Yili Chien, Harold Cole and Hanno Lustig. August 1, 2013

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Yili Chien, Harold Cole and Hanno Lustig. August 1, 2013"

Transcription

1 Implications of Heterogeneity in Preferences, Beliefs and Asset Trading Technologies for the Macroeconomy Extremely Preliminary and Incomplete August 1, 2013 Yili Chien, Harold Cole and Hanno Lustig August 1,

2 1 Introduction This paper extends the methodology developed in Chien, Cole and Lustig (2011, 2012 (hereafter CCL2011 and CCL2012 to analyze and compute the equilibria of economies with large numbers of agents who have different asset trading technologies which are design to replicate the portfolio behavior we see in the data. The different asset trading technologies fall into two classes. Active traders manage the composition of their portfolios among a given set of assets along with choosing how much to save. Passive traders take their portfolio composition as given and choose only how much to save. Within each class there can be a wide variety of different cases. For active traders, the trading technology varies depending upon the set of assets that they can use. While for passive traders it varies with the specific portfolio composition rule. In CCL2011 and CCL2012 all of our agents had to have the same CRRA flow utility functions, discount rate and beliefs. In this extension, we relax this restriction, greatly extending the set of economies to which our method applies. This richer degree of heterogeneity, especially with respect to beliefs, allows the model to match up with a number of key features of the data. To compute and characterize equilibria we utilize a recursive multiplier method and analytic aggregation results with respect to consumption shares and the stochastic discount factor that rely on a single cross-sectional moment of the multiplier distribution. As a result, we can compute equilibria via an iterative method in which we guess and recover a transition rule for the updating of this moment. In these iterations we do not need to compute market clearing prices since we know them analytically as a function of the updating rule. Instead, we simply solve the analog of a dynamic programming problem for each type of agent with respect to their individual multipliers to determine their individual multiplier updating rule. The only input into this problem is the stochastic discount rate implied by the conjectured updating rule for the key cross-sectional multiplier moment. We then pass their individual multiplier updating rules through a stochastic panel of aggregate and individual shocks to determine the implied updates of the key cross-sectional multiplier moment. If we recover the same updating rule we conjectured, then we have solved for an equilibrium of our economy. Otherwise, we use the implied updating rule to modify our conjectured rule and continue to iterate on the aggregate multiplier transition rule. In CCL2011 and CCL2012 we relied on the homogeneity of the inverse of the marginal utility of consumption when all households have common CRRA preferences, discount rates and beliefs. In our extension, we create a parallel economy of reference traders who have common CRRA preferences, discount rates and beliefs, and a mapping rule which maps our standard household s multiplier into a multiplier for the reference traders such that their consumptions are equal history-state-by-history-state if state prices are the same. All of our aggregation results hold in the parallel economy. Our extended methodology takes advantage of this by using a guess and recover method for the transition rule for the key cross-sectional moment of the reference economy multipliers. We use the regular economy to determine updating rule for their individual multipliers, given the state prices implied by the transition rule for the key moment of the reference trader s mulitplier distribution. We then use these inidividual updating rules to determine the realized individual multipliers in a stochastic panel. We map these multipliers into the multipliers for our reference traders, and then determine the cross-sectional moment and updated transition rule in the parallel economy. The new procedure essentially adds one small step to the original algorithm. However, the set of economies 2

3 that can be handled includes any for which we can construct a multiplier mapping rule for the reference traders. This turns out to be a very broad set. Our methodology is well suited to exploring the implications of a rapidly growing literature on household finance which studies the portfolio decisions of households for the macroeconomy. This literature finds that many households do not use asset markets as our standard theory would predict: both the extent of the assets they use and how they utilize the ones they do use differs in important ways (see Guiso and Sodini 2012 for a survey of this literature. First, many households do not utilize all of the available assets. Second, even households which hold equities make very few adjustments in their financial positions. Third, many households who do adjust their portfolios seem to do so in a backward looking manner that leads them to systematically mistime the market. These empirical finds suggest that many households are either completely unresponsive to variations in the pricing of risk or respond in the wrong direction. This pattern of asset usage by households is potentially important since it creates a form of market segmentation which can have wide ranging implications for many aspects of our models predictions such as household consumption behavior, the distribution of wealth, and, most directly, asset prices. CCL2011 and CCL2012 used this methodolgy to impose portfolio behavior on passive households in the model to evaluate its impact. We found that having a large number of investors who invest only in low risk / low return portfolios means that other investors have to take on more risk, and in particular aggregate risk. We also found that having a large number of investors who invest in equities very passively, allowing the equity share in their portfolios to rise and fall with excess returns on equity means that the equity investments of other traders who do adjust their equity positions must move in a counter-cyclical manner, rising when the price of risk is high and falling when it is low. We found that the concentration of aggregate risk through equities on a small number of active traders has the potential to generate both a high and a highly volatile market price of risk, which has been a challenge for our asset pricing models (see Lettau and Ludvigson Also, having a large number of households who do not use assets well can explain their failure to smooth their consumption to the degree that the richness of actual financial markets would allow. Finally, the fact that households are realizing very different returns on their investments can explain the distribution of wealth: both the fact that it is highly skewed relative to income and that equity investment is highly correlated with wealth. We apply this new methodology to several quantitative experiments. In the first experiment we examine the impact of belief heterogeneity on asset prices and trading behavior. In looking at data on mutual equity mutual fund investments, we find that many investors seem to systematically rely on recent returns to determine their current investments. In our sample this leads them to mistime the market. We conjecture that this investment behavior is motivated by changes in their beliefs about future outcomes due to their heavy reliance on recent events in formulating their forecasts. To examine this conjecture, we include volatilte-belief households (VB who have a different assessment of the likelihood of a good or bad growth rate realization than the other actively trading households (ST. Our VB households believe that the data generating mechanims may have recently changed and put additional weight on more recent observations. The ST households assume that the world is stationary and hence weight all of the historically observed transition frequencies equally. Disagreements of this sort seem natural in a world 3

4 in which the stationary of the mechanism generating our data is not obvious. Because the VB households become more (less optimistic about the likelihood of a good growth shock precisely when the price of risk is rising (falling, their investment behavior is less responsive to the price of risk, forcing the ST households to have large countercyclical aggregate risk exposure. This leads the VB traders to miss time the market and substantially increases the counter-cyclical volatility of the market price of risk. This mechanism is complementary to the mechanisms we explored in CCL2011 and CCL2012 because it involves a different set of traders and a similar cyclical concentration of risk for the ST households. In the second experiment we examine the role of difference in discount rates on the investment behavior of our active traders. We the behavior of the less patient and more patient traders to be surprisingly similar. The less patient active traders ends up essentially mirroring the more patient agents except that they act as if they had a lower wealth target. As a result, the asset pricing implication of our model are not substantially changed by their inclusion, though the predictions for individuals portfolio and savings behavior are. In the third experiment we show how our methodolgy can be extended to include traders with recursive preferences. This allows us to distinguish between risk aversion (RA and the intertemporal rate of substitution (IES. We then compare the implications of changing these two preference factors for the asset pricing, portfolio and wealth implications of our model. One striking finding of our experiments is that households with incorrect beliefs or low discount factors do not become economically negligible. In fact they remain large and important through out. The reason for this is two-fold. First, the presence of idiosyncratic risk and net wealth bounds implies that these households have large precautionary savings motivations at low wealth levels. Second, the low risk-free rate implies that exerts a downward force on household wealth. The combination of these factors leads to an ergodically stable wealth distribution for our economy. Moreover, if the standard active traders even became economically completely dominate, then asset prices would have to reflect this, which would lead to a low price of risk and a high risk-free rate. This in turn would make the other trading technologies more effective and the consequence of incorrect beliefs less substantial. Hence, prices end up adjusting so that these ST households never become dominate. 2 Literature Review-under construction 3 Model This an infinite horizon endowment economy with a large number of households and a single nonstorable consumption good in each period. Time is discrete, infinite, and indexed by t = 0, 1, 2,... The first period, t = 0, is a planning period in which financial contracting takes place. There are a unit measure of households who come in a finite set of household types indexed by i {1,..., I}. These types differ in terms of their preferences, beliefs and asset 4

5 trading technologies. All households have additively separable utility functions over consumption with constant discount rates. The aggregate endowment of this good is stochastic, and households are subject to both aggregate and idiosyncratic income shocks as well as idiosyncratic taste shocks. Asset markets are complete, and both a stock and a risk-free bond are traded. A household s portfolio selection is limited by its trading technology. 3.1 Endowments and Shocks Our economy is subject to two kinds of shocks. The first is an aggregate growth rate shock z t Z. The second is an idiosyncratic household-specific income shock η t N in period t, and θ t Θ to denote the idiosyncratic taste shock. We will assume that Z and Θ are finite. z t denotes the history of aggregate shocks and η t denotes the history of idiosyncratic income. The history state for a household is (z t, η t The aggregate per capita supply of the endowment good is given by Y t (z t, and it evolves according to Y t (z t = exp{z t }Y t 1 (z t 1, (1 with Y 0 (z 0 = 1. Households endowment of this good comes in the form of two Lucas fruit trees. The first tree yields diversifiable income (1 γy t (z t. The household is free to trade claims directly on this income and hence it forms the basis for positive net supply financial wealth. The second tree yields non-diversifiable income γy t (z t η t and it is subject to the household s idiosyncratic income shock. We assume that the household cannot directly trade away its claim to non-diversifiable income and hence its ability to do so will depend whether or not its asset trading technology allows it to trade claims which are conditional on η t. We will assume that the expected value of η t is 1 and that the law of large numbers applies. So, these idiosyncratic income shocks will average out in the population and that per capita supply of non-diversifiable income is γy t (z t, and hence γ is the overall share of income that is non-diversifiable. We will discuss taste shocks when we layout the household s preferences. The idiosyncratic income shocks are i.i.d. across households, and have mean one. For simplicity we will assume that all of the households face the same stochastic process for idiosyncratic shock. We use π(z t, η t to denote the unconditional probability of state (z t, η t being realized. In a slight abuse of notation we also use π(η t to denote the unconditional probability of personal history η t. Since we can appeal to a law of large number, π(η t also denotes the fraction of agents in state z t that have drawn an idiosyncratic history η t. The events are first-order Markov, and, continuing our pattern of notation abuse, we assume that the conditional probability of (z t+1, η t+1 is given by π(z t+1, η t+1 z t, η t = π(z t+1 z t π(η t+1 η t, z t+1. (2 Thus we allow the distribution of idiosyncratic shocks to depend upon the aggregate shock, but not the reverse. We introduce some additional notation: z t+1 z t or η t+1 η t means that the left hand side node is a successor node to the right hand side node. We denote by {z τ z t } the set of successor aggregate histories for z t including those many periods in the future; ditto for {η τ η t }. When we use, we include the current nodes z t or η t in the set. 5

6 3.2 Preferences A household of type i has a flow utility function u i (c where u i is strictly concave and C 2. Households discount future utility at a constant rate β i. The measure of type i households is given by µ i. The households are expected utility maximizers, however, we allow their beliefs to differ from the true probabilities. A household of type i has preferences over stochastic consumption sequences given by (β i t u i (c t π i (z t, η t, t 1,(z t,η t where π i (z t, η t denotes the probabilities that agent i assigns to state (z t, η t. We will assume that π i (z t, η t is separable between z t and η t, as in (2, and that all agents have common beliefs about the agent s personal outcomes η t given by the actual probabilities π(η t+1 η t, z t+1. However, agents may differ with respect to the aggregate probabilities, with π i (z t+1 z t denoting agent i s beliefs Asset Markets Households trade assets in securities markets that re-open every period. There can be a wide range of assets traded, including one-period Arrow securities, a risk-free bond and a levered equity claim. We denote the price of a unit claim to the final good in aggregate state z t+1 acquired in aggregate state z t by Q t (z t+1, z t. We will take the price of a unit claim in state (z t+1, η t+1 to be Q ( (z t+1, η t+1, ( z t, η t = Q t (z t+1, z t π(η t+1 η t, z t+1. (3 If a trader can hedge his idiosyncratic risk, then this price is implied by arbitrage, while if not it is a innocuous assumption since he will only care about the aggregate state price Q(z t+1, z t. Starting from aggregate state-contingent Arrow bond prices, we can back out the aggregate present-value prices recursively as follows: P (z t = Q(z t, z t 1 Q(z t 1, z t 2 Q(z 1, z 0 Q(z 0. From the present-value price P (z t, we can construct the state prices as P (z t = P (z t π(z t. Consistent with (3, we let P (z t, η t = P (z t π(η t z t. 2 Finally, we let m(z t+1 z t = P (z t+1 /P (z t denote the stochastic discount factor that prices any random payoffs. We will assume that there is a positive measure of traders who can freely trade aggregate the aggregate state-contingent security to guarantee the uniqueness of the stochastic discount factor. In addition to state-contingent bonds, we split the aggregate diversifiable income stream, (1 γy t (z t, into payments on a risk-free debt and an equity claim. For simplicity, the bonds are taken to be one-period risk-free 1 Without this assumption of common beliefs about idiosyncratic risk, we cannot price this risk in the simple manner assumed in equation (3 2 The state price is independent of the realization of the idiosyncratic history. 6

7 bonds. Since we assume a constant leverage ratio ψ, the supply of one-period non-contingent bonds B s t (z t in each period needs to adjust such that: B s t = ψ [(1 γv t [{Y }] B s t ], where V t [{Y }](z t denotes the value of a claim to aggregate income in node z t. The payout to bond holders is given by R f t (z t 1 B s t 1(z t 1 B s t (z t, where R f t (z t 1 is the risk-free rate between t 1 and t in node z t 1. The payments to shareholders, D t (z t, are then determined residually as: D t = (1 γy t R f t (z t 1 B s t 1 + B s t. In our model, the supply of shares is constant and all equity payouts come exclusively in the form of dividends. We denote the value of the equity claim as V t [{D}](z t. R t,t 1 [{D}](z t denotes the gross return on the dividend claim between t 1 and t. A trader who invests a fraction ψ/(1 + ψ in bonds and the rest in debt is holding the market portfolio. Note that both equities and the risk-free bond are in positive net supply because they add up to a claim to diversifiable wealth. The equity payout/output ratio is given by the following expression: ( D t = (1 γ 1 + ψ [ Vt [{Y }] (1 + R t,t 1 [1] V ] t 1[{Y }] exp{ z t }. (4 Y t 1 + ψ Y t Y t 1 As can easily be verified, the payout/output ratio is pro-cyclical provided that the price-dividend ratio of a claim to aggregate (or diversifiable output is. Since our calibrated benchmark model produces procyclical price/dividend ratios, the equity payout/output ratio inherits this property, as in the data. 3.4 Asset Trading Technologies Our households face different asset trading technologies which take the form of portfolio restrictions and net wealth constraints. Portfolio restrictions fix the relative amounts that the household can invest in certain groups of assets. As a result, a household can only choose how much to invest in such an assets group. Since the relative shares within a group will determine the return on the total amount invested in the group, given the asset returns within the group, each group becomes in effect a single asset from the perspective of a restricted household. The total number of groups available to a household will then determine the extent to which it can allocate financial wealth tomorrow across states of the world. To ensure that the stochastic discount factor is uniquely determined, at least with respect to the aggregate shock, we will assume that a positive measure of our agents can freely trade an aggregate state-contingent bond. This will imply that the return on any traded can asset can be expressed n terms of the return on an Arrow security due to arbitrage. Hence, we can simply think of all of our households as trading the state-contingent Arrow securities subject to a linear portfolio restriction. We denote by b i [(z t, η t, (z t+1, η t+1 ] the number of state contingent bonds purchased in state (z t, η t and paying off one unit in state ([z t, z t+1 ], [η t, η t+1 ] by a household of type i. We denote the vector of bond positions acquired in state (z t, η t by b i z t+1,η t+1 [(z t, η t ].(We will use this notation whenever we are converting a function into a conditional 7

8 vector. A household s trading technology implies a savings choice σ(z t, η t which has the same dimension as the number of assets groups the trader can choose among. Their savings technology implies a matrix A i (z t of asset group returns between z t and z t+1 z t, which is of dimension # [Z Θ] #σ(z t, η t (i.e. the dimension of shocks the dimension of the number of asset choices. The portfolio restrictions of these restricted households can be expressed as the requirement that b i [ z t+1,η t+1 (z t, η t ] = A i (z t σ(z t, η t. 3 This linear restriction can encompass a wide range of standard cases. Active traders have multiple groups and hence have genuine portfolio allocation decisions. Two examples of this class of traders are complete and aggregate-complete traders. Complete traders can freely trade Arrow securities, the dimension of σ(z t, η t is # [Z Θ] and A i (z t = I. For aggregate-complete traders who can only trade in aggregate state contingent bonds, σ(z t, η t has dimension #Z and A i (z t equals one for those row elements that correspond a particular realization of the aggregate shock z t+1. This leads to a collection of linear restrictions of dimension #Z for each (z t, η t which have the form b i [ (z t, η t, (z t+1, η t+1 ] σ(z t+1, η t = 0. Passive Traders have only one group so there is no allocation decision, only an overall savings decision, and we will refer to these investors as passive since they do not actively manage their portfolios. Two examples of this class of traders are nonparticipants and fixed-portfolio traders. For nonparticipant traders who can only trade a risk-free bond, σ(z t, η t has dimension 1 and A i (z t is a vector whose elements equal the risk-free rate (1 + r f (z t. This leads to a series of linear restrictions of dimension 1 for each (z t, η t with the form b i [ (z t, η t, (z t+1, η t+1 ] (1 + r f (z t σ(z t, η t = 0. For fixed-portfolio traders whose restrictions imply that they hold a portfolio with fixed values shares of stocks and bonds, then σ(z t, η t has dimension 1 and A i (z t is a vector whose elements equal the state-contingent returns on that portfolio 1 + r p (z t+1. In this case, the restrictions implied by A i (z t take the form b i [ (z t, η t, (z t+1, η t+1 ] (1 + r p (z t+1 σ(z t, η t = 0. For traders who can choose between a risk free bond and stock portfolio, then σ(z t, η t has dimension 2, with the first element being, say, investment in stocks and the second purchases of bonds, and A i (z t is a matrix with two columns where the first column is the stock return 1 + r e (z t+1 for the corresponding aggregate state and the second column is the risk-free rate 1 + r f (z t. Our trader s will also face a net-wealth constraint which puts a lower bound on the value of their financial position at (z t, η t of D i t (zt. This net-wealth constraint constraint plays an important role in the quantitative analysis since 3 To be clear, we can also write this expression as b i [ (z t+1, h t+1 (z t, h t ] = A i (z t+1,h t+1 (zt σ(z t, h t, which is the vector of realized returns for each asset in state ( z t+1, h t+1 times the investment in each the asset, summed up. 8

9 it prevents any type from trading away all of their wealth. Note that since this constraint is on net-wealth it does not directly restricted how negative a trader s bond position can be. 3.5 The Savings Function We will find it convenient to pose the traders problems in terms of feasible consumption sequences { c i (z t, η t }. For that reason, we will define the continuation net savings function. This will allow us to expression our portfolio restrictions and net-wealth restrictions in terms of the continuation consumption allocation. We next define his net savings position and relate that to his feasible net asset values. Denote the continuation net savings out of nontradeable income in state (z t, η t for a trader of type i by S i (z t, η t, where S i (z t, η t = τ t P (z τ, η τ [ γy (z τ η τ c i (z τ, η τ ], (z τ,η τ (z t,η t Since the present-value budget constraint from state (z t, η t onwards is given by S i (z t, η t + b i (z t, η t P (z t, η t = 0. Let Sz i t+1,η t+1 (z t, η t denotes the vector of continuation values conditional on the vector or history states (z t+1, η t+1 (z t, η t. Then our linear restriction on asset positions can be rewritten in terms of net savings. Or Sz i [ t+1,η t+1 (z t, η t ] = [ A i (z t σ(z t, η t ] [ ] Pzt+1,η t+1 (z t, η t. 4 (5 This will allow us to reformulate our trader s problems solely in terms of consumption sequences. 3.6 Trader i s Problem We will exploit the equivalence between the sequential choice problem and the present-value problem to formulate our trader s problem as a time-zero choice problem. Let χ denote the multiplier on the present-value budget constraint. Let ν(z t, η t denote the multiplier on the trader s portfolio restrictions, and let ν zt+1,η t+1 (z t, η t denote the vector on continuation values conditional on the history states (z t+1, η t+1 (z t, η t. Let ϕ(z t, η t denote the multiplier on the debt constraint. With this notation, the saddle point problem of trade i can be stated as: L = max min (β i t u i (c i (z t, η t π i (z t, η t {c i,σ i } {χ,ν,ϕ} t=1 (z t,η t +χ i P (z t, η t [ γy (z t η t c i (z t, η t ] + ϖ(z 0 t 1 (z t,η t + S νz i t,η t (z t 1, η t 1 z i t,η t (z t 1, η t 1 t 1 (z t,η t [ A i (z t 1 σ i (z t 1, η t 1 ] [ ] Pzt,η t (z t 1, η t 1 + { ϕ i (z t, η t D i t(z t P } (z t, η t S i (z t, η t. (6 t 1 (z t,η t 4 The symbol denotes element-by-element multiplication, which will result in each asset position for state (z t+1, h t+1 being multiplied by the present value price P (z t+1, h t+1. 9

10 The first constraint is the standard present-value budget constraint. We start each household out symmetrically by endowing them with an claim to diversifiable wealth by adding the value of this claim, ϖ(z 0, to their net savings from non-diversifiable income. There is no consumption in period 0, however households use this period to transform their claims into those consistent with their trading technology as dictated by their measurability and borrowing constraints. The second constraint is the household s measurability constraint and it dictates that each period the households continuation net savings, and hence it s beginning of period net wealth, be consistent with the realized returns in z t as given by A i (z t 1, and asset investment choices in the prior period σ i (z t 1, η t 1. This asset investment choice is chosen optimally, but its only role is to dictate the how net savings, Sz i t,η t (z t 1, η t 1, can vary across realized states. This is because the present value budget constraint already requires that overall consumption spending be consistent with the household s overall wealth. The final constraint is the borrowing limit which caps the extent to which wealth can be transferred across states by forcing the present value of net savings in that state not to be too high, and hence the net asset position too low. This is a standard convex programming problem the constraint set is still convex, even with the measurability conditions and the solvency constraints. The first order conditions are necessary and sufficient. The first-order condition for consumption is given by βiu t i (c i (z t, η t π i (z t, η t [ χi + ν i (z τ, η τ ϕ i (z τ, η τ ] P (z t, η t = 0. (z τ,η τ (z t,η t This condition is common to all of our traders irrespective of their trading technology because differences in their trading technology does not effect the way in which c(z t, η t enters the objective function or the constraint. However, it does vary depending on their utility function and discount rate. To economize on notation, define the recursive multiplier ζ i (z t, η t = χ i [ + ν i (z τ, η τ ϕ i (z τ, η τ ]. (z τ,η τ (z t,η t Note that this implies that ζ 0 = χ and that ζ evolves over time as follows for all t 1: ζ i (z t, η t = ζ i (z t 1, η t 1 + ν i ( z t, η t ϕ i (z t, η t. (7 Given this notation, we can rewrite this first-order condition for consumption in terms of the state price P (z t as βiθ t t u (c(z t, η t π i (z t, η t = ζ i (z t, η t P (z t π(z t, η t. (8 The first order condition with respect to σ(z t, η t is given by: ν ( z t+1, η t+1 R(z t+1 π(z t+1, η t+1 P (z t+1 = 0, (9 (z t+1,η t+1 (z t,η t where R(z t+1 is the state-contingent return on the asset associated with the particular element of σ(z t, η t. This condition is specific to the trading technology. The recursive rule (7, the two first order conditions, (8 and (9, the measurability condition w.r.t. net savings, (5, and the borrowing constraint written in terms of net savings, determine the updating rule our recursive multiplier. 10

11 3.7 The Reference Consumer, Consumption Shares and Asset Prices We will construct a reference consumer for each household and a mapping from the household s recursive multiplier to a Negishi-type weight for the reference consumer in a static allocation problem that will lead him to consume the same level of consumption as the household given the state prices. These reference consumers will have identical CRRA utility functions, discount rates and beliefs, and will not be subject to preference shocks (i.e. θ t = 1. As a result, we will be able to exploit an aggregation result along the lines of CCL (*. To do so, we first express the reference consumer s consumption share in terms of their Negishi weight and a single moment of the overall weight distribution in that aggregate state z t. Given this, we will be able to derive an expression for the stochastic discount factor that depends only on the aggregate growth rate of output and the updating of this single moment of the weight distribution. We will now construct a series of state allocation problems where the state contingent price of output is P (z t and each agent has CRRA flow utility ū(c, a discount rate β, common beliefs π, and a social planning weight 1/ ζ i (z t, η t. (In an abuse of language, we will refer to ζ i (z t, η t as the social planning weight even through its really it s inverse. The static allocation problem is given by 1 βt ζ i (z t, η t ū( c(zt, η t π(z t, η t P (z t c(z t, η t µ i. i (z t,η t The first-order condition for consumption is then given by β t ( c(z t, η t ᾱ P (z t = ζ(z t, η t, where ᾱ is the CRRA factor for the reference trader. Then, note that if we set ( ζ ζi i (z t, η t (z t, η t P (z t 1/ᾱ ( ζ : β t = u 1 i (z t, η t π(z t, η t P (z t βi t πi (z t, η t, (10 then both the type i trader and the reference consumer with recursive multiplier ζ i (z t, η t would make the same consumption choice. Remark 1 This mapping takes a very simple form in case where u i (c i (z t, η t is CRRA and π(z t, η t = π i (z t, η t. In this case, our mapping rule becomes ( ζi (z t, η t P (z t 1/ᾱ ( ζ i (z t, η t P (z t 1/αi =, β t β t i where α i is the CRRA coefficient for type i. Assume that we constructed the social planning weight for each type of trader as dictated by (10. Then, note that since aggregate consumption is the sum of individual consumptions, it is given by C(z t = ( ζi (z t, η t P (z t 1/ᾱ β t π(z t, η t µ i. i z t,η t 11

12 Note next that the consumption share of the type i reference consumer is given by c i (z t, η t C(z t = = i { z t,η t ( ζi (z t,η t P (z t 1/ᾱ β t ( ζi (z t,η t P (z t β t 1/ᾱ π(zt, η t ζ i (z t, η t 1/ᾱ { ζ }. i z t,η i (z t, η t 1/ᾱ π(z t, η t µ t i } µ i Hence, the consumption share of the consumer is determined solely by the ratio of his social planning weight raised to the 1/ᾱ relative to the average of this ratio in the population. Define this average as ξ(z t = ζi (z t, η t 1/ᾱ π(z t, η t µ i. (11 i z t,η t type Assume that we had constructed the reference multipliers at all dates and states, and note that for each reference β (ci (z t+1,η t+1 ᾱ P (z t+1 (c i (z t,η t ᾱ P (z t = ζ i (z t+1, η t+1. ζ i (z t, η t If we substitute in for consumption using the prior result on consumption shares, we get that which simplifies to This leads to the following proposition. β ( ζi (z t+1,η t+1 1/α ᾱ ξ(z t+1 C(z t+1 P (z t ( ζi (z t,η t 1/α ᾱ ξ(z t C(z t P (z t P (z t+1 P (z t = β ( ξ(z t+1 ξ(z t = ζ i (z t+1, η t+1, ζ i (z t, η t ᾱ ( C(z t+1 ᾱ C(z t. (12 Proposition 2 Relative state prices in this economy are determined by the growth rate of aggregate consumption and the 1/ᾱ population average of the reference social planning weight. This result implies that we can think of the equilibrium of our economy in terms of a simple fixed point. If Ξ(z t+1 = ξ(z t+1 /ξ(z t+1 is the updating rule for the 1/ᾱ population average of the reference recursive multiplier, then prices are given by (12 and, when we construct the updating rule for ζ i (z t, η t and thereby for ζ i (z t, η t, the resulting values of must satisfy (11 ζi (z t, η t 1/α π(z t, η t µ i i z t,η t 12

13 3.8 Computational Algorithm Here we discuss how to construct a computational algorithm to compute an equilibrium of our model. To keep things simple, we will assume preferences are CRRA (through they may different in terms of their degree of risk aversion. Note that agent s beliefs only differ with respect to the aggregate state s evolution. The algorithm has two major steps. First, a low of motion for the updating of the multiplier moment, Ξ(z t+1 = ξ(z t+1 /ξ(z t+1, is posited. Note that this updating rule is w.r.t. the cross-sectional moment of the reference traders. Given this updating rule, we can determine relative state prices Q(z t+1 = P (z t+1 /P (z t using (12. Second, we solve for the household s savings function and multiplier updating rule for the standard traders. Third, we map the sequences of household multipliers into the implied sequences of reference trader s multipliers and compute the implied updating rule for their multiplier moment. Fourth we compare our original guess of Ξ(z t+1 to its realized value: if they are the same, we have an equilibrium and if not we need to iterate on Ξ(z t+1 in some fashion. where To describe step 2 in more detail note that we can recursively represent the savings functions as S i (ζ, η t, z t = [ γη t Y (z t c i (ζ, z t ] + β z t+1 z t η t+1 S i (ζ t+1 (z t+1, η t+1, η t+1, z t+1 Q(z t+1 π ( z t+1 z t, βiu t (c i (ζ, z t πi (z t, η t π(z t, η t = ζp (z0 Q(z τ. z τ z t To close the system we need to specify how the household s recursive multiplier ζ is updated. In addition, there is an initial degree of freedom in the choice of P (z 0 which is chosen to clear the first period consumption market. In addition, updating of the individual s multiplier ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1, ζ i t+1(z t+1, η t+1 = ζ i t + ν i (z t+1, η t+1 ϕ i (z t+1, η t+1 must be consistent with our (i saving s measurability condition (5, (ii debt bound, and (iii optimality condition (9. To satisfy (i and (ii, there must exist σ i (z t, η t Sz i t+1,η t+1 (ζ t+1 (z t+1, η t+1, z t = [ A i (z t σ i (z t, η t ] [ ] Pzt+1,η (zt t+1, η t, (where S i z t+1,η t+1 (ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1, z t is a conditional vector and vector and ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1 is understood to vary with this conditioning and To satisfy (iii it must be the case that D i t+1 (zt+1 P (z t+1, η t+1 S i (ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1, η t+1, z t+1 0. (z t+1,η t+1 (z t,η t if the debt bound does not bind and [ ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1 ζt i ] R(z t+1 π(z t+1, η t+1 P (z t+1 = 0 ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1 = ζ i t + ν i ( z t+1, η t+1. 13

14 Whereas, if the debt bound binds, then ζ i t+1 (z t+1, η t+1 must be such as to satisfy the bound and the debt bound multiplier ϕ i (z t+1, η t+1 and ν i ( z t+1, η t+1 are chosen so that the updating rule and (9 are jointly satisfied. The outcome of step 2 is an operator T i (ζ t, η t, z t = ζ t+1 (z t+1, η t+1, ζ which given the law of motion for the recursive multiplier ζ for a household of type i. In step 3 we compute the implied sequence of multipliers { ζt(z i t, η t } for each of our types. We then use t=0 our mapping rule (10 to map these sequences into sequences of multipliers for our reference traders { ζi t (z t, η t } t=0. Then we can compute the implied values of the key moment of the distribution in each state (z t, η t using (11, and thereby complete step 3 by computing the implied value of Ξ(z t+1 = ξ(z t+1 /ξ(z t+1. This computation is made much easier by first stationarizing the economy, and second making a key assumption. The law of motion Ξ(z t+1 depends in principal upon the either history z t+1. However, we have found that a sufficiently long but finite history allows one to compute the equilibrium with a very high degree of accuracy. Let j denote the length of the utilized history and let z Z j denote an element of these j-period histories. Then the moment updating and relative state prices - Ξ(z, z and Q(z, z - are simply functions of the history transition. In addition, the saving function S i (ζ, η, z and multiplier updating rule T i (ζ, η, z are functions of the aggregate history state, the current idiosyncratic shock and the recursive multiplier ζ. Hence, computing them amounts to a simple fixed point operation. Given all this, our algorithm works by first positing Ξ 0 (z, z for all z, z Z j and Pr(z z > 0 (i.e. positive probability history transitions. Then it works as follows: { 1. Draw a long sample of aggregate shocks {z t } and a corresponding large panel of idiosyncratic shocks where i corresponds to the trader s type and j distinguishes among traders of a given type. The proportions of trader types is determined by µ i. Construct the implied history state sequence from {z t } from {z t }. 2. Construct the sequence of relative prices Q 0 (z, z for each positive probability finite history transition using Ξ 0 (z, z and the pricing rule ( For each type i, use the stationary first-order conditions and savings function S i (ζ, z, η t, θ t, along with the budget constraint and measurability conditions to construct the transition rule for their recursive multiplier T : ζ = T i (z, z, η, ζ. With recursive preferences both the recursive savings function and the appropriate ratio of future utility to expect future utility must be constructed. M(z, z, η, ζ. 4. Use T i (z, z, η, ζ and (10 to construct the implies sequence of reference recursive multiplier η ij t } { ζij } t for panel. Note that at point we normalize these reference multipliers so that the consumption shares average one, and the ratio of the actual consumption share average and one is a natural measure of the allocation error (and hence of the accuracy of our approximation. 5. Construct the panel of implied reference recursive multiplier and use them to estimate Ξ n+1 (z, z. If z takes on a small set of values this can be done using simple conditional means. 14

15 6. If the accuracy is high and Ξ n+1 (z, z Ξ n (z, z is small stop. Otherwise return to step 2 with a new guess for Ξ. 3.9 Calibration of Economy The baseline model is calibrated to annual data. We set the value of the coefficient of relative risk aversion α to five and the time discount factor β to.95. These preference parameters allow us to match the collateralizable wealth to income ratio in the data when the tradeable or collateralizable income share 1 γ is 10%, as discussed below. The average ratio of household wealth to aggregate income in the US is 4.30 between 1950 and The wealth measure is total net wealth of households and non-profit organizations (Flow of Funds Tables. With a 10% collateralizable income share, the implied ratio of wealth to consumption is 5.28 in the model s benchmark calibration. 5 Our benchmark model is calibrated to match the aggregate consumption growth moments from AlvarezJ01. The average consumption growth rate is 1.8% and the standard deviation is 3.16%. These are the moments of U.S. per capita aggregate consumption between used in MP85 s seminal paper. Recessions are less frequent than expansions: 27% of realizations are low aggregate consumption growth states. The first-order autocorrelation coefficient of aggregate consumption growth (ρ z is set to zero so all propagation is internally generated. Consequently, aggregate consumption growth is identically and independently distributed over time: π(z z = π(z. The elements of the discretized process for z are {0.9602, }. We calibrate the labor income process as in STY06, except that we eliminate the counter-cyclical variation (CCV of labor income risk. Hence, the variance of labor income risk is constant in our model. The Markov process for the log of the labor income share log η has a standard deviation of 0.71, and its autocorrelation is We use a 4-state discretization for both aggregate and idiosyncratic risk. The elements of the discretized process for η are {0.3894, }. Equity in our model is simply a leveraged claim to diversifiable income. In the Flow of Funds, the ratio of corporate debt-to-net worth is around 0.65, suggesting a leverage parameter ψ of 2. However, lam90 report that the standard deviation of the growth rate of dividends is at least 3.6 times that of aggregate consumption, suggesting that the appropriate leverage level is over 3. Following abel:99 and bansal-yaron:04, we choose to set the leverage parameter ψ to 3. We set the debt bound at zero meaning that households cannot borrow against their idiosyncratic income. We consider three types of trading technologies that can be easily ranked in terms of their sophistication. The first and most sophisticated are aggregate-complete active traders who can trade Arrow bonds conditional on aggregate growth shocks as well as equity and risk-free debt claims. The second and least sophisticated are nonparticipants - i.e. passive traders who hold only risk-free bonds. The third technology is that of the disversified traders who hold debt and equity claims in the same fixed proportion as the exist in the market. These traders are following 5 As is standard in this literature, we compare the ratio of total outside wealth to aggregate non-durable consumption in our endowment economy to the ratio of total tradeable wealth to aggregate income in the data. consumption because of durable consumption and investment. Aggregate income exceeds aggregate non-durable 15

16 the standard advice of holding the market and will earn a higher return than the nonparticipants to the extent that the economy exhibits and equity premium, which it will. That is why we rank the sophistication of their trading technology in the middle between the other two. In the most recent Survey of Consumer Finances, 51.1% of households reported owning stocks directly or indirectly. Therefore, the fraction of passive traders with zero equity holding (non-participants is calibrated to 50%. In order to deliver a large equity premium, a small fraction of active traders need to bear the residual aggregate risk created by non-participant. We set the share of active traders equal to 10%. We set the share of passive traders who hold both equities and debt to 40%, and had them hold these claims in the same proportion as the market. Note here that these shares represent fractions of total human wealth (i.e. nondiversifiable wealth, not financial wealth, owned by each trader type Baseline Results We begin by computing the equilibrium outcomes for our baseline economy. In this benchmark all of our traders have common preferences CRRA preferences and beliefs, and households differ only with respect to their asset trading technologies. The average value of the market price of risk (MPR of 0.40 and the risk-free rate of 1.9% are very close to what financial economists estimate as being in the data. The low volatility of the risk-free also accords well with the data. Figure 3, shows a plot of the Sharpe ratio for our equity asset for a fix interval from the simulation panel, indicates that the Sharpe ratio (and the MPR are counter-cyclical, as they are in the data. However, the volatility of the MPR is much lower than the is commonly estimated. As one would expect, the active traders have the most sophisticated trading technology and earn the highest return on their investments and have an excess return of 4.8%. The diversified traders have an excess return of 1.5%, while the nonparticipants, with the least sophisticated trading technology by construction have an excess return of 0. The active traders have a much more volatile excess return - the standard deviation of their excess return is 11.8 while that of the diversified traders is Because of the homogeneity of the investor s optimization problem, we can reallocate human wealth within each trader pool without affecting equilibrium asset prices. 16

17 σ(m E(m Table X: Baseline Results Std( σt(m E t(m E(R f σ(r f E(R W z R f E(R W div R f E(R W z R f σ(r W z R f E(R W z R f σ(r W z R f E (W z /W σ (W z /W E (ω z σ (ω z corr (ω z, SR σ( log(c z σ( log(c σ ( log (C z %error E(W div /W σ(w div /W E(W np /W σ(w np /W σ( log(c div σ( log(c σ ( log (C div σ( log(c np σ( log(c σ ( log (C np The active traders achieve their high and volatile returns by heavily investing in risk assets, with equities making up 80% of their portfolios on average. Moreover, their equity exposure is very tightly connected to cyclical fluctuations in the pricing of risk, and as a result the correlation of their equity share and the Sharpe ratio on equities is roughly 1. The diversified traders hold the market and hence earn the risk-return trade-off offered by the market. Both the active and diversified traders have an average Sharpe ratio on their investments of For the diversified traders they hold the portfolio offered by the market and simply earn the implied return. In contrast, the active traders are loading up on aggregate risk when expected excess returns are high, but since this is also when the variance of excess returns are high, these two factors offset and they end up achieving the same risk-return trade-off as the diversified traders. The differences in investment returns impacts on the wealth distribution. The active traders have more than twice as much wealth per capita as the average individual. The diversified traders average wealth level is equal to average per capita wealth, while the nonparticipants on average have only 84% of per capita wealth. We report the standard deviation of the group wealth ratio because this averages out idiosyncratic risk. It is highest for the active traders as a group indicating that they have the most exposure to aggregate risk. Both the diversified and the nonparticipants have much lower wealth standard deviation; 0.03 and 0.10 respectively. In terms of consumption, the agents with the most sophisticated trading technology have the lowest standard deviation of the consumption growth, while those with the least sophisticated technology have the highest. The ratio of the standard deviation of individual consumption growth to aggregate consumption growth is 3.0 for the active traders, 3.4 for the diversified traders and 3.6 for the nonparticipants respectively. However, when look at the volatility of average consumption for these groups, the results are reversed. This is because the averaging removes the impact idiosyncratic income shocks and thereby reveals that the agents with the more sophisticated trading technology are using this technology to take on more aggregate risk. 17

18 Figure 4 shows several plots of the dynamics of our economy for a fixed 100 period simulation interval. Low aggregate growth rate realizations are in the grey shaded panes. The first pane illustrates the cyclical volatility of the Sharpe ratio on equities and the high degree to which it is countercyclical, as it is in the data. The second and third panels in figure 4 show plots of the average equity share and the average wealth-to-per-capita wealth for the active traders for our fixed simulation interval. It indicates that both the average equity exposure is counter-cyclical while the wealth ratio is procyclical. These plots indicate the fundamental dynamics that are driving asset pricing in our baseline economy. The active traders absorb the aggregate risk created by having investors who hold low risk assets. They do this by holding large amounts of the equity claims and low amounts of risk-free debt. At certain points their average holdings are greater than 100%, indicating that they are shorting the risk-free security in order to meet its demand. At the same time, high realizations of the aggregate growth rate shock lead them to become relative rich, while low realizations lead to the reverse. When they are relatively poor, the active traders are induced to hold large amounts of equity by a high Sharpe ratio. These fluctuations in the relative wealth of the active traders and the resulting price they demand in order to bear the amount of aggregate risk being pushed at them by the market leads to the aggregate dynamics in the model. If all of our traders were either active traders or passive traders who held the market, then their would be no dynamics in the startionarized economy. As a result, each group would simply hold the market in their portfolios and have a constant and identical consumption share. These outcomes we report are very similar to results reported in our earlier work; in particular CCL (2011, where we discuss them in greater detail. 4 Volatile Aggregate Belief Traders 4.1 Definition A natural issue with respect to forming beliefs about the aggregates shock is how much to rely on the full time series history. This is because it is unclear how strong a stationarity assumption to impose and statistically it can be hard to determine whether and when a structural break in a time series has occurred. In forecasting models it is common practice to allow for the possibility of structural breaks by (i allowing for a moving window in the estimation, (ii allowing explicitly for parameter drift, or (iii down weighting older observations (See Clements and Hendrey Forecasting with Breaks, Handbook of Forecasting Procedures such as these will lead to parameter estimates that are more responsive to recent data than to older data, and suggest that this greater responsiveness can have a rational basis. We therefore allow for some traders who put more weight recent data, through the following beliefs. Definition 3 A trader with volatile beliefs believes with probability κ the current aggregate transition z t z t+1 is governed by π (z t+1 z t and with probability 1 κ it is governed by a new Markov transition matrix about which he has a uninformative prior. Conditional on a shift in the transition matrix occurring, his best estimate of the new 18

Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due. to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? Web Appendix

Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due. to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? Web Appendix Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? Web Appendix YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania October 4, 2011 Hanno Lustig UCLA

More information

Macro Implications of Household Finance

Macro Implications of Household Finance Introduction Model Solution Results Conclusion Appendix Macro Implications of YiLi Chien, Harold Cole and Hanno Lustig Purdue, University of Pennsylvania and UCLA November 3, 2008 Introduction Model Solution

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series The Cost of Business Cycles with Heterogeneous Trading Technologies YiLi Chien Working Paper 2014-015A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2014/2014-015.pdf

More information

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania January 29, 2008 Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Abstract

More information

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania December 15, 2007 Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Abstract

More information

MACRO IMPLICATIONS OF HOUSEHOLD FINANCE Preliminary and Incomplete

MACRO IMPLICATIONS OF HOUSEHOLD FINANCE Preliminary and Incomplete MACRO IMPLICATIONS OF HOUSEHOLD FINANCE Preliminary and Incomplete YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania May 15, 2007 Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Abstract Our paper examines

More information

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania Hanno Lustig UCLA Anderson School of Management and

More information

SED Seoul Korea Harold Cole. July 10, 2013

SED Seoul Korea Harold Cole. July 10, 2013 SED Seoul Korea 2013 Harold Cole July 10, 2013 Impact of Portfolio Behavior on the Macroeconomy New Micro Finance literature has data on portfolio behavior Finds that many households don t invest as our

More information

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance

A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance A Multiplier Approach to Understanding the Macro Implications of Household Finance YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania Hanno Lustig UCLA Anderson School of Management and

More information

Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints

Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints Appendix to: Long-Run Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh June 27, 2006 Additional Figures and Tables Calibration of Expenditure

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Appendix to: Quantitative Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints

Appendix to: Quantitative Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints Appendix to: Quantitative Asset Pricing Implications of Housing Collateral Constraints Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh December 5, 2005 1 Additional Figures and Tables Calibration of

More information

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) A stochastic discount factor is a stochastic process {M t,t+s } such that

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Slides III - Complete Markets

Slides III - Complete Markets Slides III - Complete Markets Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides III - Complete Markets Spring 2017 1 / 33 Outline 1. Risk, Uncertainty,

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing?

Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania Hanno Lustig UCLA Anderson School of Management

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 60 minutes Part B (Prof. Barro): 60

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due. to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing?

Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due. to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? Is the Volatility of the Market Price of Risk due to Intermittent Portfolio Re-balancing? YiLi Chien Purdue University Harold Cole University of Pennsylvania May 14, 2010 Hanno Lustig UCLA Anderson Abstract

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix Jerry Tsai University of Oxford Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 12, 2014 and NBER A The iid model This section

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Homework 3: Asset Pricing Homework 3: Asset Pricing Mohammad Hossein Rahmati November 1, 2018 1. Consider an economy with a single representative consumer who maximize E β t u(c t ) 0 < β < 1, u(c t ) = ln(c t + α) t= The sole

More information

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Consumption and Asset Pricing Consumption and Asset Pricing Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Williamson s lecture notes (2006) ch5 and ch 6 Further references: Stochastic dynamic programming:

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification Part 1) Working through a complete markets case - In the previous lecture, I claimed that assuming complete asset markets produced a perfect-pooling

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing Economics 714, Spring 2018 1 Asset Pricing 1.1 Lucas (1978) Asset Pricing Model We assume that there are a large number of identical agents, modeled as a representative

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis Thiên T. Nguyễn Introduction Motivation Motivation Key regulatory reform: Bank capital requirements 1 Introduction Motivation Motivation Key regulatory

More information

The Market Price of Aggregate Risk and the Wealth Distribution

The Market Price of Aggregate Risk and the Wealth Distribution The Market Price of Aggregate Risk and the Wealth Distribution Hanno Lustig UCLA January 9, 2007 Abstract I introduce bankruptcy into a complete markets model with a continuum of ex ante identical agents

More information

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California and CEPR November 10, 2017 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract Low interest rates may stimulate

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles : A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles, JF (2004) Presented by: Esben Hedegaard NYUStern October 12, 2009 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Long-Run Risk Solving the 3 Data and Calibration Results

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function: Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function: β t log(c t ), where C t is consumption and the parameter β satisfies

More information

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Log-Robust Portfolio Management Log-Robust Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Elcin Cetinkaya and Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983 Dr.

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology FE570 Financial Markets and Trading Lecture 6. Volatility Models and (Ref. Joel Hasbrouck - Empirical Market Microstructure ) Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 10/02/2012 Outline 1 Volatility

More information

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Andrea Prestipino NYU, Princeton, Federal Reserve Board 1 September 218 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the

More information

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete R. Anton Braun Tomoyuki Nakajima 2 University of Tokyo, and CREI 2 Kyoto University, and RIETI December 9, 28 Outline Introduction 2 Model Individuals

More information

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis 1/18 : estimation and model analysis, EDHEC Business School (joint work with Rama COT) Modeling and managing financial risks Paris, 10 13 January 2011 2/18 Outline 1 2 of multi-asset models Solution to

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Dean Corbae Pablo D Erasmo 1 Univ. of Wisconsin FRB Philadelphia June 12, 2014 1 The views expressed here do not necessarily

More information

Asset Pricing with Endogenously Uninsurable Tail Risks. University of Minnesota

Asset Pricing with Endogenously Uninsurable Tail Risks. University of Minnesota Asset Pricing with Endogenously Uninsurable Tail Risks Hengjie Ai Anmol Bhandari University of Minnesota asset pricing with uninsurable idiosyncratic risks Challenges for asset pricing models generate

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008)

Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Backus, Routledge, & Zin Notes on Epstein-Zin Asset Pricing (Draft: October 30, 2004; Revised: June 12, 2008) Asset pricing with Kreps-Porteus preferences, starting with theoretical results from Epstein

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series The Risk Premium and Long-Run Global Imbalances YiLi Chien And Kanda Naknoi Working Paper 2012-009C http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2012/2012-009.pdf

More information

Balance Sheet Recessions

Balance Sheet Recessions Balance Sheet Recessions Zhen Huo and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis CAERP CEPR NBER Conference on Money Credit and Financial Frictions Huo & Ríos-Rull

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia? Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia? Fiscal Limits and Default Risk Premia for Slovakia Moderné nástroje pre finančnú analýzu a modelovanie Zuzana Múčka June 15, 2015 Introduction Aims

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values P O. C Department of Finance Copenhagen Business School, Denmark H F Department of Accounting

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Portfolio Investment

Portfolio Investment Portfolio Investment Robert A. Miller Tepper School of Business CMU 45-871 Lecture 5 Miller (Tepper School of Business CMU) Portfolio Investment 45-871 Lecture 5 1 / 22 Simplifying the framework for analysis

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern.

Introduction Model Results Conclusion Discussion. The Value Premium. Zhang, JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern. , JF 2005 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 13, 2009 Outline 1 Motivation Production-Based Asset Pricing Framework 2 Assumptions Firm s Problem Equilibrium 3 Main Findings Mechanism Testable

More information

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model Chapter Portfolio Selection The theory of option pricing is a theory of deterministic returns: we hedge our option with the underlying to eliminate risk, and our resulting risk-free portfolio then earns

More information

Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints

Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints David Laibson 9/11/2014 Outline: 1. Precautionary savings motives 2. Liquidity constraints 3. Application: Numerical solution

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Virginia Olivella and Jose Ignacio Lopez October 2008 Motivation Menu costs and repricing decisions Micro foundation of sticky

More information

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default Satyajit Chatterjee Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Makoto Nakajima University of Pennsylvania Dean Corbae University of Pittsburgh

More information

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints 1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints In this section we study conditions under which savings react to changes in income uncertainty. Recall that in the PIH, when you abstract from

More information

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption Problem Set 3 Thomas Philippon April 19, 2002 1 Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption The goal of the question is to derive the formulas on p13 of Topic 2. This is a partial equilibrium analysis

More information

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis A. Buss B. Dumas R. Uppal G. Vilkov INSEAD INSEAD, CEPR, NBER Edhec, CEPR Goethe U. Frankfurt

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication. Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

More information

Margin Regulation and Volatility

Margin Regulation and Volatility Margin Regulation and Volatility Johannes Brumm 1 Michael Grill 2 Felix Kubler 3 Karl Schmedders 3 1 University of Zurich 2 European Central Bank 3 University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute Macroeconomic

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs Viktor Tsyrennikov Preliminary and Incomplete February 28, 2006 Abstract This works aims analyzes market survival of agents with incorrect beliefs.

More information

Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles

Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles Model of Zhang, L., 2005, The Value Premium, JF. Discrete time Operating leverage Asymmetric quadratic adjustment costs Counter-cyclical price of risk Algorithm

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982 Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982 Contribution Integrates domestic and international monetary theory with financial economics to provide a complete theory

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences Petr Zemčík CERGE-EI April 2005 1 Mean Reversion Equity returns display negative serial correlation at horizons longer than one year.

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8 Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8 1 Cagan Model of Money Demand 1.1 Money Demand Demand for real money balances ( M P ) depends negatively on expected inflation In logs m d t p t =

More information

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2013 *********************************************** COVER SHEET ***********************************************

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Evaluating Asset Pricing Models with Limited Commitment using Household Consumption Data 1

Evaluating Asset Pricing Models with Limited Commitment using Household Consumption Data 1 Evaluating Asset Pricing Models with Limited Commitment using Household Consumption Data 1 Dirk Krueger University of Pennsylvania, CEPR and NBER Hanno Lustig UCLA and NBER Fabrizio Perri University of

More information

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II Chao Wei Department of Economics George Washington University Washington, DC 20052 January 2007 1 1 Deterministic Dynamic Programming Below I describe a typical dynamic

More information