The Perverse Effects of Partial Employment Protection Reform: The Case of French Older Workers

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Perverse Effects of Partial Employment Protection Reform: The Case of French Older Workers"

Transcription

1 The Perverse Effects of Partial Employment Protection Reform: The Case of French Older Workers Luc Behaghel*, Bruno Crépon** and Béatrice Sédillot*** French firms laying off workers aged 50 and above have to pay a tax to the unemployment insurance system, known as the Delalande tax. We evaluate the impact of this tax on layoffs as well as on hiring, taking advantage of several changes in the measure since its introduction in A legislative change in 1992 exempted firms from the tax for workers who were hired after age 50. Following this change, the transition rate from unemployment to employment increased significantly for workers over 50 compared to workers under 50. The difference is sizeable: between one third and one half of the initial transition rate. Evidence on the effect on layoffs is less clear cut. The impact is sizeable only for the most stringent tax schedule, after Keywords: Employment protection; older workers; layoff; hiring. JEL classification: J23; J63; J65. * Corresponding author. Paris School of Economics (lea, INRA) and Crest-INSEE 48, bvd Jourdan Paris ; luc.behaghel@ens.fr ** CREST-Insee ; crepon@ensae.fr *** DARES ; beatrice.sedillot@dares.travail.gouv.fr We are particularly grateful to David Blau, Pierre Cahuc, Thierry Magnac, Thomas Piketty, and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments. We also thank participants to the 2006 EEA-ESEM meetings, seminar participants at CREST, Lunch Seminar Jourdan and at Insee Research Seminar. The usual disclaimer applies. 1

2 1. Introduction Confronted with persistently high unemployment rates, most countries in Continental Europe have reformed their employment protection over the past two decades. These reforms have however generally been partial, as governments developed exceptions to the main employment contract while leaving the latter largely untouched. A well-studied example is the development of fixed-duration contracts and its coexistence with indefinite duration contracts. Such partial employment protection reforms have unintended perverse effects. In the case of France, for instance, Blanchard and Landier (2002) and Cahuc and Postel-Vinay (2002) show how fixed-duration contracts increased the segmentation of the labor market. In the case of fixed-duration contracts, segmentation occurs because firms and workers select one type of contract depending on their characteristics and their negotiation power; the law in itself does not make a distinction between workers based on such characteristics as age, gender, disability status or experience. In this paper, we study employment protection reform in a case where the law explicitly treats workers differently depending on their age. Specifically, we study the impact of the Delalande tax, a measure introduced in 1987 in France to discourage firms from laying off older workers. 1 Firms have to pay a tax to the UI system each time they lay off a worker aged above The amount of the tax is proportional to the worker s gross wage at the time of layoff; it has varied over time but can be as high as twelve months of gross wages. Moreover, in 1992, a major reform occurs that exempts workers who are hired after the age of 50. Studying the impact of the Delalande tax is interesting for two reasons. First, the tax provides a good illustration of the potential benefits and drawbacks of targeting employment protection on specific groups of workers. On the one hand, the benefits of having the firms internalize the cost of laying off older workers are likely to be high. Indeed, the probability that an unemployed older worker finds a job is very low in France. Jointly with high layoff rates and the widespread use of early retirement schemes, this explains the low employment rate of older workers in France: for male workers aged 55 to 59, it has fallen dramatically in the early eighties and stabilized below 60% since then. The social cost of this low employment rate is probably high, but firms do not seem to internalize it; they rather tend to view the early exit of older workers as a painless way to adjust their workforce (Behaghel and Gautié, forthcoming). The question is therefore whether the tax has been effective in modifying firms and workers behavior. On the other hand, standard theory predicts that firms will refrain from hiring heavily protected workers, as they expect higher total labor costs. This negative effect of employment protection on hiring may be particularly acute in the case of the Delalande tax. 1 Temporary layoffs do not exist as such in France. Throughout the rest of this paper, we use the word layoff for permanent layoffs. 2 The age threshold was 55 in 1987 but was lowered to 50 after

3 Indeed, firms may easily substitute younger (less protected) workers to older (more protected) ones. Moreover, as the Delalande tax is paid to the UI system, its negative effect cannot be undone by private transfer, as opposed to severance payments in Lazear s (1990) argument. Overall, the Delalande tax appears as a case where the desired as well as the undesired effects of employment protection may both be particularly strong: it therefore appears as an interesting measure to study. The second interest of the Delalande tax is that it has undergone several major legislative changes that provide useful sources of identification. Building on these changes, we are able to separately analyze the effects of the tax on the probability that a worker is hired or laid off. The approach and the key results can be summarized as follows. We start by studying the adverse impact of the tax on hiring. We take advantage of a change that occurred in 1992 and exempts firms from the tax for workers hired after the age of 50, if they are laid off later on. If there was any adverse impact of the tax on unemployed workers aged above 50, it disappeared in 1992; it should therefore be evidenced ex post by an increase in the hiring rates for this particular age group. Indeed, we find that the chances of finding a job increased for unemployed workers aged just above 50 relative to those just below 50. The difference-indifference estimate is sizeable (around one third or one half of the initial transition rates), pointing toward a large adverse effect of the tax on hiring. Then, we study the desired effect of the tax on layoffs. We use three changes in the tax schedule (in 1987, 1992 and 1998) to infer consequences on layoff rates, using workers in the unprotected age group (below 50) as a control group. Our results show that the tax reduced layoffs for older men; however, the estimates are imprecise and rather small, except for the most stringent tax schedule in Results for women are sensitive to the specification. We view the negative impact of the tax on the hiring rates of workers older than 50 as an example of perverse effect of a partial reform: by targeting employment protection on a limited age group, the legislator has induced substitution from these workers toward younger ones. It is unclear whether the reduction in layoffs is sufficient to compensate for this unfavorable effect. Our paper relates to a handful of recent papers that use variation in labor legislation across groups of workers in a given country as a way to provide micro evidence on the impact of employment protection. Acemoglu and Angrist (2001) look at the effect of the American with Disabilities Act: they find that it reduced the employment rate of the protected group, the disabled workers, most likely through lower hiring rates but they do not find significant effects on layoffs. Autor, Donohue and Schwab (2002) find that employment of protected groups is ultimately reduced by the adoption of wrongful-discharge laws by various States in the U.S. In Colombia, Kugler (2004) finds that a reduction in dismissal costs increased separations and accessions for formal workers relative to informal workers, and more so in larger firms that were most likely to be affected by the reform. Kugler and Pica (2005) study the impact of a reform increasing unjust dismissal costs for firms below 15 employees in 3

4 Italy. They find that both accession and separation probabilities decreased in small relative to large firms. In Italy as well, Schivardi and Torrini (2004) study the impact of employment protection on the distribution of firm size. They find that more stringent employment protection for large firms has slightly reduced the propensity of firms to grow. Hernanz, Jimeno and Kugler (2003) study the age-specific employment protection in Spain. They analyze the 1997 reform that reduced dismissal costs and payroll taxes for workers under 30 and over 45. They find that, for men, permanent employment probabilities increased for the two age groups, as did transition rates between unemployment and employment. Effects on women are weaker. Last, Hakola and Uusitalo (2005) study the impact of the experience rating of unemployment pension benefits in Finland, using a reform that affected firms differently depending on their size. They find that layoffs are sensitive to the degree of experience rating; but they do not assess the adverse effect on hiring. Overall, we believe that our results add to the micro evidence on the two effects of employment protection on hiring and layoff, especially by providing unusually clear evidence on the effect on hiring, thanks to a unique natural experiment. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 details the legislation of the Delalande tax and the sources of identification provided by the various legislative changes. Section 3 presents the data. Section 4 deals with the effect on hiring, and section 5 with the effect on layoffs. Section 6 concludes. 2. Overview of the Delalande tax: legislative changes and natural experiments Since its introduction in 1987, the Delalande tax has been modified several times. However, its principle has remained unchanged. Firms laying off workers above a certain age threshold have to pay a tax ( la contribution Delalande ) to the UI system (Unédic). This tax is proportional to the gross wages of the worker. It is only due if the worker is employed under an indefinite term contract (CDI). Only the private sector is concerned (civil servants may not be laid off). From 1987 to 1992, the tax amounted to three months of gross wages for all workers aged 55 and above. From 1992 on, the amount of the tax depends on the age of the laid-off worker (starting at the age of 50) and, for some periods, on the size of the firm (table 1). Exemption rules also vary. These changes are sources of variation that help identify the effects of the tax. However, other major changes affecting the employment prospects of older workers occurred during this period. This section therefore reviews the main legislative changes in the Delalande tax to assess them as sources of identification. The introduction of the tax (1987) It is interesting to notice that the introduction of the Delalande tax occurred almost by surprise: it was voted as an amendment to a law on long-term unemployment, and the 4

5 government does not seem to have been involved in its elaboration a member of Parliament, Delalande, proposed the amendment during the night when the vote took place. The amendment actually had two purposes: restore the financial balance of the UI system and counteract a recent and sharp increase in the number of layoffs of older workers. This increase was explained by a weakening of employment protection in 1986, with the suppression of the administrative authorization that used to be required for layoffs. The government used this administrative authorization as a way to induce firms to use early retirement schemes when dismissing older workers. Firms had to pay part of the cost of these schemes. After 1986, they rapidly turned to layoffs, which were less costly to them and still provided generous unemployment benefits to older workers. Hence, in part, the introduction of the Delalande tax is driven by a general change in the strictness of employment protection. As this change concerned all workers and was not due to changes in the employability of older workers around 1987, it is arguably exogenous with regard to the relative demand for older workers and can thus be considered as a good source of variation to study the impact of adjustment costs on that relative labor demand. One caveat applies, though: the surge in layoffs of older workers that preceded the introduction of the tax may have consequences on the relative evolution of layoff rates of older workers, compared with younger ones. Specifically, this surge may partly reveal an increasing trend in layoff rates of older workers; if that trend is neglected, the effect on layoffs of the Delalande tax may be underestimated. Conversely, if the surge in layoffs before 1987 was strictly accidental, perhaps only the most productive older workers remained in employment in 1987, thus leading to lower layoff rates after 1987: if this is not taken into account, the estimated effect of the Delalande tax would be biased upward. To summarize, the introduction of the Delalande tax in 1987 presents some of the features of a natural experiment. It is driven by an economy-wide shock (a global change in employment protection) that is not directly related to the outcome of interest (the employment of older workers). However, two issues arise: trends in the relative demand for older workers as well as changes in unobserved heterogeneity may bias inference based on a comparison of the evolution of layoff rates across ages. The 1992 changes Two major changes occurred in First, the schedule of the tax was modified. Workers above 50 (instead of 55) are now liable for the tax, but the amount due in case of a layoff varies with age, from one to six months of gross wages. Overall, this is a substantial increase: the amount of the tax is multiplied by two for workers above 56. Figure 1 compares the cost of the Delalande tax to the mandatory severance payments that are also due (to the worker and 5

6 not to the UI system) in case of layoff. 3 After the age of 55, the amount of the Delalande tax is clearly larger than the average mandatory severance payment. Second, the tax is now restricted to workers who were hired before the age of 50 or who had been unemployed for less than three months if they were hired after the age of 50. The increase in the tax schedule in 1992 constitutes a complex source of variation. The political context had changed: the government implemented this increase as part of an effort to raise the employment rate of older workers 4 and of a global move toward more stringent employment protection, reversing changes made by the government. Second, the economic context was characterized by a slowdown of growth that was part of France s most severe recession since World War II, in This particular context may have had consequences on the relative demand for older workers. Third, the variation in the tax schedule with age renders the incentives more complex. On the one hand, a higher tax level at a given age makes it more costly to lay the worker off. But, on the other hand, the fact that the tax increases with age gives firms the incentive to lay off a worker earlier than otherwise, so as to avoid liability for a higher layoff cost in the future. Intuitively, the effect of the 1992 schedule can therefore be decomposed into two parts: the higher the level of the tax, the lower the layoff rate; but the higher the age slope of the tax, the higher the layoff rate. 5 This second effect the effect of the slope of the schedule also existed for workers just below 55 in the 1987 schedule: it is now smoothed and applies to protected workers as well as to workers entering the protected age. The second change exempted firms from the tax for workers who were older than 50 at the time of hiring and had been unemployed for at least three months. This provides a unique setting to study the effect of employment protection on hiring. Indeed, it introduces a sharp discontinuity, at the age of 50: firms hiring unemployed workers above 50 will not be liable for the tax if they lay off these workers later on; but they will if they hire workers below 50 and fire them after they turn 50. In other words, after 1992, the adverse effect of employment protection applies to unemployed workers just below 50, but not to those just above 50. This discontinuity provides a simple source of identification: the effect of the tax on hiring can be estimated from differences in hiring rates above and below the 50-year threshold. To get a sense of the advantage of this natural experiment, it is helpful to compare it to the introduction of the tax in When the tax was introduced, the consequence was that all unemployed workers became more costly to hire, as the firm was facing the possibility of paying the 3 In France, mandatory severance payments depend on the tenure of the worker in his firm. This is taken into account in the computations of figure 1: we use the distribution of workers tenure to compute the average amount of severance payments. However, additional severance payments may be due depending on the industry; these are not taken into account here. For details on the cost of employment protection in France, see Abowd and Kramarz (2003). 4 Access to early-retirement schemes is slightly restricted on the same period. 5 This decomposition can be derived in a formal model of labor demand with adjustment costs (see Behaghel, Crépon and Sédillot, 2004). A key assumption is that there is no uncertainty, so that the schedule of the tax years ahead does not intervene. 6

7 Delalande tax if it were to lay the worker off after the age of 55. Only the degree to which the firm was likely to incur that cost varied according to the age of hiring (once discounted, the Delalande cost was probably negligible for workers hired below the age of 30, for instance). However, disentangling this (continuous) effect of age on the expected Delalande cost from the (continuous) impact of age on productive characteristics that determine hiring rates would be problematic. After 1992, a comparison of hiring rates just above and below the age of 50 is in principle enough to identify the effect of the tax, under the assumption that other age effects on hiring rates are continuous and thus negligible on very short age windows. As discussed in more details in section 4, this discontinuity approach identifies the relative effect of the tax on the two age groups rather than the effect on one of the groups. Indeed, the two groups are affected by the reform. One should not think of unemployed workers over 50 as a control group unaffected by the change. They are affected for two reasons: first, they used to be liable for the tax and they are not anymore after 1992 (their own labor cost decreases); second, they are indirectly impacted by the fact that the labor cost of workers under 50 increases, as it can induce substitution effects in their favor. The important point here, however, is that the two age groups are affected in opposite directions based on a discontinuous criterion: this is what we use for identification. The 1998 change In 1998, the major change was an increase in the schedule of the tax for firms with more than 50 workers. This rise in the tax was implemented in a context of rapidly growing employment that benefited all categories of workers, except older unemployed workers. Other policies affecting older workers employment The pension reform that was progressively implemented after 1993 introduced incentives for longer careers in the private sector. Pensions were calculated on the best 25 years salaries instead of the 10 best years, and the number of years of contributions required for a full pension was raised from 37.5 to 40. This reform affected all workers and in particular introduced no discontinuity between workers aged under and over 50. Over the 1990s, other public policies were more specifically targeted on older workers and may have influenced their transition rate from unemployment to employment. From 1990 to 1995, the Contrat de retour à l emploi (CRE) provided financial incentives (monthly subsidy and exemption of employers social contributions) to recruit long-term unemployed in the private sector. The policy had an age-specific component: in 1992, the CRE was enlarged to almost all jobseekers aged over 50. The firms hiring long-term unemployed over 50 benefited from a permanent exemption of employers social contributions. This enlargement was almost concomitant to the change in the Delalande tax but did not restrict to indefinite duration contracts. In 1995, the Contrat initiative emploi (CIE) replaced the CRE. From 1996, the 7

8 CIE also provided more financial incentives to firms recruiting long-term unemployed over 50 (exemption of employer social contribution up to retirement, higher level of monthly subsidy). Given the specific provisions of CRE and CIE for jobseekers over 50, it is particularly important for our empirical analysis to disentangle the impact of the CRE-CIE policy from the impact of the Delalande tax. This is rendered possible by the fact that, although the two policies were reinforced in 1992, they were modified at different dates (1995 vs. 1998), and that the CRE and CIE targeted broader groups than the Delalande tax (all long term jobseekers were affected, not only those over 50). Their effects can thus be identified separately. Additionally, the CRE and CIE policies apply to workers under all types of contracts, whereas the Delalande tax only applies to workers under indefinite duration contracts. To summarize, legislative changes in 1987, 1992 and 1998 provide various sources of identification to study the impact of the Delalande tax, by comparing the probability of layoff and hiring of different groups of workers at specific periods of time. However, the most convincing sources of variation to study the impact on layoffs are not as convincing to study the impact on hiring, and vice versa. In the next sections, we therefore choose to separately estimate these two effects, at the expense of providing a global assessment of the impact of the tax on employment. We start by briefly reviewing the data we use. 3. The data We use the 1982 to 2002 waves of the French Labor Survey (Enquête Emploi). This is a rotating panel, with yearly interviews: members of a household are interviewed three years in a row, in March, and then leave the panel. We use the data at different time frequencies for studying hiring and layoffs. Concerning hiring, it is important to be able to precisely date the transition so as to use the age discontinuity at 50 and to be able to set apart workers who have been unemployed for less than 3 months, as they are not exempted from the tax. We therefore infer monthly transitions from the retrospective information on the date at which a new job started (if any). Concerning layoffs, we use yearly transition rates. The advantage of using the Enquête Emploi is that it provides detailed information on individual characteristics that affect hiring and layoff. Information on the firm (firm size, industry) is also available. Particular attention is paid to the definition of the employment status. Indeed, only workers under indefinite duration contracts in the private sector are liable for the tax. Due to a change in the design of the Enquête Emploi, this status has to be inferred from several questions (see Behaghel et al., 2005). 8

9 We end up with two samples. The first sample of unemployed workers is used to study the effect of the Delalande tax on hiring; it includes all workers observed at two successive interviews and who were unemployed and aged between 45 and 54 at the first interview. Descriptive statistics are given in table A1. They show the low levels of education among older unemployed workers, and the large share of long-term unemployed. The second sample is used to study the impact of the tax on layoffs; it includes all workers surveyed at two successive dates and who were employed under an indefinite-term contract and aged between 40 and 58 at the first interview. Table A2 displays descriptive statistics on that sample. 4. The effect on hiring Empirical strategy The identification of the effect on hiring uses the fact that the 1992 reform increases the tax schedule while exempting workers hired when they are more than 50 years old. As a consequence, the expected labor cost of a worker under increases, while the expected cost of a worker over 50 decreases. 6 As the relative cost of workers under 50 increases compared to those over 50, standard labor demand theory predicts that the firm should substitute workers over 50 for workers under 50. To test that prediction, the strict application of the regression discontinuity approach would imply estimating: Δ () ε post = ( E( h( t,50 ε) ) E( h( t,50 + ε) )) t 1992, where h is a binary variable that denotes the occurrence of a hiring at date t, for a worker aged just below (or just above) 50, with ε being as close as possible to 0. However, two considerations lead us to increase the age window (ε). First, the effects of the 1992 reform also vary with age within the under-50 and over-50 age categories. Consider the tax exemption: it concerns workers aged over 50, but among them, those aged are the most impacted as they were the closest to being liable for the tax (remember that, before 1992, the tax started at age 55). Taking into account this discounting effect, we thus expect the highest increase in transition to employment for unemployed workers around and the lowest for workers aged just above 50. The second part of the 1992 change is the increase in the tax. This concerns only unemployed workers below 50. Among them, due to the same 6 Note that, by contrast with severance payments whose effects can be undone by the side payments between the worker and the firm (Lazear, 1990), the tax is due to the unemployment insurance is therefore at least partly paid by the firm. 9

10 discounting reasoning, we expect the decrease in transition rates to be highest for those closest to the protected age, i.e. those just below 50. To clarify the two effects a bit more formally, take a very simple model with exogenous 7 job destructions. All jobs generate a surplus p each year which is assumed to be independent of age. Jobs are destroyed at rate d, and all workers retire at age A. Time is discounted at rate ρ. If the job is destroyed before A, a tax f(a), varying with age a, has to be paid to the UI: this is the Delalande tax. In that setting, the expected surplus of a job can be written recursively as S( a) = p + ρ ((1 d) S( a + 1) d f ( a + 1)) if a<a, and S(A-1)=p. Changes in S(a) that result from the 1992 reforms can be expressed as a function of a, f, p, d, A and ρ. They are displayed in figure 2 for some values of the parameters (p=1 by normalization, A=60, d=.04, ρ=.85). 8 The figure highlights the discontinuity at age 50. But it also shows the different treatment doses received by different age groups: in particular, the positive treatment received by workers aged above 50 is highest for those aged 54. In other words, we expect the highest contrast between workers aged 49 and workers aged 54, making it the most relevant groups for analysis. But, on the other hand, workers aged 50 are the most comparable to those aged 49. Overall, this is an argument for looking at various age windows, with due awareness that different age windows correspond to different parameters. The second consideration that leads us not to strictly apply the regression discontinuity approach is the tradeoff between the comparability of the two groups and the precision of the estimates. Increasing the age window around 50 makes the two groups more heterogeneous, but it increases the sample size and makes the estimates more precise. For these two reasons, our approach is to present results for three different age windows, of 1, 3 and 5 years above and below the age of 50. To control for fixed differences between the two age groups, we first consider a simple difference-in-difference specification, where the effect on hiring is defined as: [ ] [( E( h( t,50 ε) ) E( h( t,50 + ε) )) ] ( ε ) = ( E( h( t,50 ε) ) E( h( t,50 + ε) )) = Δ() ε Δ() ε. Δ t 1992 t< 1992 post pre However, we also introduce a set of variables x to control for different composition changes in the two age groups, and to reduce the variance of estimates. As our dataset follows unemployed workers for up to 24 months, we estimate a simple duration model. We specify a proportional hazard model with a flexible baseline hazard (step function). We also make a 7 As our focus is on hiring decisions, we do not need to model job destructions here in a detailed way. However, the argument goes through in the case of endogenous job destructions. 8 We choose a low value for ρ as a way to take into account quits. However, results are qualitatively unchanged for other values. 10

11 distinction for workers that have been unemployed for more than 3 months (who are concerned by the exemption, if they are older than 50) and those who have been unemployed for less, who are not exempted. This latter group may also react to the reform. For example, there may be an entry effect, whereby after 1992 hiring is delayed for unemployed workers aged more than 50 but with less than 3 months in unemployment, until they become eligible for the exemption. We therefore allow for a specific difference-in-difference effect for unemployed workers with less than 3 months unemployed. We end up with the following specification of the hazard rate: θ ( d x, t,a) xb + α post = λ( d) exp + α' 1 post c 1( ( t 1992) &( d 3) ) + α 1( ( a < 50) &( d 3) ) + Δ () ε 1( ( t 1992) &( a < 50) & ( d 3) ) below50 (( ) ( )) (( ) ( )) ()(( ) ( ) ) c' t 1992 & d < 3 + α' 1 a < 50 & d < 3 + Δ ε 1 t 1992 & a < 50 & ( d < 3) below50 where d is time spent in unemployment, and λ(.) is the baseline hazard function. In this c specification, the parameter of interest is Δ () ε. The estimation is conducted by maximum of likelihood. Given stock sampling, noting S(.) the survival function, d i the duration at exit and d i0 the duration when first observed, the contribution of individual i to the likelihood is θ ( di) S( di) S( d ) i0 if the individual left for employment in the private sector under indefinite S( di) duration contract, and otherwise. 9 S( d ) i0 Main results Table 2 details the steps of the difference-in-difference estimation, without any control, to estimate Δ () ε. Three alternative age windows are considered, and men and women are analyzed separately. The upper part of the table displays transition rates from unemployment to employment under indefinite duration contracts, for workers aged above and below 50, before and after the 1992 reforms. Consider men for the narrowest age window: in tune with the regression discontinuity approach, transition rates are initially close, and statistically not different. Workers aged 49 tend to find a job slightly faster. But, as shown in the middle of the table, the difference reverses after 1992 (the difference falls from +.22 point of percentage to.32 point of percentage). This reversal is summarized in the difference-in-difference estimate: the monthly transition rate of male unemployed workers aged 49 has decreased by 9 As an alternative to the duration model, we also estimate simpler specification of the difference-in-difference model with controls for composition effect (see table 5). The corresponding model is E h1( t 1992),1( a < 50) = α + α 1 t α 1 a < 50 + Δ ε 1( t 1992 & a 50 ). ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 0 post below50 < 11

12 .54 percentage points (with a standard error of.43 pp) compared to male unemployed workers aged 50. The other columns give the results for broader age windows. In all cases, the relative change is the same: as expected from the theory, the transition rate has decreased for those below 50 compared to those above The change is statistically significant in some cases, not in others. Of course, the wider the age range, the lower the standard errors, which tends to make the observed differences significant. But, on the other hand, if we look at point estimates, it seems that the highest relative change occurs for workers aged compared to workers aged As shown by figure 3, it is unfortunately not possible to go much further on estimating changes for narrowly defined age groups. Indeed, when one looks at changes in transition rates for one-year age groups, confidence intervals are very wide. It is therefore difficult to assess whether the pattern of changes in the expected job surplus (the treatment doses of figure 2) is paralleled by the changes in transition rates. Giving credit to point estimates, the discontinuity at age 50 appears as expected for men. However, there is no clear age trend in the decrease of transition rates before 50 or in the increase after 50, as we would have expected from figure 2. We now turn to the duration model. Table 3 displays our preferred specification for estimating the effect of the 1992 reforms. The coefficient of interest appears in bold characters. The econometric model allows for improvements in several dimensions. First, to track the theoretical predictions more precisely, the difference-in-difference analysis separates unemployed workers for less than 3 months and those for longer. Second, we allow for age effects within the two groups by introducing age indicators as controls, and for duration dependence in unemployment by specifying a flexible baseline hazard. Third, we control for composition changes in the following dimensions: level of schooling, number of children, size of the town of residence, time effects (seasonal monthly indicators or cyclical year indicators). Fourth, we control for the possibility that the business cycle has different effects on different age groups, by introducing age-specific effects of the GDP growth rate. Last, we control for changes in employment policies that were sometimes differentiated across age groups. Indeed, subsidies to hiring were introduced in for the long-term unemployed. They were particularly generous for workers above 50. They were modified several times, depending on the time the worker had been unemployed, her age and other individual characteristics (disability, ). It is therefore possible to introduce additional dummies that indicate three levels of subsidies across the period (no subsidy before 1989 and for the short-term unemployed afterwards; small subsidies for the long-term unemployed after 1990; large subsidies for specific groups after 1990, with changes in 1995). 10 Note that, as the age range widens, the hypothesis of initial similarity between the groups is statistically rejected (e.g., men aged 45 to 49 have a higher probability of being hired than men aged 50 to 54: +.52 pp, with a.16 pp standard error). Identification thus needs to rely on the difference-in-difference assumption that trends for the two groups are similar in the absence of reform. 12

13 The results on the parameters of interest confirm those of table 2, but they are more precise. The relative change in transition rate appears most clearly for the narrowest age range (49-50). For men, it is statistically significant. The point estimate (-.75) implies a sizeable effect: the reform has decreased the relative transition rate by as much as 53% (1-exp(-.75)). This relative effect encompasses an improvement for those above 50 and a deterioration for those below 50. For broader age ranges, the difference is smaller (the coefficient for men implies relative changes of -48% or 27%), but it is more precisely estimated, so that results remain statistically significant. The overall pattern is similar for women. However, the point estimates are smaller and the coefficients are (marginally) significant only for the intermediary age window. Though this may be due to sampling error the coefficients for men and women are not statistically different it may also reveal true differences. A conjecture is that transitions of unemployed women towards unemployment are more strongly conditioned by labor supply determinants, so that the transition rates are less sensitive to labor demand effects such as those of the Delalande tax. We briefly review the effects on control variables. We are not able to uncover a specific change for persons who have been unemployed for less than 3 months: standard errors are too large, due to the limited sample sizes. 11 The baseline hazard shows a decreasing pattern that is consistent with unemployment duration dependence or with the impact of unobserved heterogeneity. We do not find evidence that the different age groups are affected differently by the business cycle. This may simply be due to the fact that the age groups are quite close. A puzzling result concerns the impact of the employment subsidies, which is in some cases negative and significant. Before interpreting it as a stigma effect, it should be borne in mind that the identification of the effect rests on strong assumptions (stability of the labor demand with regard to workers with shorter or longer spells of unemployment). The number of children tends to reduce the transition probability for women only, in the wider age window. 12 Last, the impact of education is limited and living in Paris tends to increase transition rates. The visual inspection of figure 3 can be complemented by conducting the same estimation as in table 3, but comparing one-year age groups on the two sides of the 50 year-old threshold (e.g. 45 years old to 50 years old, 46 years old to 50 years old, etc). The resulting differencein-difference estimates are displayed in appendix table A3. Given the treatment doses that result from the 1992 reform (figure 2), one would expect the estimates to grow as one moves downward (toward age 49) and toward the right (toward age 54). However, the estimates are very imprecise. 11 Workers unemployed for less than 3 months are rare as we had to sample in the stock. 12 Note that we are considering parents older than 45, with few young children. 13

14 Analysis of substitution effects The effect we have been analyzing so far can be interpreted generally as a substitution effect: after the 1992 reform, firms prefer workers over 50 to workers under 50. However, this can take two forms. First, given two identical candidates, one over 50 and the other under 50, the firm prefers to hire the older one. Second, if a firm wants to hire a 49-year old worker, it may convince him, perhaps with some side payment, to wait in order to hire him after his 50 th birthday. 13 This second form of substitution intertemporal substitution between hiring dates is particularly likely if there are matching frictions: if finding the right match is difficult for firms, they will try to retain the worker and incur the cost of having him wait rather than search for another worker. At the limit, no rational firm would hire a worker the day before his 50th birthday. The difference-in-difference estimates around the age of 50 capture these two effects. We do two things to disentangle them. First, we exclude workers in the age range from the estimation. Indeed, it is unlikely that a firm would have a worker wait for more than one year; and if he has waited, then it should hire him in the next few months after his 50 th birthday. As a consequence, the difference-in-difference analysis on workers aged 51 and more vs. those aged 48 and less should only capture substitution between different workers. The estimates are displayed on table 4. Table 4 only differs from table 3 by the exclusion of the age range. As expected, this reduces the estimates (as one of the two substitution effects is removed) and increases the standard errors (as the samples are smaller). Nevertheless, the effect remains significant and strong when comparing male unemployed aged to those aged 51-52: there seems to be substitution between workers in that age range. Second, we analyze the monthly hazard of finding a job (figure 4). The idea is that intertemporal substitution between hiring dates has a distinctive implication: if some workers are waiting at the gate of the firm with the promise of being hired as soon as they get 50 years old, there should be a spike in hiring at the age of 50. More precisely, we should observe two discontinuities in hiring rates: (i) a rise between age 49 year 11 months and age 50 (due to the two substitution effects); (ii) a fall between age 50 and age 50 and 1 month (the mass of workers having met the firm before they were 50 is hired at age 50, whereas at age 50 and 1 month, only those who have just met a firm can be hired). In practice, the limited sample size 13 We are indebted to one reviewer for stressing that point. 14

15 does not allow looking precisely at the two discontinuities. However, the point estimates are consistent with a spike in hiring in the months that follow the age of 50. To summarize, the two substitution effects seem at work, as expected. Time analysis The difference-in-difference analysis could theoretically be performed on a very short period before and after 1992, to reduce the risk of capturing the effects of other changes in the labor market. However, if we used too short periods, the sample of unemployed workers would be too small to precisely estimate transition rates. Until now, we have therefore used a very long time period, from 1982 to Besides providing sufficient samples of unemployed workers, this long period has the advantage of covering two business cycles, one before and the other after the reform. If the business cycle has some effects on the relative demand for workers just below and just above 50, these effects should cancel out over the period. However, it is important to check whether our estimates are robust to the choice of other periods. Figure 5 shows the difficulty of precisely determining the timing of the changes with the data, given the limited sample sizes. It shows the difference in transition rates for two age groups (those aged compared to those aged 50-52). This difference is more frequently positive before 1992, and more frequently negative after. But it fluctuates a lot and is imprecisely estimated (at the semester frequency). It is therefore clear that significant results can only be obtained by averaging transition rates over time, as was done in the previous estimations, so as to mitigate the impact of sampling error. How long need the period of analysis be? Table 5 estimates the same model as table 3, but on shorter periods. Each cell comes from a different estimation and contains the difference-in-difference estimate of interest. The different estimations correspond to the three age windows and to periods of estimation of various lengths: two years before and after the 1992 reform, four years before and after, etc. The shortest time window ( ) leads to very imprecise estimations: although the point estimate is always of the expected sign, the coefficient is not statistically significant for any of the age windows. Statistically significant results are obtained for time windows of 8 and more years (4 before 1992, 4 after). They are qualitatively similar to those obtained in table 3, over 20 years of observation. Overall, the time analysis shows that we cannot precisely date the change in the relative transition rates of unemployed workers above and below 50. However, in the absence of relevant data sources with large samples, this change can only be inferred by looking at about 4 years before and after the 1992 reforms. 15

16 Robustness checks We performed a variety of robustness checks. First, we checked that results are not driven by the parameterization of the duration model. We estimated the difference-in-difference parameter in models where the dependent variable is the indicator variable of making a transition or not (from unemployment to employment under an indefinite term contract), assuming different functional forms for the probability of a transition (linear probability model, logit or probit). The results are available upon request; they are qualitatively the same as in table 3. Second, we checked that results are qualitatively unchanged if we use yearly transition rates instead of monthly ones. 14 The main results remain unchanged (they are available upon request). Third, we checked whether the results are sensitive to the omission of some controls. This is unlikely to be the case, as any difference in fixed characteristics or any trend common to the two age groups is already controlled for by the difference-in-difference setup. Robustness checks showed that the results are not highly sensitive to the list of controls. In particular, removing the indicator variables for job subsidies or the indicator variables for workers unemployed for less than three months does not alter the results significantly (results available upon request). The next two checks are of a different nature. They are attempts to test the identifying assumptions of the difference-in-difference analysis. First, the Delalande tax only concerns workers hired under indefinite term contracts. Therefore, no significant difference-in-difference effect should appear for workers hired under fixed-term contracts. This is checked in table 6. The point estimates are small and their sign varies; none is statistically significant. This can be considered as an indirect test of the identification strategy. In particular, if one is worried that employment subsidies (or other policy changes with specific effects on older workers) have not been appropriately controlled for, these changes should have affected hiring under both types of contract. 15 As this is not the case, our confidence increases that the estimates in table 3 identify the effect of the 1992 reform of the Delalande tax. Last, one may remain worried that some unobserved shocks may have affected unemployed workers below and above 50 differently. In that case, our identification strategy would fail. It 14 Indeed, the advantage of yearly transition rates is that they may be more precisely measured, as they do not rely upon a retrospective question on the date at which a new job started. But the drawback is that, for workers aged between 49 and 50 at the beginning of the year, we do not know whether they were above or below the threshold at the time a transition occurred. 15 The employment subsidies introduced in 1989 applied to both fixed-term and indefinite duration contracts. 16

17 is not possible to test it directly, as it is not possible to disentangle the effect of shocks occurring in 1992 from the effect of the 1992 reform of the Delalande tax. However, we can check whether unobserved shocks (with different effects on workers aged above and below 50) are evidenced at other dates than This amounts to checking whether the differencein-difference analysis, if it is conducted around other years than 1992, also leads to significant results. We re-estimate the model of table 3 over 8-year periods, with alternative turning points in 1986, 1988, 1990, 1994, 1996 or In other words, we check whether placebo reforms have the same impact as the true 1992 reform. Again, we focus on the difference-indifference coefficient of interest, which should be statistically significant only in The estimates are displayed on figure 6, along with 95% confidence intervals. They are significant only in 1992, except for 1990, where significant results are found for men. This however may simply be due to the fact that the estimation periods for the true reform (1992) and for the 1990 placebo reform overlap: we had to take 8-year time windows in order to get sufficient sample sizes. Our conclusion is that, though this analysis cannot precisely date the change (1990 or 1992?), there is something specific to that period, leaving the Delalande 1992 reform as a likely explanation. 5. The effect on layoffs Empirical strategy The fundamental difficulty in identifying the effect of the Delalande tax from time-series variation is the strong counter-cyclicality of layoffs, as illustrated in figure 7. The time-series correlation between the tax rate and layoffs cannot be interpreted if one does not control for other sources of changes in layoff rates, including the business cycle (as shown on figure 8, the period analysis covers two cycles). As described above, three changes in the tax schedule offer opportunities for identification of the effects of the tax. However, inference must account for other simultaneous changes. A natural way to control for cycles and possible trends in layoffs is to use younger workers, unaffected by the tax, as a control group. The corresponding econometric specification is: E ( s a, x, t) = xb + t 1( t = t0 ) + α 1( = ) + ( ) + Δ ( ) 0 a ait a γct a δ ct a t0 = 1983 λ, a= 40 where s is a dummy variable for layoff, x are control variables, c t ( a) and ( a) and the slope of the tax at age a. Parameters λ t and business cycle and of the worker s age on the probability of a layoff. c t Δ are the level α a capture the respective effects of the As discussed in the previous section, when the profile of the tax is not flat with age, the effect of the tax on layoffs has two components, which are captured by parameters γ (expected to be 17

18 negative) and δ (expected to be positive). An additional underlying assumption is that the effects of the two components of the tax (its level and its slope) on the probability of being laid off are linear. However, using younger workers as a control group assumes that the relative demand for labor across ages is acyclical and has no trend. This may be a strong assumption as we are performing the analysis over a 20-year age range. We relax that assumption by allowing for age-specific trends and age-specific business cycle effects through interactions of age indicators with a time trend and interactions of age indicators with the GDP growth rate. Moreover, it may be important to take into account the fact that the Delalande tax modifies the recruiting behavior of firms (through the effect on hiring). Firms are likely to become more selective when hiring workers close to the age of 50. If this selectivity is not captured by available controls, the distribution of unobserved heterogeneity will not be stable across periods. This can bias the estimates upward: increased retention would be attributed to the desired effect of the tax, instead of being attributed to the effect on hiring (via the higher selectivity of firms). One way to control for this selectivity is to introduce dummies to indicate hiring under the different tax schedules (there are three regimes: , in large firms and in small firms, and in large firms). The results are given in table 7. The first six columns display the results of a linear probability model with different sets of controls; the last column displays the results of a probit model. Overall, for men, the level and the slope of the tax schedule have the expected effect: a higher level of the tax deters firms from laying older workers off, whereas a higher slope tends to accelerate layoffs. However, the effect of the slope is not statistically significant. Comparing the various columns, it appears that controlling for individual characteristics of the workers matters. Estimates are substantially reduced when controlling for observed workers characteristics (in particular, tenure and education). Allowing for agespecific trends or business cycle effects does not make a large difference. The table shows the p-values of the tests for the existence of such effects. Age-specific business cycle effects are marginally significant; age-specific trends are not significant. In column 6, adding controls for the period of hiring further reduces the estimated impact of the Delalande tax; it remains however significant. Similar to the results for hiring, results for women are not significant. This is less easily interpreted in terms of labor supply, as older women who have a job at the age of 50 are quite attached to the labor force. A second puzzle is that results are sensitive to the specification: the impact of the Delalande schedule is no longer significant if we use a probit or logit model. To get an idea of the order of magnitude implied by the estimates of the linear probability model, figure 9 displays the predicted layoff rates with and without the tax, based on point 18

1 Payroll Tax Legislation 2. 2 Severance Payments Legislation 3

1 Payroll Tax Legislation 2. 2 Severance Payments Legislation 3 Web Appendix Contents 1 Payroll Tax Legislation 2 2 Severance Payments Legislation 3 3 Difference-in-Difference Results 5 3.1 Senior Workers, 1997 Change............................... 5 3.2 Young Workers,

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Not so voluntary retirement decisions? Evidence from a pension reform

Not so voluntary retirement decisions? Evidence from a pension reform Finnish Centre for Pensions Working Papers 9 Not so voluntary retirement decisions? Evidence from a pension reform Tuulia Hakola, Finnish Centre for Pensions Roope Uusitalo, Labour Institute for Economic

More information

Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI Reform for Job Separators?

Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI Reform for Job Separators? Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI for Job Separators? HRDC November 2001 Executive Summary Changes under EI reform, including changes to eligibility and length of entitlement, raise

More information

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training J. Adda, C. Dustmann,C.Meghir, J.-M. Robin February 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper evaluates the return to formal

More information

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s As part of its monetary policy strategy, the ECB regularly monitors the development of a wide range of indicators and assesses their implications

More information

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance Benefits Nynke de Groot Bas van der Klaauw February 6, 2019 Abstract This paper uses a difference-in-differences approach exploiting

More information

Euro-Productivity and Euro-Jobs. Which Institutions Really Matter? since the 1960s: Gayle Allard (Instituto de Empresa, Madrid)

Euro-Productivity and Euro-Jobs. Which Institutions Really Matter? since the 1960s: Gayle Allard (Instituto de Empresa, Madrid) Euro-Productivity and Euro-Jobs since the 1960s: Which Institutions Really Matter? Gayle Allard (Instituto de Empresa, Madrid) and Peter Lindert (UC-Davis and NBER) Two police cases that should be one:!

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand?

Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand? HCSF/217/1-2-1 15 e séance Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand? The French private non-financial sector (households and firms) indebtedness registered a steady increase since the

More information

Employment protection: Do firms perceptions match with legislation?

Employment protection: Do firms perceptions match with legislation? Economics Letters 90 (2006) 328 334 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Employment protection: Do firms perceptions match with legislation? Gaëlle Pierre, Stefano Scarpetta T World Bank, 1818 H Street NW,

More information

Unemployment Benefits, Unemployment Duration, and Post-Unemployment Jobs: A Regression Discontinuity Approach

Unemployment Benefits, Unemployment Duration, and Post-Unemployment Jobs: A Regression Discontinuity Approach Unemployment Benefits, Unemployment Duration, and Post-Unemployment Jobs: A Regression Discontinuity Approach By Rafael Lalive* Structural unemployment appears to be strongly correlated with the potential

More information

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation Evidence from Randomly Assigned Judges Omar Bamieh University of Vienna November 13th 2018 1 / 27 Why should we care about firing costs? Firing costs make it

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4691 How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment Jan C. van Ours Sander Tuit January 2010 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

5 MONITORING CYCLES, JOBS, AND THE PRICE LEVEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

5 MONITORING CYCLES, JOBS, AND THE PRICE LEVEL* Chapter. Key Concepts Chapter 5 MONITORING CYCLES, JOBS, AND THE PRICE LEVEL* Key Concepts The Business Cycle The periodic but irregular up-and-down movement in production and jobs is the business cycle. Business cycles have

More information

Labor Force Participation in New England vs. the United States, : Why Was the Regional Decline More Moderate?

Labor Force Participation in New England vs. the United States, : Why Was the Regional Decline More Moderate? No. 16-2 Labor Force Participation in New England vs. the United States, 2007 2015: Why Was the Regional Decline More Moderate? Mary A. Burke Abstract: This paper identifies the main forces that contributed

More information

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 401 406 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181116 In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva*

More information

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance Benefits Nynke de Groot Bas van der Klaauw July 14, 2014 Abstract This paper exploits a substantial reform of the Dutch UI law to

More information

Shirking and Employment Protection Legislation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

Shirking and Employment Protection Legislation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Shirking and Employment Protection Legislation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment Vincenzo Scoppa Department of Economics and Statistics, University of Calabria (Italy)

More information

Labor Market Effects of the Early Retirement Age

Labor Market Effects of the Early Retirement Age Labor Market Effects of the Early Retirement Age Day Manoli UT Austin & NBER Andrea Weber University of Mannheim & IZA September 30, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence on the effects

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Employment Protection Reforms, Employment and the Incidence of Temporary Jobs in Europe:

Employment Protection Reforms, Employment and the Incidence of Temporary Jobs in Europe: DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3241 Protection Reforms, and the Incidence of Temporary Jobs in Europe: 1995 2001 Lawrence M. Kahn December 2007 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017 Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality June 19, 2017 1 Table of contents 1 Robustness checks on baseline regression... 1 2 Robustness checks on composition

More information

Industry Sector Analysis of Work-related Injury and Illness, 2001 to 2014

Industry Sector Analysis of Work-related Injury and Illness, 2001 to 2014 Industry Sector Analysis of Work-related Injury and Illness, 2001 to 2014 This report is published as part of the ESRI and Health and Safety Authority (HSA) Research Programme on Health Safety and wellbeing

More information

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom Gaétan Stephan 1 University of Rennes 1, CREM April 2012 (Preliminary draft) Abstract We model the relation between output

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Introduction For most of the past quarter century, the labor force participation rates of the older

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

BEAUTIFUL SERBIA. Holger Bonin (IZA Bonn) and Ulf Rinne* (IZA Bonn) Draft Version February 17, 2006 ABSTRACT

BEAUTIFUL SERBIA. Holger Bonin (IZA Bonn) and Ulf Rinne* (IZA Bonn) Draft Version February 17, 2006 ABSTRACT BEAUTIFUL SERBIA Holger Bonin (IZA Bonn) and Ulf Rinne* (IZA Bonn) Draft Version February 17, 2006 ABSTRACT This paper evaluates Beautiful Serbia, an active labor market program operating in Serbia and

More information

Do labor market programs affect labor force participation?

Do labor market programs affect labor force participation? Do labor market programs affect labor force participation? Kerstin Johansson WORKING PAPER 2002:3 Do labor market programs affect labor force participation? * by Kerstin Johansson + January 30, 2002 Abstract

More information

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW*

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW* THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW* Pedro Martins** Álvaro Novo*** Pedro Portugal*** 1. INTRODUCTION In most developed countries, pension systems have

More information

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin June 15, 2008 Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The trade effect of the euro is typically

More information

CREATIVE DESTRUCTION & JOB MOBILITY: FLEXICURITY IN THE LAND OF SCHUMPETER

CREATIVE DESTRUCTION & JOB MOBILITY: FLEXICURITY IN THE LAND OF SCHUMPETER CREATIVE DESTRUCTION & JOB MOBILITY: FLEXICURITY IN THE LAND OF SCHUMPETER Andreas Kettemann, University of Zurich Francis Kramarz, CREST-ENSAE Josef Zweimüller, University of Zurich OECD, Paris February

More information

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion Luis Diaz-Serrano and Donal O Neill National University of Ireland Maynooth, Department of Economics Abstract In this paper

More information

Introduction to De Economist Special Issue Retirement and Employment Opportunities for Older Workers

Introduction to De Economist Special Issue Retirement and Employment Opportunities for Older Workers De Economist (2013) 161:219 223 DOI 10.1007/s10645-013-9214-4 Introduction to De Economist Special Issue Retirement and Employment Opportunities for Older Workers Pierre Koning Received: 10 July 2013 /

More information

ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN. Chapter 6. Unemployment. October 23, Chapter 6: Unemployment. ECON204 (A01). Fall 2012

ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN. Chapter 6. Unemployment. October 23, Chapter 6: Unemployment. ECON204 (A01). Fall 2012 ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN Chapter 6 Unemployment October 23, 2012 1 Topics in this Chapter Focus on the Long run unemployment rate Natural Rate of Unemployment contrast with cyclical behaviour of unemployment

More information

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender * COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY Adi Brender * 1 Key analytical issues for policy choice and design A basic question facing policy makers at the outset of a crisis

More information

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER Comment John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER The main theme of Robert Hall s paper is that cyclical fluctuations in unemployment are driven almost entirely by fluctuations in the jobfinding rate,

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin American and the Caribbean Volume Author/Editor: James

More information

Gender Disparity in Faculty Salaries at Simon Fraser University

Gender Disparity in Faculty Salaries at Simon Fraser University Gender Disparity in Faculty Salaries at Simon Fraser University Anke S. Kessler and Krishna Pendakur, Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University July 10, 2015 1. Introduction Gender pay equity in

More information

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t REAL INTEREST RATE AND MONETARY POLICY There are various approaches to the question of what is a desirable long-term level for monetary policy s instrumental rate. The matter is discussed here with reference

More information

The role of an EMU unemployment insurance scheme on income protection in case of unemployment

The role of an EMU unemployment insurance scheme on income protection in case of unemployment EM 11/16 The role of an EMU unemployment insurance scheme on income protection in case of unemployment H. Xavier Jara, Holly Sutherland and Alberto Tumino December 2016 The role of an EMU unemployment

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Chapter 7. Employment protection

Chapter 7. Employment protection Chapter 7 Employment protection This chapter heavily borrows from courses and slides by Tito Boeri, Professor of Economics at Bocconi University, Milan, Italy Protecting jobs Losing a job is always a bad

More information

DID AGE DISCRIMINATION PROTECTIONS HELP OLDER WORKERS WEATHER THE GREAT RECESSION? *

DID AGE DISCRIMINATION PROTECTIONS HELP OLDER WORKERS WEATHER THE GREAT RECESSION? * DID AGE DISCRIMINATION PROTECTIONS HELP OLDER WORKERS WEATHER THE GREAT RECESSION? * David Neumark Department of Economics UCI 3151 Social Science Plaza Irvine, CA 92697 and NBER and IZA dneumark@uci.edu

More information

4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance wor

4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance wor 4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance workers, or service workers two categories holding less

More information

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure

More information

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry 1 I. Motivation Business cycle synchronization (BCS) the critical

More information

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Mario Meier 1 & Andrea Weber 2 1 University of Mannheim 2 Vienna University of Economics and Business, CEPR, IZA Meier & Weber (2016) Peers in Retirement 1 / 35 Motivation

More information

EPI & CEPR Issue Brief

EPI & CEPR Issue Brief EPI & CEPR Issue Brief IB #205 ECONOMIC POLICY INSTITUTE & CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH APRIL 14, 2005 FINDING THE BETTER FIT Receiving unemployment insurance increases likelihood of re-employment

More information

Do wage subsidies affect the subsequent employment stability of permanent workers?: the case of Spain *

Do wage subsidies affect the subsequent employment stability of permanent workers?: the case of Spain * Do wage subsidies affect the subsequent employment stability of permanent workers?: the case of Spain * Artículo presentado en el XXI Simposio de Moneda y Crédito Febrero, 2009 J. Ignacio García-Pérez

More information

Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent

Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent Olivier Blanchard July 2006 There are two ways to read

More information

For Online Publication Additional results

For Online Publication Additional results For Online Publication Additional results This appendix reports additional results that are briefly discussed but not reported in the published paper. We start by reporting results on the potential costs

More information

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction,

To understand the drivers of poverty reduction, Understanding the Drivers of Poverty Reduction To understand the drivers of poverty reduction, we decompose the distributional changes in consumption and income over the 7 to 1 period, and examine the

More information

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender IFS Working Paper W15/03 Guy Laroque Sophie Osotimehin Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across ages and gender Guy Laroque

More information

THE GREAT RECESSION: UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE AND STRUCTURAL ISSUES

THE GREAT RECESSION: UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE AND STRUCTURAL ISSUES THE GREAT RECESSION: UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE AND STRUCTURAL ISSUES Jesse Rothstein CLSRN Summer School June 2013 Unemployment Rate Percent of labor force, seasonally adjusted 12 10 Oct. 2009: 10.0% 8 6

More information

Did Age Discrimination Protections Help Older Workers Weather the Great Recession? David Neumark UC Irvine. Patrick Button UC Irvine

Did Age Discrimination Protections Help Older Workers Weather the Great Recession? David Neumark UC Irvine. Patrick Button UC Irvine Did Age Discrimination Protections Help Older Workers Weather the Great Recession? David Neumark UC Irvine Patrick Button UC Irvine September 2013 Did Age Discrimination Protections Help Older Workers

More information

Cross Atlantic Differences in Estimating Dynamic Training Effects

Cross Atlantic Differences in Estimating Dynamic Training Effects Cross Atlantic Differences in Estimating Dynamic Training Effects John C. Ham, University of Maryland, National University of Singapore, IFAU, IFS, IZA and IRP Per Johannson, Uppsala University, IFAU,

More information

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell CHAPTER 2 Hidden unemployment in Australia William F. Mitchell 2.1 Introduction From the viewpoint of Okun s upgrading hypothesis, a cyclical rise in labour force participation (indicating that the discouraged

More information

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate CHAPTER 13 13-1. Suppose there are 25,000 unemployed persons in the economy. You are given the following data about the length of unemployment spells: Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate 1 0.60 2 0.20

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN * SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN * Abstract - This paper reexamines the results of my 1974 paper on Social Security and saving with the help

More information

Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment

Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment Jonneke Bolhaar, Nadine Ketel, Bas van der Klaauw ===== FIRST DRAFT, PRELIMINARY ===== Abstract We investigate the implications

More information

Analyzing the Anticipation of Treatments using Data on Notification Dates

Analyzing the Anticipation of Treatments using Data on Notification Dates Analyzing the Anticipation of Treatments using Data on Notification Dates Bruno Crépon Marc Ferracci Grégory Jolivet Gerard van den Berg CREST-INSEE University of Marne-la-Vallée University of Bristol

More information

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany Modern Economy, 2016, 7, 1198-1222 http://www.scirp.org/journal/me ISSN Online: 2152-7261 ISSN Print: 2152-7245 Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI Camille Landais (LSE) and Johannes Spinnewijn (LSE) December 15, 2016 Landais & Spinnewijn (LSE) Value of UI December 15, 2016 1 / 33 Motivation

More information

The Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Earnings, Employment and Hours through the Recession

The Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Earnings, Employment and Hours through the Recession The Impact of the National Minimum Wage on Earnings, Employment and Hours through the Recession Mark Bryan Andrea Salvatori Mark Taylor Institute for Social and Economic Research (ISER) University of Essex

More information

WHAT HAPPENED TO LONG TERM EMPLOYMENT? ONLINE APPENDIX

WHAT HAPPENED TO LONG TERM EMPLOYMENT? ONLINE APPENDIX WHAT HAPPENED TO LONG TERM EMPLOYMENT? ONLINE APPENDIX This appendix contains additional analyses that are mentioned in the paper but not reported in full due to space constraints. I also provide more

More information

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 PENSION REFORM AND THE LABOUR MARKET. Walpurga Köhler-Töglhofer *

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 PENSION REFORM AND THE LABOUR MARKET. Walpurga Köhler-Töglhofer * COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 PENSION REFORM AND THE LABOUR MARKET Walpurga Köhler-Töglhofer * 1 Introduction OECD countries, in particular the European countries within the OECD, will face major demographic challenges

More information

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data by Peter A Groothuis Professor Appalachian State University Boone, NC and James Richard Hill Professor Central Michigan University

More information

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops

More information

The Effect of Pension Subsidies on Retirement Timing of Older Women: Evidence from a Regression Kink Design

The Effect of Pension Subsidies on Retirement Timing of Older Women: Evidence from a Regression Kink Design The Effect of Pension Subsidies on Retirement Timing of Older Women: Evidence from a Regression Kink Design Han Ye University of Mannheim 20th Annual Joint Meeting of the Retirement Research Consortium

More information

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation" Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER June 30, 2011 Abstract This brief note challenges

More information

The Effect of a Longer Working Horizon on Individual and Family Labour Supply

The Effect of a Longer Working Horizon on Individual and Family Labour Supply The Effect of a Longer Working Horizon on Individual and Family Labour Supply Francesca Carta Marta De Philippis Bank of Italy December 1, 2017 Paris, ASME BdF Labour Market Conference Motivation: delaying

More information

The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State

The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State External Papers and Reports Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State Kevin Hollenbeck

More information

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM August 2015 151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H3 Tel: 613-233-8891 Fax: 613-233-8250 csls@csls.ca CENTRE FOR THE STUDY OF LIVING STANDARDS SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING

More information

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Andri Chassamboulli April 15, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the business-cycle behavior of a matching

More information

The Role of Unemployment in the Rise in Alternative Work Arrangements. Lawrence F. Katz and Alan B. Krueger* 1 December 31, 2016

The Role of Unemployment in the Rise in Alternative Work Arrangements. Lawrence F. Katz and Alan B. Krueger* 1 December 31, 2016 The Role of Unemployment in the Rise in Alternative Work Arrangements Lawrence F. Katz and Alan B. Krueger* 1 December 31, 2016 Much evidence indicates that the traditional 9-to-5 employee-employer relationship

More information

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure Christian Dustmann Johannes Ludsteck Uta Schönberg This Version: July 2008 This appendix consists of three parts. Section 1 compares alternative methods

More information

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany

Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany Online Appendix from Bönke, Corneo and Lüthen Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany Contents Appendix I: Data... 2 I.1 Earnings concept... 2 I.2 Imputation of top-coded earnings... 5 I.3 Correction of

More information

Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages. Marco Angrisani University of Southern California

Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages. Marco Angrisani University of Southern California Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages Marco Angrisani University of Southern California Maria Casanova California State University, Fullerton Erik Meijer University of Southern California

More information

To What Extent is Household Spending Reduced as a Result of Unemployment?

To What Extent is Household Spending Reduced as a Result of Unemployment? To What Extent is Household Spending Reduced as a Result of Unemployment? Final Report Employment Insurance Evaluation Evaluation and Data Development Human Resources Development Canada April 2003 SP-ML-017-04-03E

More information

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital Audra Bowlus and Chris Robinson University of Western Ontario Presentation at Craig Riddell s Festschrift UBC, September 2016 Introduction and Motivation

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL* CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL* Caterina Mendicino** Maria Teresa Punzi*** 39 Articles Abstract The idea that aggregate economic activity might be driven in part by confidence and

More information

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018 Economics 210c/236a Fall 2018 Christina Romer David Romer LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing October 10, 2018 Announcements Paper proposals due on Friday (October 12).

More information

The effects of wage subsidies for older workers Wage subsidies to encourage employers to hire older workers are often ineffective

The effects of wage subsidies for older workers Wage subsidies to encourage employers to hire older workers are often ineffective Bernhard Boockmann Institute for Applied Economic Research at the University of Tübingen, and IZA, Germany The effects of wage subsidies for older workers Wage subsidies to encourage employers to hire

More information

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Andreas Fagereng (Statistics Norway) Luigi Guiso (EIEF) Davide Malacrino (Stanford University) Luigi Pistaferri (Stanford University

More information

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model Hui Guo a, Christopher J. Neely b * a College of Business, University of Cincinnati, 48

More information

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy Luděk Niedermayer 1 This paper discusses several empirical aspects of the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy. The introduction

More information

Yannan Hu 1, Frank J. van Lenthe 1, Rasmus Hoffmann 1,2, Karen van Hedel 1,3 and Johan P. Mackenbach 1*

Yannan Hu 1, Frank J. van Lenthe 1, Rasmus Hoffmann 1,2, Karen van Hedel 1,3 and Johan P. Mackenbach 1* Hu et al. BMC Medical Research Methodology (2017) 17:68 DOI 10.1186/s12874-017-0317-5 RESEARCH ARTICLE Open Access Assessing the impact of natural policy experiments on socioeconomic inequalities in health:

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute Lisbon Conference on Structural Reforms, 6 July

More information

How to combine the Entry of Young People in the Labour Market with the Retention of Older Workers Université de Genève, 13 Mars 2014

How to combine the Entry of Young People in the Labour Market with the Retention of Older Workers Université de Genève, 13 Mars 2014 Tito Boeri How to combine the Entry of Young People in the Labour Market with the Retention of Older Workers Université de Genève, 13 Mars 2014 Outline The labor market for the young Young in/old out?

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 9.4.2018 COM(2018) 172 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on Effects of Regulation (EU) 575/2013 and Directive 2013/36/EU on the Economic

More information

Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals *

Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals * Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals * Will Dobbie Benjamin J. Keys Neale Mahoney July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper estimates the impact of a credit report with derogatory marks on financial

More information