A dynamic model of labor supply and fertility with. Ben-Porath human capital accumulation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A dynamic model of labor supply and fertility with. Ben-Porath human capital accumulation"

Transcription

1 A dynamic model of labor supply and fertility with Ben-Porath human capital accumulation Minhee Kim Job Market Paper October 23, 2017 Abstract The aim of this study is to explain two remarkable changes that occurred in the female labor market between the 1970s and the 1990s using a human capital investment model: (1) labor supply of married women has been more compatible with having children and (2) married women have faced higher wage growth rates as a result of higher participation. To this end, this paper constructs a dynamic stochastic labor supply model in which fertility and investment decisions are choice variables. I incorporate the Ben-Porath human capital accumulation into the model to link the expected intermittency caused by having children to women s human capital. Specifically, women who expect to work less during child-rearing ages invest less in their human capital and face lower wages. After calibrating the model to match the 1970s cohort in the PSID data, which has lower participation and lower wages, I examine factors that might contribute to the observed changes over the two decades. From the numerical experiments, the main findings are as follows: (1) the decrease in childcare costs is the sole factor that accounts for the simultaneous increase in the labor participation and fertility rates and (2) the increased returns to experience generate higher wage growth through higher human capital investment. I emphasize the role of investment to shed light on the observed changes by comparing the model with no investment. JEL: J13, J16 and J24 KEYWORDS: Female labor participation, Fertility choice, Ben-Porath human capital, Childcare cost, Returns to experience. Department of Economics, University at Albany, mkim8@albany.edu I would like to be grateful to my advisor, John B. Jones for insightful advice and valuable discussions. Special thanks to Michael Sattinger, Yue Li, Byoung Gun Park and Ibrahim Gunay for helpful comments and discussions. I also thank all participants in Macro workshop at University at Albany in 2016 and

2 1 Introduction Not only does the presence of children have a significant effect on married women s current labor supply, but the career breaks associated with childcare influence their future wages and hence future employment as well. Specifically, mothers leave the labor market around the time of childbirth and gradually return back as their children get older (Figure 1a). Their wage rate is rarely recovered although their participation rate almost approaches to the pre-childbirth rate. This implies that a lower labor force participation (LFP) rate during childbearing and childrearing ages has a persistent effect on their earnings. Accordingly, mothers earn less and have a lower wage growth rate than married women with no kids (Figure 1b). This is known as the motherhood wage penalty, which is empirically estimated to be a 4-7 percent wage loss per child (Waldfogel 1998; Anderson et al. 2002; Budig and England 2001; Gupta and Smith 2002). Adda et al. (2017) estimate that 75% of this motherhood wage penalty arises due to the time spent out of the labor force for childbearing and childrearing. In this paper, I explore how mothers career interruption in their childrearing age reduces their subsequent wage and its growth rate. Mincer and Ofek (1982) provide that less human capital investment before the interruption period and skill depreciation during the interruption cause lower wages for intermittent workers. In particular, mothers have less incentive to invest in human capital if they expect to have career break or career discontinuity for childbearing and childrearing (Mincer and Polachek 1974; Polachek 1975; Polachek 2004). For instance, potential mothers are less likely to attend on-the-job training, take part-time education, or put in an effort to getting promoted at work. The intermittency also depreciates existing human capital and hinders accumulating additional capital, which subsequently reduces the mother s earnings. While empirical studies estimate this wage loss due to work interruption, incorporating investment decision into a model is difficult because it is forward-looking (Light and Ureta 1995; Albrecht et al. 1999; Beblo and Wolf 2002; Spivey 2005; Baum 2002; Buligescu et al. 2009; Adda et al. 2017). However, ignoring this decision cannot fully capture the career interruption effects caused by children. As such, we need to include the investment choice in the model. To this end, I construct a dynamic stochastic discrete choice model of labor supply, fertility and human capital accumulation decisions of married women. This paper makes a contribution to literature by incorporating the Ben-Porath specification to provide a link between 2

3 children and human capital investment (Ben-Porath 1967). Although the Ben-Porath model is dominant in the human capital literature, there are relatively few analyses of the life-cycle labor supply model with the Ben-Porath mechanism (Fan et al. 2013; Manuelli et al. 2012; Erosa et al. 2016). 1 Most of the previous female labor supply studies incorporate the learning-by-doing (LBD) framework in which human capital is accumulated automatically through participation. In the Ben-Porath formulation, however, human capital is generated by explicit investment as well as participation, to some extent. This investment plays a role in capturing the effects of discontinuities in women s careers from raising kids on their wages. To consider two aspects of work interruption costs suggested by Mincer and Ofek (1982), this paper also includes the human capital depreciation when career interruption occurs. The joint model of labor supply and fertility choices allows us to understand how the career decisions of married women interact with their fertility choices. Nonetheless, many of the previous studies treat the female labor participation and fertility decisions separately. Some papers propose a dynamic model of female labor supply by taking fertility decisions as given (Eckstein and Wolpin 1989; Attanasio et al. 2008; Olivetti 2006; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Van der Klaauw 1996; Blundell et al. 2016; Cardia and Gomme 2013; Jones et al. 2003; Doepke et al. 2015). Other authors establish a dynamic model of fertility by taking the labor supply decisions as exogenous (Arroyo and Zhang 1997; Hotz and Miller 1993). 2 Recently, however, a growing literature has analyzed dynamic life-cycle models of joint decisions over labor supply and fertility (Francesconi 2002; Adda et al. 2017; Sheran 2007; Gayle and Miller 2006; Fehr and Ujhelyiova 2013; Erosa et al. 2016). I use the model to explain the observed changes in the female labor market from the 1970s to the 1990s. This model is calibrated by matching to the 1970s cohort using the PSID (Panel Study of Income Dynamics) data. This paper has a two-step calibration strategy similar to Olivetti (2006). First, the wage equations of a wife and a husband are estimated outside the structural model, separately. The husband s earning equation is estimated by a fixed effect model to control for unobserved heterogeneity and the wife s wage equation is estimated by a Heckman two-stage method to control the selection bias. I find a positive selection bias, suggesting that high ability women are more likely to participate. Thus, the average wage falls if more women enter the labor market. In the second step, this paper calibrates the model to 1 Fan et al. (2013) and Manuelli et al. (2012) adopt the Ben-Porath model to explain retirement, and Erosa et al. (2016) find that lower hours worked of women can account for the gender wage gap. 2 Cardia and Gomme (2013) and Van der Klaauw (1996) consider marital decisions together. 3

4 match life-cycle participation, fertility and wages age profiles of the 1970s cohort to those generated by the model. The estimated and calibrated model provides a good fit to the data. The model can replicate lower participation of married women in childbearing and childrearing ages, and a decreasing fertility rate with ages. The calibrated parameters are comparable with the values in previous literature. After calibration, several factors are examined to explain the changes over the two decades. Even though many studies already account for the increase in the labor supply of women in the late twentieth century, this is the first attempt to shed light on the simultaneous increases in labor supply, fertility rates and wages in a dynamic setting. There are two remarkable changes that occurred in the 1990s. First, participation has been more compatible with having children. It has been a general belief that an increase in labor participation leads to the reduction in the probability of having a baby. Doepke et al. (2015) reveal that the reduction in the labor supply of young women induces to the Baby Boom period ( ). 3 In Figure 2, however, the participation rate has risen while the fertility rate slightly increased in the periods of our interests. In Figure 3a and 3b, we can observe the similar phenomena using the cohort base data. The LFP and fertility rates have simultaneously increased for married women aged ,5 Therefore, women were less likely to withdraw from the labor force while they gave birth and raised kids. The negative correlation between the LFP and fertility rates has significantly disappeared. The literature also documents that the fertility rate increased while the LFP rate rose after the early 1980s (Ahn and Mira 2002; Cardia and Gomme 2013). Second, as women worked more, the logarithm of hourly real wage has risen more rapidly with the ages, partly due to an increase in investment, in the 1990s (Figure 4a). The average wage growth rate increased from to over the two decades. The possible determinants include a decreased childcare cost relative to household income, increased returns to experience, a decrease in husbands income and increased education. From the numerical experiments, the key findings are following: (1) the reduction in childcare cost is the sole factor that simultaneously raises the labor participation and fertility rates 3 The wartime increased labor participation of women and it had a persistent effect, because older women had work experiences after the war. They demonstrate that young women left the labor market because of the competition with experienced women hence gave more birth. 4 The 1970s (1980s, 1990s) cohort consists of married women aged in 1972 (1982, 1990). 5 This phenomenon may be due to the delay of having a child in the 1990s, since the model starts at age 25. However, the number of children women ever had from their first child until age 44 increased from to The number of children at age 25 was 1.71 in the 1970s and 1.67 in the 1990s, but that at age 44 was 1.64 in the 1970s and 1.73 in the 1990s. 4

5 and (2) the increased returns to experience account for higher wage growth rates in the 1990s. In the learning-by-doing specification as in Attanasio et al. (2008), the increased returns to experience do not raise wages and wage growth rates. This is due to the selection effect, wherein new entrants to the labor market have lower productivity than existing participants (Attanasio et al. 2008). In the Ben-Porath specification, however, women have more incentive to invest in human capital when they participate more, which generates higher wages and wage growth rates. Thus, the higher wages and growth rates can be explained by the rise of investment, which dominates the selection effect. Furthermore, the results are presented by education status because women may react differently to observed changes depending on their education level. This paper is built as follows: Section 2 reviews the previous female labor supply and fertility literature. I present a life-cycle model in Section 3 and describe the data in Section 4. The calibration and experiments are shown in Section 5 and Section 6. In Section 7, I compare the results between the Ben-Porath specification and the learning-by-doing model. I describe the different behaviors by education in Section 8. The conclusion is provided in Section 9. 2 Previous literature: The increases in labor supply and fertility of married women from the 1970s to the 1990s This section reviews the determinants of labor supply and fertility decisions considered in the previous literature. The increase in labor supply of married women is a noticeable change in the U.S. labor market (Buttet and Schoonbroodt 2013; Goldin and Mitchell 2017). A large and growing number of studies address the question of why women s LFP rate has dramatically increased as in Figure 3a. The leading explanations include an increase in the education of women (Eckstein and Wolpin 1989; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Keane and Wolpin 2009; Francesconi 2002), an increase in their relative wages (Attanasio et al. 2008; Cardia and Gomme 2013; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Van der Klaauw 1996; Jones et al. 2003; Greenwood et al. 2015), increased returns to experience (Attanasio et al. 2008; Olivetti 2006; Buttet and Schoonbroodt 2013) and issues related to the household environment such as the childcare cost (Attanasio et al. 2008; Bick 2016; Sheran 2007; Cardia and Gomme 2013; Connelly 1992; Hardoy and Schøne 2015; Blau and Robins 1989; Powell 2002) or home production changes (Greenwood et al. 2005; Greenwood et al. 2015; Cardia and Gomme 2013; Jones et al. 2003). 5

6 Existing literature also emphasizes the role of an increased divorce rate (Fernández and Wong 2014) and a decreased fertility rate (Fernández and Wong 2014; Buttet and Schoonbroodt 2013). Table 2 provides a summary. Between the 1970s and the 1990s, the ratio of women s hourly income to that of men rose from 0.69 to Also, the college entrance rate of married women increased from 38.85% to 48.44%. Higher educational attainment can be a key driver of higher participation as the rise in college entrance results in increased potential earnings. However, these explanations can affect the LFP of both single and married women, but married women experience the sharp increase in the LFP alone in the late twentieth century (Leibowitz and Klerman 1995; Blau and Kahn 2005; Eckstein et al. 2016). In consequence, issues related to family and children appear more likely to account for the increase in the labor supply of married women than the reasons listed above. Eckstein and Lifshitz (2011) find that approximately 40 percent of the rise in women s labor supply cannot be explained by improved education or wages. The unexplained portion may be due to changes in household environments related to children and husbands. In the decades of interest, the fertility rate of married women has risen (Figure 3b). Some papers emphasize that the decreased participation of married women or improved maternal health causes the post-war baby boom (Doepke et al. 2015; Prados and Albanesi 2014), but there are a few studies that focus on increased fertility rate in the late twentieth century. First, Ahn and Mira (2002) suggest that positive relation between labor supply and fertility after the late 1980 s is largely due to an increase in the use of childcare services. An increase in availability of childcare service can provide incentives to have more kids while women raise their labor force participation. Second, they also provide that the rise of income effect can be another factor for the increase in the fertility rate. However, increased income of a mother may have a negative association with fertility rate because of higher opportunity costs of having a kid (Gayle and Miller 2006; Balbo et al. 2013). Improved educational attainment which results in higher earnings will lead to a reduction in the birth rate (Francesconi 2002; Caucutt et al. 2002). On the other hand, an association between other household income and having a child is ambiguous (Gayle and Miller 2006). While the positive relation arises if a child is a normal good (Hotz and Miller 1988), higher income can reduce the birth rate if parents consider the quality of children. Recent studies show that high income parents can choose to invest more in their existing children instead of having more children, a quality-quantity trade-off. (Balbo et al. 2013; Jones et al. 2008). Third, Bouvier (1991) provides that an increase in immigration 6

7 and an increasing proportion of high fertility groups such as Asian and Hispanic contribute to the rise of the fertility rates. 3 Model 3.1 Model set-up This section formulates a dynamic stochastic discrete choice model of labor supply and fertility decisions for married women. The model is built on Eckstein and Wolpin (1989), Eckstein and Lifshitz (2011) and Francesconi (2002). 6 The model begins at age 25 and decisions are taken at an annual basis. At the start of the model (age 25), marital status and education are predetermined. That is, all women have husbands and their education status is either less than a college education or a college education. I restrict for married women because they can more freely leave the labor market for children as a second earner. The wife is the sole decision maker in the household. In each period between age 25 to 59 (t), one maximizes the present value of her lifetime utility by choosing whether to work, whether to give birth, her human capital investment and consumption. Since extensive margin is a main change in the data, I focus on participation decisions (Attanasio et al. 2008). While several previous papers suppose that women imperfectly control their fertility (Hotz and Miller 1988; Sheran 2007; Erosa et al. 2016), I assume that women can give birth in the same period that they decide to. The model incorporates two dynamic considerations: children and human capital accumulation. The number of children evolves according to N t = N t 1 + n t (1) where N t is the total number of children at period t and n t is equal to one if a woman has a additional child at t. She can have 0, 1, 2 or 3 children, and N t = 3 is an absorbing state. At the beginning of every period, married women observe their realization of the shocks. And then, they take decisions by maximizing: max V t = E[St=td T t t 1 U(P t, c t, n t, N t 1, h t 1, v t )] (2) {P t,c t,i t,n t } t 6 Their models are discrete choice models, but Eckstein and Lifshitz (2011) only consider labor supply decision, while Francesconi (2002) and Eckstein and Wolpin (1989) consider the labor supply and fertility decisions together. 7

8 where d 1 is a discount factor and E is the expectation operator given information at t. P t indicates whether the woman works, c t is consumption, n t is an indicator whether she gives birth and i t is the human capital investment level. h t v t is a preference shock. 1 is accumulated human capital at period t-1. The consumption is divided evenly between spouses in each period because this is a unitary household. The household budget constraint is given by: y w t P t + y h t = c t + g(n t 2, n t 1, n t, P t ) (3) where y w t is the wife s earnings and yt h is the husband s earnings. g(n t 2, n t 1, n t, P t ) is a childcare cost function. It depends on the number of children at t-2 (N t 2 ), whether there are newborn children at t-1 and t (n t 1 and n t ) and the mother s current work status (P t ), according to g(n t 2, n t 1, n t, P t )=(f 0 + f 1 P t )N t 2 +(f 10 + f 11 P t )n t 1 +(f 20 + f 21 P t )n t. (4) The parameters f 0, f 10 and f 20 are costs incurred per child regardless of whether the mother works or not. Mothers spend additional costs to purchase the paid child care services when they work (f 1 > 0, f 11 > 0, f 21 > 0). The cost also depends on the children s ages. The literature finds that small children generate higher childcare expenditures (Ribar 1995; Gayle and Miller 2006). However, instead I suppose the costs of having an infant (n t ) or a toddler (n t 1 ) differ from those of older children because this model does not include the children s ages. The toddler and the infant spend higher childcare expenditure (f 0 < f 10 < f 20, f 0 < f 10 < f 20 ). The budget constraint implies that there is neither saving nor borrowing. That is, households spend all their net income in each period. Although the assumption is extreme, it is standard in the previous studies on female labor supply, for tractability (Eckstein and Wolpin 1989; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Van der Klaauw 1996; Francesconi 2002; Sheran 2007; Keane and Wolpin 2009; Yamaguchi 2016). The saving decision is excluded because incorporating decisions related to children makes female labor supply models more complicated (Yamaguchi 2016). I discuss about the saving assumption more in Section 3.4. According to Eckstein and Wolpin (1989) and Francesconi (2002), if the utility function is linear and additive in consumption, the life-time utility maximization problem is equivalent to a life-time wealth optimization problem modified by the non-monetary value of work and children. 8

9 The flow utility function is given by: U t = (a 1 + v t )P t + c t + a 2 P t c t + a 3 P t h t 1 + a 41 N t + a 42 N 2 t + a 5c t n t + a 6 n t t. (5) The first four parts of the function describe the utility related to women s current work. The cost of working depends on household earnings (a 2 < 0) and their previous human capital (a 3 < 0). The model also allows the number of children including the current birth to affect the utility (a 41 > 0, a 42 < 0), but this is not depending on women s participation. A value of a 5 can produce a relationship between consumption and giving birth. Also, the disutility of giving birth increases with the mother s age (a 6 < 0). In the model, women can have birth until age 59, but a negative value of a 6 discourages them from giving birth when they get old. An old woman gives little birth without the restriction of the birth periods to certain ages. All women have working husbands. This is not an abnormal assumption because the PSID data show that 96% of married men worked in the 1970s and the 1990s. 7 The husband s income equation is: ln(yt h )=g 0 + g 1 edu + g 2 t + g 3 edu t + g 4 t 2 + e 1t. (6) The husband s earnings equation consists of wife s characteristics because of the positive correlation of age and education in the marriage market which is known as assortative mating, and the temporary component. Since the fraction of couples with the same education is 74.1% (Table 3), the wife s age and education can be proxy variables for husband s age and education as in Van der Klaauw (1996) and Sheran (2007). Furthermore, the husband s income increases with the spouse s age, but grows at a different rate depending on the wife s education. Altuğ and Miller (1998) find that the coefficient on an interaction term between age and education is positive, implying that the education effect increases with age. Due to assortative mating, a similar relationship appears with the wife s age and education in the husbands earnings. Figure 5 shows that the income of husbands married to more educated women increases more rapidly with age than that of husbands of less-than-college-educated women, in both the 1970s and the 1990s. Women s earnings depend on the current human capital (h t ), human capital investment (i t ), education (edu) and her earning shock (e 2t ). In each period, women make investments in their future human capital following the Ben-Porath model if they work. Higher investment 7 The ratio is 95% in Van der Klaauw (1996) 9

10 rates, however, lead to lower current earned income. Thus, women who plan to work less in the future may choose lower investments. The wife s earnings are given by: ln(y w t )=b 0 +(1 i t )R t h t + b 3 edu + e 2t (7) where R t is a human capital rental rate that for simplicity is normalized to 1. The parameter b 3 captures returns to education, and schooling raises the earnings (b 3 > 0). e it, i = 1, 2 is the standard zero-mean, finite variance, serially independent error. This paper also assumes that the husband s income shock (e 1t ) is positively correlated with the wife s earning shock (e 2t ) as Attanasio et al. (2008). 3.2 Human capital accumulation One of the key features in this model is the human capital accumulation process. In learningby-doing model, the current labor participation augments human capital, and hence has impacts on future wages and future labor supply decisions (Eckstein and Wolpin 1989; Attanasio et al. 2008; Olivetti 2006). The presence of a child can affect human capital accumulation through non-participation. In the Ben-Porath model, however, individuals accumulate their human capital not only through labor participation but also through explicit investment. This specification can have an additional consideration for children in that women who plan to have discontinuities in their careers during child-rearing ages choose lower investment, which translates into lower wages (Mincer and Polachek 1974; Polachek 1975; Polachek 2004). This investment is defined as training at work. There are two types of human capital investment: formal education and training at work. While education is enhancing general skills, training is developing a specific skill. Also, training requires some portion of time (Song and Jones 2007). Therefore, lower investment for women implies that they have less efforts to enhance specific skills due to their lower expectation over future careers. Once women work, they spend a fraction of time, i t, investing in human capital and spend the rest of it, 1 i t at pure work. I specify the human capital production function as in Heckman et al. (1998): h t =(1 d 2 )h t 1 + b 1 i b i t where d 2 is the depreciation rate and P t 1 hb h t 1 + b 2(1 P t 1 ) (8) 1 represents the previous participation decision. The parameter b 1 reflects the ability to learn, because it measures the extent to which human capital 10

11 investment contributes to future earnings (Heckman et al. 1998). This paper has a further consideration on the depreciation related to non-participation. The parameter b 2 measures the depreciation in human capital associated with previous nonparticipation (b 2 < 0). The learning-by-doing effect is captured through P t 1. If married women did not work at t-1, the investment is equal to zero, i t 1 = 0, and human capital is h t =(1 d 2 )h t 1 + b 2. I assume that the exponent b i lies between 0 and 1, so that all working women invest at least some portion of their earnings. The parameters d 2 and b 2 both reflect human capital depreciations but they work differently in the model. The parameter d 2 represents general human capital depreciation incurred regardless of whether one works or not. However, the parameter b 2 reflects a cost of work interruption due to specific skill obsolescence. Inserting into the earnings function in equation (7) yields: ln(y w t )=b 0 +(1 i t )((1 d 2 )h t 1 + b 1 i b i t 1 hb h t 1 + b 2(1 P t 1 )) + b 3 edu + e 2t. (9) This model does not explicitly include experience. However, since work experience facilitates human capital accrual, the returns to experience (RTE) can be defined as the change in current earnings due to a change in lagged human capital: RTE t ln(yw t ) h t 1 =(1 i t )[(1 d 2 )+b 1 b h i b i t 1 hb h 1 t 1 ]. (10) The returns to experience are endogenously determined. Married women who made higher human capital investments in the previous period (i t 1 ) have higher current returns to experience at any value of the current investment (i t ). However, higher current investment (i t ) reduces not only the current wages but also the returns to experience. The returns to experience fall in human capital (h t 1 ) because the wage function is concave in that variable ( RTE t h t 1 < 0). 3.3 Solving the model The dynamic programming solution to the optimization problem is obtained by a process of backward recursion from the age of the last period. At each age, the value function and optimal decision rules are solved given the current state vector and the value function for the next period. The state vector is defined as: W t = {h t, N t 2, n t 1, edu, e 1t, e 2t, v t }. (11) 11

12 V t (W t ) is the value function, defined recursively as V t (W t )= max P t,c t,i t,n t U t ( )+d 1 E[V t+1 (W t+1 W t )]. (12) The solution to the problem is obtained from two stages. In the first stage, each individual maximizes her value by choosing human capital investment levels when they work. A nonworking woman does not invest in human capital. V t (W t )=max i t U t ( )+d 1 E[V t+1 (W t+1 W t, P t = 1, n t )]. (13) In the second step, given the optimal human capital investment, they choose the participationbirth alternative that yields the highest value: V t (W t )=max[v 11 t ( ), V 10 t ( ), V 01 t ( ), V 00 t ( )] (14) V 11 t (W t )=max U 11 t ( )+d 1 E[V t+1 (W t+1 W t, P t = 1, n t = 1)] (15) V 10 t (W t )=max U 10 t ( )+d 1 E[V t+1 (W t+1 W t, P t = 1, n t = 0)] (16) V 01 t (W t )=max U 01 t ( )+d 1 E[V t+1 (W t+1 W t, P t = 0, n t = 1)] (17) V 00 t (W t )=max U 00 t ( )+d 1 E[V t+1 (W t+1 W t, P t = 0, n t = 0)] (18) t ( ) represents the value when a woman chooses to both work and give birth. V 10 ( ) is the V 11 value when she chooses to work, but not to give birth. Vt 01 ( ) is the value when she chooses not to work, but to give birth. Vt 00 ( ) is the value for no work and no birth. All alternatives are mutually exclusive. Existing studies solve the model by assuming that the value function after the terminal period is zero, V T+1 = 0 (Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Francesconi 2002). However, if women consider their consumption after the retirement, the value after the last period can be positive and they may be more willing to work more in their later ages. Thus, this paper supposes that the terminal value function is V T+1 = z ln y w T+1. The solution method is presented in Appendix A.1. t 12

13 3.4 Risk neutral and no savings assumption In the model, women do not have incentives to insure against the future uncertainty with the assumption of a linear utility function in consumption. Although this is the standard setting in the female labor supply literature, I need to discuss how participation decision would change if the saving decision is added to the model. Including the ability to save still does not change women s decisions if utility is still linear. On the other hand, if the model includes the assumption of risk aversion and no ability to save, women work more in their younger ages for future uncertainty because the participation is the only device for consumption smoothing. Including savings with the risk aversion also can raise the participation, but the magnitude of the increase is less than the model without savings because savings can be another device to smooth consumption. However, it appears that including these assumptions has little effect on participation decisions and hence human capital accumulation of married women during the child-rearing periods. According to Attanasio et al. (2005), women do not increase participation to smooth consumption during the child-rearing periods, until age 35, due to childcare costs. They also find that women do not save during this period even though the model allows the ability to save. This supports that including the assumptions of savings and risk aversion has little effect on the participation decision. 4 Data This paper utilizes two cohorts of married women from the PSID (Panel Study of Income Dynamics) data. The data construction is described in Appendix A.2. First, the 1970s cohort consists of married women aged in 1972 (born between 1945 and 1949). I track this cohort for 37 years, until They spent their child-rearing periods in the 1970s. The baseline model is fit to the life-cycle age profiles of this cohort. This paper also tracks the 1990s cohort, consisting of married women aged in 1990 (born between 1963 and 1967). 8 These women were in their late twenties and early thirties in the 1990s. I track this cohort for 21 years, until The 1970s cohort includes women aged 25-59, but the 1990s cohort includes women aged because the oldest age of the 1990s cohort in 2011 is 48. These two cohorts are used to explore the changes in the LFP, fertility rate and wage profiles between the 1970s and the 1990s. 8 I also generate the 1970s cohorts and the 1990s cohorts by changing the base year. The results maintain the facts that the LFP and fertility rates increase together between two cohorts. 13

14 Figure 10 shows the timeline for the two cohorts. Table 5 reports the sample statistics of 1970s cohort and 1990s cohort by 10-year age groups. Furthermore, continuously married women have different behaviors from married women who maintained their marriage life for short periods. If women have higher probability of getting divorced, they might work more and accumulate human capital more. Previous studies find that higher divorce rates can raise the LFP rate of married women (Fernández and Wong 2014). Thus, the final sample consists of women who were married at least ten years during the sample periods. I do not restrict the age of getting married. The LFP rate is defined as the fraction of women who work at least 100 hours per year as in Attanasio et al. (2008). The fertility rate is defined as the fraction of married women who have a newborn baby at age t. Real values are calculated using the CPI (the base year 1982) from the BLS web site. 9 5 Calibration 5.1 Calibration strategy In Table 9, I report the set of external, calibrated and estimated parameters for the baseline economy. A two-step strategy is similar to Olivetti (2006). First, I take some of the external parameters from the existing literature and estimate some using the PSID (d 1, d 2, b c 0, bl 0, bc 2, b l 2, b i, b h, s e1, s e2, r e1e2, g 0, g 1, g 2, g 3, g 4 ). The parameters of the husband s and wife s income equations are estimated using the fixed effects model for unobserved heterogeneity and the Heckman two-stage method for selection bias, separately. In the second step, I follow the calibration procedure as in Buttet and Schoonbroodt (2013). Thus, the remaining parameters in the utility function and childcare cost function, (a 1, a 2, a 3, a 41, a 42, a 5, a 6, b c 1, bl 1, f 0, f 1, f 10, f 11,f 20, f 21, z), are calibrated to the 1970s cohort of the PSID by matching the following moments (see Table 10): (1) the average labor force participation rates of married women at all ages combined and by 5-year age groups (8 moments), (2) the average fertility rates of married women at all ages combined and by 5-year age groups (8 moments), (3) women s wages at all ages combined and by 5-year age groups (8 moments),

15 (4) the gender wage gap at all ages combined (1 moment), (5) the average labor force participation rates by education (2 moments), (6) the ratio of childcare costs to household income (1 moment), (7) the ratio of childcare costs to household income for newborn mothers (1 moment). The system is over-identified because the 16 parameters are calibrated by matching 29 moments. To fit the data, I minimize the sum of squared errors (SSE) between the moments simulated by the model and the moments from the data as in Buttet and Schoonbroodt (2013). Let q be a vector of parameters, m a j be the 29 1 vector of moments from the actual data and m s j (q) be the 29 1 vector of simulated moments. W is the weighting matrix, equals to the variance on the diagonal and zero otherwise. I minimize the objective function with respect to q. 10 The objective function is [m a j m s j (q)]0 W[m a j m s j (q)]. (19) Table 9 summarizes the parameter values used in the baseline economy External parameters Some parameters (d 1, d 2, s e1, s e2, r e1e2, b i, b h ) are taken from the previous literature. First, I suppose that the discount factor, d 1 equals This value is consistent with other studies, which set their discount factors between 0.8 and 0.96 (Attanasio et al. 2008; Sheran 2007; Adda et al. 2017; Francesconi 2002). Second, the depreciation rate, d 2 is set to following Blandin (2015). This represents general human capital depreciation due to the skill obsolescence or aging that is independent of the work decision. There is no consensus on the magnitude of this depreciation rate. Some papers assume that no human capital depreciation occurs when individuals work (Attanasio et al. 2008; Sheran 2007; Heckman et al. 1998), but others report that the value is between and (Huggett et al. 2006; Blandin 2015; Polachek et al. 2015; Prados and Albanesi 2014). I also assume that the standard deviations of both the wife s and husband s income shocks are 0.13 and the correlation between two shocks is 0.25, as in Attanasio et al. (2008). The parameters b i and b h are set to 0.85 and I follow the neutrality assumption b i = b h from the Ben-Porath (1967) s original specification for a tractable reason. According to Heckman et al. (1998), the conditions 0<b i <1 and 0appleb h apple1 guarantee a concave human capital 10 I use the Simplex method to find the parameters. 15

16 function. They estimate b i = b h to be and 0.871, by education level. Blandin (2015) also sets both parameters to 0.7 which is the average value of the previous literature. The magnitudes of these values are in the range of the values in the existing studies, (Heckman et al. 1998; Blandin 2015; Huggett et al. 2006) Estimated parameters I estimate the husband s and wife s wage equations separately. 11 The parameters of these equations are estimated outside the structural model to reduce the computational burden of dynamic programming. The husband s hourly wage is expressed as a function of the wife s age, age squared, education and the interaction between age and education (Equation 6). The coefficients using the fixed effects model to control the unobserved heterogeneity are presented in Table 6. For the 1970s cohort, the estimates of the returns to wife s education (g 1 ) and the coefficient of the wife s age (g 2 ) are estimated to 8.91% and 1.05%, respectively. For the 1990s cohort, these values are 17.7% and 5.84%, implying that husband s skill premium has risen due to the assortative matching. The positive interaction term (g 3 > 0) finds that husbands who marry college graduates have higher wage growth rates, consistent with Figure 5. From those estimated results, the parameters g 0, g 1, g 2, g 3 and g 4 are set to 2.150, , , and , separately. In this paper, I use the Heckman two-steps model to control the selectivity bias in women s wage equation (Heckman 1979). The exclusion restrictions which affect the participation, but do not enter the wage equation are the number of children, the age of the youngest child and spouse s income. Table 7 shows the estimated coefficients for the wife s wage equation by education for the 1970s and the 1990s. The results reveal that return to a college education is 42.2% and return to an experience is 7.93%. The parameters b l 2 and bc 2 reflect wage losses from career interruptions. Previous estimates of the negative effect of work interruptions on wages vary significantly from 3.3% to 33.0% depending on measures and data (Mincer and Ofek 1982; Light and Ureta 1995; Albrecht et al. 1999; Beblo and Wolf 2002; Spivey 2005; Baum 2002; Jacobsen and Levin 1995). 12 A career interruption indicator equals to one if women participate less than 1,500 hours a year following Olivetti (2006). In the 1970s and the 1990s, 39% and 29% of married women have career interruptions, separately. The estimates show that a career 11 I include 2 years more in the sample, because the cohort sample is small. 12 Mincer and Ofek (1982) estimate it 3.3%-7.6%. The effect in Spivey (2005) is 12-15%, whereas Light and Ureta (1995) find an effect of 23%. 16

17 interruption of one year reduces subsequent wages by 14.7% for college educated women and 9.2% for less than college educated women. From the estimated results, the parameters, b c 2 and b l 2, are set to and Also, the positive coefficients (l) on the Heckman correction term in the 1970s and the 1990s sample suggest that high ability women are more likely to participate. This provides that the average wage may fall if more women enter the labor market. This paper supposes that individuals with different educational attainment have different learning abilities (b c 1 and bl 1 ) and depreciation rates (bc 2 and bl 2 ). Both parameters increase in education as results in Polachek et al. (2015) and Buttet and Schoonbroodt (2013). The estimated results also reveal that women with college education have higher costs for work interruptions (see Table 7). Furthermore, I suppose that two educated groups have different constant terms (b c 0 and bl 0 ), which are like TFP. In this case, the value of b 3 is given by the difference in constant terms between two education groups, b c 0 b l 0. bc 0 and bl 0 are set to and Calibrated parameters I report the calibrated parameters in Table 9. The first panel of Table 9 presents the calibrated values of the utility function (see also equation (5)). Previous estimated results provide guidance on these parameters (Francesconi 2002; Van der Klaauw 1996; Eckstein and Wolpin 1989; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Sheran 2007): First, the parameter a 1, which reflects the disutility of labor participation, is set to Previous studies also estimate a negative value (Eckstein and Wolpin 1989; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011; Francesconi 2002; Van der Klaauw 1996). Second, the sign of the interaction between consumption and labor supply has varied in previous studies. While Attanasio et al. (2008) suggest a positive value, Francesconi (2002) and Eckstein and Lifshitz (2011) estimate a negative one. I suggest that the value of consumption falls with participation (a 2 =-0.337), implying that consumption and employment (leisure) are substitutes (complements). Thus, the marginal utility of consumption, 1 + a 2 P t + a 5, is lower when working than when not working. Likewise, the marginal disutility of work is higher when consumption is higher. This also implies that wives with higher earning spouses are less likely to participate. The parameter a 3 represents the utility of work related to previous human capital. If a 3 is negative, the disutility of labor participation increases with total human capital (Francesconi 2002; Eckstein and Lifshitz 2011). If it is positive, there is habit persistence in working (Sheran 17

18 2007). However, there is little theoretical evidence about the value of this parameter (Francesconi 2002). In this baseline economy, a 3 is set to so that higher human capital increases the disutility from work, perhaps because higher wages increase the value of non-participation. In this model, the past human capital has two effects: it reduces the current utility through a 3, but increases the current wages. Eckstein and Wolpin (1989) argue that because women have increased their experience, the increased wage effect must dominate the decrease in utility effect. Also, flow utility increases with the number of children (a 41 = 0.146), but at a decreasing rate (a 42 = ). The parameter a 5 is negative, -0.02, so the value of consumption falls with a birth, which is similar in magnitude to Francesconi (2002). The negative value of a 6 ( ) reflects that mothers utility from newborn babies falls with their age because of their physical limitations. In the wife s earning equation, the parameter b 1 is set to and for college graduates and less than college educated women, respectively. Furthermore, six parameters of the childcare cost function are calibrated (f 0, f 1, f 10, f 11, f 20, f 21 ). The parameters f 0, f 10 and f 20 reflect necessary childcare costs for all mothers. However, the parameters, f 1, f 11 and f 21 are additional childcare costs incurred when working and using paid care. Their values are provided in Table Baseline life-cycle profiles Using the parameters in Table 9, I generate life-cycle profiles for the labor force participation rate, fertility rate, wages and human capital investment. The matched statistics overall and by age groups are shown in Table 10. The statistics use the weights across ages in the 1970s cohort in Table 4. The fit between observed data and moments is good because the minimum distance for the quadratic form is As shown in Figure 7, the predicted employment profiles well approximate the data profiles of the 1970s cohort. The overall labor force participation rate from the data is 70.6%, and the statistic from the model is 70.3%. The average LFP rate, fertility rate and wage rate are constructed using the distribution of ages in the PSID (see Table 4). As in the data, the model predicts that the LFP rate of college educated women is higher than that of married women without college education. The model also precisely replicates lower participation of women during the childbearing and rearing periods. The average fertility rate is equal to 8.6% from the data, and 8.8% from the model. The fertility rate also decreases with age, as in the data. After age 40, few women give birth. 18

19 The log hourly wage of married women is from data and from the model. The predicted wage profile decreases after age 50 due to lower investment and depreciation rate than the wage profile in the pooled data. However, this is consistent with the wage profile after controlling fixed effects even though I match the pooled data. This implies that women with higher earnings more remain in the labor market in their later ages. Furthermore, the relative wage (married women/married men) from the data is 69.0%, and from the model is 72.1%. The standard deviation in earnings in the baseline economy is The average childcare cost to household income is also a target in the model. The data show that the ratio of childcare cost to household income is 17.3% for the 1970s cohort, the cost ratio for newborn mothers is 20.1%. In the model, the childcare cost share equals 17.2% and 20.9%, separately. The distribution for education in the model is exogenous, and sets to that in the data, which show that 38.85% of married women entered college in the 1970s. The model generates life-cycle human capital investment profiles of married women. Human capital is accumulated through time investment. According to Ben-Porath (1967), individuals invest substantially when they are young and monotonically reduce investment as they age and their remaining work lives shorten. In Figure 8a, the investment falls with ages and women make the minimum investment at their later ages. Furthermore, mothers have lower investment than the averaged married women due to their lower participation, 46.9%. Thus, they have less incentive to invest in human capital, which is consistent with Mincer and Polachek (1974) and Polachek (1975). Women with smaller expectation over future participation have lower investment even while at work because they understand that their returns depend on how much they work in the future. A feature of the Ben-Porath model is a difference between observed wages and human capital due to investment in equation (7), suggested by Heckman et al. (1998). This generates a different gap in human capital and observed wage between mothers and non-mothers. Figure 8b shows the gap in human capital and wages between mothers and non-mothers from a simulated profile. Mothers do not invest as much as non-mothers during child-rearing periods. At younger ages, the wage gap between the two groups is less than the human capital difference because of lower investment of mothers. Mothers devote their time at work more to the current earnings rather than human capital accumulation, at any level of existing human capital. This implies that the observed wage difference between two groups, which is the wage penalty of motherhood, does not fully capture the human capital gap. Furthermore, the human capi- 19

20 tal gap and wage gap rise together because lower investment of mothers accumulates human capital less than non-mothers. 6 Numerical experiments In this section, I examine several factors that may play a key role in explaining the changing behaviors of married women between the 1970s and the 1990s cohorts, to assess their effects on labor supply, fertility and wages: (1) childcare costs, (2) the returns to investment, (3) husbands earnings and (4) college entrance rates. They are factors that mainly considered to shed light on the increased participation in the previous literature. Figure 9a-9f reveal the simulated life cycle profiles of the average wages of married women from the above experiments. However, the change in average wages depend on the change in the composition of married women. If fewer (more) capable workers enter the labor market due to the changes in experimental factors, average wages decrease (increase), although the wages of existing participants may be constant or higher. Therefore, this paper separately presents the wages of participants who were already in the labor market prior to the experiments (the dotted lines shown in Figure 9a-9f). Furthermore, Table 11 presents LFP rates, wages and fertility rates both overall and for each education group because college educated married women may respond differently to the experiments from the less than college educated women. 6.1 Decrease in childcare costs Evidence on how childcare costs have changed A decrease in childcare costs can be a key determinant of the increase in the labor participation and fertility of married women (Attanasio et al. 2008; Bick 2016; Sheran 2007; Cardia and Gomme 2013; Connelly 1992; Hardoy and Schøne 2015; Blau and Robins 1989; Powell 2002; Buttet and Schoonbroodt 2013). As the primary caregivers, mothers have an incentive to work more if they can purchase child care services at cheaper prices, and the lower costs of children also stimulate potential mothers to have more kids. However, there is little systematic evidence on the changes in childcare costs between the 1970s to the 1990s in the data. The datasets such as the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) and the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) provide information since the 1980s. The PSID data include cost 20

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard Blundell, Monica Costa-Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw June 2014 Key question How do in-work benefits and the welfare system affect

More information

Anatomy of Welfare Reform:

Anatomy of Welfare Reform: Anatomy of Welfare Reform: Announcement and Implementation Effects Richard Blundell, Marco Francesconi, Wilbert van der Klaauw UCL and IFS Essex New York Fed 27 January 2010 UC Berkeley Blundell/Francesconi/van

More information

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan Hwei-Lin Chuang* Professor Department of Economics National Tsing Hua University Hsin Chu, Taiwan 300 Tel: 886-3-5742892

More information

The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation

The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation Richard Blundell, Mike Brewer, Monica Costa Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw Preliminary comments welcome Institute

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard Blundell, Monica Costa-Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw October 2013 Motivation Issues to be addressed: 1 How should labour supply, work

More information

Minhee Kim. Labor economics, Empirical macroeconomics, Econometrics

Minhee Kim. Labor economics, Empirical macroeconomics, Econometrics Minhee Kim 1400 Washington Avenue, Albany, NY 12222 Email: mkim8@albany.edu Phone: (518)512-1408 Citizenship: South Korea (on F-1 Visa) https://sites.google.com/site/mhkim0904/ EDUCATION Ph.D., Economics,,

More information

Family and Work. 1. Labor force participation of married women

Family and Work. 1. Labor force participation of married women Family and Work 1. Labor force participation of married women - why has it increased so much since WW II? - how is increased market work related to changes in the gender wage gap? 2. Is there a time crunch?

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department Special Report on the Longitudinal Survey of Newborns in the 21st Century and the Longitudinal Survey of Adults in the 21st Century: Ten-Year Follow-up, 2001 2011 Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare

More information

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY AUXILIARY SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS ON THE HOUSEHOLD RETIREMENT DECISION

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY AUXILIARY SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS ON THE HOUSEHOLD RETIREMENT DECISION THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY AUXILIARY SPOUSE AND SURVIVOR BENEFITS ON THE HOUSEHOLD RETIREMENT DECISION DAVID M. K. KNAPP DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN AUGUST 7, 2014 KNAPP (2014) 1/12

More information

Fertility and Female Employment: ADifferent View of the Last 50 Years

Fertility and Female Employment: ADifferent View of the Last 50 Years Fertility and Female Employment: ADifferent View of the Last 50 Years Sebastien Buttet and Alice Schoonbroodt August 5, 2005 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract Over the period from 1964 to 2003, married

More information

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital Audra Bowlus and Chris Robinson University of Western Ontario Presentation at Craig Riddell s Festschrift UBC, September 2016 Introduction and Motivation

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform (NBER Working Paper, also on my webp) Richard Blundell, Monica Costa-Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw Institute for Fiscal Studies and University

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY. Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY. Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang Working Paper 22817 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22817 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 2 issue brief 2 the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course John Havens introduction For the past decade, significant attention has been paid to the aging of the U.S. population.

More information

Female Labour Market Outcomes and the impact of Maternity Leave Policies

Female Labour Market Outcomes and the impact of Maternity Leave Policies Female Labour Market Outcomes and the impact of Maternity Leave Policies Hamish Low University of Cambridge and IFS Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria May 2015 Abstract This paper shows how

More information

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018 Summary of Keister & Moller 2000 This review summarized wealth inequality in the form of net worth. Authors examined empirical evidence of wealth accumulation and distribution, presented estimates of trends

More information

The Effect of Public Pensions on Women s Labor Market Participation over a Full Life-Cycle

The Effect of Public Pensions on Women s Labor Market Participation over a Full Life-Cycle The Effect of Public Pensions on Women s Labor Market Participation over a Full Life-Cycle Virginia Sánchez-Marcos and Carlos Bethencourt Universidad de Cantabria and Universidad de La Laguna December

More information

Núria Rodríguez-Planas, City University of New York, Queens College, and IZA (with Daniel Fernández Kranz, IE Business School)

Núria Rodríguez-Planas, City University of New York, Queens College, and IZA (with Daniel Fernández Kranz, IE Business School) Núria Rodríguez-Planas, City University of New York, Queens College, and IZA (with Daniel Fernández Kranz, IE Business School) Aim at protecting and granting rights to working mothers (fathers) However,

More information

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 J.R.Walker March 20, 2012 Suppose that births are biological feasible in the first two periods of a family s life cycle, but

More information

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $ CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $ Joyce Jacobsen a, Melanie Khamis b and Mutlu Yuksel c a Wesleyan University b Wesleyan

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CHANGES IN THE LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR OF MARRIED WOMEN: Francine D. Blau Lawrence M. Kahn

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CHANGES IN THE LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR OF MARRIED WOMEN: Francine D. Blau Lawrence M. Kahn NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CHANGES IN THE LABOR SUPPLY BEHAVIOR OF MARRIED WOMEN: 1980-2000 Francine D. Blau Lawrence M. Kahn Working Paper 11230 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11230 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

What accounts for the increase in female labor force participation in Spain

What accounts for the increase in female labor force participation in Spain Discussion Paper No. 2018-6 January 18, 2018 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2018-6 Please cite the corresponding Journal Article at http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2018-16

More information

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth Shelly J. Lundberg University of Washington and Jennifer Ward-Batts University of Michigan Prepared for presentation at the Second Annual

More information

Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor

Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor Household Labor Supply in a Heterogeneous-Agents Model with Tradable Home Labor Christian Bredemeier Falko Juessen First Version: January 2009 This Version: December 2009 Abstract This paper investigates

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics Lecture Notes for MSc Public Finance (EC426): Lent 2013 AGENDA Efficiency cost

More information

in the Life Cycle Decisions of Black, Hispanic and White Women Michael P. Keane Yale University and Kenneth I. Wolpin University of Pennsylvania

in the Life Cycle Decisions of Black, Hispanic and White Women Michael P. Keane Yale University and Kenneth I. Wolpin University of Pennsylvania The Role of Labor and Marriage Markets, Preference Heterogeneity and the Welfare System in the Life Cycle Decisions of Black, Hispanic and White Women by Michael P. Keane Yale University and Kenneth I.

More information

The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility

The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility The Role of Fertility in Business Cycle Volatility Sarada Duke University Oana Tocoian Claremont McKenna College Oct 2013 - Preliminary, do not cite Abstract We investigate the two-directional relationship

More information

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 2-2013 Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Bureau of Labor Statistics Follow this and additional works at:

More information

Assessing the Impact of the Maternity Capital Policy in Russia Using a Dynamic Stochastic Model of Fertility and Employment

Assessing the Impact of the Maternity Capital Policy in Russia Using a Dynamic Stochastic Model of Fertility and Employment Assessing the Impact of the Maternity Capital Policy in Russia Using a Dynamic Stochastic Model of Fertility and Employment Fabián Slonimczyk Anna Yurko September 30, 2012 Abstract With declining population

More information

The Role of Labor and Marriage Markets, Preference Heterogeneity and the Welfare System in the Life Cycle Decisions of Black, Hispanic and White Women

The Role of Labor and Marriage Markets, Preference Heterogeneity and the Welfare System in the Life Cycle Decisions of Black, Hispanic and White Women The Role of Labor and Marriage Markets, Preference Heterogeneity and the Welfare System in the Life Cycle Decisions of Black, Hispanic and White Women by Michael P. Keane ARC Federation Fellow, University

More information

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Upjohn Institute Policy Papers Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Leslie A. Muller Hope College

More information

Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States

Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States C L M. E C O N O M Í A Nº 17 MUJER Y ECONOMÍA Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States Joseph S. Falzone Peirce College Philadelphia, Pennsylvania

More information

How Economic Security Changes during Retirement

How Economic Security Changes during Retirement How Economic Security Changes during Retirement Barbara A. Butrica March 2007 The Retirement Project Discussion Paper 07-02 How Economic Security Changes during Retirement Barbara A. Butrica March 2007

More information

Does the Earned Income Tax Credit Help Single Women Climb the Wage Ladder?

Does the Earned Income Tax Credit Help Single Women Climb the Wage Ladder? Does the Earned Income Tax Credit Help Single Women Climb the Wage Ladder? Gizem Koşar Federal Reserve Bank of New York October 20, 2015 Abstract: In order to understand the impact of the EITC on life-cycle

More information

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES? June 2013, Number 13-10 RETIREMENT RESEARCH HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES? By April Yanyuan Wu, Nadia S. Karamcheva, Alicia H. Munnell, and Patrick Purcell* Introduction

More information

Female Labour Market Outcomes and Parental Leave Policies

Female Labour Market Outcomes and Parental Leave Policies Female Labour Market Outcomes and Parental Leave Policies Hamish Low University of Cambridge, IFS Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria April 2013 Abstract There is substantial variation in

More information

Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home?

Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home? Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home? Irena Dushi U.S. Social Security Administration Alicia H. Munnell Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher Anthony Webb Center for Retirement Research at

More information

PIER Working Paper

PIER Working Paper Penn Institute for Economic Research Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania 3718 Locust Walk Philadelphia, PA 19104-6297 pier@econ.upenn.edu http://www.econ.upenn.edu/pier PIER Working Paper

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

American Dream Delayed: Shifting Determinants of Homeownership Preliminary and Incomplete

American Dream Delayed: Shifting Determinants of Homeownership Preliminary and Incomplete American Dream Delayed: Shifting Determinants of Homeownership Preliminary and Incomplete Natalia Khorunzhina Robert A. Miller May 29, 207 Abstract This paper investigates the delay in homeownership and

More information

Using Data for Couples to Project the Distributional Effects of Changes in Social Security Policy

Using Data for Couples to Project the Distributional Effects of Changes in Social Security Policy This article addresses the importance of using data for couples rather than individuals to estimate Social Security benefits. We show how individual data can underestimate actual Social Security benefits,

More information

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications Kazuo Yamaguchi Hanna Holborn Gray Professor and Chair Department of Sociology The University of Chicago October, 2009

More information

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Life-cycle Labour Supply The simple static labour supply model discussed so far has a number of short-comings For example, The

More information

Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies. From the White Paper on Gender Equality Summary

Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies. From the White Paper on Gender Equality Summary Toward Active Participation of Women as the Core of Growth Strategies From the White Paper on Gender Equality 2013 Summary Cabinet Office, Government of Japan June 2013 The Cabinet annually submits to

More information

Labor Force Participation Elasticities of Women and Secondary Earners within Married Couples. Rob McClelland* Shannon Mok* Kevin Pierce** May 22, 2014

Labor Force Participation Elasticities of Women and Secondary Earners within Married Couples. Rob McClelland* Shannon Mok* Kevin Pierce** May 22, 2014 Labor Force Participation Elasticities of Women and Secondary Earners within Married Couples Rob McClelland* Shannon Mok* Kevin Pierce** May 22, 2014 *Congressional Budget Office **Internal Revenue Service

More information

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions Answers To Chapter 7 Review Questions 1. Answer d. In the household production model, income is assumed to be spent on market-purchased goods and services. Time spent in home production yields commodities

More information

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 12-2011 Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Bureau of Labor Statistics Follow this and additional works at:

More information

Baby Busts and Baby Booms

Baby Busts and Baby Booms Baby Busts and Baby Booms The Fertility Response to Shocks in Dynastic Models Larry Jones 1 Alice Schoonbroodt 2 1 University of Minnesota and NBER 2 University of Southampton and CPC DGEM, REDg at CEMFI

More information

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Introduction For most of the past quarter century, the labor force participation rates of the older

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard Blundell, Monica Costa Dias, Costas Meghir, and Jonathan Shaw April 2013, this draft March 2015 Abstract We consider the impact of tax credits

More information

HOUSEWORK AND THE WAGES OF YOUNG, MIDDLE-AGED, AND OLDER WORKERS

HOUSEWORK AND THE WAGES OF YOUNG, MIDDLE-AGED, AND OLDER WORKERS HOUSEWORK AND THE WAGES OF YOUNG, MIDDLE-AGED, AND OLDER WORKERS KRISTEN KEITH and PAULA MALONE* This article uses samples of young, middle-aged, and older married workers drawn from the Panel Study of

More information

Paying for Private School Education: Maternal Employment and Savings over the Life-cycle

Paying for Private School Education: Maternal Employment and Savings over the Life-cycle Paying for Private School Education: Maternal Employment and Savings over the Life-cycle Shaiza Qayyum Johns Hopkins University December 16, 2018 Abstract This paper builds and estimates a dynamic life-cycle

More information

Household Search or Individual Search: Does it Matter? Evidence from Lifetime Inequality Estimates.

Household Search or Individual Search: Does it Matter? Evidence from Lifetime Inequality Estimates. Household Search or Individual Search: Does it Matter? Evidence from Lifetime Inequality Estimates. Luca Flabbi Georgetown University James Mabli Mathematica Policy Research SED - Montreal - July 2010

More information

Happy Together: A Structural Model of Couples Joint Retirement Choices

Happy Together: A Structural Model of Couples Joint Retirement Choices Happy Together: A Structural Model of Couples Joint Retirement Choices María Casanova January 31, 2011 Abstract Evidence from different sources shows that a significant proportion of spouses retire within

More information

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 9-2007 Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Bureau of Labor Statistics Follow this and additional works at:

More information

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002

Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002 The University of British Columbia Department of Economics Economics 351: Women in the Economy Answer Key Midterm Exam Winter 2002 I. For each of the following questions, circle the letter corresponding

More information

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security Each month, over 3 million children receive benefits from Social Security, accounting for one of every seven Social Security beneficiaries. This article examines the demographic characteristics and economic

More information

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371

Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Topic 2.3b - Life-Cycle Labour Supply Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 371 Life-cycle Labour Supply The simple static labour supply model discussed so far has a number of short-comings For example, The

More information

CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS

CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS CHAPTER 11 CONCLUDING COMMENTS I. PROJECTIONS FOR POLICY ANALYSIS MINT3 produces a micro dataset suitable for projecting the distributional consequences of current population and economic trends and for

More information

Free to Leave? A Welfare Analysis of Divorce Regimes

Free to Leave? A Welfare Analysis of Divorce Regimes Free to Leave? A Welfare Analysis of Divorce Regimes Raquel Fernández & Joyce Cheng Wong American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2017 Presented by Francisco Javier Rodríguez for the Macro Reading Group

More information

STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION DOI: 10.19275/RSEP013 Received: 21.04.2017 Accepted: 10.06.2017 STRUCTRAL CHANGE, DISCRIMINATION AND FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION Marie Scheitor University of Greifswald, Germany E-mail: marie.scheitor@uni-greifswald.de

More information

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records Raj Chetty, Harvard University and NBER John N. Friedman, Harvard University and NBER Tore Olsen, Harvard

More information

Changing Levels or Changing Slopes? The Narrowing of the U.S. Gender Earnings Gap,

Changing Levels or Changing Slopes? The Narrowing of the U.S. Gender Earnings Gap, Changing Levels or Changing Slopes? The Narrowing of the U.S. Gender Earnings Gap, 1959-1999 Catherine Weinberger and Peter Kuhn Department of Economics University of California, Santa Barbara Santa Barbara,

More information

Exploring the Usefulness of a Non-Random Holdout Sample for Model Validation: Welfare Effects on Female Behavior. Michael P. Keane.

Exploring the Usefulness of a Non-Random Holdout Sample for Model Validation: Welfare Effects on Female Behavior. Michael P. Keane. Exploring the Usefulness of a Non-Random Holdout Sample for Model Validation: Welfare Effects on Female Behavior Michael P. Keane Yale University and Kenneth I. Wolpin University of Pennsylvania May, 2005

More information

Changes in the Labor Supply Behavior of Married Women:

Changes in the Labor Supply Behavior of Married Women: Changes in the Labor Supply Behavior of Married Women: 1980 2000 Francine D. Blau, Cornell University, National Bureau of Economic Research, IZA, and CESifo Lawrence M. Kahn, Cornell University, IZA, and

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

The effect of parental leave policy reform on labour market outcomes and births in Japan

The effect of parental leave policy reform on labour market outcomes and births in Japan The effect of parental leave policy reform on labour market outcomes and births in Japan Yukiko Asai 1 Research Fellow Institute of Social Science University of Tokyo Abstract This analysis focuses on

More information

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

Nordic Journal of Political Economy Nordic Journal of Political Economy Volume 39 204 Article 3 The welfare effects of the Finnish survivors pension scheme Niku Määttänen * * Niku Määttänen, The Research Institute of the Finnish Economy

More information

Wage Shocks, Household Labor Supply, and Income Instability

Wage Shocks, Household Labor Supply, and Income Instability Wage Shocks, Household Labor Supply, and Income Instability Sisi Zhang 1 July 2011 Abstract Do married couples make joint labor supply decisions in response to each other s wage shocks? The study of this

More information

Returns to Human Capital and Explaining the Recent Decline of Married Women s Labor Supply: A Cohort Approach

Returns to Human Capital and Explaining the Recent Decline of Married Women s Labor Supply: A Cohort Approach Returns to Human Capital and Explaining the Recent Decline of Married Women s Labor Supply: A Cohort Approach A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF MINNESOTA

More information

Birth Control and the Rise in Female LFP; What Can We Learn from Women s Occupational Choices?

Birth Control and the Rise in Female LFP; What Can We Learn from Women s Occupational Choices? Birth Control and the Rise in Female LFP; What Can We Learn from Women s Occupational Choices? John Knowles y First Version: March, 2007 Abstract The rate at which young women enter managerial /professional

More information

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012 TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012 AGENDA Why care about labor supply responses to taxes and

More information

Economic incentives and gender identity

Economic incentives and gender identity Economic incentives and gender identity Andrea Ichino European University Institute and University of Bologna Martin Olsson Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN) Barbara Petrongolo Queen Mary

More information

Female Labor Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform

Female Labor Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Female Labor Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard Blundell, Monica Costa Dias, Costas Meghir, and Jonathan Shaw April 2013, this draft March 2015 Abstract We estimate a dynamic model of employment,

More information

THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE

THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE FOR UK PENSIONERS Richard Disney Sarah Tanner THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP 00/13 THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE FOR UK PENSIONERS 1 Richard Disney Sarah Tanner

More information

Wage Progression in the UK

Wage Progression in the UK Wage Progression in the UK Monica Costa Dias Robert Joyce DWP meeting, January 2017 Outline Brief overview of recent and planned research relating to earnings progression Women: wages over the lifecycle,

More information

Wages and Family Time Allocation WORKING PAPERS. Alexandros THELOUDIS 1, 2. LISER, Luxembourg 2. University College London, United Kingdom

Wages and Family Time Allocation WORKING PAPERS. Alexandros THELOUDIS 1, 2. LISER, Luxembourg 2. University College London, United Kingdom n 2018-06 February 2018 WORKING PAPERS Wages and Family Time Allocation Alexandros THELOUDIS 1, 2 www.liser.lu 1 LISER, Luxembourg 2 University College London, United Kingdom LISER Working Papers are intended

More information

Economic Development: Theory and Policy

Economic Development: Theory and Policy Economic Development: Theory and Policy Andreas Schäfer Center of Economic Research at ETH (CER-ETH) and University of Leipzig Institute of Theoretical Economics WS 14/15 Andreas Schäfer (CER-ETH and UL)

More information

A STATISTICAL PROFILE OF WOMEN IN THE SASKATCHEWAN LABOUR MARKET

A STATISTICAL PROFILE OF WOMEN IN THE SASKATCHEWAN LABOUR MARKET A STATISTICAL PROFILE OF WOMEN IN THE SASKATCHEWAN LABOUR MARKET A report prepared for: Status of Women Office Saskatchewan Ministry of Social Services by Sask Trends Monitor April 2017 Table of Contents

More information

Convergences in Men s and Women s Life Patterns: Lifetime Work, Lifetime Earnings, and Human Capital Investment

Convergences in Men s and Women s Life Patterns: Lifetime Work, Lifetime Earnings, and Human Capital Investment DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 8425 Convergences in Men s and Women s Life Patterns: Lifetime Work, Lifetime Earnings, and Human Capital Investment Joyce Jacobsen Melanie Khamis Mutlu Yuksel August

More information

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the Importance of Capital Chadwick C. Curtis University of Richmond Steven Lugauer University of Kentucky September 28, 2018 Abstract This paper argues that the impact

More information

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES? September 2013, Number 13-13 RETIREMENT RESEARCH CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES? By Gary Burtless* Introduction The labor force participation of

More information

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 12-2010 Women in the Labor Force: A Databook Bureau of Labor Statistics Follow this and additional works at:

More information

Since the late 1940s the percent of the male population participating in the labor

Since the late 1940s the percent of the male population participating in the labor Changes in Behavioral and Characteristic Determination of Female Labor Force Participation, 1975 2005 JULIE L. HOTCHKISS The author is a research economist and policy adviser in the regional group of the

More information

Labor Economics 7th Edition TEST BANK Borjas Full download at: https://testbankreal.com/download/labor-economics-7th-edition-testbank-borjas/

Labor Economics 7th Edition TEST BANK Borjas Full download at: https://testbankreal.com/download/labor-economics-7th-edition-testbank-borjas/ Labor Economics 7th Edition SOLUTION MANUAL Borjas Full download at: https://testbankreal.com/download/labor-economics-7th-editionsolution-manual-borjas/ Labor Economics 7th Edition TEST BANK Borjas Full

More information

)*+,($&''( -#./))0 1!!7#8".1.8.!"3

)*+,($&''( -#./))0 1!!7#8.1.8.!3 !"#"#$%&''( )*+,($&''( " -#./))0 1#.2!3 45#6 &'4/,.!!7!!8.9 31#. :#819#;###;# #65"#"##..8;91,$&/))03718.8 19

More information

THE SURVEY OF INCOME AND PROGRAM PARTICIPATION CHILDCARE EFFECTS ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS (91 ARC) No. 135

THE SURVEY OF INCOME AND PROGRAM PARTICIPATION CHILDCARE EFFECTS ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS (91 ARC) No. 135 THE SURVEY OF INCOME AND PROGRAM PARTICIPATION CHILDCARE EFFECTS ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS (91 ARC) No. 135 H. M. lams Social Security Administration U. S. Department of Commerce BUREAU OF THE CENSUS

More information

Child-Related Transfers, Household Labor Supply and Welfare

Child-Related Transfers, Household Labor Supply and Welfare Child-Related Transfers, Household Labor Supply and Welfare Nezih Guner, Remzi Kaygusuz and Gustavo Ventura CEMFI Tilburg University Arizona State University January 2017 Motivation Availability and cost

More information

Review of Economic Dynamics

Review of Economic Dynamics Review of Economic Dynamics 13 (2010) 725 741 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Review of Economic Dynamics www.elsevier.com/locate/red Taxes and female labor supply Remzi Kaygusuz Faculty of Arts

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect The Rise of the Added Worker Effect Jochen Mankart Rigas Oikonomou February 9, 2016 Abstract We document that the added worker effect (AWE) has increased over the last three decades. We develop a search

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov Working Paper 17866 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17866 NATIONAL BUREAU OF

More information

State Dependence in a Multinominal-State Labor Force Participation of Married Women in Japan 1

State Dependence in a Multinominal-State Labor Force Participation of Married Women in Japan 1 State Dependence in a Multinominal-State Labor Force Participation of Married Women in Japan 1 Kazuaki Okamura 2 Nizamul Islam 3 Abstract In this paper we analyze the multiniminal-state labor force participation

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM. Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM. Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M. Shaw Working Paper 19007 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19007

More information

Children and Career Interruptions: The Family Gap in Denmark

Children and Career Interruptions: The Family Gap in Denmark DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 263 Children and Career Interruptions: The Family Gap in Denmark Nabanita Datta Gupta Nina Smith February 2001 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Do Childbirth Grants Increase the Fertility Rate? Policy Impacts in South Korea

Do Childbirth Grants Increase the Fertility Rate? Policy Impacts in South Korea Do Childbirth Grants Increase the Fertility Rate? Policy Impacts in South Korea Yeon Jeong Son * University of Illinois at Chicago March 2017 Abstract In response to a low fertility rate, a number of municipalities

More information

CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE

CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE CHILDREN, TIME ALLOCATION AND CONSUMPTION INSURANCE Richard Blundell, Luigi Pistaferri and Itay Saporta-Eksten April 2017 Abstract We consider the life-cycle choices of a household that in each period

More information

Wages and Family Time Allocation

Wages and Family Time Allocation Wages and Family Time Allocation Alexandros Theloudis University College London February 1, 2016 JOB MARKET PAPER Please view the latest version at www.theloudis.net Abstract This paper examines how married

More information