Household Labour Supply, Childcare Costs and Tax Credits

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Household Labour Supply, Childcare Costs and Tax Credits"

Transcription

1 Household Labour Supply, Childcare Costs and Tax Credits Richard Blundell Alan Duncan Julian MacCrae Costas Meghir This version: January 2000 Abstract The UK Government is planning to replace Family Credit, the existing system of in-work support for families with children, by a new tax credit, the Working Families Tax Credit (WFTC) to be paid directly through the income tax system. This tax credit includes a generous childcare tax credit component, making childcare more affordable to working households on low incomes. In this paper we model the impact of the WFTC on work incentives and on use of childcare services. Household labour supply is modelled as a discrete choice among a finite set of hours alternatives. Our estimation strategy control explicitly for fixed and child-related costs, and allows for random preference heterogeneity, state-specific errors in perception, and local variations in the provision and cost of childcare services. In simulation we find small positive behavioural responses in aggregate to the introduction of the new tax credit Paper prepared for the workshop, The Economics of Childcare, November 15th-16th 1999, held at IZA, Bonn, Germany. Acknowledgements: We are grateful to Tom Crossley, Andrew Dilnot, Jayne Taylor, and seminar participants at ANU, Cordoba, Essex, Manchester, Melbourne and Santiago for useful comments and suggestions. The financial support of the ESRC Centre for the Micro-Economic Analysis of Fiscal Policy at IFS is gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies. Contact: Alan Duncan, School of Economics, University of Nottingham, University Park, Nottingham NG7 2RD, United Kingdom. Tel: +44 (0) alan.duncan@nottingham.ac.uk. URL: University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies University of Nottingham and Institute for Fiscal Studies Institute for Fiscal Studies University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies 1

2 1 Introduction and Background From April 2000 the UK will introduce a new Working Families Tax Credit (WFTC) as a replacement for Family Credit (FC), the UK s main in-work benefit. The structure of the WFTC reform is modelled closely on the existing FC system, with the exception that the WFTC is to be packaged as a refundable tax credit, rather than as a welfare benefit. The WFTC is intended to improve work incentives for families by making work pay. This is to be achieved by boosting the in-work incomes available to families with children in low wage jobs. Most of the extra resources are delivered by reducing the benefit reduction rate of the WFTC to 55%, down from the 70% taper found in FC. Additionally, the WFTC contains generous provision for the subsidy of childcare costs. The aim of this paper is to consider the effects on the labour market of the Working Families Tax Credit reform. In particular, we aim to study the impact of WFTC on hours of work and participation. Since this is a policy reform that is to be implemented in the future, an ex-ante evaluation is all that is available. Consequently, our analysis will rely on a structural simulation model of the type used in the work by Hoynes (1996) and?. However, as we document below, this is not the first in-work benefit reform in the UK and past reforms to the system will be used to assess the reliability of the model specification. Such ex-post evaluations are close in spirit to the difference-in-differences or natural experiment evaluation of reforms (see Eissa and Liebman (1996), for example). The difference-in-difference parameter will also have an interpretation within a structural model, although it is unlikely to relate directly to any specific preference parameter. One (eventual) aim of this paper is to use the history of the FC reforms in the UK to build a bridge between these evaluation methods and more structural approaches that are necessary for any ex-ante policy reform evaulation of the kind described here. There are effectively two target groups for the WFTC reform: single parents and married couples with children. Nearly 50% of currently working single parents are in receipt of some FC. For married couples with children this proportion is smaller, at around 16%. However, the latter group is more than two and half times the size of the former. The behaviour of both of these groups, and their economic circumstances, are sufficiently different to warrant a separate analysis. Consequently, we provide results for each group separately. A reasonable evaluation of such a reform requires three compenents: Firstly, a sample with a sufficiently large number from each of these two target groups. For this we use the UK Family Resources Survey (FRS) which covers almost 50,000 2

3 individuals per year. Secondly, sufficient detailed information on each household so as to reliably construct their net incomes under the FC and WFTC systems. For this we have implemented the Institute for Fiscal Studies tax and benefit simulation model, TAXBEN, on the FRS data. Finally, we need a behavioural model that can reasonably predict changes in labour supply resulting from the reforms to the welfare system. In this respect we have built an econometric model of work behaviour for lone parents and for couples with children that is implemented on the FRS data. This model is evaluated against the previous reforms to FC that have occured since its intorduction in These three requirements and the way they are developed to address the impact of WFTC are discussed in more detail below. However, it is worth pointing out two other key features of our simulations. Firstly, we construct the full budget constraint facing each individual in a family. This accounts for different levels of tax allowances and marginal tax rates as well as the detailed interactions of the benefit and WFTC systems. Secondly, we account for childcare costs and availability. This posed a particularly difficult challenge. Our approach is to assume that the reforms do not change the structure of the childcare market. The proportions choosing types and levels of childcare post-reform are determined by the pre-reform distribution of childcare. Consequently, we do not allow the childcare market to adapt to the introduction of WFTC. However, we do allow childcare usage to vary with hours worked and with the demographic composition of the household. We nevertheless recognise that the move to WFTC may impact on the childcare market in a manner which could have implications for the costs of the new program. The plan of the paper is as follows. We initially discuss the background and detail of the proposed Working Families Tax Credit, comparing the structure of WFTC with FC and the US EITC system. We go on in Section 3 to discuss the general structure of joint models of childcare demand and labour supply, with particular emphasis on the issue of identification in such models. In Section 4 we describe the basic structural discrete choice model, and how that model may be extended to control for childcare in estimation. Section 5 describes the empirical labour supply estimates, and Section 6 offers a prediction of the behavioural response to the WFTC. In Section 7 we offer some concluding remarks. 3

4 2 The New Working Families Tax Credit The fact that the UK Government has chosen to replace Family Credit seems initially surprising, since among means-tested benefits Family Credit is perhaps the most efficient at delivering well-targetted support. 1 So why alter a system which appears to be working well? There are three major problems perceived in the UK tax and benefit systemthat have motivated the proposed move from Family Credit to a tax credit system of in-work support: 1.Tax credits are associated with reduced stigmatisation of in-work state support. Those advocating the use of the tax system claim that giving benefits as part of an income tax refund would reduce the stigma associated with welfare receipt for those in work. If true, a reduction in stigma could encourage those people to enter employment who are presently discouraged because in work they still feel dependent on Government largesse. 2.Payment of benefit could be automatic. If employers administered an in-work tax credit, as in the UK income tax system, the Government could guarantee those who needed help would get it immediately and assistance would no longer depend on individuals having to make a claim for Family Credit. 3.Shifting in work support to the tax system could have presentational benefits. If there is public disquiet over the level of welfare spending, elements of state support disguised as a tax refund might be accepted more readily. In particular, increasing the generosity of the support could then be presented as a tax cut rather than an increase in Government spending. It is often cited that this has proved remarkably important in the US debate, even though the majority of EITC expenditure counts as public spending rather than tax foregone in the US and indeed in all countries public accounts. For these reasons, the UK government announced in the March 1998 budget that Family Credit was to be replaced by a new income tax credit to be known as the Working Families Tax Credit (WFTC). The WFTC 2 can be summarised as a more generousversionoffcwithanalteredmethodofpayment. Theimpactofthe structural change, as opposed to the increase in generosity, hinges on whether the re-branding of FC as a tax credit will have any impact on behaviour. 1 The fact that the structure of Family Credit has been altered to increase generosity three times in recent history is testimony to this contention. 2 full details of which can be found in HM Treasury (1998) 4

5 2.1 The Structure of FC and WFTC Family Credit is designed to provide support for low wage families with children who are working. Once someone in a family with children works more than 16 hours a week, they become eligible for FC. Each family is potentially eligible to a maximum amount, depending on the number of children in the household and a small addition if they work full time. Currently, the maximum level of FC comprises a weekly adult credit of and child credits starting at per child for children under 11. This maximum amount is payable if the family s net income (after income tax and National Insurance Contributions) is lower than a threshold ( per week in ). Net income in excess of this threshold reduces entitlement to FC from the maximum by 70p for every 1 of excess income. Family Credit is payable on a six monthly flat rate regardless of changes in the claimants circumstances in order to minimise administrative and compliance costs and to hide the effects of the high withdrawal rate over the period of the fixedpayment. TakeupofFCafter its introduction in 1988 was initially low but has increased. The present estimated take-up rates are 69% of recipients and 82% of potential expenditure. The WFTC will be substantially more generous than FC. By the end of the century, the government expects to be spending 5bn per year on the WFTC, which is 1.5bn more than was expected under FC. The WFTC will increase the generosity of in-work support relative to the FC system in three ways 1.an increase in the credit for children under 11 from to per child 2.an increase in the threshold from 79 to 90 per week 3.a reduction in the taper from 70% to 55% 4.a childcare tax credit of up to 105 per week for those who pay for some form of formal childcare. A stylised comparison of the structure of WFTC with FC is shown in Figures 1 and 2. Those currently receiving the maximum payment see a small increase in the level of their payment if they have children under 11. Those with net incomes between 79 and 90 move from being on the taper to receiving maximum support. The others on the taper see the taper rate fall from 70% to 55%. The largest cash gains go to those people who are currently just at the end of the taper. The increased generosity of in work support also creates new entitlement to in work support. We also include in 1 the structure of the US Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) system, in which payments to families under the American earned income tax credit 5

6 Figure 1: Alternative Structures of In-Work Support Family Credit/WFTC Hours of work WFTC with childcare WFTC Family Credit are related to the number of children and the annual level of earned income of the family. For a family with two or more children, the credit is phased in at a rate of 40c per $ over the first $8890 ( 5,454) of earnings reaching a maximum payment of $3556 ( 2,182). The credit remains level at this rate until earned income rises to $11,610 ( 7,123). From this point onward the EITC is reduced at a rate just over 21c per $ until the family is no longer eligible. Whilst families earning less than this amount, $28,495 ( 17,481) will still pay income tax throughout the year, they receive a EITC as a tax refund at year end. This comparison is instructive in a number of ways. First, note how much more generous is the WFTC relative to FC. The combination of a larger credit (particularly for those taking advantage of the childcare credit), a higher applicable amount and a lower withdrawal rate suggests that a significant number of households who were not eligible for FC will be entitled to receive WFTC. This is likely to have two major effects - the direct redistribution through transfer payments and an alteration in labour supply incentives. Previous research has shown that in most cases the distributional effect of a reform is by far the most important. 3 For workless families, the WFTC will unambiguously increase the financial returns to working. It lowers some of the highest marginal tax rates, but only to levels just below 70%. Others will become entitled to the WFTC and will therefore see their marginal tax rates increase substantially. Notice also the difference between WFTC and EITC. The US credit 3 see Duncan and Giles (1996). 6

7 Figure 2: Example budget constraint: one-parent household Family disposable income ( p.w.) Hours of work WFTC Family Credit extends over a much broader hours range down to the point of nonparticipation, but is less generous at the maximum level. To reproduce the EITC structure at maximum generosity levels close to WFTC would be prohibitively expensive. 3 Childcare and Labour Supply: some theoretical issues 3.1 Identification Although the literature on childcare demand and labour supply is wide, the number and strength of assumptions underpinning many empirical models are not always clear. In fact, many assumptions which are typically made for empirical feasibility or through limited data availability actually serve as identifying assumptions in the estimated model. We lay out in this section a theoretical framework with which to analyse issues of identification in the modelling of childcare and labour supply. The particular specification we use involves a slight modification of standard theoretical models presented in the literature. 7

8 3.2 A theoretical framework Let us start with a typical set of preferences U defined over consumption c and full leisure l 4 1, but augmented to include a measure Q of child quality among the arguments. This is a familiar starting point in much of the existing literature, as evidenced for example in work by Ribar (1991), Connolly (1991), Hotz and Kilburn (1991) and Blau and Robins (1988). Let these preferences be written as U = U(c, l 1,Q), (1) with Uc 0 > 0, Ul 0 1 > 0 and UQ 0 > 0. The child quality index Q may be interpreted as some production function for child quality, with inputs of maternal childcare l, formal (external) childcare H, and the quality q of the formal care used. Consider the following general form for child quality; Q = F (l,h,q), (2) with F 0 l > 0, F 0 H > 0 and F 0 q > Let us now suppose that expenditure e on formal childcare may be given by e = phq, (3) where p represents the price per unit of childcare of standard quality (that is, formal care with quality q =1). Turn now to the constraints on the use of time. We consider first the mother, for whom the full time endowment T is shared between employment h and non-work time according to T = h + l +(l 1 l ). (T1) So, the mother s time away from work (that is, l 1 ) is shared between maternal childcare (l ) and non-childcare (l 1 l ) time. We require l 1 l 0 (or alternatively H h), with equality when the mother devotes the entirity of her non-work time to maternal care. This alternatively requires that A second time constraint centres on the formal care requirement for the child. Specifically, we require that H = h +(l 1 l ). (T2) 4 by which we mean all time spent by the mother away from employment. 5 Note however that this does not imply an unambiguous sign for Q/ H. Given some relationship l = g(h) between maternal and formal care, with g 0 < 0, this full derivative becomes Q/ H = FH 0 + g0.fl

9 That is, the amount of care required for the child is the sum of the mother s time at work and any non-work time not spent in childcare. A third time constraint requires that the child is always in someone s care, such that T = H + l. That is to say, the sum of formal and maternal care exhausts the child s time endowment. However, this constraint is naturally implied by a combination of (T1) and (T2). Turning to the budget constraint facing the mother, we have that takes the following general form; wh + τ + v = c + qhp (BC) where τ = T (h, w, v) represents tax payments minus benefit receipts, assumed to depend on the hours of work, gross wages w and unearned income v. The price of consumption is normalised to unity The optimisation problem The optimisation problem facing the mother involves the maximisation of preferences (8) subject to a number of constraints. Noting that U = U[c, l 1,F(l,H,q)] = U[c, l 1,F(h + l 1 H, H, q)] from (T2) = u (c, T h, H, q) from (T1) (4) the full optimisation problem may be written max {c,h,h,q} u (c, T h, H, q) subjectto(bc)andh h (5) This program may be solved with reference to the following Lagrangian: L = u (c, T h, H, q)+λ.(wh + τ + v c qhp)+µ 1.(H h) (6) for which the general First-Order conditions are u λ c = 0; λ 0 (FOC1) u h + λw µ 1 = 0 (FOC2) u H λqp + µ 1 0; µ 1.[H h] =0; µ 1 0 (FOC3) u λph q = 0 (FOC4) 6 This notation remains consistent for a two-person household under the assumption that the male partner is a non-carer whose labour supply is taken as exogenous (in which case his earned income forms part of v). 9

10 together with (BC). One can consider solutions to this optimisation program under two regimes, the first of which restricts the second constraint in (4) to hold with equality. That is to say, the level of childcare required by the mother in a household is just sufficient to cover her time in employment Regime 1. Equality constrained optimisation Under this scenario, H = h (or l 1 = l ) which implies µ 1 > 0. The First Order conditions for this case become u λ c = 0; λ 0 (C1) u h + λw µ 1 = 0; (C2) u H λqp + µ 1 0; (C3) u λph q = 0, (C4) together with (BC). Combining (C2) and (C3) and substituting out for λ using (C1) gives a revised set of conditions µ u H u (pq w). u h c = 0; (C1 0 ) u q ph. u c = 0. (C2 0 ) So, the two conditions C1 0 to C2 0 imply three endogenous variables (q,h and c) with two exogenous instruments (p and w). The system is therefore identifiable in principle on the basis of data alone, without any further restrictions required on the form of preferences over consumption, leisure and child quality. The condition (C1 0 ) is of particular interest here, in that it clarifies just what is being identified in models of labour supply which do not control for childcare costs (and indeed benefits) in estimation. What (C1 0 ) demonstrates is that the marginal (dis)utility of hours may not be separated from the marginal utility of formal childcare in equilibrium without further restrictions on the form of preferences. When standard labour supply models are estimated with no controls for childcare costs, what is in fact identified is not the pure marginal disutility of hours; rather, it is this marginal disutility compensated by the marginal utility of childcare. Hence, even with monotonicity of preferences, the difference u u H h may be non-monotonic, leading to a bliss-point in the marginal preferences for (childcare conditioned hours of work. 10

11 3.3.2 Regime 2. Inequality constrained optimisation Under this scenario, H > h (or l 1 >l ) which implies µ 1 =0. The First Order conditions for this case become u λ c = 0; λ 0 (I1) u + λw h = 0; (I2) u λqp H = 0; (I3) u λph = 0, (I4) q along with (BC). The combination of (I2) and (I3) still give u u H h λ(pq w) = 0. However, the full set of conditions conditions (I1) to (I4) imply four endogenous variables (q, H, h and c) with the same two exogenous instruments (p and w). The system is therefore not identified without further restrictions on preferences, unless some information from Regime 1 can be brought to bear. One can see, for example, that we may combine (I2) and (I3) to give u h Á u H = w. Under an additional assumption of separability of q in (4), this leads to a relationship between q, H and h of the general pq form f(h) =g(h, q)+ε. (7) The imposition of a relationship of the form (7) would serve to identify the general economic model which underpins the optimisation program (4). We return to the issue of factoring controls for childcare expenditures into a fully structural model of labour market participation and hours following some discussion of a structural specification of labour supply appropriate to the simulation of actual or hypothetical childcare policy reforms. 4 A Discrete Choice Modelling Framework The traditional approach to the modelling of labour supply maintains that the decision variable, hours of work, is continuous and unconstrained. Utility is assumed to derive from net household income Y (shared between current and future consumption) and the leisure L = {L 1,L 2 } enjoyed by each individual in a two-person household. 7. Let these preferences be represented by U = U(Y,L 1,L 2 ; X), (8) 7 The simplifications necessary to model the labour supply behaviour of single person households are obvious, and covered in Duncan and Giles (1998). 11

12 where X represents characteristics for the household and each individual therein. Behavioural decisions are constrained to lie within a budget set defined in terms of the set of gross wage rates W = {W 1,W 2 } for each individual, total household income V from assets and other unearned sources, and the tax system. Let H k = T L k, k =1, 2 forsometimeendowmentt. Then the household budget set takes the following general form; Y = W 1 H 1 + W 2 H 2 + V T (H, W,V; X) FC 1 (Z 1 ) FC 2 (Z 2 ), (9) where T (H, W, V; X) represents tax payments minus benefit receipts, assumed to depend on the hours and wages of each household member, unearned income and household characteristics, and FC k (Z k ) represents the fixedcostofemploymentfor the kth individual with characteristics Z k. One may assume that households choose a point on the edge of their budget set, which ignores the potential to save for future consumption. Alternatively, one may replace income by current consumption expenditure (if data are available) to make the model consistent with a life-cycle behavioural pattern; see Blundell and Walker (1986). In the standard continuous model households are assumed to maximise (8) subject to (9) over a continuum of hours. That is, desired hours Hk for each household member stem from the solution to the following problem; max U (Y,T H 1,T H 2 ) s.t. Y {H 1,H 2 } 2X 2X W k H k +V T (H, W,V; X) FC k (Z k ). k=1 (10) The maximisation problem is not straightforward, however, because of the fundamentally non-linear character of the tax function T (.). What tends instead to happen insteadisthat(10)issolvedforaconstant marginal tax rate to recover parametric forms for the Marshallian labour supply functions for each household member. 8 The complexities of the tax schedule are then dealt with in estimation (see, for example, Hausman and Ruud (1984); Hausman (1985); Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir (1998)). However, in a number of recent studies analysts have begun to examine policy issues using labour supply models which are characterized by a more realistic discretized budget set. 9 There are a number of reasons for this. Firstly, analysts increasingly question whether a model which allows continuous substitution of hours 8 Note that this derivation ignores any element of jointness in the household labour supply decision. 9 See, for example, Bingley and Walker (1997); Duncan and Giles (1996); Duncan and Weeks (1997); Keane (1995);?; Van Van Soest (1995). 12 k=1

13 for leisure constitutes a realistic representation of the supply choices open to the individual. For many socio-demographic groups labour market participation takes the form of fixed wage-hours contracts, with individuals choosing from among a discrete set of hours combinations (most often at part-time levels of around 20 hours, and at full- time levels of between 38 and 40 hours per week). Secondly, there are statistical and practical reasons to favour a discrete approach to the modelling of labour supply in preference to more classical continuous models. These largely stem from the difficulties associated with the treatment of non-linear budget constraints in continuous estimation (see Gourieroux, Laffont, and Montfort (1980), and Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir (1992)). The strategy adopted in the discrete approach is to replace the entire household budget set with a finite number of points thereon, and optimise only over those discrete points. The procedure supposes that hours choices can be approximated by the discretized hours level H k(.) {H 1,H 2,..,H P } for individual k accordingtothe grouping rule H k(.) = H 1 if H k H B 1 = H 2 if H B 1 <H k H B 2... = H P 1 if HP B 2 <H k HP B 1 = H P if H k >HP B 1, giving P alternative values for H k(.). 10 Household net incomes may then be calculated for the set of discrete hours combinations H (.) ={H 1(.),H 2(.) }as Y [H (.) ]=Y [H 1(.),H 2(.) ]= 2X W k H k(.) +V T (H (.), W,V; X) for H 1(.),H 2(.) {H 1,H 2,.., H P } k=1 The household is assumed to maximise the following; max U Y [H 1(.),H 2(.) ],T H 1(.),T H 2(.) for H1(.),H 2(.) {H 1,H 2,..,H P } H 1(.),H 2(.) {H 1,H 2,..,H P } (11) This approach removes from the optimisation problem many of the complexities of a nonlinear tax schedule, but at the cost of introducing rounding errors in the hours 10 For example, a five-state labour supply regime for each household member might be described bythechoiceseth k(.) = {0, 10, 20, 30, 40} for k =1,.., K where H1 B =5,H2 B =15, H3 B =25, and H4 B =35. 13

14 levels used for estimation. The degree of aggregation may therefore have a potentially detrimental effect on the authenticity of the parameters estimated under a discrete regime, and ought at the very least to be subjected to sensitivity analysis. 4.1 a structural discrete model of labour supply and childcare choice To operationise the discrete model of household labour supply, we choose to model household preferences as a unitary quadratic direct utility function of household net income and individual labour supply (or equivalently, leisure time). Our estimation strategy allows both for random preference heterogeneity and state-specific errors in perception. Let U H(.) = U(Y H(.),T H 1(.),T H 2(.) ; X), for H k(.) {H 1,H 2,..,H P },k =1,.., K, (12) where the unified preference function now depends both on the (discrete) hours set H (.) ={H 1(.),H 2(.) } and household net income Y H(.) = Y [H 1(.),H 2(.) ].Comparedwith other discrete approaches, this method is parsimonious in its parameterisation and preserves the same preference structure over the whole range of hours. Random disturbances are added to utilities in each joint labour market state {H 1(.),H 2(.) } {H 1,H 2,.., H P } to give random utilities UH(.) = U(Y H(.),T H 1(.),T H 2(.) ; X)+ε H(.), (13) where each ε H(.) is assumed to be independently distributed as a Type I Extreme Value. The probability of choosing the labour market state for which H 1(.) = H j and H 2(.) = H k is therefore Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k )] = = Pr[U {H j,h k } >U {H p 1,H p 2} for all p 1 6= j, p 2 6= k, {p 1,p 2 } {1,.., P exp[u(y {H j,h k },T H j,t H k ; X)] P P p 1 =1 P P p 2 =1 exp[u(y {H p 1,H p 2 },T H p 1,T H p 2; X)]. (1 For our empirical analysis we choose the quadratic direct utility function favoured by?, where U(Y,H 1,H 2 φ) = α YY.Y 2 + α H1 H 1.H1 2 + α H2 H 2.H2 2 + α YH1.Y H 1 + α YH2.Y H 2 + α H1 H 2.H 1 H 2 +β Y.Y + β H1.H 1 + β H2.H 2 (15) for parameters φ =(α YY, α H1 H 1, α H2 H 2, α YH1, α YH2, α H1 H 2, β Y, β H1, β H2 )=(α, β). This function is tractible, yet permits a wide range of possible behavioural responses See Stern (1986) for an excellent discussion of the properties of this and other functions. 14

15 Observed heterogeneity is introduced linearly through parameters β =(β Y, β H1, β H2 ) 0.Specifically, β Y = β y0 + β 0 yx (16) β H1 = β 1 h0 + β 10 h X (17) β H2 = β 2 h0 + β 20 h X (18) The characteristics we include in the empirical estimates include dummies for the age of the youngest child, age, age squared and the age at which the woman left school. For the basic structural model, the likelihood contribution corresponding to (15) for parameters φ =(α, β) is `(φ X) = = PX j=1 k=1 PX j=1 k=1 PX d jk ln Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k ] PX d jk U(Y {H j,h k },T H j,t H k X, φ) (19) P P p 1 =1 P P p 2 =1 U(Y {H p 1,H p 2 },T H p 1,T H p 2 X, φ)] (20) where d jk = 1 H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k. 4.2 random preference heterogeneity To incorporate random preference heterogeneity we choose to randomise the linear utility parameters β =(β Y, β H1, β H2 ) 0 in (15), giving β Y = β Y + v Y (21) β H 1 = β H1 + v H1 (22) β H 2 = β H2 + v H2 (23) where v =(v Y,v H1,v H2 ) 0 are assumed jointly normal with covariance Σ v. Estimation typically requires simulation methods, either using a simple method of Simulated Maximum Likelihood or the more complex Method of Simulated Moments. Both are coveredindetailin?, although they do note that the simpler method is not unbiased for a finite number of parameter draws. For models which factor random preference heterogeneity into estimation, the simulated likelihood is conditioned on n m draws from the assumed distribution of 15

16 the random preference components. Assuming that disturbances v are distributed multivariate normally around zero mean with variance Σ v, and that the mth draw from that distribution yields realisations v m =(vy m,vh m 1,vH m 2 ) 0, define the mth set φ m of preference parameters as φ m =(α, β + v m ) 0 =(α, β m ) 0. For n m draws, the Simulated log likelihood for (15) given random preferences is written as `(φ, Σ v X, n m ) = = n m X PX m=1 j=1 k=1 n m X PX m=1 j=1 k=1 X n m PX d jk ln Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k X, φ m ] PX d jk U(Y {H j,h k },T H j,t H k X, φ m ) m=1 P P p 1 =1 P P p 2 =1 U(Y {H p 1,H p 2 },T H p 1,T H p 2 X, φ(24) m )] The estimation of covariance parameters in iterative models of this form can be difficult, since for each iteration conditions are required on the relative values of variance and covariance terms in Σ v. Rather than impose conditions directly, we choose to parameterise the Cholesky of Σ v rather than Σ v itself. 4.3 modelling participation The participation decision is probably the hardest aspect of labour supply decision to get right. Yet the work incentive impact at the point of participation is often the most important consideration when assessing the incentive and welfare impact of tax or benefit reformproposals. 12 Most empirical evidence suggests that the participation elasticity is strong relative to conditional hours elasticities, suggesting a low reservation wage for many groups. There are other reasons for observing individuals out of the labour market (including involuntary unemployment, and potential participants discouraged from seeking work by fixedorsearchcostsofemployment)whichaffect the likelihood that a potential worker will get a job, and which ideally ought to be accommodated in model estimation. Blundell, Ham, and Meghir (1987) discuss a likelihood-based approach which exploits sample information to differentiate those who are unemployed but seeking work and those who are self-reported non-participants, and Cogan (1981) describes a method to control directly for fixed costs in estimation. We also see the implementation of selection-type models to separate the participation decision from the choice of hours conditional on participation, thereby breaking the reservation wage condition. This is consistent with fixed costs, but reduced form to the extent 12 See Heckman (1993). 16

17 that the empirical model of participation typically doesn t explicitly depend on the detail of the tax and benefit system. In consequence, such models make at best an uneasy transition into microsimulation, where tax and benefit changes ought explicitly to affect participation decisions. In fact, most microsimulation studies of the impact of tax reform on labour supply deal with participation simply by assuming that reservation wages exceed the market wage on offer. There is, however, ample empirical evidence that this corner solution characterisation of nonparticipation is statistically unsustainable (see Mroz (1987)). Our source of microdata allows us to separate various types of individuals not in paid employment. Some report that they are looking for work, some report that they want to work but aren t looking (including those who cite the need to care for children as a reason for not looking), and some report that they don t want to work. We take advantage of this information to differentiate individuals. Specifically, if we attribute to those who want to work but don t look for work an unobserved (shadow) fixed cost, parameterise it in terms of observable characteristics and a random element, and identify the expected level of fixed costs through systematic differences in those observed characteristics thought to influence fixed costs, then we have the basis of an empirical model which is consistent in estimation, yet structural enough to provide a valid framework for microsimulation. What we have in mind is a discrete version of Cogan (1981). This gives us the potential to condition labour market decisions (participation and hours) on simulated (shadow) fixed costs, taking account of unobserved variability. By breaking the reservation wage condition most commonly applied to as an explanation of nonparticipation in microsimulation studies, we enjoy an abiliy to separate out discouraged workers from labour market nonparticipants and unemployed seekers. That said, we do not attempt to separate non-employed males into discouraged workers, unemployed seekers or labour market non-participants. The main reason for this simplification is that, from casual observation, male labour market decisions are restricted to a choice between non-participation and full-time work at between 37 and 40 hours per week. Given this lack of variability in hours of work among working males, it is extremely difficult statistically to identify separate fixed costs and involuntary unemployment terms from the taste parameters that would define male non-participants. Instead we pool all non-working males into one group and estimate their labour market choice as a simple binary decision. 17

18 4.3.1 controlling for the involuntarily unemployed Our approach to modelling the involuntarily unemployed among the women in our sample follows Blundell, Ham, and Meghir (1987) by specifying an employment equation of the form I = Z.δ + v I, (25) where δ represents a parameter vector, Z denotes a series of characteristics thought to influence the probability of getting a job, and where v I is assumed independent standard normal. The probability of getting a job is therefore Pr(I > 0 Z) = Φ(Z.δ). We use regional dummies (Metropolitan area, Greater London and North) to identify the model, together with years of formal education (squared and in levels) and age. Introducing the involuntarity unemployed into estimation requires a modification to the likelihood. Let d e represent an indicator variable for which d e =1if a labour market participant finds a job, 0 otherwise. Conditioning on the labour market status H 1(.) of the male partner, the probabilities of observing a non-participant (NP), an unemployed seeker (US) and a working woman are, respectively, Pr[H 1(.),NP X, Z, φ] = U (Y {H1(.),0},T H 1(.),T X, φ) > Pr, max [U(Y {H1(.),H 2(.) },T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X, φ)] H 2 (.)>0 Pr[H 1(.),US X, Z, φ] = U (Y {H1(.),0},T H 1(.),T X, φ) < [1 Φ(Z.δ)]. Pr max {H 1(.),H 2(.) },T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X, φ)] H 2 (.)>0 Pr[H 1(.),H 2(.) = U (Y H j {H1(.),H X, Z, φ] =Φ(Z.δ). Pr },T H 1(.),T H j X, φ) < max {H H 2 (.)6=H j 1(.),H 2(.) },T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X factoring fixed costs into estimation In continuous studies, fixed costs of work are typically accommodated by modelling the participation and hours decisions separately using the selection-type models of Heckman (1979) (see Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir (1998) inter alia). Specifically, by including in the model of participation instruments which are thought to be correlated with fixed costs, one may control for the effects of fixed costs in estimation. However, as Blundell (1992) notes, this method is less appropriate when the model is to be extended to simulate the impact of tax or benefit reform on participation. Firstly, the statistical model of participation is typically unaffected by changes in tax parameters. And secondly, fixed costs of work are generally neither measured nor explicitly predicted. Hence, one cannot factor such costs into a comparison of utility 18

19 in and out of the labour market. In consequence, many microsimulation studies report a relative inertia in the propensity to move into work in response to tax or benefit reforms which ought in principle to improve work incentives. In this study, we choose to follow Callan and Van Soest (1996) in which fixed costs are imputed directly from the structure of the economic model. We exploit observed differences in labour market status among women who are largely homogeneous in the characteristics thought to influence tastes for work. By relating those observed differences to instruments which proxy fixed costs, any systematic relationships are picked up in the parameters of a shadow fixed cost equation of the form FC = X FC.γ + v f, (26) where the unobserved fixed cost component v f is distributed normally around zero mean. In our most general specification we also allow for potential correlation between v f and the random preference parameters v Y, v H1 and v H2.Thefixedcost relationship (26) is factored into estimation in a relatively straightforward manner; since fixed costs impact only on workers, we replace utilities U (Y {H1(.),H 2(.) },T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X, φ) in the likelihood (20) by U (Y {H1(.),H 2(.) } FC,T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X, φ) for all states H j > 0. To characterise a worker in the presence of fixed costs therefore requires that max U (Y {H1(.),H H 2(.) >0 2(.) } FC,T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X) >U (Y {H1(.),0},T H 1(.),T X, φ) (27) where U0 = U (Y {H1(.),0},T H 1(.),T X, φ). This adds a fourth labour market state to the likelihood. Specifically, a discouraged worker is one who would like to work, but is not seeking employment because of fixed costs. The probability of observing a discouraged worker is Pr[H 1(.),DW X, X FC,Z,φ] =Pr max H 2(.) >0 U (Y {H1(.),H 2(.) } FC,T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X, φ) <U 0 and max H 2(.) >0 U (Y {H1(.),H 2(.) },T H 1(.),T H 2(.) X, φ) >U controlling for costs of childcare in estimation To simulate the full impact of the WFTC on work incentives among families with children requires a specific consideration of the role of childcare costs on labour market decisions. At the very least childcare costs act as an extra tax on employment, although a fuller consideration of labour supply in the presence of childcare would recognise the benefits of good quality childcare both for the child and the mother. 19

20 Figure 3: Alternative Labour Market States I * Workers Labour Market Nonparticipants 0 Discouraged Workers + + U(y) -U(y-FC) Unemployed Seekers + U(y) -U 0 13 The childcare credit component of the WFTC is a potentially generous benefit for those who purchase formal childcare. To assess the implications for work incentives of the new WFTC requires that we take account of the likely childcare costs incurred by households in different labour market states. In the absence of complete sample information in the FRS on childcare costs and utilisation, we adopt a probabilistic approach to integrate out childcare costs in estimation. We use empirical distributions of hourly costs of formal childcare together with imputed relationships between hours of work and hours of formal childcare to predict childcare costs for different demographic groups at different labour market states for specific childcare prices. By integrating the likelihood (20) over the range of childcare costs we are able to control for childcare costs in estimation. Furthermore, when introducing the WFTC in simulation, the level of the childcare credit component is assessed on the basis of the imputed distribution of childcare costs. Let the variable P c represent the hourly price of childcare, and let f Xc (p c ) represent the corresponding distribution of childcare prices for a household with characteristics X c. Furthermore, let us assume that there exists a relationship between 13 In some studies, childcare is treated as a good in its own right in order to rationalise the purchase of formal childcare by households with non-working members. 20

21 hours of work and hours of childcare per child of the form H cc = G(H 1,H 2 X c ). (28) Then, given a price P c per hour of childcare, the childcare costs for a household with characteristics X c whose members work H 1 and H 2 hours of work respectively is 14 CC(H 1,H 2 P c,x c )=P c.g(h 1,H 2 X c ). (29) Net household incomes for a household facing a price P c for childcare must therefore be adjusted. Specifically, Y (P c )=W 1 H 1 +W 2 H 2 +V T (H, W,V,CC; X) FC 1 (Z 1 ) FC 2 (Z 2 ) CC(H 1,H 2 P c,x c ). (30) Note that T (H, W,V,CC; X) may potentially adjust to take account of the level of childcare expenditure, as would be the case for example with the childcare credit component of the WFTC. We condition for childcare costs in estimation in the following way. 15 Let Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k ) P c = p c ] represent labour market state probabilities conditional on apricep c per hour for childcare, and let `(φ X, P c = p c )= PX PX d jk ln Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k P c = p c ] (31) j=1 k=1 represent the corresponding conditional likelihood. Assuming a continuous distribution f Xc (p c ) for childcare prices among households with characteristics X c,wemay integrate (31) over the range of prices to give PX PX Z `c(φ X) = d jk ln Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k P c = p c ].f Xc (p c ) p c. (32) j=1 k=1 From a computational point of view it is easier to work with a discrete distribution for childcare prices. Specifically, if F Xc [p c ]=Pr[P c = p c X c ] for P c P, where P = {p0,p 1,.., p n } represents a finite set of prices, then `c(φ X) = PX PX X d jk ln Pr[H 1(.) = H j,h 2(.) = H k P c = p c ].F Xc [p c ]. (33) j=1 k=1 P c P For our empirical work we choose to work with a six-point empirical distribution for hourly childcare prices. 14 This characterisation admits the possibility of free formal or informal care (P c =0). 15 For (relative) notational simplicity we derive the likelihood in the absence of controls for random preferences. 21

22 5 Results 5.1 data We use the Family Resources Survey to examine the income and incentive impact of tax credits. This is an annual budget survey of individual, family and household incomes, characteristics and labour market attachment. It is a new survey in the UK and contains a much larger and more representative sample of households than the surveys, principally the family Expenditure Survey, on which the vast majority of previous work has been carried out. For this analysis, we use the and FRS datasets, together combining information on over 50,000 UK households. We select for our empirical work two samples; single parent households and married or de facto married couples. Excluding self-employed and retired households, together with students and those in HM forces, leaves samples of 1807 single parents and 4694 two-person households for use in estimation. 5.2 net incomes To generate net incomes we use the Institute for Fiscal Studies tax and benefit model TAXBEN. 16 TAXBEN is a microsimulation model of the UK tax and benefit system that calculates taxes due and benefit entitlements for the Family Resources Survey data, and calculates the financial returns for each working age individual to employment at all possible hours by calculating gross and net incomes at these levels. For workers we assume their current wage remains unchanged, and for non-workers, we estimate wages using a wage equation based on their characteristics. The use of TAXBEN combined with varying the potential hours of individuals allows us to generate highly accurate budget constraints for each individual in the survey in order to estimate the labour supply effect of the reforms to taxation. 5.3 childcare expenditures and childcare use The childcare credit component of the Working Families Tax Credit could potentially offer generous benefits for those women who purchase some form of registered formal childcare. It is therefore important both in estimation and in our simulations of the work incentive impact of the WFTC reform that we account in some way for childcare expenditures. Ideally, we would like to observe actual childcare expenditures and childcare use among the full sample of women drawn from the Family 16 See Giles and McCrae (1995). 22

23 Resources Survey. Previous work has established that up to 30% of non-working households may purchase formal childcare to some degree, which suggests that any model designed to assess work incentives in the presence of childcare ought ideally to include childcare expenditures among non-working households. However, these data are not available to us. Instead, we are forced to impute childcare expenditures because the Family Resources Survey neglects to record childcare expenditures among non-working households. Our strategy uses sample information on hourly prices of childcare (given in Table 1), and the relationship between formal hours of childcare and hours of work (Table 2). We allow for the fact that similar households may purchase different types or levels of childcare by using information on the distribution of childcare prices paid by specific demographic groups directly in our estimation procedure via a likelihood of the form (33). Table 1: Average hourly childcare costs: percentages in range lower bound upper bound no cost Married Women one child, youngest < one child, youngest two children, youngest < two children, youngest three+ children, youngest < three+ children, youngest Single Parents one child, youngest < one child, youngest two children, youngest < two children, youngest three+ children, youngest < three+ children, youngest Total Average price within range Notes: data drawn from the and Family Resources Surveys. 5.4 Model Estimates For the main series of estimates we choose a five-state labour supply regime for women and a two- state choice set for men. Specifically, for women we allow for 23

24 Table 2: Estimated hours of childcare Constant (t-value) Slope (t-value) Married Women one child, youngest < (1.569) (26.746) one child, youngest (3.026) (8.839) two children, youngest < (2.431) (20.167) two children, youngest (3.414) (10.504) three+ children, youngest < (0.061) (9.216) three+ children, youngest (3.821) (5.158) Single Parents one child, youngest < (0.605) (13.763) one child, youngest (5.234) (5.671) two children, youngest < (1.052) (9.362) two children, youngest (5.651) (3.632) three+ children, youngest < (1.720) (3.310) three+ children, youngest (1.352) (3.143) Notes: Dependent variable: average hours of childcare per child; independent variable: hours of work by mother. Data drawn from the and Family Resources Surveys. hours choices to take one value in the set H (.) = {0, 10, 20, 30, 40} using the following allocation rule: H (.) = 0 if H 5 = 10 if 5 <H 15 = 20 if 15 <H 25 = 30 if 25 <H 35 = 40 if H>35. For married or cohabiting couples, a cursory view of the data reveals that male partnersareessentiallyfacedwiththesimplechoiceofwhetherornottowork. Conditional on working, male partners tend in the main to work somewhere between 35 and 40 hours per week, with few men in part-time employment. In consequence we choose to model the household labour supply decision of a two-person household by restricting the male partner to a simple participation choice, and define participants to be those who work more than 5 hours per week. Women in couples are allocated the same five-state choice set as one-parent households. The instruments we choose to include to pick up variation in tastes for work include dummies for the age of the youngest child (0-2, 3-4 and 5-10), the age of the parent (squared also), whether or not the parent left school at 16, and the number 24

Labour Supply and Taxes

Labour Supply and Taxes Labour Supply and Taxes Barra Roantree Introduction Effect of taxes and benefits on labour supply a hugely studied issue in public and labour economics why? Significant policy interest in topic how should

More information

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits William Elming Introduction Effect of taxes and benefits on labour supply a hugely studied issue in public and labour economics why? Significant policy interest in topic

More information

Evaluating the labour market impact of Working Families. Tax Credit using difference-in-differences

Evaluating the labour market impact of Working Families. Tax Credit using difference-in-differences Evaluating the labour market impact of Working Families Tax Credit using difference-in-differences Richard Blundell, Mike Brewer and Andrew Shephard Institute for Fiscal Studies, 7 Ridgmount Street, London,

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard Blundell, Monica Costa-Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw June 2014 Key question How do in-work benefits and the welfare system affect

More information

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics Lecture Notes for MSc Public Finance (EC426): Lent 2013 AGENDA Efficiency cost

More information

THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY

THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY Richard Blundell Mike Brewer Andrew Shepherd THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 52 The Impact

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2588 2 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 932 MARCH 2005 BEHAVIOURAL MICROSIMULATION MODELLING WITH THE MELBOURNE INSTITUTE TAX AND TRANSFER

More information

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review EALE-SOLE June 2010 Richard Blundell University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies Institute for Fiscal Studies Empirical

More information

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012 TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012 AGENDA Why care about labor supply responses to taxes and

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform (NBER Working Paper, also on my webp) Richard Blundell, Monica Costa-Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw Institute for Fiscal Studies and University

More information

The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation

The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation Richard Blundell, Mike Brewer, Monica Costa Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw Preliminary comments welcome Institute

More information

Estimation of Labour Supply Models for Four Separate Groups in the Australian Population *

Estimation of Labour Supply Models for Four Separate Groups in the Australian Population * Estimation of Labour Supply Models for Four Separate Groups in the Australian Population * Guyonne Kalb Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research The University of Melbourne Melbourne

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard Blundell, Monica Costa-Dias, Costas Meghir and Jonathan Shaw October 2013 Motivation Issues to be addressed: 1 How should labour supply, work

More information

Taxes and Labour Supply

Taxes and Labour Supply Taxes and Labour Supply Lecture notes Dan Anderberg RoyalHollowayUniversityofLondon January 2007 1 Introduction Labour supply is an important factor of production The most important source of income. Taxes

More information

Anatomy of Welfare Reform:

Anatomy of Welfare Reform: Anatomy of Welfare Reform: Announcement and Implementation Effects Richard Blundell, Marco Francesconi, Wilbert van der Klaauw UCL and IFS Essex New York Fed 27 January 2010 UC Berkeley Blundell/Francesconi/van

More information

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis IFS Briefing Note 118 James Browne The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis 1. Introduction 1 James Browne Institute

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Labour Supply. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

Labour Supply. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 Labour Supply Lecture notes Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003 1 Introduction Definition 1 Labour economics is the study of the workings and outcomes of the market for labour. ² Most require

More information

Optimal policy modelling: a microsimulation methodology for setting the Australian tax and transfer system

Optimal policy modelling: a microsimulation methodology for setting the Australian tax and transfer system Optimal policy modelling: a microsimulation methodology for setting the Australian tax and transfer system B Phillips, R Webster and M Gray CSRM WORKING PAPER NO. 10/2018 Series note The ANU Centre for

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Lecture 2: Taxation of Earnings. Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation

Lecture 2: Taxation of Earnings. Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review Lecture 2: Taxation of Earnings Munich Lectures in Economics 2010 CESifo November 2010 Richard Blundell University College London

More information

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation:

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review October 2010 (draft) Richard Blundell University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies Institute for Fiscal Studies

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 978 0 7340 3718 3 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 1008 October 2007 The Optimal Composition of Government Expenditure by John Creedy & Solmaz

More information

Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes

Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes Guyonne Kalb, Hsein Kew and Rosanna Scutella Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic

More information

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 3: Labor Supply: Blundell, Duncan and Meghir EMA (1998)

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 3: Labor Supply: Blundell, Duncan and Meghir EMA (1998) 14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 3: Labor Supply: Blundell, Duncan and Meghir EMA (1998) Daan Struyven September 29, 2012 Questions: How big is the labor supply elasticitiy? How should estimation deal whith

More information

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation:

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review ES World Congress August 2010 Richard Blundell University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies Institute for Fiscal

More information

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev Department of Economics, Trinity College, Dublin Policy Institute, Trinity College, Dublin Open Republic

More information

Analyzing Female Labor Supply: Evidence from a Dutch Tax Reform

Analyzing Female Labor Supply: Evidence from a Dutch Tax Reform DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4238 Analyzing Female Labor Supply: Evidence from a Dutch Tax Reform Nicole Bosch Bas van der Klaauw June 2009 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Working Families Tax Credit: A Review of the Evidence, Issues and Prospects for Further Research

Working Families Tax Credit: A Review of the Evidence, Issues and Prospects for Further Research Working Families Tax Credit: A Review of the Evidence, Issues and Prospects for Further Research By Richard Blundell and Ian Walker Inland Revenue Research Report 1 Working Families Tax Credit A Review

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2584 X THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 928 MARCH 2005 DISCRETE HOURS LABOUR SUPPLY MODELLING: SPECIFICATION, ESTIMATION AND SIMULTATION

More information

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity Department of Economics Working Paper Series The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity John Creedy & Norman Gemmell October 2010 Research Paper Number 1110 ISSN: 0819 2642 ISBN: 978

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond Institute for Fiscal Studies and Nu eld College, Oxford Måns Söderbom Centre for the Study of African Economies,

More information

Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families

Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families Review of Economic Studies (2011) 01, 1 31 0034-6527/11/00000001$02.00 c 2011 The Review of Economic Studies Limited Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families RICHARD BLUNDELL

More information

The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model

The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model Eleonora Matteazzi, Martina Menon, and Federico Perali University of Verona University of Verona University of Verona

More information

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand Background paper for Session 5 of the Victoria University of Wellington Tax Working Group October 2009 Prepared by the New Zealand Treasury

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2587 4 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 931 MARCH 2005 AN IN-WORK PAYMENT WITH AN HOURS THRESHOLD: LABOUR SUPPLY AND SOCIAL WELFARE by

More information

Commentary. Thomas MaCurdy. Description of the Proposed Earnings-Supplement Program

Commentary. Thomas MaCurdy. Description of the Proposed Earnings-Supplement Program Thomas MaCurdy Commentary I n their paper, Philip Robins and Charles Michalopoulos project the impacts of an earnings-supplement program modeled after Canada s Self-Sufficiency Project (SSP). 1 The distinguishing

More information

Chapter 1 Labor Supply (Complete)

Chapter 1 Labor Supply (Complete) Labor Economics Chapter 1 Labor Supply (Complete) Pierre Cahuc, Stéphane Carcillo and André Zylberberg 1 / 81 In this chapter, we will: See how people make choices between consumption, leisure and household

More information

WELFARE REFORM AND THE BEHAVIOUR OF THE UNEMPLOYED. Sarah Brown and Karl Taylor Department of Economics University Of Sheffield InstEAD and IZA

WELFARE REFORM AND THE BEHAVIOUR OF THE UNEMPLOYED. Sarah Brown and Karl Taylor Department of Economics University Of Sheffield InstEAD and IZA WELFARE REFORM AND THE BEHAVIOUR OF THE UNEMPLOYED Sarah Brown and Karl Taylor Department of Economics University Of Sheffield InstEAD and IZA Understanding Behaviour Change and the Role of Conditionality

More information

Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay

Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay EM 3/15 Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay Mike Brewer and Paola De Agostini February 2015 1 Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle

More information

Work Incentives and Labour Supply of Lone Parents:

Work Incentives and Labour Supply of Lone Parents: Work Incentives and Labour Supply of Lone Parents: Employment Credits in Australia Alan Duncan March 2002 ABSTRACT Lone parents are proportionately the main client groups for many government benefit, transfer

More information

Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility

Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility Article Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility Koon-Shing Kwong 1, Yiu-Kuen Tse 1 and Wai-Sum Chan 2, * 1 School of Economics, Singapore Management University, Singapore

More information

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say? Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say? Prediction n 1 : Conditional convergence: Countries at an early phase of capital accumulation tend to grow faster than countries at a later

More information

1 Excess burden of taxation

1 Excess burden of taxation 1 Excess burden of taxation 1. In a competitive economy without externalities (and with convex preferences and production technologies) we know from the 1. Welfare Theorem that there exists a decentralized

More information

THE PERSISTENCE OF UNEMPLOYMENT AMONG AUSTRALIAN MALES

THE PERSISTENCE OF UNEMPLOYMENT AMONG AUSTRALIAN MALES THE PERSISTENCE OF UNEMPLOYMENT AMONG AUSTRALIAN MALES Abstract The persistence of unemployment for Australian men is investigated using the Household Income and Labour Dynamics Australia panel data for

More information

CEP Discussion Paper No 724 Revised and republished June 2015

CEP Discussion Paper No 724 Revised and republished June 2015 ISSN 2042-2695 CEP Discussion Paper No 724 Revised and republished June 2015 Incidence, Salience and Spillovers: The Direct and Indirect Effects of Tax Credits on Wages Ghazala Azmat Abstract Tax credits

More information

Structural models of the labour market and the impact and design of tax policies

Structural models of the labour market and the impact and design of tax policies Structural models of the labour market and the impact and design of tax policies Andrew James Shephard A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

More information

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform IFS Working Paper W16/03 Richard Blundell Monica Costas Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan Shaw Female Labor Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform Richard

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Intermediate Macroeconomics Intermediate Macroeconomics Lecture 9 - Government Expenditure & Taxes Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2011 November 9 Data on government expenditure government expenditure is the dollar amount spent at all

More information

Labor Supply and Income Effects of the Earned Income Tax Credit and Welfare Programs

Labor Supply and Income Effects of the Earned Income Tax Credit and Welfare Programs Labor Supply and Income Effects of the Earned Income Tax Credit and Welfare Programs Ximing Wu March 8, 2005 Abstract This paper examines the effect of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) and welfare programs

More information

Reforms to Universal Credit

Reforms to Universal Credit s to Universal Credit Executive summary This joint report by the Trades Union Congress and the Child Poverty Action Group considers reforms to Universal Credit that could have a significant impact on the

More information

Parental investment in child nutrition

Parental investment in child nutrition Parental investment in child nutrition Tom Crossley, Rachel Griffith, Wenchao (Michelle) Jin and Valerie Lechene 30 March 2012 (IFS) Crossley, Griffith, Jin and Lechene 30 March 2012 1 / 35 Motivation

More information

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training J. Adda, C. Dustmann,C.Meghir, J.-M. Robin February 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper evaluates the return to formal

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Simplifying the Formal Structure of UK Income Tax

Simplifying the Formal Structure of UK Income Tax Fiscal Studies (1997) vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 319 334 Simplifying the Formal Structure of UK Income Tax JULIAN McCRAE * Abstract The tax system in the UK has developed through numerous ad hoc changes to its

More information

Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children

Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children Patricia Apps Sydney University Law School and IZA Jan Kabátek* Tilburg University and Netspar Arthur van Soest Tilburg

More information

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model R. Barrell S.G.Hall 3 And I. Hurst Abstract This paper argues that the dominant practise of evaluating the properties

More information

The Impact of In-Work Benefits on Poverty and Household Labour Supply A simulation study for Switzerland. Michael Gerfin Robert E.

The Impact of In-Work Benefits on Poverty and Household Labour Supply A simulation study for Switzerland. Michael Gerfin Robert E. The Impact of In-Work Benefits on Poverty and Household Labour Supply A simulation study for Switzerland Michael Gerfin Robert E. Leu 03-04 April 2003 Diskussionsschriften Universität Bern Volkswirtschaftliches

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE

THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE FOR UK PENSIONERS Richard Disney Sarah Tanner THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP 00/13 THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE FOR UK PENSIONERS 1 Richard Disney Sarah Tanner

More information

Welfare-to-Work, Wages and Wage Growth

Welfare-to-Work, Wages and Wage Growth DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1144 Welfare-to-Work, Wages and Wage Growth Reamonn Lydon Ian Walker May 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Welfare-to-Work,

More information

Topic 11: Disability Insurance

Topic 11: Disability Insurance Topic 11: Disability Insurance Nathaniel Hendren Harvard Spring, 2018 Nathaniel Hendren (Harvard) Disability Insurance Spring, 2018 1 / 63 Disability Insurance Disability insurance in the US is one of

More information

What is the Federal EITC? The Earned Income Tax Credit and Labor Market Participation of Families on Welfare. Coincident Trends: Are They Related?

What is the Federal EITC? The Earned Income Tax Credit and Labor Market Participation of Families on Welfare. Coincident Trends: Are They Related? The Earned Income Tax Credit and Labor Market Participation of Families on Welfare V. Joseph Hotz, UCLA & NBER Charles H. Mullin, Bates & White John Karl Scholz, Wisconsin & NBER What is the Federal EITC?

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM. Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM. Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M. Shaw Working Paper 19007 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19007

More information

Effective Policy for Reducing Inequality: The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income

Effective Policy for Reducing Inequality: The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income Effective Policy for Reducing Inequality: The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income Hilary Hoynes, UC Berkeley Ankur Patel US Treasury April 2015 Overview The U.S. social safety net for

More information

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

Real Business Cycles (Solution) Real Business Cycles (Solution) Exercise: A two-period real business cycle model Consider a representative household of a closed economy. The household has a planning horizon of two periods and is endowed

More information

Roy Model of Self-Selection: General Case

Roy Model of Self-Selection: General Case V. J. Hotz Rev. May 6, 007 Roy Model of Self-Selection: General Case Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

Labor supply models. Thor O. Thoresen Room 1125, Friday

Labor supply models. Thor O. Thoresen Room 1125, Friday Labor supply models Thor O. Thoresen Room 1125, Friday 10-11 tot@ssb.no, t.o.thoresen@econ.uio.no Ambition for lecture Give an overview over structural labor supply modeling Specifically focus on the discrete

More information

Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children

Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children Patricia Apps Sydney University Law School and IZA Jan Kabátek* Tilburg University and Netspar Arthur van Soest Tilburg

More information

Household Labor Supply and Welfare Participation in Sweden

Household Labor Supply and Welfare Participation in Sweden DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 769 Household Labor Supply and Welfare Participation in Sweden Lennart Flood Jörgen Hansen Roger Wahlberg April 2003 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623

Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 Wolpin s Model of Fertility Responses to Infant/Child Mortality Economics 623 J.R.Walker March 20, 2012 Suppose that births are biological feasible in the first two periods of a family s life cycle, but

More information

From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden

From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden Lennart Flood a, Elina Pylkkänen a Roger Wahlberg a Abstract a Department of Economics, Göteborg

More information

The Impact of a $15 Minimum Wage on Hunger in America

The Impact of a $15 Minimum Wage on Hunger in America The Impact of a $15 Minimum Wage on Hunger in America Appendix A: Theoretical Model SEPTEMBER 1, 2016 WILLIAM M. RODGERS III Since I only observe the outcome of whether the household nutritional level

More information

Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families

Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families Richard Blundell UCL & IFS Andrew Shephard Princeton University First version August 2008; This version May 2011 Abstract The optimal

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Modelling labour supply in Poland: elasticity estimates and policy simulations

Modelling labour supply in Poland: elasticity estimates and policy simulations Modelling labour supply in Poland: elasticity estimates and policy simulations IBS Seminar 24.10.17 Michał Myck Centre for Economic Analysis, CenEA (Szczecin) Analysis financed through projects conducted

More information

BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE A SHORT COURSE IN ALAN DUNCAN DIRECTOR, BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE WORLD BANK,, WASHINGTON DC, JULY 2017

BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE A SHORT COURSE IN ALAN DUNCAN DIRECTOR, BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE WORLD BANK,, WASHINGTON DC, JULY 2017 BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE A SHORT COURSE IN MICROSIMULAtion methods ` ` ALAN DUNCAN DIRECTOR, BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE WORLD BANK,, WASHINGTON DC, 13-14 JULY 2017 The Bankwest Curtin Economics

More information

Topic 2-3: Policy Design: Unemployment Insurance and Moral Hazard

Topic 2-3: Policy Design: Unemployment Insurance and Moral Hazard Introduction Trade-off Optimal UI Empirical Topic 2-3: Policy Design: Unemployment Insurance and Moral Hazard Johannes Spinnewijn London School of Economics Lecture Notes for Ec426 1 / 27 Introduction

More information

Labour Supply Elasticities in New Zealand

Labour Supply Elasticities in New Zealand Labour Supply Elasticities in New Zealand John Creedy and Penny Mok WORKING PAPER 10/2017 July 2017 Working Papers in Public Finance Chair in Public Finance Victoria Business School The Working Papers

More information

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is:

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is: Markowitz portfolio optimisation Solver To use Solver to solve the quadratic program associated with tracing out the efficient frontier (unconstrained efficient frontier UEF) in Markowitz portfolio optimisation

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Fuel-Switching Capability

Fuel-Switching Capability Fuel-Switching Capability Alain Bousquet and Norbert Ladoux y University of Toulouse, IDEI and CEA June 3, 2003 Abstract Taking into account the link between energy demand and equipment choice, leads to

More information

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013 Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak November 2013 Well known that policymakers face important tradeoffs between equity and efficiency in the design of the tax system The issue we address in this paper informs

More information

Aggregating Elasticities: Intensive and Extensive Margins of Women s Labour Supply

Aggregating Elasticities: Intensive and Extensive Margins of Women s Labour Supply Aggregating Elasticities: Intensive and Extensive Margins of Women s Labour Supply Orazio Attanasio Peter Levell Hamish Low Virginia Sánchez-Marcos June 4, 2018 Abstract We show that there is substantial

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Equality impact assessment Universal Credit: welfare that works. 19 November 2010

Equality impact assessment Universal Credit: welfare that works. 19 November 2010 Equality impact assessment Universal Credit: welfare that works 19 November 2010 Equality impact assessment for Universal Credit: welfare that works (Cm 7957) 1. Introduction The Department for Work and

More information

Choice Models. Session 1. K. Sudhir Yale School of Management. Spring

Choice Models. Session 1. K. Sudhir Yale School of Management. Spring Choice Models Session 1 K. Sudhir Yale School of Management Spring 2-2011 Outline The Basics Logit Properties Model setup Matlab Code Heterogeneity State dependence Endogeneity Model Setup Bayesian Learning

More information

Alternative VaR Models

Alternative VaR Models Alternative VaR Models Neil Roeth, Senior Risk Developer, TFG Financial Systems. 15 th July 2015 Abstract We describe a variety of VaR models in terms of their key attributes and differences, e.g., parametric

More information

Department for Education Northern Ireland

Department for Education Northern Ireland Department for Education Northern Ireland Consultation on changes to eligibility criteria for free school meals and uniform grants Response from the Low Incomes Tax Reform Group (LITRG) 1 Executive Summary

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT (A SOCIAL WELFARE APPROACH)

THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT (A SOCIAL WELFARE APPROACH) THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT (A SOCIAL WELFARE APPROACH) Lucía Gorjón Sara de la Rica Antonio Villar Ispra, 2018 1 INDICATORS What we measure affects what we think 2 INTRODUCTION 3 BEYOND UNEMPLOYMENT

More information

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals IFS Briefing Note BN209 Stuart Adam Andrew Hood Robert Joyce David Phillips Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

More information

From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden

From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 891 From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden Lennart Flood Elina Pylkkänen Roger Wahlberg October 2003

More information

Optimal Income Taxation of Married Couples: An Empirical Analysis of Joint and Individual Taxation

Optimal Income Taxation of Married Couples: An Empirical Analysis of Joint and Individual Taxation DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3819 Optimal Income Taxation of Married Couples: An Empirical Analysis of Joint and Individual Taxation Peter Haan Dolores Navarro November 2008 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

I. Labour Supply. 1. Neo-classical Labour Supply. 1. Basic Trends and Stylized Facts

I. Labour Supply. 1. Neo-classical Labour Supply. 1. Basic Trends and Stylized Facts I. Labour Supply 1. Neo-classical Labour Supply 1. Basic Trends and Stylized Facts 2. Static Model a. Decision of hether to ork or not: Extensive Margin b. Decision of ho many hours to ork: Intensive margin

More information

Who stays poor? Who becomes poor? Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey

Who stays poor? Who becomes poor? Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey Who stays poor? Who becomes poor? Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey Lorenzo Cappellari Stephen P. Jenkins 5 June 2001 Acknowledgements Research supported by a Nuffield Foundation New Career

More information

Centre for Economic Policy Research

Centre for Economic Policy Research The Australian National University Centre for Economic Policy Research DISCUSSION PAPER Labor Supply Heterogeneity and Demand for Child Care of Mothers with Young Children Patricia Apps Sydney University

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information