starting with the irst available time use data in 1965, I abstract rom many actors that might have been important or the ertility decline in earlier periods, such as a reduction in inant mortality or qualityquantity considerations in the wake o technological changes during the 19th century (Becker, Murphy, and Tamura (1990), Galor and Weil (2000)). However, in an extension I show that the model under parameters calibrated to perorms well in replicating the whole 20th century data. Moreover, since the ocus is on the time series, I do not model heterogeneity within a cohort. Nonetheless it is worth noting that Hazan and Zoabi (2015) ind in recent U.S. cross-sectional data that ertility is not monotonically declining in women s education, but U-shaped. For each cohort I consider a representative household that maximizes the sum o a male and a emale member s utilities. Both members can work in the market and at home. Due to complementaries in home production the household is not perectly specialized. When women s wages are lower than men s, they contribute more time to home production. A rise in emale relative wages directly increases emale labor supply and lowers emale home production, whereas more male time is devoted to home activities and less to market work. Initially, when the gender wage gap is large, there is an overall drop in home labor and a couple devotes less time to having and raising children. However, when the gender wage gap is airly small and shrinks urther, ertility stabilizes and might even increase. The reason or this dierential reaction to improvement in emale relative wages is in the degree to which households are specialized. Initially, a husband s labor supply was much higher than his wie s, and his time spent working at home much lower than hers. As a consequence, the opportunity cost o having children was largely determined by her wage (which was low compared to his), and when emale wages improved the cost o having children increased substantially. In this situation the substitution eect o higher emale wages dominates the positive income eect, leading to a all in ertility. But as relative wages become more equal, the increase in the opportunity cost o having children becomes smaller, since the cost o reallocating home production rom the wie to the husband alls. As a consequence, the substitution eect weakens with the narrowing o the gender wage gap. On top o this, with the improvement in the wie s earnings, a couple can acquire more parental time-saving inputs, and the larger her labor supply already is, the more the household gains when her wage increases. Both the rise in male home labor and the higher use o parental time-saving inputs into home production is what I ind key in explaining why the ertility decline ended. First I use a simpliied model to show analytically that the combined substitution eect becomes weaker than the income eect beore the gender wage gap has ully closed i complementaries between both parents time spent in the household are suiciently strong and i marketization is possible. Then I calibrate the ull model to study the quantitative implications, which suggest urther that the degree o marketization is important or the 6

7 timing o the ertility stabilization. To the best o my knowledge, the only previous paper that has noted the lattening out in total ertility rates and inormally suggested an explanation in terms o increased male home production is Feyrer, Sacerdote, and Stern (2008). 8 My paper ormally models and quantiies the endogenous response o male and emale hours and their implications or ertility. In a working paper Regalia and Ríos-Rull (1999) discuss the stability in ertility and use a rich model to assess the eects o changes in wage premia, including the gender wage gap, or ertility decisions. My paper diers along two margins. On the one hand, ocusing on married ertility, I assume that the number o children is a joint decision the couple takes. On the other hand, since both parents can contribute to home production, the implicit cost o having children is endogenous and a unction o both parents wages. Other papers that have studied the implications o the decline in the gender wage gap or both male and emale hours include Jones, Manuelli, and McGrattan (2003) and Knowles (2013), who highlights the rise o male home production and on whose work I build. In a calibrated lie-cycle model Attanasio, Low, and Sanchez-Marcos (2008) ind that a reduction in the gender wage gap alone cannot explain the change in labor supply o young mothers and that also a all in the cost o children is needed. However, none o these papers have explored the implications or ertility. In my model, the rise o men s time spent on home production in response to improved emale wages endogenously lowers mothers cost o having children and the ertility decline ends. 9 Galor and Weil (1996) present a uniied ramework to explain the rise in emale employment and the all in ertility that we observed until the early 1970s. Since their mechanism links ertility decisions to the market value o women s disposable time 10, it cannot explain why ertility stopped alling when emale wages continued improving. My work thereore highlights that the existing literature that assumes perect specialization within amilies, such that women shoulder all o home production or child care, has overlooked important implications o intrahousehold allocations. 2 Cross-sectional Time Use Data To support the view that the reallocation o home production rom women to men is linked to relative wages, I use data rom the American Time Use Survey (ATUS) or the 8 Feyrer, Sacerdote, and Stern (2008) explain the increase in male home hours with intrahousehold bargaining. I show that bargaining is not necessary; a change in relative wages per se implies not only a reallocation o work in the market, but also at home. 9 Attanasio, Low, and Sanchez-Marcos (2008) report that data on child care costs are not consistently available beore For that reason, they calibrate the drop in the price o market child care using their model. Since they assume that only mothers provide domestic child care, they are likely to overstate the required reduction in child care costs as they do not take into account responses in athers time. 10 Other papers linking ertility decisions to the market value o women s disposable time include Greenwood, Seshadri, and Vandenbroucke (2005) and Doepke, Hazan, and Maoz (2015), besides others. 7

8 Table 1: Cross-sectional regressions o time spent on home production (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Nbr. o Kids in Hh (7.01) (8.00) (7.34) (8.15) (7.22) (8.35) (7.98) (8.06) (Nbr. o Kids in Hh) (2.02) (2.35) (2.11) (2.39) (2.03) (2.40) (2.34) (2.36) Own market hours (0.28) (0.36) (0.28) (0.36) Spouse s market hours (0.30) (0.39) (0.30) (0.39) Own wage (0.28) (0.29) (0.29) Spouse s wage (0.22) (0.23) (0.23) Own earnings (0.01) (0.01) Spouse s earnings (0.01) (0.01) Own age (0.72) (0.81) Spouse s age Constant (0.72) (0.82) (17.51) (23.96) (8.41) (8.96) (23.07) (18.96) (22.53) (9.16) Race Dummies No No No No Yes Yes No No Sample All Empl All Empl All Empl Empl Empl Observations R Standard errors in parentheses p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p < 0.01 year 2011, provided by Hoerth, Flood, and Sobek (2013). The ATUS provides data on the time use o only the respondents themselves but not o other amily members. It is thereore not possible to directly study how home production chores are split within a household. However as the ATUS respondents are sampled rom individuals who completed the Current Population Survey (CPS), it is possible to link the respondents time use data to the previous CPS data which include labor market characteristics o both the respondent and their partner. The lag between the ATUS and CPS interviews spans between 2 and 5 month, with an average o around 3 month. I restrict the sample to married or cohabiting couples in which both partners are o age 21 to 65, and drop households with amily businesses. To compute hourly wages or both partners, I divide weekly earnings by usual hours worked. As in igure 4, I deine time spent working at home as the sum o home production, purchasing goods, and caring or household members. 11 Then I regress individuals home work on their own and their partner s labor market characteristics, which come rom the earlier CPS sample, and a set o other controls including number o children in the household. Denoting individual 11 In the ATUS, the respondents answer how many minutes they have spent on the various activities over a 24-hour period. 8

9 i s time spent on household production by h i, I estimate h i = β 0 + β 1 b i + β 2 b 2 i + γ o Xi o + γ s Xi s + error i where b i are the number o children living in the household, and Xi o individual i s own and Xi s their spouses labor market characteristics, such as market hours worked, hourly wages, and weekly earnings (all taken rom the previous CPS). Table 1 shows the results or dierent speciications. The results o column 1 imply that individuals who work longer hours in the market tend to spend less time on home production. However, ceteris paribus, they spend more time on home production i their partner works more. The relationship is robust to include wages or age as urther covariates, as seen in columns 2 and 5 respectively. Moreover, columns 3, 4 and 6 show that individuals tend to devote less time to household production i they have higher hourly wages or weekly earnings, but more i their spouse earns more. Using wages in the analysis restricts the sample to households in which both the respondent and their spouse are working and wages are observed. Due to a potential sel-selection into labor market participation, the result or the interdependence between home production time and spouses wages are potentially not representative or the overall population. However, the results or the relationship with market hours worked (column 1) and with earnings (column 3) include households in which a spouse is not in employment. Excluding observations with zero market hours or earnings to restrict the sample to couples in which both are employed, gives the results in columns 7 and 8. For the correlation between home hours and market hours, or earnings, whether to include individuals out o employment, or not, does not matter much or the results. To summarize, table 1 highlights that married individuals time allocated to home production depends not only on their own labor market characteristics, but also on their spouses. 12 These results are in line with the conjecture that higher emale wages, or higher emale market hours, are associated with a reduction in women s time in home production and an increase in their husband s home hours. To the extent that better educated women earn higher wages, this is consistent with Hazan and Zoabi (2015) s inding that married men s time spent providing childcare at home increases with mothers education. However Hazan and Zoabi do not explore the implications o athers time or the ertility decision. In the next section I propose a model in which both parents time matters, and provide a link between the rise in male home production and the lattening out o ertility over time. 12 Splitting the regression sample by the gender o the respondent does not change the general pattern; see online appendix A.4. 9

10 3 The Model 3.1 Assumptions To explain the time series o ertility as well as o male and emale time allocations or married individuals, I propose a parsimonious model. For tractability I assume that each cohort can be represented by a representative married couple household that decides on how to allocate male and emale time and on a continuous number o children to have. In the main text I ocus on a version in which the couple lives or one period only, such that their choices are static. In the online appendix I present a lie-cycle version o this model and show quantitatively that the general conclusions regarding ertility and time allocations remain the same. The advantage o the simple model presented in the main text is that it allows or an analytical characterization o the mechanism that links ertility to women s relative wages Agents and Households All agents, men and women, derive utility rom the consumption o a market good (c), rom having children (b), and rom leisure, which is the time spent neither working in the labor market (n) or at home (h). Each individual is endowed with one unit o time. Agents dier in terms o their gender (g {m, }) and their age (j). I assume that all economic active men and women live in couple households, ormed by one man ( husband ) and one woman ( wie ). I apply a model o collective household behavior, as introduced by Chiappori (1988). The male and the emale partner have their own preerences, and derive elicity u m and u respectively. Since they have children together, they solve a joint maximization problem. In particular, the couple household solves a Pareto program with relative weight θ attached to the husband s and 1 θ to the wie s utility. As will be seen later, under the model assumption made the spouses relative time spent on home production is independent o the bargaining weight, but solely based on comparative advantage. As a consequence, θ has no eect on the implicit cost o having children. I thereore restrict attention to the unitary model with θ = throughout Fertility Child-care requires more home production (x), which could be done by the ather, the mother, or both. 13 A urther input to home production are goods acquired in the market (e). Although I reer to this home-labor saving input as home appliances, in a broader sense this could include paid domestic help, such as hiring nannies. I assume that the 13 The ormer assumption is similar to Erosa, Fuster, and Restuccia (2010), the latter is as in Knowles (2007) and similar to Greenwood and Seshadri (2005). 10

11 amount o the home good needed is (1) x(b) = κ 0 + κ 1 b κ 2 with κ 0, κ 1, κ 2 > 0, which implies x (b) > Household Production Following Olivetti (2006) and in particular Knowles (2013), I assume that the home good is produced using a technology that is consistent with substitution among household member s time and home appliances according to (2) x = e γ H 1 γ, with 0 γ < 1, where the home labor input is (3) H = ( z m h 1 m ) + z h 1 1 1, and z m and z are the male and emale home labor productivities. The parameter > 0 is the inverse o the elasticity o substitution between male and emale inputs. For inite, this deinition o H as a CES aggregator allows or substitutability between male and emale inputs to home production as long as both z m > 0 and z > 0. With γ > 0, this technology allows, to some degree, or a marketization o inputs to home production. 14 Moreover, this home production unction is consistent with the indings by Ramey (2009). From regressing the home capital-labor ratio on appliances prices, Ramey inds that the production unction is more or less consistent with a Cobb- Douglas technology over home capital and labor Preerences Agents derive utility rom consuming the market good, rom having children, and rom leisure time. In particular, assume that preerences are additively separable and given by 15 (4) u(c g, n g, h g, b) = log(c g ) + φ l (1 n g h g ) 1 η 1 1 η + φ b b 1 σ b 1 1 σ b where c g, n g, and h g are speciic to a spouse g {m, }, but the number o children b is common to the couple. 14 In a structural transormation ramework, Ngai and Pissarides (2008) study substitutions between home and market production, but do not distinguish between male and emale labor. 15 Adding utility rom children in this additive orm is generalizing Galor and Weil (1996) and Greenwood and Seshadri (2005), who assume ln(b). 11

12 Note that in this model setup individuals derive utility rom leisure, i.e. the time spent not working in the market or at home, and both spouses contribute to home production due to complementaries. 16 I assume that there is a subsistence level in consumption o the home produced good, which is increasing in the number o children living in the household (b). As a simpliying assumption, ollowing Knowles (2007), agents do not derive any urther utility rom home production, and this constraint will be binding, x = x(b). 3.2 Couple Household s Optimization The representative couple household maximizes the sum o male and emale utilities, by choosing male and emale hours o home production and o market labor supply and how many children to have, subject to a budget constraint, the home production requirement (1) and the home production technology (2). The household can earn a labor income w m n m + w n, where w m is the male wage and w the emale wage, which can be used to purchase consumption goods, c m and c, and time-saving inputs to home production, e. The representative couple s maximization problem is thereore given by (5) max c m,c,b,e n m,n,h m,h θu m (c m, n m, h m, b) + (1 θ)u (c, n, h, b) subject to the constraint set: (6) (7) (8) (9) c m + c + e = w m n m + w n x(b) = e γ ( z m h 1 m n m + h m 1 and n + h 1 + z h 1 n g 0 and h g 0 or g {m, } ) 1 γ 1 where (6) is the household s budget constraint and (7) the relationship between the required amount o the home good and the home production inputs. The inequalities in (8) constrain the male and emale total time working in the market and at home to be no larger than the time endowment o 1. As the marginal utility o leisure goes to ininity when leisure goes to zero, these constraint will be slack or both spouses. The inequalities in (9) are non-negativity conditions on the spouses time spent working in the market and at home. As the home production unction (3) eatures complementarity between male and emale home hours, optimality requires h m and h to be positive and the associated constraints never bind. The non-negativity constraints on market hours could in principle 16 In an earlier working paper version, Siegel (2012), I had proposed an alternative to generate imperect specialization within the household based on preerences eaturing imperect substitutability in the disutilities rom working at home or in the market. Both models generate qualitatively the same predictions or the eects o changing relative wages on the couple s time allocation and on the ertility choice. 12

13 bind, but since I ocus on a representative couple, I will choose parameter values or which both n m and n are positive (to capture the trends in igure 1). As a consequence all time constraint will be slack in equilibrium and I will ocus throughout on interior solutions. Also note that since I am ocusing on a representative couple, the household can choose any non-negative continuous quantity o children b. Combining (7) with (6), the eective budget constraint to the household s maximization problem can be written as (10) c m + c + ( zm h 1 m x(b) + z h 1 ) 1 γ 1 Combining these optimality conditions implies (11) c = 1 θ c m θ and or the optimal time allocations 1 γ = w m n m + w n (12) (13) (14) (15) h m = ( ) 1 zm w m ( ) 1 z ( 1 γ γ ( 1 γ h = w γ ( φl c m n m = 1 h m w m ( 1 θ n = 1 h θ ) γ [ z 1 ) γ [ z 1 ) 1 η mw mw ) 1 φ l c η m w 1 m 1 m + z 1 + z 1 1 w 1 w ] γ 1 1 x(b) ] γ 1 1 x(b) The optimal ertility choice satisies (16) φ b b σ b = θ ( ) γ ( ) 1 γ 1 1 [ 1 1 z mwm + z 1 1 c m γ 1 γ w ] (1 γ) 1 }{{} C x(w m,w ) x (b) Equations (10) to (16) ully characterize the couple s utility maximizing choices. When choosing a ertility plan, the couple is outweighing beneits and costs rom having children. The let-hand side in (16) is the marginal beneit o having an additional child, which at the optimum has to equal the marginal cost (in utility terms), the right-hand side. The term ( ) γ ( ) 1 γ [ C x (w m, w ) = γ 1 γ z mwm +z 1 1 w ] (1 γ) 1 is the minimal cost to produce one unit o the home good x. The marginal cost o having more children lies in the need or more home production. To increase home production, the couple devotes more time to home labor and uses more purchased inputs. Both adjustments reduce consumption o the parents. Notice that C x (w m, w ) is increasing in the male and emale wage rates as 13

14 these represent the opportunity cost o male and emale home labor; devoting more time to home production lowers labor income and thereby reduces consumption. Since how costly it is to orgo consumption depends negatively on the original consumption level, the right-hand side o (16) is decreasing in c m. Ceteris paribus, higher wages imply an increase in the cost o having children, whereas higher consumption implies a lower cost. Also note that C x is independent o the bargaining weight θ. The reason or this is that the spouses relative time spent on home production is solely based on comparative advantage. From (12) and (13) it can be seen that the optimal ratio o male to emale home hours is hm h = ( ) 1 z m w z w m 3.3 Eect o Higher Female Wages. When emale relative wages improve, the couple inds it optimal to allocate a larger share o home production to the husband. Holding the number o children and the required amount o the home good constant, this leads to a reallocation o men s time rom market to home labor, and or women rom home to market labor. This impacts the marginal cost o having children in (16). Higher emale wages directly increase the opportunity cost o home production, but they also improve labor income and thereby consumption. While the ormer channel tends to reduce ertility as the couple substitutes rom having children towards consumption o market goods, the latter channel tends to increase it as the household experiences higher income and children are normal goods in the utility unction. The irst eect is the substitution eect and the second one the income eect. To derive a condition under which the substitution eect dominates and ertility alls, use the parametrization o home production requirement (1) to write the optimal number o children as (17) b = φ b c m κ 1 κ 2 θ γγ (1 γ) 1 γ[ z 1 mw 1 m 1 w ] (1 γ) 1 + z 1 }{{} =1/C x(w m,w ) 1 σ b +κ 2 1 Note that (17) implies that, holding consumption constant ertility alls in response to higher wages (due to the substitution eect) only i σ b + κ 2 1 > 0, which is a restriction on parameters I will assume throughout. Consumption itsel is pinned down by the budget constraint (10) given the optimal choices according to (11) to (15). In general this gives a system o two non-linear equations which has no closed orm solution. On the one hand, higher emale wages increase the cost o home production, which induces a substitution eect that implies a reduction in ertility. But on the other hand, they also have a positive income eect, which implies an increase in consumption and in ertility. When C x increases by more than c m, ertility alls. In the next subsection I 14

15 ocus on a special case, or which one can derive a closed-orm solution or the couple s optimal number o children. I show under what conditions ertility alls in response to higher emale wages, and when it does not. In the subsection thereater I show that the drawn conclusions generalize Special Case: σ b = 1 and φ l = 0 Consider the special case o σ b = 1 and φ l = 0. This means that agents have log utility rom children and do not value leisure time, such that n g + h g = 1 or g {m, }. These assumptions allow to derive a closed orm solution. The optimal ertility choice is b = ( ( φb 1 κ 1 κ 2 + φ b (w m + w )γ γ (1 γ) 1 γ[ z 1 m w 1 m + z 1 1 w ] (1 γ) 1 κ 0 )) 1 κ 2 b The sign o w, which captures how the optimal ertility choice responds to increasing emale wages, is given by (18) z 1 1 w = γz 1 + z 1 1 m wm 1 w (1 γ)z 1 + w m ( ( zm w m 1 w ) 1 (1 γ) ( z (1 γ)z 1 w mw 1 ) w ) 1 No marketization: First, consider a scenario in which there is no marketization o home production by setting γ = 0. Then b w < 0 i and only i < z z m. Hence, higher emale wages reduce ertility when women s relative wages are low compared to their relative productivities at home. w w m The reason is that when women s comparative advantage lies in home production, the emale share in the cost o children is larger than the emale share in total income. This implies that higher emale wages increase the cost o having children by more than household income. As a consequence, the substitution eect dominates the income eect, and ertility alls. No male home production: Next, consider a scenario with marketization but without men contributing to home production, which is nested as the optimal choice b when z m = 0. Here, w < 0 i and only i < 1 γ. Thus, when the degree o γ marketization, as measured by γ, is suiciently low, higher emale wages reduce ertility. When the usage o time-saving inputs is limited, the cost o home production increases by more than income. Intuitively this happens since there is a lack o possibilities to exploit the beneits rom higher emale wages. Since there is no substitution with men s time and substitution with purchased inputs is limited, women s home hours cannot all much; as a consequence her labor supply and the household s income do not increase much. As a result, the substitution eect is stronger than the income eect. I one assumes that in the long-run emale and male wages are equalized, a suicient condition or ertility to always all when emale wages go up is γ < 1. Hence, i there is no male home production 2 15 w w m

16 and the degree o marketization is suiciently low, ertility always alls when women s wages improve. With marketization and male home production: When γ > 0 and z m > 0, and the home production technology allows both or marketization and or substitutability between male and emale time, b w (19) γ w w m + < 0 i and only i ( zm z ) 1 ( w w m ) 1 < 1 γ Since the let-hand side is increasing in w w m, whereas the right-hand side is constant, this inequality is satisied i and only i w w m is suiciently low. This means that improvements in emale wages reduce the optimal number o children only i emale relative wages are suiciently low, echoing the conclusions drawn above. Notice that this inequality is more likely to hold when men s relative productivity in home production is high. To understand how the degree o substitutability between male and emale time aects this condition, consider irst a scenario where men and women have equal productivities at home (z m = z ). In this case, the let-hand side o (19) increases in or w w m < 1. This implies that or larger, i.e. when there are stronger complementarities between male and emale time in home production, the ertility decline ends at a lower emale relative wage threshold. When male and emale home productivities dier, there is an additional eect through the term ( ) 1 z m z. When z m < z, which is a reasonable assumption or some child care tasks, this term depends positively on, resulting in an additional channel through which the let-hand side o (19) increases in. 17 This implies that the larger the complementaries between male and emale time at home, the earlier the ertility decline ends in response to improvements in women s relative wages. With larger complementaries, the household gains more rom increasing the husband s home hours when the wie lowers hers; as a consequence the home production cost, C x, increases less when w rises. The condition or the ertility decline to end is also more likely to be satisied when the degree o marketization is higher. A larger γ means that the additional margin, the possibility to substitute between parental time and purchased inputs, is more important, which weakens the strength o the overall substitution eect on ertility relative to the income eect. From inequality (19) one can derive a suicient condition that ensures a bottoming out o ertility. Fertility stops alling, and potentially starts increasing, beore emale and male wages are equalized, only i (20) ( zm z ) 1 > 1 2γ 17 When z m > z and men are more productive than women in home production, the opposite result emerges and a larger reduces ( ) 1 z m z, making it less likely that inequality (19) is satisied. 16

17 To summarize, ertility alls in response to higher emale wages only i the gender wage gap is large. Moreover, both the substitution o emale time spent in home production with male time as well as the substitution with inputs purchased in the market are important. The ertility decline ends beore the gender wage gap is ully closed, when men s inputs to home production suiciently well complement emale time and when there is a suicient degree o marketization. Obviously, once ertility stops alling, it in general increases. Whether the model implies that overall ertility looks rather stable or more like a pronounced U-shape, is a quantitative question whose answer depends on other parameters, and on which I return in section Log-Linearization o the General Case (σ b 1) To study the eect o higher emale wages on the ertility decision in the more general case with σ b 1, I rely on a irst-order approximation. For tractability I continue to assume φ l = 0, implying n g + h g = 1 or g {m, }. Given the optimal choices or emale consumption and or the time allocations as a unction o male consumption, according to (11) to (15), the budget constraint (10) implies (21) ( ) γ ( c m 1 1 θ + γ 1 γ ) 1 γ [ z 1 1 m 1 w ] (1 γ) 1 mw + z 1 } {{ } C x(w m,w ) x(b) = w m + w which pins down c m or a given number o children b. The household chooses b optimally according to (17). These two equations ully characterize the optimal choices. As there is no closed orm solution, I log-linearize the two equations. In particular, I consider the log deviations o a variable between this period and the previous one. To keep the notation simple, I denote previous period s values by a tilde and log deviations between two periods by a hat; or a generic variable Z, the previous period s values is Z = Z t 1, and the log deviations between the two periods is Ẑ = log(z) log( Z) Zt Z t 1 Z t 1. The log-linearization o the optimality condition or the ertility choice (17) gives 1 ( ) b = ĉ m σ b κ 2 1 Ĉx and o the reduced-orm budget constraint (21) Ĉ x + x ( b) b w m ŵ m + w ŵ ˆb cm = θ ĉm b w m + w cm θ where Ĉ x = z 1 1 m w m 1 γ + z 1 w 1 ( 17 ) z 1 1 m w m ŵm + z 1 1 w ŵ

18 Solving these equations or ŵ m = 0, gives or b (the log change in ertility) as a unction o ŵ (the log change in women s wages), b = 1 cm θ (σ b κ 2 1) w m+ w cm θ + x ( b) 1 w m + w cm θ w 1 (1 γ)z w 1 z 1 1 m w m + z 1 w 1 ( w m + w ) ŵ The sign o b ŵ is thereore given by the term in parentheses, which can re-written as 1 1 w z 1 1 m w m + z 1 w 1 ( z 1 1 m w m + z 1 w 1 ( w m + w )(1 γ)z 1 w As the terms outside o these parentheses are necessarily positive, the crucial term is the one inside, which is the very same as in condition (18). Thereore, the conclusions drawn in subsection above generalize to cases with σ b 1, as long as σ b > 1 κ 2 (which is the parameter restriction ensuring a normal substitution eect). Higher emale relative wages lower ertility when the gender wage gap is large, but the ertility decline might end beore the gap is closed, depending on the properties o the home production technology. In the quantitative model calibrated in the next section, I ind that these results also go through when allowing or φ l 0. ) 1 4 Calibration To quantitatively assess the eect o the narrowing o the gender wage gap on ertility, I calibrate the model. I choose parameters such that the model replicates in 1965 eatures o the data or married couples. I target married men s and married women s hours worked, both at home and in the market, and an indicator or married ertility. All parameters are time-invariant, and the only exogenous change over time is in the gender wage gap. As the Aguiar and Hurst (2007) data is available once per decade, I study the choices o representative couples born ten years apart. Below I irst discuss what data is targeted and then the choice o parameters. I calibrate the model in the ollowing order: the home production unction, the required amount o the home good, and the preerence parameters. 4.1 Targets To construct the targets, I need to map the hours worked data o igures 1 and 4 into the model. Since the model is about the decisions o prime-aged couples, I restrict the sample to married individuals o age 20 to 60. In the model, agents have a time endowment o one, which they can split between market work, home work, and leisure time. Assuming that 18

19 people need 8 hours o rest a day, 2/3 o time is discretionary. Hence to map the weekly data rom Aguiar and Hurst (2007) into my model, I divide all hours by (2/3 24 7). For market hours worked, I use data rom the Panel Study o Income Dynamics (PSID) rom 1968 to 2007, which I average over 10 year periods. 18 Since in the PSID market hours worked are given per year, I divided these by (2/ ). Not to conound trends in market and home hours with potential composition eects that could be due to demographic changes, I irst compute average hours or individuals at dierent ages in 5 year bins, and then take the simple average over the bins, which gives every age group the same weight. As the theory I propose applies to couples, the model s implications are or married ertility. Since the total ertility rate is constructed by age-speciic birthrates, it does not allow or a break-down into unmarried and married ertility. I thereore use children-ever born to women at age 40 44, or which there is data by marital history (shown in the right panel o igure 2), published by the United States Census Bureau in the Fertility Data Historical Time Series 19. This is an indicator o completed ertility. However, most couples have children at an earlier point in their lives than at age (and thereby take a decision under earlier wages). To construct an indicator or married ertility that corresponds to the model, I shit the series o children-ever born. I take the average number o children an ever-married women at age ever had, and shit it back by 16 years, since the mean age o a mother when giving birth is in the data. 20 The drawback o this indicator or the married ertility choice is that the constructed series ends early; the model s predictions cannot be evaluated against constructed data or 2005 (yet). However, one advantage o using this measure o completed ertility over other ertility indicators, such as the total ertility rate, is that it is not conounded by changes in the timing o births. For the gender wage gap I take the ratio o median emale to median male wages in the PSID, shown in igure 3. To eed it into the model, where a period corresponds to 10 years, I take simple averages. 4.2 Home Production Technology I set the elasticity o substitution between male and emale time spent in home production to replicate the rise in the ratio o married men s home hours to married women s observed in the data. In the model, equations (12) and (13) imply or relative male home hours hm,t h,t = ( z m w,t ) 1 z w m,t ; their ratio betweens periods T and 0 is thereore h m,t /h,t h m,0 /h,0 = 18 I discuss the advantages o using data rom the PSID, rather than rom the CPS, and compare the data rom these two surveys in section A o the online appendix The average age o a mother (total over all birth orders) was 24.9 in 1968 and 27.4 in 2003, according to Vital Statistics o the United States, 2003, Volume I, Natality. The average over is

20 ( w,t /w m,t ) 1 w,t /w m,t. To match the change in married men s relative home hours over 1965 to 2003 rom 0.25 to 4, given the change in emale relative wages rom 7 to 0.78, this requires or the inverse elasticity o substitution = In turn this implies or the relative home productivities zm z = ( h m,1965 h,1965 ) w m,1965 w,1965. Restricting z m + z = 1, men s productivity in home production ollows as z m = and women s as z = 04. In the literature the range o estimates or the labor share in home production is very wide. Studies that include housing as capital or equipment used or home production typically ind a relatively low value, close to the one o market production, e.g. Greenwood, Rogerson, and Wright (1995), while Benhabib, Rogerson, and Wright (1991), who exclude housing, estimate a very high value o In my model, the need or home production arises at the margin only rom having children (in the household) and does not correspond closely to either study. Since parents can acquire home production inputs in the market, such as hiring nannies or paid domestic help, the share o time-saving inputs acquired in the market, γ, should be higher than the Benhabib, Rogerson, and Wright (1991) value. As a benchmark I consider an intermediate value o γ = 0.29, but I conduct a series o robustness checks in section Home Production Requirement The required amount o home production (1), x(b) = κ 0 + κ 1 b κ 2 is calibrated in two steps, conditional on the home technology parameters pinned down earlier. First I choose κ 0 to ensure that the level o home hours are matched by the model. Second, I choose the additional home production required when having children, κ 1 b κ 2, to replicate some cross-sectional variation in home hours. While the parameterization o the home production technology ensures that relative male home hours are replicated by the model, I choose κ 0 to match in 1965 the level o male time spent on home production (as a raction o the time endowment o one). This yields κ 0 = To calibrate by how much the need or home production increases due to children, I make use o the observed variation o married men s and women s home hours against the number o children in the household. In the model, equations (12) and (13) im- ) + z h 1 1 ( ) γ [ = z mwm + ply or aggregated parental time input (3) ( z m h 1 m z 1 1 w ] γ 1 x(b), which can be rearranged to give 1 γ γ (22) κ 1 b κ 2 = ( 1 γ γ ( zm h 1 m + z h 1 ) γ [ 1 1 z mw m + z 1 ) w ] γ 1 κ 0 This relationship can be used to iner the home production requirement rom the Aguiar and Hurst (2007) data, which includes not only time use inormation, but or some 20

STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION DOI: 10.19275/RSEP013 Received: 21.04.2017 Accepted: 10.06.2017 STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION Marie Scheitor University of Greifswald, Germany E-mail: marie.scheitor@uni-greifswald.de

More information

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect The Rise of the Added Worker Effect Jochen Mankart Rigas Oikonomou February 9, 2016 Abstract We document that the added worker effect (AWE) has increased over the last three decades. We develop a search

More information

Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor

Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor Christian Bredemeier Falko Juessen First Version: January 2009 This Version: December 2009 Abstract This paper investigates

More information

What accounts for the increase in female labor force participation in Spain

What accounts for the increase in female labor force participation in Spain Discussion Paper No. 2018-6 January 18, 2018 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2018-6 Please cite the corresponding Journal Article at http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2018-16

More information

1. Expected utility, risk aversion and stochastic dominance

1. Expected utility, risk aversion and stochastic dominance . Epected utility, risk aversion and stochastic dominance. Epected utility.. Description o risky alternatives.. Preerences over lotteries..3 The epected utility theorem. Monetary lotteries and risk aversion..

More information

Published in French in: Revue d Economie du Développement, Vol.3, (1995), pp HOUSEHOLD MODELING FOR THE DESIGN OF POVERTY ALLEVIATION

Published in French in: Revue d Economie du Développement, Vol.3, (1995), pp HOUSEHOLD MODELING FOR THE DESIGN OF POVERTY ALLEVIATION Published in French in: Revue d Economie du Développement, Vol.3, (1995), pp. 3-23. HOUSEHOLD MODELING FOR THE DESIGN OF POVERTY ALLEVIATION STRATEGIES 1 by Alain de Janvry and Elisabeth Sadoulet University

More information

THE CHORE WARS Household Bargaining and Leisure Time

THE CHORE WARS Household Bargaining and Leisure Time THE CHORE WARS Household Bargaining and Leisure Time Leora Friedberg University of Virginia and NBER Anthony Webb Center for Retirement Research, Boston College Motivation Can time use of spouses be explained

More information

Demographic Transition and Growth

Demographic Transition and Growth Demographic Transition and Growth Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis April 2017 5 A. Introduction! Long-term trend in population (Western Europe, Maddison 1982/1995):

More information

Alain de Janvry and Elisabeth Sadoulet

Alain de Janvry and Elisabeth Sadoulet DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURAL AND RESOURCE ECONOMICS DIVISION OF AGRICULTURE AND NATURAL RESOURCES UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT BERKELEY W ORKING PAPER NO. 787 HOUSEHOLD MODELING FOR THE DESIGN OF POVERTY

More information

Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth

Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth Child Mortality Decline, Inequality and Economic Growth Tamara Fioroni Lucia Zanelli 5th October 2007 Abstract The aim of this paper is to analyze the effect of child mortality and fertility reductions

More information

Economic incentives and gender identity

Economic incentives and gender identity Economic incentives and gender identity Andrea Ichino European University Institute and University of Bologna Martin Olsson Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN) Barbara Petrongolo Queen Mary

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $ CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $ Joyce Jacobsen a, Melanie Khamis b and Mutlu Yuksel c a Wesleyan University b Wesleyan

More information

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the Importance of Capital Chadwick C. Curtis University of Richmond Steven Lugauer University of Kentucky September 28, 2018 Abstract This paper argues that the impact

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY. Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY. Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang Working Paper 22817 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22817 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 2 issue brief 2 the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course John Havens introduction For the past decade, significant attention has been paid to the aging of the U.S. population.

More information

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality . 1 Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality Lutz Hendricks Iowa State University, CESifo, CFS March 28, 2004. 1 Introduction 2 Wealth is highly concentrated in U.S. data: The richest 1% of households

More information

1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper.

1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper. Course Goals 1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper. 2. Introduce you to macro literatures with a strong empirical component and the datasets used in these literatures.

More information

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

Nordic Journal of Political Economy Nordic Journal of Political Economy Volume 39 204 Article 3 The welfare effects of the Finnish survivors pension scheme Niku Määttänen * * Niku Määttänen, The Research Institute of the Finnish Economy

More information

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim)

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim) Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim) Evidence Evidence : Evidence : Evidence : Evidence : : Evidence : : Evidence : : Evidence

More information

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families Jay H. Hong José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University of Pennsylvania CAERP, CEPR, NBER Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Competition, Deposit Insurance and Bank Risk-taking

Competition, Deposit Insurance and Bank Risk-taking Competition, eposit Insurance and Bank Risk-taking Roung-Jen Wu * Chien-Ping Chi ** Abstract This paper presents a inancial intermediation model integrating both loan and deposit markets to study the impacts

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot Online Theory Appendix Not for Publication) Equilibrium in the Complements-Pareto Case

More information

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013 Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak November 2013 Well known that policymakers face important tradeoffs between equity and efficiency in the design of the tax system The issue we address in this paper informs

More information

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics Lecture Notes for MSc Public Finance (EC426): Lent 2013 AGENDA Efficiency cost

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy

Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy L. Rachel Ngai London School of Economics and CFM and CEPR Barbara Petrongolo Queen Mary University and CEP LSE October 2013 Abstract The paper documents

More information

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles Martin Beraja Erik Hurst Juan Ospina University of Chicago University of Chicago University of Chicago Fall 2017 This Paper Can we use cross-sectional

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data The Distributions of Income and Consumption Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data Elin Halvorsen Hans A. Holter Serdar Ozkan Kjetil Storesletten February 15, 217 Preliminary Extended Abstract Version

More information

Economic Development: Theory and Policy

Economic Development: Theory and Policy Economic Development: Theory and Policy Andreas Schäfer Center of Economic Research at ETH (CER-ETH) and University of Leipzig Institute of Theoretical Economics WS 14/15 Andreas Schäfer (CER-ETH and UL)

More information

Child-Related Transfers, Household Labor Supply and Welfare

Child-Related Transfers, Household Labor Supply and Welfare Child-Related Transfers, Household Labor Supply and Welfare Nezih Guner, Remzi Kaygusuz and Gustavo Ventura CEMFI Tilburg University Arizona State University January 2017 Motivation Availability and cost

More information

HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES

HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES Working Paper The University of Chicago 1126 E. 59th Street Box 107 Chicago IL 60637 www.hceconomics.org Inequality in the Joint Distribution of Consumption and Time Use Jeehoon

More information

Baby Busts and Baby Booms

Baby Busts and Baby Booms Baby Busts and Baby Booms The Fertility Response to Shocks in Dynastic Models Larry Jones 1 Alice Schoonbroodt 2 1 University of Minnesota and NBER 2 University of Southampton and CPC DGEM, REDg at CEMFI

More information

CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE

CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE Richard Blundell, Luigi Pistaferri and Itay Saporta-Eksten April 2017 Abstract We consider the life-cycle choices of a household that in each period

More information

Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy

Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy L. Rachel Ngai & Barbara Petrongolo American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2017 Presented by Francisco Javier Rodríguez for the Macro Reading Group Universidad

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information

Fertility and Female Employment: ADifferent View of the Last 50 Years

Fertility and Female Employment: ADifferent View of the Last 50 Years Fertility and Female Employment: ADifferent View of the Last 50 Years Sebastien Buttet and Alice Schoonbroodt August 5, 2005 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract Over the period from 1964 to 2003, married

More information

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 J.R.Walker March 20, 2012 Suppose that births are biological feasible in the first two periods of a family s life cycle, but

More information

Allocation of Time and Consumption-Equivalent Welfare: A Case of South Korea

Allocation of Time and Consumption-Equivalent Welfare: A Case of South Korea IARIW-Bank of Korea Conference Beyond GDP: Experiences and Challenges in the Measurement of Economic Well-being, Seoul, Korea, April 26-28, 2017 Allocation of Time and Consumption-Equivalent Welfare: A

More information

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University. The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil Brown University December 2007 Goal: analyze quantitatively the economic effects of interventions

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Explaining Educational Attainment across Countries and over Time

Explaining Educational Attainment across Countries and over Time Explaining Educational Attainment across Countries and over Time Diego Restuccia University of Toronto Guillaume Vandenbroucke University of Iowa April 2011 Abstract Consider the following facts. In 1950

More information

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002 The University of British Columbia Department of Economics Economics 351: Women in the Economy Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002 I. For each of the following questions, circle the letter corresponding

More information

Assessing the Engines of Liberation : Home Appliances and Female Labor Force Participation

Assessing the Engines of Liberation : Home Appliances and Female Labor Force Participation Assessing the Engines of Liberation : Home Appliances and Female Labor Force Participation Tiago V. de V. Cavalcanti José Tavares July 19, 2004 Abstract The secular rise in female labor force participation,

More information

Trends in U.S. Hours and the Labor Wedge *

Trends in U.S. Hours and the Labor Wedge * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 53 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2010/0053.pdf Trends in U.S. Hours and the Labor

More information

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Life-cycle Labour Supply The simple static labour supply model discussed so far has a number of short-comings For example, The

More information

The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility

The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility Sarada Duke University Oana Tocoian Claremont McKenna College Oct 2013 - Preliminary, do not cite Abstract We investigate the two-directional relationship

More information

Nontariff Barriers and Domestic Regulation. Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan

Nontariff Barriers and Domestic Regulation. Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan I. Taris A. Market or Imports B. Domestic Market II. Nontari Barriers III. IV. Nontari Barriers and Domestic Regulation Alan V. Deardor University o Michigan Regulation and Related Government Policies

More information

Online Appendix. Long-term Changes in Married Couples Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from the US and Europe Since the 1980s

Online Appendix. Long-term Changes in Married Couples Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from the US and Europe Since the 1980s Online Appendix Long-term Changes in Married Couples Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from the US and Europe Since the 1980s Alexander Bick Arizona State University Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln Goethe University

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

On the Role of Authority in Just-In-Time Purchasing Agreements

On the Role of Authority in Just-In-Time Purchasing Agreements Discussion Paper No. A-55 On the Role o Authority in Just-In-Time Purchasing Agreements CHRISTIAN EWERHART and MICHAEL LORTH May 1997 On the Role o Authority in Just-In-Time Purchasing Agreements Christian

More information

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Niklas Engbom June 16, 2016 Christian Moser World Bank-Bank of Spain Conference This project Shed light on drivers of earnings inequality

More information

Environmental Regulation through Voluntary Agreements

Environmental Regulation through Voluntary Agreements MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Environmental Regulation through Voluntary Agreements Lars Gårn Hansen 1997 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/47537/ MPRA Paper No. 47537, posted 11. June 2013

More information

Taxes and Time Allocation: Evidence from Single Women and Men * Alexander M. Gelber The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, and NBER

Taxes and Time Allocation: Evidence from Single Women and Men * Alexander M. Gelber The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, and NBER Taxes and Time Allocation: Evidence from Single Women and Men * Alexander M. Gelber The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, and NBER Joshua W. Mitchell Harvard University May 2010 Abstract The

More information

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012 TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012 AGENDA Why care about labor supply responses to taxes and

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Revisiting the Role of Home Production in Life-Cycle Labor Supply R. Jason Faberman March 2015 WP 2015-02 Revisiting the Role of Home Production in Life-Cycle Labor Supply

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development?

Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Does Female Empowerment Promote Economic Development? Matthias Doepke (Northwestern) Michèle Tertilt (Mannheim) April 2018, Wien Evidence Development Policy Based on this evidence, various development

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Life-cycle Labour Supply The simple static labour supply model discussed so far has a number of short-comings For example, The

More information

Can Social Programs Reduce Producitivity and Growth? A Hypothesis for Mexico

Can Social Programs Reduce Producitivity and Growth? A Hypothesis for Mexico INTERNATIONAL POLICY CENTER Gerald R. Ford School o Public Policy University o Michigan IPC Working Paper Series Number 37 Can Social Programs Reduce Producitivity and Growth? A Hypothesis or Mexico Santiago

More information

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe The Effect of Partial and Full Retirement Decision of Husbands and Wives on Their Partners Partial and Full Retirement Decision Gülin Öylü MSc Thesis 07/2017-006

More information

Optimal Internal Control Regulation

Optimal Internal Control Regulation Optimal Internal ontrol Regulation Stean F. Schantl University o Melbourne and lred Wagenhoer University o Graz bstract: Regulators increasingly rely on regulation o irms internal controls (I) to prevent

More information

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan Takashi Oshio, Institute for Economics Research, Hitotsubashi University Emiko Usui, Institute for Economics Research, Hitotsubashi University Satoshi

More information

Time Use During Recessions

Time Use During Recessions Time Use During Recessions Mark Aguiar Princeton University Loukas Karabarbounis University of Chicago July 2011 Erik Hurst University of Chicago Abstract We use data from the American Time Use Survey

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Family and Work. 1. Labor force participation of married women

Family and Work. 1. Labor force participation of married women Family and Work 1. Labor force participation of married women - why has it increased so much since WW II? - how is increased market work related to changes in the gender wage gap? 2. Is there a time crunch?

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Economists and Time Use Data

Economists and Time Use Data Economists and Time Use Data Harley Frazis Bureau of Labor Statistics Disclaimer: The views expressed here are not necessarily those of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1 Outline A Few Thoughts on Time

More information

Determining Factors in Middle-Aged and Older Persons Participation in Volunteer Activity and Willingness to Participate

Determining Factors in Middle-Aged and Older Persons Participation in Volunteer Activity and Willingness to Participate Determining Factors in Middle-Aged and Older Persons Participation in Volunteer Activity and Willingness to Participate Xinxin Ma Kyoto University Akiko Ono The Japan Institute for Labour Policy and Training

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Constantine Angyridis Ryerson University Dept. of Economics Toronto, Canada December 7, 2012 Abstract This paper considers an endogenous growth

More information

Sectoral Changes and the Increase in Women s Labor Force Participation

Sectoral Changes and the Increase in Women s Labor Force Participation Sectoral Changes and the Increase in Women s Labor Force Participation Rahsan Akbulut y Department of Economics Pomona College December 2007 Abstract Throughout the second half of the 20th century, women

More information

Unemployment or Out of the Labor Force: A Perspective from Time Allocation and Life Satisfaction

Unemployment or Out of the Labor Force: A Perspective from Time Allocation and Life Satisfaction Unemployment or Out of the Labor Force: A Perspective from Time Allocation and Life Satisfaction Chen Song University of International Business and Economics Chao Wei George Washington University January

More information

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE I. Introduction Income disparities between males and females have been identified as one major issue in the process

More information

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender IFS Working Paper W15/03 Guy Laroque Sophie Osotimehin Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across ages and gender Guy Laroque

More information

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Mario Meier 1 & Andrea Weber 2 1 University of Mannheim 2 Vienna University of Economics and Business, CEPR, IZA Meier & Weber (2016) Peers in Retirement 1 / 35 Motivation

More information

Optimal Taxation of Secondary Earners in the Netherlands: Has Equity Lost Ground?

Optimal Taxation of Secondary Earners in the Netherlands: Has Equity Lost Ground? Optimal Taxation of Secondary Earners in the Netherlands: Has Equity Lost Ground? Henk-Wim de Boer Egbert Jongen Patrick Koot February 2018 Abstract The Netherlands witnessed major reforms in the taxation

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21 Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach Roozbeh Hosseini University of Georgia Ali Shourideh Wharton School QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21 Roozbeh Hosseini(UGA) 0 of 34 Background and Motivation

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an Outlier?

Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an Outlier? Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an Outlier? Richard Rogerson Arizona State University January 2, 2006 Abstract This paper argues that in assessing the effects of tax rates on aggregate hours of

More information

Trade and Development

Trade and Development Trade and Development Table of Contents 2.2 Growth theory revisited a) Post Keynesian Growth Theory the Harrod Domar Growth Model b) Structural Change Models the Lewis Model c) Neoclassical Growth Theory

More information

Review of Economic Dynamics

Review of Economic Dynamics Review of Economic Dynamics 13 (2010) 725 741 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Review of Economic Dynamics www.elsevier.com/locate/red Taxes and female labor supply Remzi Kaygusuz Faculty of Arts

More information

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure Christian Dustmann Johannes Ludsteck Uta Schönberg This Version: July 2008 This appendix consists of three parts. Section 1 compares alternative methods

More information

Misreporting Corporate Performance

Misreporting Corporate Performance ast revision: January 23 Misreporting Corporate Perormance ucian Arye Bebchuk arvard aw School and NBER (bebchuk@law.harvard.edu Oren Bar-Gill arvard Society o Fellows (bargill@law.harvard.edu We are grateul

More information

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications Kazuo Yamaguchi Hanna Holborn Gray Professor and Chair Department of Sociology The University of Chicago October, 2009

More information

Structural Transformation and the Deterioration of European Labor Market Outcomes

Structural Transformation and the Deterioration of European Labor Market Outcomes Structural Transformation and the Deterioration of European Labor Market Outcomes Richard Rogerson Arizona State University September 17, 2005 Abstract This paper examines the evolution of hours worked

More information

SAMPLE DESIGN APPENDIX A

SAMPLE DESIGN APPENDIX A SAMPLE DESIGN APPENDIX A A.1 SAMPLE SIZE AND ALLOCATION The Armenia Demographic and Health Survey (ADHS) required a nationally representative sample o women age 15-49 and men age 15-54. The sample was

More information

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions Answers To Chapter 7 Review Questions 1. Answer d. In the household production model, income is assumed to be spent on market-purchased goods and services. Time spent in home production yields commodities

More information

Reemployment after Job Loss

Reemployment after Job Loss 4 Reemployment after Job Loss One important observation in chapter 3 was the lower reemployment likelihood for high import-competing displaced workers relative to other displaced manufacturing workers.

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department Special Report on the Longitudinal Survey of Newborns in the 21st Century and the Longitudinal Survey of Adults in the 21st Century: Ten-Year Follow-up, 2001 2011 Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Alexandre Dmitriev University of New South Wales Ivan Roberts Reserve Bank of Australia and University of New South Wales February 2, 2011 Abstract Two-country,

More information